Economics: Principles and Policy, 11th Edition

  • 60 1,408 6
  • Like this paper and download? You can publish your own PDF file online for free in a few minutes! Sign Up

Economics: Principles and Policy, 11th Edition

ECONOMICS Principles and Policy Eleventh Edition 2010 Update William J. Baumol New York University and Princeton Univer

4,072 762 18MB

Pages 846 Page size 625.92 x 801.12 pts Year 2010

Report DMCA / Copyright

DOWNLOAD FILE

Recommend Papers

File loading please wait...
Citation preview

ECONOMICS Principles and Policy Eleventh Edition 2010 Update

William J. Baumol New York University and Princeton University

Alan S. Blinder Princeton University

Australia • Brazil • Japan • Korea • Mexico • Singapore • Spain • United Kingdom • United States

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Economics: Principles and Policy, Eleventh Edition 2010 Update William J. Baumol, Alan S. Blinder VP Editorial Director: Jack W. Calhoun Publisher: Joe Sabatino Executive Editor: Michael Worls Supervising Developmental Editor: Katie Yanos Editorial Assistant: Lena Mortis Senior Marketing Manager: John Carey Senior Marketing Communications Manager: Sarah Greber Marketing Coordinator: Suellen Ruttkay Media Editor: Deepak Kumar Director, Content and Media Production: Barbara Fuller Jacobsen Content Project Manager: Emily Nesheim Senior Frontlist Buyer, Manufacturing: Sandee Milewski Production Service: Pre-PressPMG Senior Art Director: Michelle Kunkler Cover and Internal Designer: Lisa Albonetti Cover Images: © Getty Images; © First Light Associated Photographers, Inc. Senior Rights Acquisitions Account Manager, Text: Mardell Glinski Schultz Text Permissions Researcher: Sue Howard

© 2011, 2009 South-Western, Cengage Learning ALL RIGHTS RESERVED. No part of this work covered by the copyright herein may be reproduced, transmitted, stored, or used in any form or by any means graphic, electronic, or mechanical, including but not limited to photocopying, recording, scanning, digitizing, taping, web distribution, information networks, or information storage and retrieval systems, except as permitted under Section 107 or 108 of the 1976 United States Copyright Act, without the prior written permission of the publisher. For product information and technology assistance, contact us at Cengage Learning Customer & Sales Support, 1-800-354-9706 For permission to use material from this text or product, submit all requests online at www.cengage.com/permissions Further permissions questions can be emailed to [email protected]

ExamView® is a registered trademark of eInstruction Corp. Windows is a registered trademark of the Microsoft Corporation used herein under license. Macintosh and Power Macintosh are registered trademarks of Apple Computer, Inc. used herein under license. © 2008 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. Library of Congress Control Number: 2010923646 ISBN-13: 9781439039120 ISBN-10: 1-4390-3912-7 South-Western Cengage Learning 5191 Natorp Boulevard Mason, OH 45040 USA

Senior Rights Acquisitions Account Manager, Images: Deanna Ettinger

Cengage Learning products are represented in Canada by Nelson Education, Ltd.

Images Permissions Researcher: Scott Rosen, Bill Smith Group

For your course and learning solutions, visit www.cengage.com Purchase any of our products at your local college store or at our preferred online store www.cengagebrain.com

Printed in the United States of America 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 14 13 12 11 10

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

To Sue Anne Batey Blackman: wise, beloved, and irreplaceable.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Brief Contents Preface xxvii About the Authors xxxi

PART 1

GETTING ACQUAINTED WITH ECONOMICS Chapter Chapter Chapter Chapter

PART 2

THE BUILDING BLOCKS OF DEMAND AND SUPPLY Chapter Chapter Chapter Chapter Chapter

PART 3

Consumer Choice: Individual and Market Demand 83 Demand and Elasticity 107 Production, Inputs, and Cost: Building Blocks for Supply Analysis 127 Output, Price, and Profit: The Importance of Marginal Analysis 155 Investing in Business: Stocks and Bonds 177

10 11 12 13

The Firm and the Industry under Perfect Competition 197 Monopoly 217 Between Competition and Monopoly 235 Limiting Market Power: Regulation and Antitrust 263

THE VIRTUES AND LIMITATIONS OF MARKETS Chapter Chapter Chapter Chapter Chapter

PART 5

5 6 7 8 9

MARKETS AND THE PRICE SYSTEM Chapter Chapter Chapter Chapter

PART 4

1 What Is Economics? 3 2 The Economy: Myth and Reality 21 3 The Fundamental Economic Problem: Scarcity and Choice 39 4 Supply and Demand: An Initial Look 55

14 15 16 17 18

The Case for Free Markets I: The Price System 287 The Shortcomings of Free Markets 309 The Market’s Prime Achievement: Innovation and Growth 333 Externalities, the Environment, and Natural Resources 355 Taxation and Resource Allocation 377

THE DISTRIBUTION OF INCOME Chapter 19 Pricing the Factors of Production 397 Chapter 20 Labor and Entrepreneurship: The Human Inputs 419 Chapter 21 Poverty, Inequality, and Discrimination 445

v

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

vi

Brief Contents

PART 6

THE MACROECONOMY: AGGREGATE SUPPLY AND DEMAND Chapter Chapter Chapter Chapter Chapter Chapter

PART 7

22 23 24 25 26 27

An Introduction to Macroeconomics 467 The Goals of Macroeconomic Policy 489 Economic Growth: Theory and Policy 517 Aggregate Demand and the Powerful Consumer 537 Demand-Side Equilibrium: Unemployment or Inflation? 559 Bringing in the Supply Side: Unemployment and Inflation? 583

FISCAL AND MONETARY POLICY Chapter Chapter Chapter Chapter Chapter Chapter

PART 8

28 29 30 31 32 33

Managing Aggregate Demand: Fiscal Policy 605 Money and the Banking System 625 Managing Aggregate Demand: Monetary Policy 645 The Debate over Monetary and Fiscal Policy 661 Budget Deficits in the Short and Long Run 683 The Trade-Off between Inflation and Unemployment 701

THE UNITED STATES IN THE WORLD ECONOMY Chapter 34 International Trade and Comparative Advantage 723 Chapter 35 The International Monetary System:Order or Disorder? 745 Chapter 36 Exchange Rates and the Macroeconomy 763

PART 9

POSTSCRIPT: THE FINANCIAL CRISIS OF 2007–2009 Chapter 37 The Financial Crisis and the Great Recession 779

| APPENDIX | Answers to Odd-Numbered Test Yourself Questions 795

Glossary 813 Index 825

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Table of Contents Preface xxvii About the Authors xxxi

PART 1

GETTING ACQUAINTED WITH ECONOMICS 1

Chapter 1

What Is Economics? 3

IDEAS FOR BEYOND THE FINAL EXAM 4 Idea 1: How Much Does It Really Cost? 4 Idea 2: Attempts to Repeal the Laws of Supply and Demand—The Market Strikes Back 5 Idea 3: The Surprising Principle of Comparative Advantage 5 Idea 4: Trade Is a Win–Win Situation 5 Idea 5: The Importance of Thinking at the Margin 6 Idea 6: Externalities—A Shortcoming of the Market Cured by Market Methods 6 Idea 7: The Trade-Off between Efficiency and Equality 7 Idea 8: Government Policies Can Limit Economic Fluctuations—But Don’t Always Succeed 7 Idea 9: The Short-Run Trade-Off between Inflation and Unemployment 7 Idea 10: Productivity Growth Is (Almost) Everything in the Long Run 8 Epilogue 8

INSIDE THE ECONOMIST’S TOOL KIT 8 Economics as a Discipline 8 The Need for Abstraction 8 The Role of Economic Theory 11 What Is an Economic Model? 12 Reasons for Disagreements: Imperfect Information and Value Judgments 12 Summary 13 Key Terms 14 Discussion Questions 14

| APPENDIX | Using Graphs: A Review 14 GRAPHS USED IN ECONOMIC ANALYSIS 14 TWO-VARIABLE DIAGRAMS 14 THE DEFINITION AND MEASUREMENT OF SLOPE 15 RAYS THROUGH THE ORIGIN AND 45° LINES 17 SQUEEZING THREE DIMENSIONS INTO TWO: CONTOUR MAPS 18 Summary 19 Key Terms 19 Test Yourself 20

Chapter 2

The Economy: Myth and Reality 21

THE AMERICAN ECONOMY: A THUMBNAIL SKETCH 22 A Private-Enterprise Economy 23 A Relatively “Closed” Economy 23 A Growing Economy . . . 24 But with Bumps along the Growth Path 24

THE INPUTS: LABOR AND CAPITAL 26 The American Workforce: Who Is in It? 27 The American Workforce: What Does It Do? 28 The American Workforce: What It Earns 29 Capital and Its Earnings 30

THE OUTPUTS: WHAT DOES AMERICA PRODUCE? 30 THE CENTRAL ROLE OF BUSINESS FIRMS 31 Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

vii

viii

Contents

WHAT’S MISSING FROM THE PICTURE? GOVERNMENT 32 The Government as Referee 33 The Government as Business Regulator 33 Government Expenditures 34 Taxes in America 35 The Government as Redistributor 35

CONCLUSION: IT’S A MIXED ECONOMY 36 Summary 36 Key Terms 36 Discussion Questions 37

Chapter 3

The Fundamental Economic Problem: Scarcity and Choice 39

ISSUE: WHAT TO DO ABOUT THE BUDGET DEFICIT? 40

SCARCITY, CHOICE, AND OPPORTUNITY COST 40 Opportunity Cost and Money Cost 41 Optimal Choice: Not Just Any Choice 42

SCARCITY AND CHOICE FOR A SINGLE FIRM 42 The Production Possibilities Frontier 43 The Principle of Increasing Costs 44

SCARCITY AND CHOICE FOR THE ENTIRE SOCIETY 45 Scarcity and Choice Elsewhere in the Economy 45

ISSUE REVISITED: COPING WITH THE BUDGET DEFICIT 46

THE CONCEPT OF EFFICIENCY 46 THE THREE COORDINATION TASKS OF ANY ECONOMY 47 TASK 1. HOW THE MARKET FOSTERS EFFICIENT RESOURCE ALLOCATION 48 The Wonders of the Division of Labor 48 The Amazing Principle of Comparative Advantage 49

TASK 2. MARKET EXCHANGE AND DECIDING HOW MUCH OF EACH GOOD TO PRODUCE 50 TASK 3. HOW TO DISTRIBUTE THE ECONOMY’S OUTPUTS AMONG CONSUMERS 50 Summary 52 Key Terms 53 Test Yourself 53 Discussion Questions 53

Chapter 4

Supply and Demand: An Initial Look

55

PUZZLE: WHAT HAPPENED TO OIL PRICES? 56

THE INVISIBLE HAND 56 DEMAND AND QUANTITY DEMANDED 57 The Demand Schedule 58 The Demand Curve 58 Shifts of the Demand Curve 58

SUPPLY AND QUANTITY SUPPLIED 61 The Supply Schedule and the Supply Curve 61 Shifts of the Supply Curve 62

SUPPLY AND DEMAND EQUILIBRIUM 64 The Law of Supply and Demand 66

EFFECTS OF DEMAND SHIFTS ON SUPPLY-DEMAND EQUILIBRIUM 66 SUPPLY SHIFTS AND SUPPLY-DEMAND EQUILIBRIUM 67 PUZZLE RESOLVED: THOSE LEAPING OIL PRICES 68 Application: Who Really Pays That Tax? 69

BATTLING THE INVISIBLE HAND: THE MARKET FIGHTS BACK 70 Restraining the Market Mechanism: Price Ceilings 70 Case Study: Rent Controls in New York City 72 Restraining the Market Mechanism: Price Floors 73

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Contents

Case Study: Farm Price Supports and the Case of Sugar Prices 73 A Can of Worms 74

A SIMPLE BUT POWERFUL LESSON 76 Summary 76 Key Terms 77 Test Yourself 77 Discussion Questions 78

PART 2

THE BUILDING BLOCKS OF DEMAND AND SUPPLY 81

Chapter 5

Consumer Choice: Individual and Market Demand 83

PUZZLE: WHY SHOULDN’T WATER BE WORTH MORE THAN DIAMONDS? 84

SCARCITY AND DEMAND 84 UTILITY: A TOOL TO ANALYZE PURCHASE DECISIONS 85 The Purpose of Utility Analysis: Analyzing How People Behave, Not What They Think 85 Total versus Marginal Utility 86 The “Law” of Diminishing Marginal Utility 86 Using Marginal Utility: The Optimal Purchase Rule 87 From Diminishing Marginal Utility to Downward-Sloping Demand Curves 90

BEHAVIORAL ECONOMICS: ARE ECONOMIC DECISIONS REALLY MADE “RATIONALITY”? 92 CONSUMER CHOICE AS A TRADE-OFF: OPPORTUNITY COST 92 Consumer’s Surplus: The Net Gain from a Purchase 93

PUZZLE: RESOLVING THE DIAMOND–WATER PUZZLE 95 Income and Quantity Demanded 95

FROM INDIVIDUAL DEMAND CURVES TO MARKET DEMAND CURVES 96 Market Demand as a Horizontal Sum of the Demand Curves of Individual Buyers 96 The “Law” of Demand 97 Exceptions to the “Law” of Demand 97 Summary 98 Key Terms 99 Test Yourself 99 Discussion Questions 99

| APPENDIX | Analyzing Consumer Choice Graphically: Indifference Curve Analysis 99 GEOMETRY OF AVAILABLE CHOICES: THE BUDGET LINE 100 Properties of the Budget Line 100 Changes in the Budget Line 101

WHAT THE CONSUMER PREFERS: PROPERTIES OF THE INDIFFERENCE CURVE 101 THE SLOPES OF INDIFFERENCE CURVES AND BUDGET LINES 103 Tangency Conditions 104 Consequences of Income Changes: Inferior Goods 104 Consequences of Price Changes: Deriving the Demand Curve 105 Summary 106 Key Terms 106 Test Yourself 106

Chapter 6

Demand and Elasticity 107

ISSUE: WILL TAXING CIGARETTES MAKE TEENAGERS STOP SMOKING? 108

ELASTICITY: THE MEASURE OF RESPONSIVENESS 108 Price Elasticity of Demand and the Shapes of Demand Curves 111

PRICE ELASTICITY OF DEMAND: ITS EFFECT ON TOTAL REVENUE AND TOTAL EXPENDITURE 113 ISSUE REVISITED: WILL A CIGARETTE TAX DECREASE TEENAGE SMOKING SIGNIFICANTLY? 114

WHAT DETERMINES DEMAND ELASTICITY? 115 ELASTICITY AS A GENERAL CONCEPT 116 1. Income Elasticity 116 2. Price Elasticity of Supply 117 3. Cross Elasticity of Demand 117 Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

ix

x

Contents

THE TIME PERIOD OF THE DEMAND CURVE AND ECONOMIC DECISION MAKING 118 REAL-WORLD APPLICATION: POLAROID VERSUS KODAK 120 IN CONCLUSION 121 Summary 121 Key Terms 121 Test Yourself 121 Discussion Questions 122

| APPENDIX | How Can We Find a Legitimate Demand Curve from Historical Statistics? 122 AN ILLUSTRATION: DID THE ADVERTISING PROGRAM WORK? 123 HOW CAN WE FIND A LEGITIMATE DEMAND CURVE FROM THE STATISTICS? 124

Chapter 7

Production, Inputs, and Cost: Building Blocks for Supply Analysis 127

PUZZLE: HOW CAN WE TELL IF LARGER FIRMS ARE MORE EFFICIENT? 128

SHORT-RUN VERSUS LONG-RUN COSTS: WHAT MAKES AN INPUT VARIABLE? 128 The Economic Short Run versus the Economic Long Run 129 Fixed Costs and Variable Costs 129

PRODUCTION, INPUT CHOICE, AND COST WITH ONE VARIABLE INPUT 130 Total, Average, and Marginal Physical Products 130 Marginal Physical Product and the “Law” of Diminishing Marginal Returns 131 The Optimal Quantity of an Input and Diminishing Returns 132

MULTIPLE INPUT DECISIONS: THE CHOICE OF OPTIMAL INPUT COMBINATIONS 133 Substitutability: The Choice of Input Proportions 134 The Marginal Rule for Optimal Input Proportions 135 Changes in Input Prices and Optimal Input Proportions 136

COST AND ITS DEPENDENCE ON OUTPUT 137 Input Quantities and Total, Average, and Marginal Cost Curves 137 The Law of Diminishing Marginal Productivity and the U-Shaped Average Cost Curve 140 The Average Cost Curve in the Short and Long Run 141

ECONOMIES OF SCALE 142 The “Law” of Diminishing Returns and Returns to Scale 143 Historical Costs versus Analytical Cost Curves 144

PUZZLE: RESOLVING THE ECONOMIES OF SCALE PUZZLE 145 Cost Minimization in Theory and Practice 146 Summary 147 Key Terms 148 Test Yourself 148 Discussion Questions 149

| APPENDIX | Production Indifference Curves 149 CHARACTERISTICS OF THE PRODUCTION INDIFFERENCE CURVES, OR ISOQUANTS 149 THE CHOICE OF INPUT COMBINATIONS 150 COST MINIMIZATION, EXPANSION PATH, AND COST CURVES 151 Summary 152 Key Terms 153 Test Yourself 153

Chapter 8

Output, Price, and Profit: The Importance of Marginal Analysis 155

PUZZLE: CAN A COMPANY MAKE A PROFIT BY SELLING BELOW ITS COSTS? 157

PRICE AND QUANTITY: ONE DECISION, NOT TWO 157 TOTAL PROFIT: KEEP YOUR EYE ON THE GOAL 158 ECONOMIC PROFIT AND OPTIMAL DECISION MAKING 158 Total, Average, and Marginal Revenue 159 Total, Average, and Marginal Cost 161 Maximization of Total Profit 161 Profit Maximization: A Graphical Interpretation 162 Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Contents

MARGINAL ANALYSIS AND MAXIMIZATION OF TOTAL PROFIT 163 Marginal Revenue and Marginal Cost: Guides to Optimization 165 Finding the Optimal Price from Optimal Output 167

GENERALIZATION: THE LOGIC OF MARGINAL ANALYSIS AND MAXIMIZATION 168 Application: Fixed Cost and the Profit-Maximizing Price 168

PUZZLE RESOLVED: USING MARGINAL ANALYSIS TO UNRAVEL THE CASE OF THE “UNPROFITABLE” CALCULATOR 169

CONCLUSION: THE FUNDAMENTAL ROLE OF MARGINAL ANALYSIS 170 THE THEORY AND REALITY: A WORD OF CAUTION 171 Summary 171 Key Terms 172 Test Yourself 172 Discussion Question 172

| APPENDIX | The Relationships Among Total, Average, and Marginal Data 173 GRAPHICAL REPRESENTATION OF MARGINAL AND AVERAGE CURVES 174 Test Yourself 175

Chapter 9

Investing in Business: Stocks and Bonds

177

PUZZLE 1: WHAT IN THE WORLD HAPPENED TO THE STOCK MARKET? 178 PUZZLE 2: THE STOCK MARKET’S UNPREDICTABILITY 178

CORPORATIONS AND THEIR UNIQUE CHARACTERISTICS 179 Financing Corporate Activity: Stocks and Bonds 180 Plowback, or Retained Earnings 182 What Determines Stock Prices? The Role of Expected Company Earnings 183

BUYING STOCKS AND BONDS 183 Selecting a Portfolio: Diversification 184

STOCK EXCHANGES AND THEIR FUNCTIONS 185 Regulation of the Stock Market 186 Stock Exchanges and Corporate Capital Needs 187

SPECULATION 189 PUZZLE 2 RESOLVED: UNPREDICTABLE STOCK PRICES AS “RANDOM WALKS” 190 PUZZLE 1 REDUX: THE BOOM AND BUST OF THE U.S. STOCK MARKET 192 Summary 193 Key Terms 193 Test Yourself 193 Discussion Questions 194

PART 3

MARKETS AND THE PRICE SYSTEM 195

Chapter 10 The Firm and the Industry under Perfect Competition

197

PUZZLE: POLLUTION REDUCTION INCENTIVES THAT ACTUALLY INCREASE POLLUTION 198

PERFECT COMPETITION DEFINED 198 THE PERFECTLY COMPETITIVE FIRM 199 The Firm’s Demand Curve under Perfect Competition 199 Short-Run Equilibrium for the Perfectly Competitive Firm 200 Short-Run Profit: Graphic Representation 201 The Case of Short-Term Losses 202 Shutdown and Break-Even Analysis 202 The Perfectly Competitive Firm’s Short-Run Supply Curve 204

THE PERFECTLY COMPETITIVE INDUSTRY 205 The Perfectly Competitive Industry’s Short-Run Supply Curve 205 Industry Equilibrium in the Short Run 205 Industry and Firm Equilibrium in the Long Run 206 Zero Economic Profit: The Opportunity Cost of Capital 209 The Long-Run Industry Supply Curve 210 Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

xi

xii

Contents

PERFECT COMPETITION AND ECONOMIC EFFICIENCY 211 PUZZLE RESOLVED: WHICH MORE EFFECTIVELY CUTS POLLUTION—THE CARROT OR THE STICK? 212 Summary 214 Key Terms 214 Test Yourself 214 Discussion Questions 215

Chapter 11 Monopoly 217 PUZZLE: WHAT HAPPENED TO AT&T’S “NATURAL MONOPOLY” IN TELEPHONE SERVICE? 218

MONOPOLY DEFINED 218 Sources of Monopoly: Barriers to Entry and Cost Advantages 219 Natural Monopoly 220

THE MONOPOLIST’S SUPPLY DECISION 221 Determining the Profit-Maximizing Output 223 Comparing Monopoly and Perfect Competition 224 Monopoly Is Likely to Shift Demand 225 Monopoly Is Likely to Shift Cost Curves 226

CAN ANYTHING GOOD BE SAID ABOUT MONOPOLY? 226 Monopoly May Aid Innovation 227 Natural Monopoly: Where Single-firm Production Is Cheapest 227

PRICE DISCRIMINATION UNDER MONOPOLY 227 Is Price Discrimination Always Undesirable? 230

PUZZLE RESOLVED: COMPETITION IN TELEPHONE SERVICE 230 Summary 231 Key Terms 232 Test Yourself 232 Discussion Questions 232

Chapter 12 Between Competition and Monopoly 235 PUZZLE: THREE PUZZLING OBSERVATIONS 236 PUZZLE 1: WHY ARE THERE SO MANY RETAILERS? 236 PUZZLE 2: WHY DO OLIGOPOLISTS ADVERTISE MORE THAN “MORE COMPETITIVE” FIRMS? 236 PUZZLE 3: WHY DO OLIGOPOLISTS SEEM TO CHANGE THEIR PRICES SO INFREQUENTLY? 236

MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION 236 Characteristics of Monopolistic Competition 237 Price and Output Determination under Monopolistic Competition 238 The Excess Capacity Theorem and Resource Allocation 239

1ST PUZZLE RESOLVED: EXPLAINING THE ABUNDANCE OF RETAILERS 240

OLIGOPOLY 241 2ND PUZZLE RESOLVED: WHY OLIGOPOLISTS ADVERTISE BUT PERFECTLY COMPETITIVE FIRMS GENERALLY DO NOT 241 Why Oligopolistic Behavior Is So Difficult to Analyze 242 A Shopping List 242 Sales Maximization: An Oligopoly Model with Interdependence Ignored 246

3RD PUZZLE RESOLVED: THE KINKED DEMAND CURVE MODEL 247 The Game Theory Approach 250 Games with Dominant Strategies 250 Games without Dominant Strategies 252 Other Strategies: The Nash Equilibrium 253 Zero-Sum Games 253 Repeated Games 254

MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION, OLIGOPOLY, AND PUBLIC WELFARE 257 A GLANCE BACKWARD: COMPARING THE FOUR MARKET FORMS 258 Summary 259 Key Terms 260 Test Yourself 260 Discussion Questions 260 Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Contents

Chapter 13 Limiting Market Power: Regulation and Antitrust 263 THE PUBLIC INTEREST ISSUE: MONOPOLY POWER VERSUS MERE SIZE 264 PART 1: ANTITRUST LAWS AND POLICIES 265 MEASURING MARKET POWER: CONCENTRATION 267 Concentration: Definition and Measurement—The Herfindahl-Hirschman Index 267 The Evidence of Concentration in Reality 269

A CRUCIAL PROBLEM FOR ANTITRUST: THE RESEMBLANCE OF MONOPOLIZATION AND VIGOROUS COMPETITION 269 ANTICOMPETITIVE PRACTICES AND ANTITRUST 270 Predatory Pricing 270 The Microsoft Case: Bottlenecks, Bundling, and Network Externalities 270

USE OF ANTITRUST LAWS TO PREVENT COMPETITION 271 PART 2: REGULATION 273 WHAT IS REGULATION? 273 PUZZLE: WHY DO REGULATORS OFTEN RAISE PRICES? 273

SOME OBJECTIVES OF REGULATION 274 Control of Market Power Resulting from Economics of Scale and Scope 274 Universal Service and Rate Averaging 275

TWO KEY ISSUES THAT FACE REGULATORS 275 Setting Prices to Protect Consumers’ Interests and Allow Regulated Firms to Cover Their Cost 275 Marginal versus Average Cost Pricing 276 Preventing Monopoly Profit but Keeping Incentives for Efficiency and Innovation 277

THE PROS AND CONS OF “BIGNESS” 278 Economies of Large Size 278 Required Scale for Innovation 279

DEREGULATION 279 The Effects of Deregulation 279

PUZZLE REVISITED: WHY REGULATORS OFTEN PUSH PRICES UPWARD 282

CONCLUDING OBSERVATIONS 282 Summary 283 Key Terms 283 Discussion Questions 283

PART 4

THE VIRTUES AND LIMITATIONS OF MARKETS 285

Chapter 14 The Case for Free Markets I: The Price System 287 PUZZLE: CROSSING THE SAN FRANCISCO–OAKLAND BAY BRIDGE: IS THE PRICE RIGHT? 288

EFFICIENT RESOURCE ALLOCATION AND PRICING 288 Pricing to Promote Efficiency: An Example 289 Can Price Increases Ever Serve the Public Interest? 290

SCARCITY AND THE NEED TO COORDINATE ECONOMIC DECISIONS 292 Three Coordination Tasks in the Economy 292 Input-Output Analysis: The Near Impossibility of Perfect Central Planning 295 Which Buyers and Which Sellers Get Priority? 297

HOW PERFECT COMPETITION ACHIEVES EFFICIENCY: A GRAPHIC ANALYSIS 299 HOW PERFECT COMPETITION ACHIEVES OPTIMAL OUTPUT: MARGINAL ANALYSIS 301 The Invisible Hand at Work 303 Other Roles of Prices: Income Distribution and Fairness 304 Yet Another Free-Market Achievement: Growth versus Efficiency 305

PUZZLE RESOLVED: SAN FRANCISCO BRIDGE PRICING REVISITED 306

TOWARD ASSESSMENT OF THE PRICE MECHANISM 306 Summary 307 Key Terms 307 Test Yourself 307 Discussion Questions 307 Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

xiii

xiv

Contents

Chapter 15 The Shortcomings of Free Markets 309 PUZZLE: WHY ARE HEALTH-CARE COSTS IN CANADA RISING? 310

WHAT DOES THE MARKET DO POORLY? 310 EFFICIENT RESOURCE ALLOCATION: A REVIEW 311 EXTERNALITIES: GETTING THE PRICES WRONG 312 Externalities and Inefficiency 312 Externalities Are Everywhere 314 Government Policy and Externalities 315

PROVISION OF PUBLIC GOODS 316 ALLOCATION OF RESOURCES BETWEEN PRESENT AND FUTURE 318 The Role of the Interest Rate 318 How Does It Work in Practice? 319

SOME OTHER SOURCES OF MARKET FAILURE 320 Imperfect Information: “Caveat Emptor” 320 Rent Seeking 320 Moral Hazard 320 Principals, Agents, and Recent Stock Option Scandals 321

MARKET FAILURE AND GOVERNMENT FAILURE 323 THE COST DISEASE OF SOME VITAL SERVICES: INVITATION TO GOVERNMENT FAILURE 324 Deteriorating Personal Services 325 Personal Services Are Getting More Expensive 325 Why Are These “In-Person” Services Costing So Much More? 326 Uneven Labor Productivity Growth in the Economy 327 A Future of More Goods but Fewer Services: Is It Inevitable? 327 Government May Make the Problem Worse 329

PUZZLE RESOLVED: EXPLAINING THE RISING COSTS OF CANADIAN HEALTH CARE 329

THE MARKET SYSTEM ON BALANCE 330 EPILOGUE: THE UNFORGIVING MARKET, ITS GIFT OF ABUNDANCE, AND ITS DANGEROUS FRIENDS 330 Summary 331 Key Terms 332 Test Yourself 332 Discussion Questions 332

Chapter 16 The Market’s Prime Achievement: Innovation and Growth

333

PUZZLE: HOW DID THE MARKET ACHIEVE ITS UNPRECEDENTED GROWTH? 334

THE MARKET ECONOMY’S INCREDIBLE GROWTH RECORD 334 INNOVATION, NOT INVENTION, IS THE UNIQUE FREE-MARKET ACCOMPLISHMENT 338 SOURCES OF FREE-MARKET INNOVATION: THE ROLE OF THE ENTREPRENEUR 339 Breakthrough Invention and the Entrepreneurial Firm 340

MICROECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF THE INNOVATIVE OLIGOPOLY FIRM 340 The Large Enterprises and Their Innovation “Assembly Lines” 340 The Profits of Innovation: Schumpeter’s Model 343 Financing the Innovation “Arms Race”: High R&D Costs and “Monopoly Profits” 345 How Much Will a Profit-Maximizing Firm Spend on Innovation? 346 A Kinked Revenue Curve Model of Spending on Innovation 346 Innovation as a Public Good 348 Effects of Process Research on Outputs and Prices 348

DO FREE MARKETS SPEND ENOUGH ON R&D ACTIVITIES? 349 Innovation as a Beneficial Externality 350 Why the Shortfall in Innovation Spending May Not Be So Big After All 351

THE MARKET ECONOMY AND THE SPEEDY DISSEMINATION OF NEW TECHNOLOGY 351 CONCLUSION: THE MARKET ECONOMY AND ITS INNOVATION ASSEMBLY LINE 353 Summary 353 Key Terms 354 Discussion Questions 354

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Contents

Chapter 17 Externalities, the Environment, and Natural Resources 355 PUZZLE: THOSE RESILIENT NATURAL RESOURCE SUPPLIES 356

PART 1: THE ECONOMICS OF ENVIRONMENTAL PROTECTION 356 REVIEW—EXTERNALITIES: A CRITICAL SHORTCOMING OF THE MARKET MECHANISM 356 The Facts: Is the World Really Getting Steadily More Polluted? 357 The Role of Individuals and Governments in Environmental Damage 360 Pollution and the Law of Conservation of Matter and Energy 361

BASIC APPROACHES TO ENVIRONMENTAL POLICY 363 Emissions Taxes versus Direct Controls 364 Another Financial Device to Protect the Environment: Emissions Permits 366

TWO CHEERS FOR THE MARKET 367 PART 2: THE ECONOMICS OF NATURAL RESOURCES 368 ECONOMIC ANALYSIS: THE FREE MARKET AND PRICING OF DEPLETABLE RESOURCES 369 Scarcity and Rising Prices 369 Supply-Demand Analysis and Consumption 369

ACTUAL RESOURCE PRICES IN THE TWENTIETH CENTURY 371 Interferences with Price Patterns 372 Is Price Interference Justified? 374 On the Virtues of Rising Prices 374

PUZZLE REVISITED: GROWING RESERVES OF EXHAUSTIBLE NATURAL RESOURCES 375 Summary 375 Key Terms 375 Test Yourself 376 Discussion Questions 376

Chapter 18 Taxation and Resource Allocation 377 ISSUE: SHOULD THE BUSH TAX CUTS BE (PARTLY) REPEALED? 378

THE LEVEL AND TYPES OF TAXATION 378 Progressive, Proportional, and Regressive Taxes 379 Direct versus Indirect Taxes 379

THE FEDERAL TAX SYSTEM 379 The Federal Personal Income Tax 380 The Payroll Tax 381 The Corporate Income Tax 381 Excise Taxes 381 The Payroll Tax and the Social Security System 381

THE STATE AND LOCAL TAX SYSTEM 383 Sales and Excise Taxes 383 Property Taxes 383 Fiscal Federalism 384

THE CONCEPT OF EQUITY IN TAXATION 384 Horizontal Equity 384 Vertical Equity 384 The Benefits Principle 385

THE CONCEPT OF EFFICIENCY IN TAXATION 385 Tax Loopholes and Excess Burden 387

SHIFTING THE TAX BURDEN: TAX INCIDENCE 387 The Incidence of Excise Taxes 389 The Incidence of the Payroll Tax 390

WHEN TAXATION CAN IMPROVE EFFICIENCY 391 EQUITY, EFFICIENCY, AND THE OPTIMAL TAX 391 ISSUE REVISITED: THE PROS AND CONS OF REPEALING THE BUSH TAX CUTS 392 Summary 393 Key Terms 393 Test Yourself 394 Discussion Questions 394

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

xv

xvi

Contents

PART 5

THE DISTRIBUTION OF INCOME 395

Chapter 19 Pricing the Factors of Production 397 PUZZLE: WHY DOES A HIGHER RETURN TO SAVINGS REDUCE THE AMOUNT SOME PEOPLE SAVE? 398

THE PRINCIPLE OF MARGINAL PRODUCTIVITY 398 INPUTS AND THEIR DERIVED DEMAND CURVES 399 INVESTMENT, CAPITAL, AND INTEREST 401 The Demand for Funds 402 The Downward-Sloping Demand Curve for Funds 403

PUZZLE RESOLVED: THE SUPPLY OF FUNDS

404

The Issue of Usury Laws: Are Interest Rates Too High? 404

THE DETERMINATION OF RENT 405 Land Rents: Further Analysis 406 Generalization: Economic Rent Seeking 408 Rent as a Component of an Input’s Compensation 409 An Application of Rent Theory: Salaries of Professional Athletes 410 Rent Controls: The Misplaced Analogy 410

PAYMENTS TO BUSINESS OWNERS: ARE PROFITS TOO HIGH OR TOO LOW? 411 What Accounts for Profits? 412 Taxing Profits 414

CRITICISMS OF MARGINAL PRODUCTIVITY THEORY 414 Summary 415 Key Terms 416 Test Yourself 416 Discussion Questions 416

| APPENDIX | Discounting and Present Value 417 Summary 418 Key Term 418 Test Yourself 418

Chapter 20 Labor and Entrepreneurship: The Human Inputs 419 PART 1: THE MARKETS FOR LABOR 420 PUZZLE: ENTREPRENEURS EARN LESS THAN MOST PEOPLE THINK—WHY SO LITTLE? 420

WAGE DETERMINATION IN COMPETITIVE MARKETS 421 The Demand for Labor and the Determination of Wages 422 Influences on MRPL: Shifts in the Demand for Labor 422 Technical Change, Productivity Growth, and the Demand for Labor 423 The Service Economy and the Demand for Labor 423

THE SUPPLY OF LABOR 424 Rising Labor-Force Participation 425 An Important Labor Supply Conundrum 425 The Labor Supply Conundrum Resolved 427

WHY DO WAGES DIFFER? 428 Labor Demand in General 428 Labor Supply in General 429 Investment in Human Capital 429 Teenagers: a Disadvantaged Group in the labor Market

429

UNIONS AND COLLECTIVE BARGAINING 430 Unions as Labor Monopolies 431 Monopsony and Bilateral Monopoly 433 Collective Bargaining and Strikes 433

PART 2: THE ENTREPRENEUR: THE OTHER HUMAN INPUT 435 ENTREPRENEURSHIP AND GROWTH 435 The Entrepreneur’s Prices and Profits 436 Fixed Costs and Public Good Attributes in Invention and Entrepreneurship

437

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Contents

Discriminatory Pricing of an Innovative Product over Its Life Cycle Negative Financial Rewards for Entrepreneurial Activity 439

PUZZLE RESOLVED: WHY ARE ENTREPRENEURIAL EARNINGS SURPRISINGLY LOW?

437

439

INSTITUTIONS AND THE SUPPLY OF INNOVATIVE ENTREPRENEURSHIP

440

Summary 441 Key Terms 442 Test Yourself 442 Discussion Questions 443

Chapter 21 Poverty, Inequality, and Discrimination 445 ISSUE: WERE THE BUSH TAX CUTS UNFAIR? 446

THE FACTS: POVERTY 446 Counting the Poor: The Poverty Line 447 Absolute versus Relative Poverty 448

THE FACTS: INEQUALITY 449 SOME REASONS FOR UNEQUAL INCOMES 450 THE FACTS: DISCRIMINATION 452 THE TRADE-OFF BETWEEN EQUALITY AND EFFICIENCY 453 POLICIES TO COMBAT POVERTY 454 Education as a Way Out 455 The Welfare Debate and the Trade-Off 455 The Negative Income Tax 456

OTHER POLICIES TO COMBAT INEQUALITY 457 The Personal Income Tax 457 Death Duties and Other Taxes 457

POLICIES TO COMBAT DISCRIMINATION 458 A LOOK BACK 459 Summary 460 Key Terms 460 Test Yourself 460 Discussion Questions 461

| APPENDIX | The Economic Theory of Discrimination 461 DISCRIMINATION BY EMPLOYERS 461 DISCRIMINATION BY FELLOW WORKERS 461 STATISTICAL DISCRIMINATION 462 THE ROLES OF THE MARKET AND THE GOVERNMENT 462 Summary 463 Key Term 463

PART 6

THE MACROECONOMY: AGGREGATE SUPPLY AND DEMAND 465

Chapter 22 An Introduction to Macroeconomics 467 ISSUE: HOW DID THE HOUSING BUST LEAD TO THE GREAT RECESSION? 468

DRAWING A LINE BETWEEN MACROECONOMICS AND MICROECONOMICS 468 Aggregation and Macroeconomics 468 The Foundations of Aggregation 469 The Line of Demarcation Revisited 469

SUPPLY AND DEMAND IN MACROECONOMICS 469 A Quick Review 470 Moving to Macroeconomic Aggregates 470 Inflation 471 Recession and Unemployment 471 Economic Growth 471 Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

xvii

xviii

Contents

GROSS DOMESTIC PRODUCT 471 Money as the Measuring Rod: Real versus Nominal GDP 472 What Gets Counted in GDP? 472 Limitations of the GDP: What GDP Is Not 474

THE ECONOMY ON A ROLLER COASTER 475 Growth, but with Fluctuations 475 Inflation and Deflation 477 The Great Depression 478 From World War II to 1973 479 The Great Stagflation, 1973–1980 480 Reaganomics and Its Aftermath 481 Clintonomics: Deficit Reduction and the “New Economy” 481 Tax Cuts and the Bush Economy 482

ISSUE REVISITED: HOW DID THE HOUSING BUST LEAD TO THE GREAT RECESSION? 482

THE PROBLEM OF MACROECONOMIC STABILIZATION: A SNEAK PREVIEW 483 Combating Unemployment 483 Combating Inflation 484 Does It Really Work? 484 Summary 485 Key Terms 486 Test Yourself 486 Discussion Questions 487

Chapter 23 The Goals of Macroeconomic Policy 489 PART 1: THE GOAL OF ECONOMIC GROWTH 490 PRODUCTIVITY GROWTH: FROM LITTLE ACORNS . . . 490 ISSUE: IS FASTER GROWTH ALWAYS BETTER? 492

THE CAPACITY TO PRODUCE: POTENTIAL GDP AND THE PRODUCTION FUNCTION 492 THE GROWTH RATE OF POTENTIAL GDP 493 ISSUE REVISITED: IS FASTER GROWTH ALWAYS BETTER? 494

PART 2: THE GOAL OF LOW UNEMPLOYMENT 495 THE HUMAN COSTS OF HIGH UNEMPLOYMENT 496 COUNTING THE UNEMPLOYED: THE OFFICIAL STATISTICS 497 TYPES OF UNEMPLOYMENT 498 HOW MUCH EMPLOYMENT IS “FULL EMPLOYMENT”? 499 UNEMPLOYMENT INSURANCE: THE INVALUABLE CUSHION 499 PART 3: THE GOAL OF LOW INFLATION 500 INFLATION: THE MYTH AND THE REALITY 501 Inflation and Real Wages 501 The Importance of Relative Prices 503

INFLATION AS A REDISTRIBUTOR OF INCOME AND WEALTH 504 REAL VERSUS NOMINAL INTEREST RATES 504 INFLATION DISTORTS MEASUREMENTS 505 Confusing Real and Nominal Interest Rates 506 The Malfunctioning Tax System 506

OTHER COSTS OF INFLATION 506 THE COSTS OF LOW VERSUS HIGH INFLATION 507 LOW INFLATION DOES NOT NECESSARILY LEAD TO HIGH INFLATION 509 Summary 509 Key Terms 510 Test Yourself 510 Discussion Questions 511

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Contents

| APPENDIX | How Statisticians Measure Inflation 511 INDEX NUMBERS FOR INFLATION 511 THE CONSUMER PRICE INDEX 512 USING A PRICE INDEX TO “DEFLATE” MONETARY FIGURES 513 USING A PRICE INDEX TO MEASURE INFLATION 513 THE GDP DEFLATOR 513 Summary 514 Key Terms 514 Test Yourself 514

Chapter 24 Economic Growth: Theory and Policy 517 PUZZLE: WHY DOES COLLEGE EDUCATION KEEP GETTING MORE EXPENSIVE? 518

THE THREE PILLARS OF PRODUCTIVITY GROWTH 518 Capital 519 Technology 519 Labor Quality: Education and Training 520

LEVELS, GROWTH RATES, AND THE CONVERGENCE HYPOTHESIS 520 GROWTH POLICY: ENCOURAGING CAPITAL FORMATION 522 GROWTH POLICY: IMPROVING EDUCATION AND TRAINING 524 GROWTH POLICY: SPURRING TECHNOLOGICAL CHANGE 526 THE PRODUCTIVITY SLOWDOWN AND SPEED-UP IN THE UNITED STATES 527 The Productivity Slowdown, 1973–1995 527 The Productivity Speed-up, 1995–? 528

PUZZLE RESOLVED: WHY THE RELATIVE PRICE OF COLLEGE TUITION KEEPS RISING 530

GROWTH IN THE DEVELOPING COUNTRIES 531 The Three Pillars Revisited 531 Some Special Problems of the Developing Countries 532

FROM THE LONG RUN TO THE SHORT RUN 533 Summary 533 Key Terms 534 Test Yourself 534 Discussion Questions 535

Chapter 25 Aggregate Demand and the Powerful Consumer 537 ISSUE: DEMAND MANAGEMENT AND THE ORNERY CONSUMER 538

AGGREGATE DEMAND, DOMESTIC PRODUCT, AND NATIONAL INCOME 538 THE CIRCULAR FLOW OF SPENDING, PRODUCTION, AND INCOME 539 CONSUMER SPENDING AND INCOME: THE IMPORTANT RELATIONSHIP 541 THE CONSUMPTION FUNCTION AND THE MARGINAL PROPENSITY TO CONSUME 544 FACTORS THAT SHIFT THE CONSUMPTION FUNCTION 545 ISSUE REVISITED: WHY THE TAX REBATES FAILED IN 1975 AND 2001 547

THE EXTREME VARIABILITY OF INVESTMENT 548 THE DETERMINANTS OF NET EXPORTS 549 National Incomes 549 Relative Prices and Exchange Rates 549

HOW PREDICTABLE IS AGGREGATE DEMAND? 550 Summary 550 Key Terms 551 Test Yourself 551 Discussion Questions 552

| APPENDIX | National Income Accounting 552 DEFINING GDP: EXCEPTIONS TO THE RULES 552 GDP AS THE SUM OF FINAL GOODS AND SERVICES 553 GDP AS THE SUM OF ALL FACTOR PAYMENTS 553

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

xix

xx

Contents

GDP AS THE SUM OF VALUES ADDED 555 Summary 556 Key Terms 557 Test Yourself 557 Discussion Questions 558

Chapter 26 Demand-Side Equilibrium: Unemployment or Inflation? 559 ISSUE: WHY DOES THE MARKET PERMIT UNEMPLOYMENT? 560

THE MEANING OF EQUILIBRIUM GDP 560 THE MECHANICS OF INCOME DETERMINATION 562 THE AGGREGATE DEMAND CURVE 564 DEMAND-SIDE EQUILIBRIUM AND FULL EMPLOYMENT 566 THE COORDINATION OF SAVING AND INVESTMENT 567 CHANGES ON THE DEMAND SIDE: MULTIPLIER ANALYSIS 569 The Magic of the Multiplier 569 Demystifying the Multiplier: How It Works 570 Algebraic Statement of the Multiplier 571

THE MULTIPLIER IS A GENERAL CONCEPT 573 THE MULTIPLIER AND THE AGGREGATE DEMAND CURVE 574 Summary 575 Key Terms 576 Test Yourself 576 Discussion Questions 577

| APPENDIX A | The Simple Algebra of Income Determination and the Multiplier 577 Test Yourself 578 Discussion Questions 578

| APPENDIX B | The Multiplier with Variable Imports 578 Summary 581 Test Yourself 581 Discussion Question 581

Chapter 27 Bringing in the Supply Side: Unemployment and Inflation? 583 PUZZLE: WHAT CAUSES STAGFLATION? 584

THE AGGREGATE SUPPLY CURVE 584 Why the Aggregate Supply Curve Slopes Upward 584 Shifts of the Agregate Supply Curve 585

EQUILIBRIUM OF AGGREGATE DEMAND AND SUPPLY 587 INFLATION AND THE MULTIPLIER 588 RECESSIONARY AND INFLATIONARY GAPS REVISITED 589 ADJUSTING TO A RECESSIONARY GAP: DEFLATION OR UNEMPLOYMENT? 591 Why Nominal Wages and Prices Won’t Fall (Easily) 591 Does the Economy Have a Self-Correcting Mechanism? 592 An Example from Recent History: Deflation in Japan 593

ADJUSTING TO AN INFLATIONARY GAP: INFLATION 593 Demand Inflation and Stagflation 594 A U.S. Example 594

STAGFLATION FROM A SUPPLY SHOCK 595 APPLYING THE MODEL TO A GROWING ECONOMY 596 Demand-Side Fluctuations 597 Supply-Side Fluctuations 598

PUZZLE RESOLVED: EXPLAINING STAGFLATION 600

A ROLE FOR STABILIZATION POLICY 600 Summary 600 Key Terms 601 Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Contents

Test Yourself 601 Discussion Questions 602

PART 7

FISCAL AND MONETARY POLICY 603

Chapter 28 Managing Aggregate Demand: Fiscal Policy 605 ISSUE: THE GREAT FISCAL STIMULUS DEBATE OF 2009–2010 606

INCOME TAXES AND THE CONSUMPTION SCHEDULE 606 THE MULTIPLIER REVISITED 607 The Tax Multiplier 607 Income Taxes and the Multiplier 608 Automatic Stabilizers 609 Government Transfer Payments 609

ISSUE REVISITED: THE 2009–2010 STIMULUS DEBATE 610

PLANNING EXPANSIONARY FISCAL POLICY 610 PLANNING CONTRACTIONARY FISCAL POLICY 611 THE CHOICE BETWEEN SPENDING POLICY AND TAX POLICY 611 ISSUE REDUX: DEMOCRATS VERSUS REPUBLICANS 612

SOME HARSH REALITIES 612 THE IDEA BEHIND SUPPLY-SIDE TAX CUTS 613 Some Flies in the Ointment 614

ISSUE: THE PARTISAN DEBATE ONCE MORE 615 Toward an Assessment of Supply-Side Economics 616 Summary 617 Key Terms 617 Test Yourself 617 Discussion Questions 618

| APPENDIX A | Graphical Treatment of Taxes Fiscal Policy 618 MULTIPLIERS FOR TAX POLICY 620 Summary 621 Key Terms 621 Test Yourself 621 Discussion Questions 621

| APPENDIX B | Algebraic Treatment of Taxes and Fiscal Policy 622 Test Yourself 623

Chapter 29 Money and the Banking System 625 ISSUE: WHY ARE BANKS SO HEAVILY REGULATED? 626

THE NATURE OF MONEY 626 Barter versus Monetary Exchange 627 The Conceptual Definition of Money 628 What Serves as Money? 628

HOW THE QUANTITY OF MONEY IS MEASURED 630 M1 630 M2 631 Other Definitions of the Money Supply 631

THE BANKING SYSTEM 632 How Banking Began 632 Principles of Bank Management: Profits versus Safety 634 Bank Regulation 634

THE ORIGINS OF THE MONEY SUPPLY 635 How Bankers Keep Books 635

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

xxi

xxii

Contents

BANKS AND MONEY CREATION 636 The Limits to Money Creation by a Single Bank 636 Multiple Money Creation by a Series of Banks 638 The Process in Reverse: Multiple Contractions of the Money Supply 640

WHY THE MONEY-CREATION FORMULA IS OVERSIMPLIFIED 642 THE NEED FOR MONETARY POLICY 643 Summary 643 Key Terms 644 Test Yourself 644 Discussion Questions 644

Chapter 30 Managing Aggregate Demand: Monetary Policy 645 ISSUE: JUST WHY IS BEN BERNANKE SO IMPORTANT? 646

MONEY AND INCOME: THE IMPORTANT DIFFERENCE 646 AMERICA’S CENTRAL BANK: THE FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM 647 Origins and Structure 647 Central Bank Independence 648

IMPLEMENTING MONETARY POLICY: OPEN-MARKET OPERATIONS 649 The Market for Bank Reserves 649 The Mechanics of an Open-Market Operation 650 Open-Market Operations, Bond Prices, and Interest Rates 652

OTHER METHODS OF MONETARY CONTROL 652 Lending to Banks 653 Changing Reserve Requirements 654

HOW MONETARY POLICY WORKS 654 Investment and Interest Rates 655 Monetary Policy and Total Expenditure 655

MONEY AND THE PRICE LEVEL IN THE KEYNESIAN MODEL 656 Application: Why the Aggregate Demand Curve Slopes Downward 657

UNCONVENTIONAL MONETARY POLICY 658 FROM MODELS TO POLICY DEBATES 658 Summary 659 Key Terms 659 Test Yourself 659 Discussion Questions 660

Chapter 31 The Debate over Monetary and Fiscal Policy 661 ISSUE: SHOULD WE FORSAKE STABILIZATION POLICY? 662

VELOCITY AND THE QUANTITY THEORY OF MONEY 662 Some Determinants of Velocity 664 Monetarism: The Quantity Theory Modernized 665

FISCAL POLICY, INTEREST RATES, AND VELOCITY 665 Application: The Multiplier Formula Revisited 666 Application: The Government Budget and Investment 667

DEBATE: SHOULD WE RELY ON FISCAL OR MONETARY POLICY? 667 DEBATE: SHOULD THE FED CONTROL THE MONEY SUPPLY OR INTEREST RATES? 668 Two Imperfect Alternatives 670 What Has the Fed Actually Done? 670

DEBATE: THE SHAPE OF THE AGGREGATE SUPPLY CURVE 671 DEBATE: SHOULD THE GOVERNMENT INTERVENE? 673 Lags and the Rules-versus-Discretion Debate 675

DIMENSIONS OF THE RULES-VERSUS-DISCRETION DEBATE 675 How Fast Does the Economy’s Self-Correcting Mechanism Work? 675 How Long Are the Lags in Stabilization Policy? 676 How Accurate Are Economic Forcasts? 676 The Size of Government 676

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Contents

Uncertainties Caused by Government Policy 677 A Political Business Cycle? 677

ISSUE REVISITED: WHAT SHOULD BE DONE? 679 Summary 679 Key Terms 680 Test Yourself 680 Discussion Questions 681

Chapter 32 Budget Deficits in the Short and Long Run 683 ISSUE: IS THE FEDERAL GOVERNMENT BUDGET DEFICIT TOO LARGE? 684

SHOULD THE BUDGET BE BALANCED? THE SHORT RUN 684 The Importance of the Policy Mix 685

SURPLUSES AND DEFICITS: THE LONG RUN 685 DEFICITS AND DEBT: TERMINOLOGY AND FACTS 687 Some Facts about the National Debt 687

INTERPRETING THE BUDGET DEFICIT OR SURPLUS 689 The Structural Deficit or Surplus 689 On-Budget versus Off-Budget Surpluses 691 Conclusion: What Happened after 1981— and after 2001? 691

WHY IS THE NATIONAL DEBT CONSIDERED A BURDEN? 691 BUDGET DEFICITS AND INFLATION 692 The Monetization Issue 693

DEBT, INTEREST RATES, AND CROWDING OUT 694 The Bottom Line 695

THE MAIN BURDEN OF THE NATIONAL DEBT: SLOWER GROWTH 695 ISSUE REVISITED: IS THE BUDGET DEFICIT TOO LARGE? 696

THE ECONOMICS AND POLITICS OF THE U.S. BUDGET DEFICIT 698 Summary 699 Key Terms 699 Test Yourself 699 Discussion Questions 700

Chapter 33 The Trade-Off between Inflation and Unemployment 701 ISSUE: IS THE TRADE-OFF BETWEEN INFLATION AND UNEMPLOYMENT A RELIC OF THE PAST? 702

DEMAND-SIDE INFLATION VERSUS SUPPLY-SIDE INFLATION: A REVIEW 702 ORIGINS OF THE PHILLIPS CURVE 703 SUPPLY-SIDE INFLATION AND THE COLLAPSE OF THE PHILLIPS CURVE 705 Explaining the Fabulous 1990s 705

ISSUE RESOLVED: WHY INFLATION AND UNEMPLOYMENT BOTH DECLINED 706

WHAT THE PHILLIPS CURVE IS NOT 706 FIGHTING UNEMPLOYMENT WITH FISCAL AND MONETARY POLICY 708 WHAT SHOULD BE DONE? 709 The Costs of Inflation and Unemployment 709 The Slope of the Short-Run Phillips Curve 709 The Efficiency of the Economy’s Self-Correcting Mechanism 709

INFLATIONARY EXPECTATIONS AND THE PHILLIPS CURVE 710 THE THEORY OF RATIONAL EXPECTATIONS 712 What Are Rational Expectations? 712 Rational Expectations and the Trade-Off 713 An Evaluation 713

WHY ECONOMISTS (AND POLITICIANS) DISAGREE 714 THE DILEMMA OF DEMAND MANAGEMENT 715 ATTEMPTS TO REDUCE THE NATURAL RATE OF UNEMPLOYMENT 715 INDEXING 716 Summary 717

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

xxiii

xxiv

Contents

Key Terms 718 Test Yourself 718 Discussion Questions 718

PART 8

THE UNITED STATES IN THE WORLD ECONOMY 721

Chapter 34 International Trade and Comparative Advantage 723 ISSUE: HOW CAN AMERICANS COMPETE WITH “CHEAP FOREIGN LABOR”? 724

WHY TRADE? 725 Mutual Gains from Trade 725

INTERNATIONAL VERSUS INTRANATIONAL TRADE 726 Political Factors in International Trade 726 The Many Currencies Involved in International Trade 726 Impediments to Mobility of Labor and Capital 726

THE LAW OF COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE 727 The Arithmetic of Comparative Advantage 727 The Graphics of Comparative Advantage 728 Must Specialization Be Complete? 731

ISSUE RESOLVED: COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE EXPOSES THE “CHEAP FOREIGN LABOR” FALLACY 731

TARIFFS, QUOTAS, AND OTHER INTERFERENCES WITH TRADE 732 Tariffs versus Quotas 733

WHY INHIBIT TRADE? 734 Gaining a Price Advantage for Domestic Firms 734 Protecting Particular Industries 734 National Defense and Other Noneconomic Considerations 735 The Infant-Industry Argument 736 Strategic Trade Policy 737

CAN CHEAP IMPORTS HURT A COUNTRY? 737 ISSUE: LAST LOOK AT THE “CHEAP FOREIGN LABOR” ARGUMENT 738 Summary 740 Key Terms 740 Test Yourself 741 Discussion Questions 741

| APPENDIX | Supply, Demand, and Pricing in World Trade 742 HOW TARIFFS AND QUOTAS WORK 743 Summary 744 Test Yourself 744

Chapter 35 The International Monetary System: Order or Disorder? 745 PUZZLE: WHY HAS THE DOLLAR SAGGED? 746

WHAT ARE EXCHANGE RATES? 746 EXCHANGE RATE DETERMINATION IN A FREE MARKET 747 Interest Rates and Exchange Rates: The Short Run 749 Economic Activity and Exchange Rates: The Medium Run 750 The Purchasing-Power Parity Theory: The Long Run 750 Market Determination of Exchange Rates: Summary 752

WHEN GOVERNMENTS FIX EXCHANGE RATES: THE BALANCE OF PAYMENTS 753 A BIT OF HISTORY: THE GOLD STANDARD AND THE BRETTON WOODS SYSTEM 754 The Classical Gold Standard 755 The Bretton Woods System 755

ADJUSTMENT MECHANISMS UNDER FIXED EXCHANGE RATES 756 WHY TRY TO FIX EXCHANGE RATES? 756 THE CURRENT “NONSYSTEM” 757

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Contents

The Role of the IMF 758 The Volatile Dollar 758 The Birth and Adolescence of the Euro 759

PUZZLE RESOLVED: WHY THE DOLLAR ROSE, THEN FELL, THEN ROSE 760 Summary 761 Key Terms 761 Test Yourself 762 Discussion Questions 762

Chapter 36 Exchange Rates and the Macroeconomy 763 ISSUE: SHOULD THE U.S. GOVERNMENT TRY TO STOP THE DOLLAR FROM FALLING? 764

INTERNATIONAL TRADE, EXCHANGE RATES, AND AGGREGATE DEMAND 764 Relative Prices, Exports, and Imports 765 The Effects of Changes in Exchange Rates 765

AGGREGATE SUPPLY IN AN OPEN ECONOMY 766 THE MACROECONOMIC EFFECTS OF EXCHANGE RATES 767 Interest Rates and International Capital Flows 768

FISCAL AND MONETARY POLICIES IN AN OPEN ECONOMY 768 Fiscal Policy Revisited 768 Monetary Policy Revisited 770

INTERNATIONAL ASPECTS OF DEFICIT REDUCTION 770 The Loose Link between the Budget Deficit and the Trade Deficit 771

SHOULD WE WORRY ABOUT THE TRADE DEFICIT? 772 ON CURING THE TRADE DEFICIT 772 Change the Mix of Fiscal and Monetary Policy 772 More Rapid Economic Growth Abroad 773 Raise Domestic Saving or Reduce Domestic Investment 773 Protectionism 773

CONCLUSION: NO NATION IS AN ISLAND 774 ISSUE REVISITED: SHOULD THE UNITED STATES LET THE DOLLAR FALL? 775 Summary 775 Key Terms 776 Test Yourself 776 Discussion Questions 776

PART 9

POSTSCRIPT: THE FINANCIAL CRISIS OF 2007–2009 777

Chapter 37 The Financial Crisis and the Great Recession 779 ISSUE: DID THE FISCAL STIMULUS WORK? 780

ROOTS OF THE CRISIS 780 LEVERAGE, PROFITS, AND RISK 782 THE HOUSING PRICE BUBBLE AND THE SUBPRIME MORTGAGE CRISIS 784 FROM THE HOUSING BUBBLE TO THE FINANCIAL CRISIS 786 FROM THE FINANCIAL CRISIS TO THE GREAT RECESSION 788 HITTING BOTTOM AND RECOVERING 791 ISSUE: DID THE FISCAL STIMULUS WORK? 792

LESSONS FROM THE FINANCIAL CRISIS 792 Summary 793 Key Terms 793 Test Yourself 794 Discussion Questions 794

| APPENDIX | Answers to Odd-Numbered Test Yourself Questions 795

Glossary 813 Index 825 Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

xxv

Preface

A

s usual, when updating an edition, we have made many small changes to improve clarity of exposition and to update the text both for recent economics events—the global downturn—and for relevant advances in the literature. But this time we have focused on two particular additions. One is a host of changes pertaining to the stunning economic events of 2007–2009. These appear scattered all over the macroeconomic chapters, but especially in the all-new Chapter 37 on the financial crisis and the Great Recession. The second, introduced in the eleventh edition, is a substantial discussion of the role of the entrepreneurs and of the microtheory of their activities, their pricing and their earnings, and the implications for economic growth. Several studies of the place of the entrepreneur in economics textbooks (including earlier editions of this one) have all reached the same conclusion: that entrepreneurs are either completely invisible or are virtually so. Indeed, in a substantial set of the textbooks the word entrepreneur does not even appear in the index. Now, this omission should appear strange because entrepreneurs are often classified as one of the four factors of production—but the only one to which no chapter is devoted. More than that, it seems universally recognized by economists that economic growth is the prime contributor to the general welfare and that more than 80 percent of the current income of the average American was contributed by growth in the past century alone. Moreover, it is clear that, even though entrepreneurs did not produce this growth by themselves, much, if not most, of this historically unprecedented achievement would not have occurred without them. Yet, in the textbooks, they have been the invisible men and women. More than that, the description and analysis of the activities of entrepreneurs is evidently a topic in microeconomics: the incentives and the responses of the individual actors in the economy. This means that analysis of economic growth and policies for its stimulation need to be examined from two sides: the macroeconomic, where issues such as the requisite savings and investment are studied, and the microeconomic, where the twin activities of invention and entrepreneurship are analyzed. Yet the discussion of growth in most textbooks is entirely confined to the macro sections of the volume, with the subject completely absent from the micro analysis. In our new edition, as the reader will see, this is no longer so. In addition to the usual discussion of growth in the macro portion of the book, there is a complete chapter on the microeconomics of growth and half a chapter on the entrepreneur as one of the two human factors of production. This eleventh edition is the product of nearly 30 years of the existence and modification of this book. In the responses to a survey of faculty users, it became clear that a number of chapters were generally not covered by instructors for lack of time, although the material is of considerable interest to students and is not—or need not be—technically demanding. So we simplified several such chapters further—notably Chapter 9 on the stock and bond markets, Chapter 13 on regulation and antitrust, Chapter 17 on environmental economics, and Chapter 21 on poverty and inequality—to make it practical for an instructor to assign any or all of them to the students for reading entirely by themselves. In the micro sections of the book, we have added a number of new materials in response to requests by correspondents. For example, in the material on the staticoptimality properties of perfect competition, we added a discussion of the Coase theorem and more on behavioral economics. But as already indicated, the primary change was in the new material on the microeconomics of growth and entrepreneurship. In the macroeconomic portions of the book, we try to make the links between the short run and the long run clearer and more explicit with each passing edition. For the updated eleventh edition, we have also added much new material on the problems in the subprime mortgage markets, the ensuing financial crisis and possible recession, and several economic issues in the 2008 presidential campaign. As is our practice, these new materials are scattered over many chapters of the text, so as to locate the discussions of current events xxvii

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

xxviii

Preface

and policy close to the places where the relevant principles are taught. This edition also adds a bit more material on China; sadly, the experience in Zimbabwe has provided a contemporary example of hyperinflation. We ended this section of the preface to the tenth edition by singling out the critical contributions of one colleague and friend of amazingly long duration. We now repeat some of our words about the late Sue Anne Batey Blackman, who worked closely with us through 10 editions of this book; for all practical purposes, she had become a co-author. Indeed, the chapter on environmental matters is now largely her product. Her creative mind guided our efforts; her eagle eyes caught our errors; and her stimulating and pleasant company kept us going. Perhaps most important, we loved and valued her most profoundly. Unfortunately, she has been taken from us much too young. Our children and grandchildren will understand and surely support our decision not to dedicate this edition of the book to them, but rather to our precious lost friend, Sue Anne.

NOTE TO THE STUDENT May we offer a suggestion for success in your economics course? Unlike some of the other subjects you may be studying, economics is cumulative: Each week’s lesson builds on what you have learned before. You will save yourself a lot of frustration—and a lot of work—by keeping up on a week-to-week basis. To assist you in doing so, we provide a chapter summary, a list of important terms and concepts, a selection of questions to help you review the contents of each chapter, as well as the answers to odd-numbered Test Yourself questions. Making use of these learning aids will help you to master the material in your economics course. For additional assistance, we have prepared student supplements to help in the reinforcement of the concepts in this book and provide opportunities for practice and feedback. The following list indicates the ancillary materials and learning tools that have been designed specifically to be helpful to you. If you believe any of these resources could benefit you in your course of study, you may want to discuss them with your instructor. Further information on these resources is available at http://academic.cengage.com/economics/ baumol. We hope our book is helpful to you in your study of economics and welcome your comments or suggestions for improving student experience with economics. Please write to us in care of Baumol and Blinder, Editor for Economics, South-Western/Cengage Learning 5191 Natorp Boulevard, Mason, Ohio, 45040, or through the book’s web site at http://academic.cengage.com/economics/baumol.

CourseMate Multiple resources for learning and reinforcing principles concepts are now available in one place! CourseMate is your one-stop shop for the learning tools and activities to help you succeed. Access online resources like ABC News Videos, Ask the Instructor Videos, Flash Cards, Interactive Quizzing, the Graphing Workshop, News Articles, Economic debates, Links to Economic Data, and more. Visit www.cengagebrain.com to see the study options available with this text.

Study Guide The study guide assists you in understanding the text’s main concepts. It includes learning objectives, lists of important concepts and terms for each chapter, quizzes, multiplechoice tests, lists of supplementary readings, and study questions for each chapter—all of which help you test your understanding and comprehension of the key concepts.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Preface

IN GRATITUDE Finally, we are pleased to acknowledge our mounting indebtedness to the many who have generously helped us in our efforts through the nearly 30-year history of this book. We often have needed help in dealing with some of the many subjects that an introductory textbook must cover. Our friends and colleagues Charles Berry, Princeton University; Rebecca Blank, University of Michigan; William Branson, Princeton University; Gregory Chow, Princeton University; Avinash Dixit, Princeton University; Susan Feiner, University of Southern Maine; Claudia Goldin, Harvard University; Ronald Grieson, University of California, Santa Cruz; Daniel Hamermesh, University of Texas; Yuzo Honda, Osaka University; Peter Kenen, Princeton University; Melvin Krauss, Stanford University; Herbert Levine, University of Pennsylvania; Burton Malkiel, Princeton University; Edwin Mills, Northwestern University; Janusz Ordover, New York University; David H. Reiley Jr., University of Arizona; Uwe Reinhardt, Princeton University; Harvey Rosen, Princeton University; Laura Tyson, University of California, Berkeley; and Martin Weitzman, Harvard University have all given generously of their knowledge in particular areas over the course of 10 editions. We have learned much from them and have shamelessly relied on their help. Economists and students at colleges and universities other than ours offered numerous useful suggestions for improvements, many of which we have incorporated into this eleventh edition. We wish to thank Larry Allen, Lamar University; Nestor M. Arguea, University of West Florida; Gerald Bialka, University of North Florida; Kyongwook Choi, Ohio University; Basil G. Coley, North Carolina A &T State University; Carol A. Conrad, Cerro Coso Community College; Brendan Cushing-Daniels, Gettysburg College; Edward J. Deak, Fairfield University; Kruti Dholakia, The University of Texas at Dallas; Aimee Dimmerman, George Washington University; Mark Gius, Quinnipiac University; Ahmed Ispahani, University of La Verne; Jin Kim, Georgetown University; Christine B. Lloyd, Western Illinois University; Laura Maghoney, Solano Community College; Kosmas Marinakis, North Carolina State University; Carl B. Montano, Lamar University; Steve Pecsok, Middlebury College; J. M. Pogodzinski, San Jose State University; Adina Schwartz, Lakeland College; David Tufte, Southern Utah University; and Thierry Warin, Middlebury College for their insightful reviews. Obviously, the book you hold in your hands was not produced by us alone. An essential role was played by Susan Walsh, who stepped into the space vacated by Sue Anne and handled the tasks superbly, with insight and reliability, and did so in a most pleasant manner. In updating the eleventh edition, Anne Noyes Saini helped to refresh data and information throughout the book, and our colleague William Silber, New York University, generously helped us draft new content on derivatives and securitization—we thank both for their contributions. We also appreciate the contribution of the staff at SouthWestern Cengage Learning, including Joe Sabatino, Editor-in-Chief; Michael Worls, Executive Editor; John Carey, Senior Marketing Manager; Katie Yanos, Supervising Developmental Editor; Emily Nesheim, Content Project Manager; Deepak Kumar, Media Editor; Michelle Kunkler, Senior Art Director; Deanna Ettinger, Photo Manager; and Sandee Milewski, Senior Manufacturing Coordinator. It was a pleasure to deal with them, and we appreciate their understanding of our approaches, our goals, and our idiosyncrasies. We also thank our intelligent and delightful assistants at Princeton University and New York University, Kathleen Hurley and Janeece Roderick Lewis, who struggled successfully with the myriad tasks involved in completing the manuscript. And, finally, we must not omit our continuing debt to our wives, Hilda Baumol and Madeline Blinder. They have now suffered through 11 editions and the inescapable neglect and distraction the preparation of each new edition imposes. Their tolerance and understanding has been no minor contribution to the project. William J. Baumol Alan S. Blinder

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

xxix

About the Authors WILLIAM J. BAUMOL William J. Baumol was born in New York City and received his BSS at the College of the City of New York and his Ph.D. at the University of London. He is the Harold Price Professor of Entrepreneurship and Academic Director of the Berkley Center for Entrepreneurial Studies at New York University, where he teaches a course in introductory microeconomics, and the Joseph Douglas Green, 1895, Professor of Economics Emeritus and Senior Economist at Princeton University. He is a frequent consultant to the management of major firms in a wide variety of industries in the United States and other countries as well as to a number of governmental agencies. In several fields, including the telecommunications and electric utility industries, current regulatory policy is based on his explicit recommendations. Among his many contributions to economics are research on the theory of the firm, the contestability of markets, the economics of the arts and other services—the “cost disease of the services” is often referred to as “Baumol’s disease“—and economic growth, entrepreneurship, and innovation. In addition to economics, he taught a course in wood sculpture at Princeton for about 20 years and is an accomplished painter (you Alan Blinder and Will Baumol may view some of his paintings at http://pages.stern.nyu.edu/~wbaumol/). Professor Baumol has been president of the American Economic Association and three other professional societies. He is an elected member of the National Academy of Sciences, created by the U.S. Congress, and of the American Philosophical Society, founded by Benjamin Franklin. He is also on the board of trustees of the National Council on Economic Education and of the Theater Development Fund. He is the recipient of 11 honorary degrees. Baumol is the author of hundreds of journal and newspaper articles and more than 35 books, including Global Trade and Conflicting National Interests (2000); The Free-Market Innovation Machine (2002); Good Capitalism, Bad Capitalism (2007); and The Microtheory of Innovative Entrepreneurship (2010). His writings have been translated into more than a dozen languages.

ALAN S. BLINDER Alan S. Blinder was born in New York City and attended Princeton University, where one of his teachers was William Baumol. After earning a master’s degree at the London School of Economics and a Ph.D. at MIT, Blinder returned to Princeton, where he has taught since 1971, including teaching introductory macroeconomics since 1977. He is currently the Gordon S. Rentschler Memorial Professor of Economics and Public Affairs and co-director of Princeton’s Center for Economic Policy Studies, which he founded. In January 1993, Blinder went to Washington as part of President Clinton’s first Council of Economic Advisers. Then, from June 1994 through January 1996, he served as vice chairman of the Federal Reserve Board. He thus played a role in formulating both the fiscal and monetary policies of the 1990s, topics discussed extensively in this book. He has also advised several presidential campaigns. Blinder has consulted for a number of the world’s largest financial institutions, testified dozens of times before congressional committees, and been involved in several entrepreneurial start-ups. For many years, he has written newspaper and magazine articles on economic policy, and he currently has a regular column in the Wall Street Journal. In addition, Blinder’s op-ed pieces still appear periodically in other newspapers. He also appears frequently on PBS, CNN, CNBC, and Bloomberg TV. xxxi

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

xxxii

About the Authors

Blinder has served as president of the Eastern Economic Association and vice president of the American Economic Association and is a member of the American Philosophical Society, the American Academy of Arts and Sciences, and the Council on Foreign Relations. He has two grown sons, two grandsons, and lives in Princeton with his wife, where he plays tennis as often as he can.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Part

Getting Acquainted with Economics

W

elcome to economics! Some of your fellow students may have warned you that “econ is boring.” Don’t believe them—or at least, don’t believe them too much. It is true that studying economics is hardly pure fun. But a first course in economics can be an eye-opening experience. There is a vast and important world out there—the economic world—and this book is designed to help you understand it. Have you ever wondered whether jobs will be plentiful or scarce when you graduate, or why a college education becomes more and more expensive? Should the government be suspicious of big firms? Why can’t pollution be eliminated? How did the U.S. economy manage to grow so rapidly in the 1990s while Japan’s economy stagnated? If any of these questions have piqued your curiosity, read on. You may find economics is more interesting than you had thought! It is only in later chapters that we will begin to give you the tools you need to begin carrying out your own economic analyses. However, the four chapters of Part 1 that we list next will introduce you to both the subject matter of economics and some of the methods that economists use to study their subject.

C H A P T E R S 1 | What Is Economics? 2 | The Economy: Myth and Reality

3 | The Fundamental Economic

Problem: Scarcity and Choice

4 | Supply and Demand: An Initial Look

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

What Is Economics? Why does public discussion of economic policy so often show the abysmal ignorance of the participants? Why do I so often want to cry at what public figures, the press, and television commentators say about economic affairs? ROBERT M . S OLOW, WI NNER OF THE 1987 NOBEL PRIZE IN ECONOMICS

E

conomics is a broad-ranging discipline, both in the questions it asks and the methods it uses to seek answers. Many of the world’s most pressing problems are economic in nature. The first part of this chapter is intended to give you some idea of the sorts of issues that economic analysis helps to clarify and the kinds of solutions that economic principles suggest. The second part briefly introduces the tools that economists use—tools you are likely to find useful in your career, personal life, and role as an informed citizen, long after this course is over.

C O N T E N T S IDEAS FOR BEYOND THE FINAL EXAM Idea 1: How Much Does It Really Cost? Idea 2: Attempts to Repeal the Laws of Supply and Demand—The Market Strikes Back Idea 3: The Surprising Principle of Comparative Advantage Idea 4: Trade Is a Win-Win Situation Idea 5: The Importance of Thinking at the Margin Idea 6: Externalities—A Shortcoming of the Market Cured by Market Methods Idea 7: The Trade-Off between Efficiency and Equality

Idea 8: Government Policies Can Limit Economic Fluctuations—But Don’t Always Succeed Idea 9: The Short-Run Trade-Off between Inflation and Unemployment Idea 10: Productivity Growth Is (Almost) Everything in the Long Run Epilogue

INSIDE THE ECONOMIST’S TOOL KIT Economics as a Discipline The Need for Abstraction The Role of Economic Theory What Is an Economic Model?

Reasons for Disagreements: Imperfect Information and Value Judgments

| APPENDIX | Using Graphs: A Review Graphs Used in Economic Analysis Two-Variable Diagrams The Definition and Measurement of Slope Rays through the Origin and 45° Lines Squeezing Three Dimensions into Two: Contour Maps

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

4

Part 1

Getting Acquainted with Economics

IDEAS FOR BEYOND THE FINAL EXAM

IDEAS FOR BEYOND THE FINAL EXAM

Elephants may never forget, but people do. We realize that most students inevitably forget much of what they learn in a course—perhaps with a sense of relief—soon after the final exam. Nevertheless, we hope that you will remember some of the most significant economic ideas and, even more important, the ways of thinking about economic issues that will help you evaluate the economic issues that arise in our economy. To help you identify some of the most crucial concepts, we have selected 10 from the many in this book. Some offer key insights into the workings of the economy, and several bear on important policy issues that appear in newspapers; others point out common misunderstandings that occur among even the most thoughtful lay observers. Most of them indicate that it takes more than just good common sense to analyze economic issues effectively. As the opening quote of this chapter suggests, many learned judges, politicians, and university administrators who failed to understand basic economic principles could have made wiser decisions. Try this one on for size. Imagine you own a widget manufacturing company that rents a warehouse. Your landlord raises your rent by $10,000 per year. Should you raise the price of your widgets to try to recoup some of your higher costs or should you do the opposite— lower your price to try to sell more and spread the so-called overhead costs over more products? In fact, as we shall see in Chapter 8, both answers are probably wrong! Each of the 10 Ideas for Beyond the Final Exam, many of which are counterintuitive, will be sketched briefly here. More important, each will be discussed in depth when it occurs in the course of the book, where it will be called to your attention by a special icon in the margin. Don’t expect to master these ideas fully now, but do notice how some of the ideas arise again and again as we deal with different topics. By the end of the course you will have a better grasp of when common sense works and when it fails, and you will be able to recognize common fallacies that are all too often offered by public figures, the press, and television commentators.

Idea 1: How Much Does It Really Cost?

The opportunity cost of a decision is the value of the next best alternative that must be given up because of that decision (for example, working instead of going to school).

Because no one has infinite riches, people are constantly forced to make choices. If you purchase a new computer, you may have to give up that trip you had planned. If a business decides to retool its factories, it may have to postpone its plans for new executive offices. If a government expands its defense program, it may be forced to reduce its outlays on school buildings. Economists say that the true costs of such decisions are not the number of dollars spent on the computer, the new equipment, or the military, but rather the value of what must be given up in order to acquire the item—the vacation trip, the new executive offices, and the new schools. These are called opportunity costs because they represent the opportunities the individual, firm, or government must forgo to make the desired expenditure. Economists maintain that rational decision making must be based on opportunity costs, not just dollar costs (see Chapters 3, 8, 14, and 15). The cost of a college education provides a vivid example. How much do you think it costs to go to college? Most people are likely to answer by adding together their expenditures on tuition, room and board, books, and the like, and then deducting any scholarship funds they may receive. Suppose that amount comes to $15,000. Economists keep score differently. They first want to know how much you would be earning if you were not attending college. Suppose that salary is $20,000 per year. This may seem irrelevant, but because you give up these earnings by attending college, they must be added to your tuition bill. You have that much less income because of your education. On the other side of the ledger, economists would not count all of the university’s bill for room and board as part of the costs of your education. They would want to know how much more it costs you to live at school rather than at home. Economists would count only these extra costs as an educational expense because you would have incurred these

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 1

What Is Economics?

costs whether or not you attend college. On balance, college is probably costing you much more than you think. And, as we will see later, taking opportunity cost into account in any personal planning will help you to make more rational decisions.

Idea 2: Attempts to Repeal the Laws of Supply and Demand—The Market Strikes Back When a commodity is in short supply, its price naturally tends to rise. Sometimes disgruntled consumers badger politicians into “solving” this problem by making the high prices illegal—by imposing a ceiling on the price. Similarly, when supplies are plentiful—say, when fine weather produces extraordinarily abundant crops—prices tend to fall. Falling prices naturally dismay producers, who often succeed in getting legislators to impose price floors. Such attempts to repeal the laws of supply and demand usually backfire and sometimes produce results virtually the opposite of those intended. Where rent controls are adopted to protect tenants, housing grows scarce because the law makes it unprofitable to build and maintain apartments. When price floors are placed under agricultural products, surpluses pile up because people buy less. As we will see in Chapter 4 and elsewhere in this book, such consequences of interference with the price mechanism are not accidental. They follow inevitably from the way in which free markets work.

Idea 3: The Surprising Principle of Comparative Advantage China today produces many products that Americans buy in huge quantities, including toys, textiles, and electronic equipment. American manufacturers often complain about Chinese competition and demand protection from the flood of imports that, in their view, threatens American standards of living. Is this view justified? Economists think that it is often false. They maintain that both sides normally gain from international trade, but what if the Chinese were able to produce everything more cheaply than we can? Wouldn’t Americans be thrown out of work and our nation be impoverished? A remarkable result, called the law of comparative advantage, shows that, even in this extreme case, the two nations could still benefit by trading and that each could gain as a result! We will explain this principle first in Chapter 3 and then more fully in Chapter 34. For now, a simple parable will make the reason clear. Suppose Sally grows up on a farm and is a whiz at plowing, but she is also a successful country singer who earns $4,000 per performance. Should Sally turn down singing engagements to leave time to work the fields? Of course not. Instead, she should hire Alfie, a much less efficient farmer, to do the plowing for her. Sally may be better at plowing, but she earns so much more by singing that it makes sense for her to specialize in that and leave the farming to Alfie. Although Alfie is a less skilled farmer than Sally, he is an even worse singer. So Alfie earns his living in the job at which he at least has a comparative advantage (his farming is not as inferior as his singing), and both Alfie and Sally gain. The same is true of two countries. Even if one of them is more efficient at everything, both countries can gain by producing the things they do best comparatively.

Idea 4: Trade Is a Win-Win Situation One of the most fundamental ideas of economics is that both parties must expect to gain something in a voluntary exchange. Otherwise, why would they both agree to trade? This principle seems self-evident, yet it is amazing how often it is ignored in practice. For example, it was widely believed for centuries that in international trade one country’s gain from an exchange must be the other country’s loss (Chapter 34). Analogously, some people feel instinctively that if Ms. A profits handsomely from a deal with Mr. B,

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

5

6

Part 1

Getting Acquainted with Economics

then Mr. B must have been exploited. Laws sometimes prohibit mutually beneficial exchanges between buyers and sellers—as when a loan transaction is banned because the interest rate is “too high” (Chapter 19), or when a willing worker is condemned to remain unemployed because the wage she is offered is “too low” (Chapter 20), or when the resale of tickets to sporting events (“ticket scalping”) is outlawed even though the buyer is happy to get the ticket that he could not obtain at a lower price (Chapter 4). In every one of these cases, well-intentioned but misguided reasoning blocks the possible mutual gains that arise from voluntary exchange and thereby interferes with one of the most basic functions of an economic system (see Chapter 3).

Idea 5: The Importance of Thinking at the Margin We will devote many pages of this book to explaining and extolling a type of decisionmaking process called marginal analysis (see especially Chapters 5, 7, 8, and 14), which we can best illustrate through an example. Suppose an airline is told by its accountants that the full average cost of transporting one passenger from Los Angeles to New York is $300. Can the airline profit by offering a reduced fare of $200 to students who fly on a standby basis? The surprising answer is probably yes. The reason is that most of the costs of the flight must be paid whether the plane carries 20 passengers or 120 passengers. Costs such as maintenance, landing rights, and ground crews are irrelevant to the decision of whether to carry additional standby passengers at reduced rates. The only costs that are relevant are the extra costs of writing and processing additional tickets, the food and beverages consumed by these passengers, the additional fuel required, and so on. These so-called marginal costs are probably quite small in this example. A passenger who pays the airline any amount more than it costs the airline to give her a seat that would otherwise be unused (its marginal cost of flying her) adds something to the company’s profit. So it probably is more profitable to let students ride at low fares than to leave the seats empty. In many real cases, a failure to understand marginal analysis leads decision makers to reject advantageous possibilities, like the reduced fare in our example. These people are misled by using average rather than marginal cost figures in their calculations—an error that can be very costly.

Idea 6: Externalities—A Shortcoming of the Market Cured by Market Methods Markets are adept at producing the goods that consumers want and in just the quantities they desire. They do so by rewarding those who respond to what consumers want and who produce these commodities economically. This all works out well as long as each exchange involves only the buyer and the seller—and no one else. However, some transactions affect third parties who were not involved in the decision. Examples abound: Electric utilities that generate power for midwestern states also produce pollution that kills freshwater fish in upstate New York. A farmer sprays crops with toxic pesticides, but the poison seeps into the groundwater and affects the health of neighboring communities. Such social costs are called externalities because they affect parties external to the economic transactions that cause them. Externalities escape the control of the market mechanism because no financial incentive motivates polluters to minimize the damage they do—as we will learn in Chapters 15 and 17. So business firms make their products as cheaply as possible, disregarding any environmental harm they may cause. Yet Chapters 15 and 17 will point out a way for the government to use the market mechanism to control undesirable externalities. If the electric utility and the farmer are charged for the clean air and water they use, just as they are charged for any coal and fertilizer they consume, then they will have a financial incentive to reduce the amount of pollution they generate. Thus, in this case, economists believe that market methods are often the best way to cure one of the market’s most important shortcomings.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 1

What Is Economics?

Idea 7: The Trade-Off between Efficiency and Equality Wages and income have grown more unequal in the United States since the late 1970s. Highly skilled workers have pulled away from low-skilled workers. The rich have grown richer while the poor have become (relatively) poorer, yet U.S. unemployment has been much lower than that in Europe for many years. In many European countries inequality has not grown more extreme. Many economists see these phenomena as two sides of the same coin. Europe and the United States have made different choices regarding how best to balance the conflicting claims of greater economic efficiency (more output and jobs) versus greater equality. Roughly speaking, the American solution is to let markets work to promote efficiency— something they are very good at doing—with only minimal government interferences to reduce economic inequalities. (Some of these interferences are studied in Chapter 21.) However, much of continental Europe takes a different view. They find it scandalous that many Americans work for less than $6 per hour, with virtually no fringe benefits and no job security. European laws mandate not only relatively high minimum wages but also substantial fringe benefits and employment protections; of course, European taxes must be much higher to pay for these programs. As economists see it, each system’s virtue is also its vice. There is an agonizing trade-off between the size of a nation’s output and the degree of equality with which that output is distributed. European-style policies designed to divide the proverbial economic pie more equally inadvertently can cause the size of the pie to shrink. American-style arrangements that promote maximal efficiency and output may permit or even breed huge inequalities and poverty. Which system is better? There is no clear answer, but we will examine the issue in detail in Chapter 21.

Idea 8: Government Policies Can Limit Economic Fluctuations—But Don’t Always Succeed One of the most persistent problems of market economies has been their tendency to go through cycles of boom and bust. The booms, as we shall see, often bring inflation, and the busts always raise unemployment. Years ago, economists, businesspeople, and politicians viewed these fluctuations as inevitable: there was nothing the government could or should do about them. That view is now considered obsolete. As we will learn in Part 6, and especially Part 7, modern governments have an arsenal of weapons that they can and do deploy to try to mitigate fluctuations in their national economies—to limit both inflation and unemployment. Some of these weapons constitute what is called fiscal policy: control over taxes and government spending. Others come from monetary policy: control over money and interest rates. Trying to tame the business cycle is not the same as succeeding. Economic fluctuations remain with us, and one reason is that the government’s fiscal and monetary policies sometimes fail—for both political and economic reasons. As we will see in Part 7, policy makers do not always make the right decisions. And even when they do, the economy does not always react as expected. Furthermore, for reasons we will explain later, the “right” decision is not always clear.

Idea 9: The Short-Run Trade-Off between Inflation and Unemployment The U.S. economy was lucky in the second half of the 1990s. A set of fortuitous events— falling energy prices, tumbling computer prices, a rising dollar, and so on—pushed inflation down even as unemployment fell to its lowest level in almost 30 years. During the 1970s and early 1980s, the United States was not so fortunate. Skyrocketing prices for food and energy sent both inflation and unemployment up to extraordinary heights. In both episodes, then, inflation and unemployment moved in the same direction.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

7

8

Part 1

Getting Acquainted with Economics

But economists maintain that neither of these two episodes was “normal.” When we are experiencing neither unusually good luck (as in the 1990s) nor exceptionally bad luck (as in the 1970s), there is a trade-off between inflation and unemployment—meaning that low unemployment normally makes inflation rise and high unemployment normally makes inflation fall. We will study the mechanisms underlying this trade-off in Parts 6 and 7, especially in Chapter 33. It poses one of the fundamental dilemmas of national economic policy.

Idea 10: Productivity Growth Is (Almost) Everything in the Long Run Today in Geneva, Switzerland, workers in a watch factory turn out more than 100 times as many mechanical watches per year as their ancestors did three centuries earlier. The productivity of labor (output per hour of work) in cotton production has probably gone up more than 1,000-fold in 200 years. It is estimated that rising labor productivity has increased the standard of living of a typical American worker approximately sevenfold in the past century (see Chapters 16 and 24). Other economic issues such as unemployment, monopoly, and inequality are important to us all and will receive much attention in this book, but in the long run, nothing has as great an effect on our material well-being and the amounts society can afford to spend on hospitals, schools, and social amenities as the rate of growth of productivity—the amount that an average worker can produce in an hour. Chapter 16 points out that what appears to be a small increase in productivity growth can have a huge effect on a country’s standard of living over a long period of time because productivity compounds like the interest on savings in a bank. Similarly, a slowdown in productivity growth that persists for a substantial number of years can have a devastating effect on living standards.

Epilogue These ideas are some of the more fundamental concepts you will find in this book—ideas that we hope you will retain beyond the final exam. There is no need to master them right now, for you will hear much more about each as you progress through the book. By the end of the course, you may be amazed to see how natural, or even obvious, they will seem.

INSIDE THE ECONOMIST’S TOOL KIT We turn now from the kinds of issues economists deal with to some of the tools they use to grapple with them.

Economics as a Discipline Although economics is clearly the most rigorous of the social sciences, it nevertheless looks decidedly more “social” than “scientific” when compared with, say, physics. An economist must be a jack of several trades, borrowing modes of analysis from numerous fields. Mathematical reasoning is often used in economics, but so is historical study. And neither looks quite the same as when practiced by a mathematician or a historian. Statistics play a major role in modern economic inquiry, although economists had to modify standard statistical procedures to fit their kinds of data.

The Need for Abstraction Some students find economics unduly abstract and “unrealistic.” The stylized world envisioned by economic theory seems only a distant cousin to the world they know. There is an old joke about three people—a chemist, a physicist, and an economist—stranded on an desert island with an ample supply of canned food but no tools to open the cans. The chemist thinks that lighting a fire under the cans would burst the cans. The physicist advocates building a catapult with which to smash the cans against some boulders. The economist’s suggestion? “Assume a can opener.” Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Abstraction from unimportant details is necessary to understand the functioning of anything as complex as the economy.

SOURCE: From The Wall Street Journal. Permission, Cartoon Features Syndicate.

Economic theory does make some unrealistic assumptions— you will encounter some of them in this book—but some abstraction from reality is necessary because of the incredible complexity of the economic world, not because economists like to sound absurd. Compare the chemist’s simple task of explaining the interactions of compounds in a chemical reaction with the economist’s complex task of explaining the interactions of people in an economy. Are molecules motivated by greed or altruism, by envy or ambition? Do they ever imitate other molecules? Do forecasts about them influence their behavior? People, of course, do all these things and many, many more. It is therefore vastly more difficult to predict human behavior than to predict chemical reactions. If economists tried to keep track of every feature of human behavior, they would never get anywhere. Thus:

9

What Is Economics?

Chapter 1

“Yes, John, we’d all like to make economics less dismal . . . “

NOTE: The nineteenth-century British writer Thomas Carlyle described An analogy will make it clear why economists abstract from economics as the “dismal science,” a label that stuck. details. Suppose you have just arrived for the first time in Los Angeles. You are now at the Los Angeles Civic Center—the point marked A in Maps 1 and Abstraction means 2, which are alternative maps of part of Los Angeles. You want to drive to the Los Angeles ignoring many details so as to focus on the most County Museum of Art, point B on each map. Which map would be more useful? Map 1 has complete details of the Los Angeles road system, but this makes it hard to important elements of a read and hard to use as a way to find the art museum. For this purpose, Map 1 is far too problem. detailed, although for other purposes (for example, locating a small street in Hollywood) it may be far better than Map 2. In contrast, Map 2 omits many minor roads—you might say they are assumed away—so that the freeways and major arteries stand out more clearly. As a result of this simplification, several routes from the Civic Center to the Los Angeles County Museum of Art

MAP 1

SOURCE: Map © by Rand McNally, RL. 08-S-32. Reprinted by permission.

Detailed Road Map of Los Angeles

NOTE: Point A marks the Los Angeles Civic Center, and Point B marks the Los Angeles County Museum of Art.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

10

Part 1

Getting Acquainted with Economics

M AP 2

SOURCE: Map © by Rand McNally, R.L.04-S-14. Reprinted by permission.

Major Los Angeles Arteries and Freeways

emerge. For example, we can take the Hollywood Freeway west to Alvarado Boulevard, go south to Wilshire Boulevard, and then head west again. Although we might find a shorter route by poring over the details in Map 1, most strangers to the city would be better off with Map 2. Similarly, economists try to abstract from a lot of confusing details while retaining the essentials. Map 3, however, illustrates that simplification can go too far. It shows little more than the major interstate routes that pass through the greater Los Angeles area and therefore

M AP 3

SOURCE: California Department of Transportation

Greater Los Angeles Freeways

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 1

11

What Is Economics?

will not help a visitor find the art museum. Of course, this map was never intended to be used as a detailed tourist guide, which brings us to an important point: There is no such thing as one “right” degree of abstraction and simplification for all analytic purposes. The proper degree of abstraction depends on the objective of the analysis. A model that is a gross oversimplification for one purpose may be needlessly complicated for another.

Economists are constantly seeking analogies to Map 2 rather than Map 3, walking the thin line between useful generalizations about complex issues and gross distortions of the pertinent facts. For example, suppose you want to learn why some people are fabulously rich whereas others are abjectly poor. People differ in many ways, too many to enumerate, much less to study. The economist must ignore most of these details to focus on the important ones. The color of a person’s hair or eyes is probably not important for the problem but, unfortunately, the color of his or her skin probably is because racial discrimination can depress a person’s income. Height and weight may not matter, but education probably does. Proceeding in this way, we can pare Map 1 down to the manageable dimensions of Map 2. But there is a danger of going too far, stripping away some of the crucial factors, so that we wind up with Map 3.

The Role of Economic Theory Some students find economics “too theoretical.” To see why we can’t avoid it, let’s consider what we mean by a theory. To an economist or natural scientist, the word theory means something different from what it means in common speech. In science, a theory is not an untested assertion of alleged fact. The statement that aspirin provides protection against heart attacks is not a theory; it is a hypothesis, that is, a reasoned guess, which will prove to be true or false once the right sorts of experiments have been completed. But a theory is different. It is a deliberate simplification (abstraction) of reality that attempts to explain how some relationships work. It is an explanation of the mechanism behind observed phenomena. Thus, gravity forms the basis of theories that describe and explain the paths of the planets. Similarly, Keynesian theory (discussed in Parts 6 and 7) seeks to describe and explain how government policies affect unemployment and prices in the national economy. People who have never studied economics often draw a false distinction between theory and practical policy. Politicians and businesspeople, in particular, often reject abstract economic theory as something that is best ignored by “practical” people. The irony of these statements is that

A theory is a deliberate simplification of relationships used to explain how those relationships work.

It is precisely the concern for policy that makes economic theory so necessary and important.

To analyze policy options, economists are forced to deal with possibilities that have not actually occurred. For example, to learn how to shorten periods of high unemployment, they must investigate whether a proposed new policy that has never been tried can help. Or to determine which environmental programs will be most effective, they must understand how and why a market economy produces pollution and what might happen if the government taxed industrial waste discharges and automobile emissions. Such questions require some theorizing, not just examination of the facts, because we need to consider possibilities that have never occurred. The facts, moreover, can sometimes be highly misleading. Data often indicate that two variables move up and down together. But this statistical correlation does not prove that either variable causes the other. For example, when it rains, people drive slower and there are also more traffic accidents, but no one thinks slower driving causes more accidents when it’s raining. Rather, we understand that both phenomena are caused by a common underlying factor—more rain. How do we know this? Not just by looking at the correlation between data on accidents and driving speeds. Data alone tell us little about cause and effect. We must use some simple theory as part of our analysis. In this case, the theory might explain that drivers are more apt to have accidents on wet roads.

Two variables are said to be correlated if they tend to go up or down together. Correlation need not imply causation.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

12

Part 1

Getting Acquainted with Economics

Similarly, we must use theoretical analysis, and not just data alone, to understand how, if at all, different government policies will lead to lower unemployment or how a tax on emissions will reduce pollution. Statistical correlation need not imply causation. Some theory is usually needed to interpret data.

What Is an Economic Model? An economic model is a representation of a theory or a part of a theory, often used to gain insight into cause and effect. The notion of a “model” is familiar enough to children; and economists—like other researchers—use the term the same way children do. A child’s model airplane looks and operates much like the real thing, but it is smaller and simpler, so it is easier to manipulate and understand. Engineers for Boeing also build models of planes. Although their models are far larger and much more elaborate than a child’s toy, they use them for the same purposes: to observe the workings of these aircraft “up close” and to experiment to see how the models behave under different circumstances. (“What happens if I do this?”) From these experiments, they make educated guesses as to how the real-life version will perform. Economists use models for similar purposes. The late A. W. Phillips, famous engineer-turned-economist who discovered the “Phillips curve” (discussed in Chapter 33), was talented enough to construct a working model of the determination of national income in a simple economy by using colored water flowing through pipes. For years this contraption has graced the basement of the London School of Economics. Although we will explain the models with words and diagrams, Phillips’s engineering background enabled him to depict the theory with tubes, valves, and pumps. Because many of the models used in this book are depicted in diagrams, for those of you who need review, we explain the construction and use of various types of graphs in the appendix to this chapter. Don’t be put off by seemingly abstract models. Think of them as useful road maps and remember how hard it would be to find your way around Los Angeles without one. SOURCE: Science Museum/Science & Society Picture Library

An economic model is a simplified, small-scale version of an aspect of the economy. Economic models are often expressed in equations, by graphs, or in words.

Reasons for Disagreements: Imperfect Information and Value Judgments

“If all the earth’s economists were laid end to end, they could not reach an agreement,” the saying goes. Politicians and reporters are fond of pointing out that economists can be found on both sides of many public policy issues. If economics is a science, why do economists so often disagree? After all, astronomers do not debate whether the earth revolves around the sun or vice versa. This question reflects a misunderstanding of the nature of science. Disputes are normal at the frontier of any science. For example, astronomers once argued vociferously over whether the earth revolves around the sun. Nowadays, they argue about gamma-ray bursts, dark matter, and other esoterica. These arguments go mostly unnoticed by the public because few of us understand what they are talking about. But economics is a social science, so its disputes are aired in public and all sorts of people feel competent to join economic debates. Furthermore, economists actually agree on much more than is commonly supposed. Virtually all economists, regardless of their politics, agree that taxing polluters is one of the best ways to protect the environment (see Chapters 15 and 17), that rent controls can ruin a city (Chapter 4), and that free trade among nations is usually preferable to the erection of barriers through tariffs and quotas (see Chapter 34). The list could go on and on. It

A. W. Phillips built this model in the early 1950s to illustrate Keynesian theory.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

What Is Economics?

Chapter 1

13

is probably true that the issues about which economists agree far exceed the subjects on which they disagree. Finally, many disputes among economists are not scientific disputes at all. Sometimes the pertinent facts are simply unknown. For example, you will learn in Chapter 17 that the appropriate financial penalty to levy on a polluter depends on quantitative estimates of the harm done by the pollutant; however, good estimates of this damage may not be available. Similarly, although there is wide scientific agreement that the earth is slowly warming, there are disagreements over the costs of global warming. Such disputes make it difficult to agree on a concrete policy proposal. Another important source of disagreements is that economists, like other people, come in all political stripes: conservative, middle-of-the-road, liberal, radical. Each may have different values, and so each may hold a different view of the “right” solution to a public policy problem—even if they agree on the underlying analysis. Here are two examples: 1. We suggested early in this chapter that policies that lower inflation are likely to raise unemployment. Many economists believe they can measure the amount of unemployment that must be endured to reduce inflation by a given amount. However, they disagree about whether it is worth having, say, three million more people out of work for a year to cut the inflation rate by 1 percent. 2. In designing an income tax, society must decide how much of the burden to put on upper-income taxpayers. Some people believe the rich should pay a disproportionate share of the taxes. Others disagree, believing it is fairer to levy the same income tax rate on everyone. Economists cannot answer questions like these any more than nuclear physicists could have determined whether dropping the atomic bomb on Hiroshima was a good idea. The decisions rest on moral judgments that can be made only by the citizenry through its elected officials. Although economic science can contribute theoretical and factual knowledge on a particular issue, the final decision on policy questions often rests either on information that is not currently available or on social values and ethical opinions about which people differ, or on both.

| SUMMARY | 1. To help you get the most out of your first course in economics, we have devised a list of 10 important ideas that you will want to retain beyond the final exam. Briefly, they are the following: a. Opportunity cost is the correct measure of cost. b. Attempts to fight market forces often backfire. c. Nations can gain from trade by exploiting their comparative advantages. d. Both parties can gain in a voluntary exchange. e. Good decisions typically require marginal analysis, which weighs added costs against added benefits. f. Externalities may cause the market mechanism to malfunction, but this defect can often be repaired by market methods. g. Governments have tools that can mitigate cycles of boom and bust, but these tools are imperfect. h. There is a trade-off between efficiency and equality. Many policies that promote one damage the other.

j. In the long run, productivity is almost the only thing that matters for a society’s material well-being. 2. Common sense is not always a reliable guide in explaining economic issues or in making economic decisions. 3. Because of the great complexity of human behavior, economists are forced to abstract from many details, to make generalizations that they know are not quite true, and to organize what knowledge they have in terms of some theoretical structure called a “model.” 4. Correlation need not imply causation. 5. Economists use simplified models to understand the real world and predict its behavior, much as a child uses a model railroad to learn how trains work. 6. Although these models, if skillfully constructed, can illuminate important economic problems, they rarely can answer the questions that confront policy makers. Value judgments involving such matters as ethics are needed for this purpose, and the economist is no better equipped than anyone else to make them.

i. In the short run, policy makers face a trade-off between inflation and unemployment. Policies that reduce one normally increase the other. Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

14

Part 1

Getting Acquainted with Economics

| KEY TERMS | abstraction

9

economic model

12

correlation

11

opportunity cost

4

theory

11

| DISCUSSION QUESTIONS | 1. Think about a way you would construct a model of how your college is governed. Which officers and administrators would you include and exclude from your model if the objective were one of the following: a. To explain how decisions on financial aid are made b. To explain the quality of the faculty

every word uttered by the lecturer? Why don’t you write down just the title of the lecture and stop there? How do you decide, roughly speaking, on the correct amount of detail? 3. Explain why a government policy maker cannot afford to ignore economic theory.

Relate this to the map example in the chapter. 2. Relate the process of abstraction to the way you take notes in a lecture. Why do you not try to transcribe

| APPENDIX | Using Graphs: A Review1 As noted in the chapter, economists often explain and analyze models with the help of graphs. Indeed, this book is full of them. But that is not the only reason for studying how graphs work. Most college students will deal with graphs in the future, perhaps frequently. You will see them in newspapers. If you become a doctor, you will use graphs to keep track of your patients’ progress. If you join a business firm, you will use them to check profit or performance at a glance. This appendix introduces some of the techniques of graphic analysis—tools you will use throughout the book and, more important, very likely throughout your working career.

GRAPHS USED IN ECONOMIC ANALYSIS Economic graphs are invaluable because they can display a large quantity of data quickly and because they facilitate data interpretation and analysis. They enable the eye to take in at a glance important statistical relationships that would be far less apparent from written descriptions or long lists of numbers.

TWO-VARIABLE DIAGRAMS Much of the economic analysis found in this and other books requires that we keep track of two variables simultaneously. A variable is something measured by a number; it is used to analyze what happens to other things when the size of that number changes (varies). Students who have some acquaintance with geometry and feel quite comfortable with graphs can safely skip this appendix.

1

For example, in studying how markets operate, we will want to keep one eye on the price of a commodity and the other on the quantity of that commodity that is bought and sold. For this reason, economists frequently find it useful to display real or imaginary figures in a two-variable diagram, which simultaneously represents the behavior of two economic variables. The numerical value of one variable is measured along the horizontal line at the bottom of the graph (called the horizontal axis), starting from the origin (the point labeled “0”), and the numerical value of the other variable is measured up the vertical line on the left side of the graph (called the vertical axis), also starting from the origin. The “0” point in the lower-left corner of a graph where the axes meet is called the origin. Both variables are equal to zero at the origin.

Figures 1(a) and 1(b) are typical graphs of economic analysis. They depict an imaginary demand curve, represented by the brick-colored dots in Figure 1(a) and the heavy brick-colored line in Figure 1(b). The graphs show the price of natural gas on their vertical axes and the quantity of gas people want to buy at each price on the horizontal axes. The dots in Figure 1(a) are connected by the continuous brick-colored curve labeled DD in Figure 1(b). Economic diagrams are generally read just as one would read latitudes and longitudes on a map. On the demand curve in Figure 1, the point marked a represents a hypothetical combination of price and quantity of natural gas demanded by customers in St. Louis. By drawing a horizontal line leftward from that point to the vertical axis, we learn that at this point the average price for gas in St. Louis is $3 per thousand cubic feet.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

15

What Is Economics?

Chapter 1

FI GURE 1 6

6

5

5

4 a

P

3

Price

Price

D

4 P

3

a b

b

2

A Hypothetical Demand Curve for Natural Gas in St. Louis

2

D

1

1 0

20

40

60

Q 80 100 120 140

0

Quantity (a)

20

40

60

Q 80 100 120 140

Quantity (b)

NOTE: Price is in dollars per thousand cubic feet; quantity is in billions of cubic feet per year.

TA BLE 1 Quantities of Natural Gas Demanded at Various Prices

Price (per thousand cubic feet) Quantity demanded (billions of cubic feet per year)

$2

$3

$4

$5

$6

120

80

56

38

20

By dropping a line straight down to the horizontal axis, we find that consumers want 80 billion cubic feet per year at this price, just as the statistics in Table 1 show. The other points on the graph give similar information. For example, point b indicates that if natural gas in St. Louis were to cost only $2 per thousand cubic feet, quantity demanded would be higher—it would reach 120 billion cubic feet per year. Notice that information about price and quantity is all we can learn from the diagram. The demand curve will not tell us what kinds of people live in St. Louis, the size of their homes, or the condition of their furnaces. It tells us about the quantity demanded at each possible price—no more, no less. A diagram abstracts from many details, some of which may be quite interesting, so as to focus on the two variables of primary interest—in this case, the price of natural gas and the amount of gas that is demanded at each price. All of the diagrams used in this book share this basic feature. They cannot tell the reader the “whole story,” any more than a map’s latitude and longitude figures for a particular city can make someone an authority on that city.

THE DEFINITION AND MEASUREMENT OF SLOPE One of the most important features of economic diagrams is the rate at which the line or curve being

sketched runs uphill or downhill as we move to the right. The demand curve in Figure 1 clearly slopes downhill (the price falls) as we follow it to the right (that is, as consumers demand more gas). In such instances, we say that the curve has a negative slope, or is negatively sloped, because one variable falls as the other one rises. The slope of a straight line is the ratio of the vertical change to the corresponding horizontal change as we move to the right along the line between two points on that line, or, as it is often said, the ratio of the “rise” over the “run.”

The four panels of Figure 2 show all possible types of slope for a straight-line relationship between two unnamed variables called Y (measured along the vertical axis) and X (measured along the horizontal axis). Figure 2(a) shows a negative slope, much like our demand curve in the previous graph. Figure 2(b) shows a positive slope, because variable Y rises (we go uphill) as variable X rises (as we move to the right). Figure 2(c) shows a zero slope, where the value of Y is the same irrespective of the value of X. Figure 2(d) shows an infinite slope, meaning that the value of X is the same irrespective of the value of Y. Slope is a numerical concept, not just a qualitative one. The two panels of Figure 3 show two positively sloped straight lines with different slopes. The line in Figure 3(b) is clearly steeper. But by how much? The labels should help you compute the answer. In Figure 3(a) a horizontal movement, AB, of 10 units (13 2 3) corresponds to a vertical movement, BC, of 1 unit (9 2 8). So the slope is BC/AB 5 1/10. In Figure 3(b), the same horizontal movement of 10 units corresponds to a vertical movement of 3 units (11 2 8). So the slope is 3/10, which is larger—the rise divided by the run is greater in Figure 3(b). By definition, the slope of any particular straight line remains the same, no matter where on that line we

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

16

Getting Acquainted with Economics

Part 1

F I GURE 2 Different Types of Slope of a Straight-Line Graph

Y

Y

Y

Negative slope

Positive slope

X

0

Y

Zero slope

X

0

(a)

Infinite slope

X

0

(b)

X

0

(c)

(d)

FIGURE 3 How to Measure Slope Y

Y 3 Slope = — 10 C 11

9 8

0

C

1 Slope = — 10 B

A

3

13 (a)

choose to measure it. That is why we can pick any horizontal distance, AB, and the corresponding slope triangle, ABC, to measure slope. But this is not true for curved lines. Curved lines also have slopes, but the numerical value of the slope differs at every point along the curve as we move from left to right.

The four panels of Figure 4 provide some examples of slopes of curved lines. The curve in Figure 4(a) has a negative slope everywhere, and the curve in Figure 4(b) has a positive slope everywhere. But these are not the only possibilities. In Figure 4(c) we encounter a curve that has a positive slope at first but a negative slope later on. Figure 4(d) shows the opposite case: a negative slope followed by a positive slope. We can measure the slope of a smooth curved line numerically at any particular point by drawing a straight line that touches, but does not cut, the curve at

X

8

0

B

A

3

13

X

(b)

the point in question. Such a line is called a tangent to the curve. The slope of a curved line at a particular point is defined as the slope of the straight line that is tangent to the curve at that point.

Figure 5 shows tangents to the brick-colored curve at two points. Line tt is tangent at point T, and line rr is tangent at point R. We can measure the slope of the curve at these two points by applying the definition. The calculation for point T, then, is the following: Slope at point T 5 Slope of line tt 5

5

Distance BC Distance BA

11 2 52 24 5 5 22 13 2 12 2

A similar calculation yields the slope of the curve at point R, which, as we can see from Figure 5, must be

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

17

What Is Economics?

Chapter 1

FIGU R E 4 Behavior of Slopes in Curved Graphs

Y

Y

Y

Y

Negative slope Negative slope

Positive slope

Positive slope

Negative slope

Positive slope X

0

X

0

(a)

(c)

How to Measure Slope at a Point on a Curved Graph

Y

6

D

5

The point at which a straight line cuts the vertical (Y) axis is called the Y-intercept.

R

t

F C

E

4

G

T

3

The Y-intercept of a line or a curve is the point at which it touches the vertical axis (the Y-axis). The X-intercept is defined similarly.

r

M

For example, the Y-intercept of the line in Figure 3(a) is a bit less than 8.

2 1 0

A t

B 1

2

3

(d)

RAYS THROUGH THE ORIGIN AND 45° LINES

r

7

X

0

like valleys, as in Figure 4(d), have a zero slope at their lowest point.

FIGU R E 5

8

X

0

(b)

4

5

6

7

8

9

10

X

smaller numerically. That is, the tangent line rr is less steep than line tt: Slope at point R 5 Slope of line rr

5

15 2 72 22 5 5 21 18 2 62 2

Exercise Show that the slope of the curve at point G is about 1. What would happen if we tried to apply this graphical technique to the high point in Figure 4(c) or to the low point in Figure 4(d)? Take a ruler and try it. The tangents that you construct should be horizontal, meaning that they should have a slope exactly equal to zero. It is always true that where the slope of a smooth curve changes from positive to negative, or vice versa, there will be at least one point whose slope is zero. Curves shaped like smooth hills, as in Figure 4(c), have a zero slope at their highest point. Curves shaped

Lines whose Y-intercept is zero have so many special uses in economics and other disciplines that they have been given a special name: a ray through the origin, or a ray.

Figure 6 shows three rays through the origin, and the slope of each is indicated in the diagram. The ray in the center (whose slope is 1) is particularly useful in many economic applications because it marks points where X and Y are equal (as long as X and Y are measured in the same units). For example, at point A we have X 5 3 and Y 5 3; at point B, X 5 4 and Y 5 4. A similar relation holds at any other point on that ray. How do we know that this is always true for a ray whose slope is 1? If we start from the origin (where both X and Y are zero) and the slope of the ray is 1, we know from the definition of slope that Slope 5

Vertical change 51 Horizontal change

This implies that the vertical change and the horizontal change are always equal, so the two variables must always remain equal. Any point along that ray (for example, point A) is exactly equal in distance

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

18

Getting Acquainted with Economics

Part 1

If a point representing some data is above the 45° line, we know that the value of Y exceeds the value of X. Similarly, whenever we find a point below the 45° line, we know that X is larger than Y.

F I GURE 6 Rays through the Origin Y

Slope = + 1

4

3

SQUEEZING THREE DIMENSIONS INTO TWO: CONTOUR MAPS

Slope = + 2

5

B C A

2

1 Slope = + – 2

K

1

E

0

1

2

D 3

4

5

X

from the horizontal and vertical axes (length DA 5 length CA)—the number on the X-axis (the abscissa) will be the same as the number on the Y-axis (the ordinate). Rays through the origin with a slope of 1 are called 45° lines because they form an angle of 45° with the horizontal axis. A 45° line marks off points where the variables measured on each axis have equal values.2

F I GURE 7

SOURCE: Mount Everest. Alpenvereinskarte. Vienna: Kartographische Anstalt Freytag-Berndt und Artaria, 1957, 1988.

A Geographic Contour Map

Sometimes problems involve more than two variables, so two dimensions just are not enough to depict them on a graph. This is unfortunate, because the surface of a sheet of paper is only two-dimensional. When we study a business firm’s decision-making process, for example, we may want to keep track simultaneously of three variables: how much labor it employs, how much raw material it imports from foreign countries, and how much output it creates. Luckily, economists can use a well-known device for collapsing three dimensions into two—a contour map. Figure 7 is a contour map of the summit of the highest mountain in the world, Mt. Everest, on the border of Nepal and Tibet. On some of the irregularly shaped “rings” on this map, we find numbers (like 8500) indicating the height (in meters) above sea level at that particular spot on the mountain. Thus, unlike other maps, which give only latitudes and longitudes, this contour map (also called a topographical map) exhibits three pieces of information about each point: latitude, longitude, and altitude. Figure 8 looks more like the contour maps encountered in economics. It shows how a third variable, called Z (think of it as a firm’s output, for example), varies as we change either variable X (think of it as a firm’s employment of labor) or variable Y (think of it as the use of imported raw material). Just like the map of Mt. Everest, any point on the diagram conveys three pieces of data. At point A, we can read off the values of X and Y in the conventional way (X is 30 and Y is 40), and we can also note the value of Z by finding out on which contour line point A falls. (It is on the Z 5 20 contour.) So point A is able to tell us that 30 hours of labor and 40 yards of cloth produce 20 units of output per day. The contour line that

The definition assumes that both variables are measured in the same units. 2

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

indicates 20 units of output shows the various combinations of labor and cloth a manufacturer can use to produce 20 units of output. Economists call such maps production indifference maps.

FIGU R E 8 An Economic Contour Map Y

A production indifference map is a graph whose axes show the quantities of two inputs that are used to produce some output. A curve in the graph corresponds to some given quantity of that output, and the different points on that curve show the different quantities of the two inputs that are just enough to produce the given output.

80 70 Yards of Cloth per Day

19

What Is Economics?

Chapter 1

60 50 A

40

Z = 40 B

30

Although most of the analyses presented in this book rely on the simpler two-variable diagrams, contour maps will find their applications, especially in the appendixes to Chapters 5 and 7.

Z = 30

20

Z = 20

10 Z = 10 0

10

20

30

40

50

60

70

80

X

Labor Hours per Day

| SUMMARY | 1. Because graphs are used so often to portray economic models, it is important for students to acquire some understanding of their construction and use. Fortunately, the graphics used in economics are usually not very complex. 2. Most economic models are depicted in two-variable diagrams. We read data from these diagrams just as we read the latitude and longitude on a map: each point represents the values of two variables at the same time. 3. In some instances, three variables must be shown at once. In these cases, economists use contour maps, which, as the name suggests, show “latitude,” “longitude,” and “altitude” all at the same time.

4. Often, the most important property of a line or curve drawn on a diagram will be its slope, which is defined as the ratio of the “rise” over the “run,” or the vertical change divided by the horizontal change when one moves along the curve. Curves that go uphill as we move to the right have positive slopes; curves that go downhill have negative slopes. 5. By definition, a straight line has the same slope wherever we choose to measure it. The slope of a curved line changes, but the slope at any point on the curve can be calculated by measuring the slope of a straight line tangent to the curve at that point.

| KEY TERMS | 45° line

18

origin (of a graph)

ray through the origin, or ray 14

production indifference map

19

slope of a straight (or curved) line 15, 16

17

tangent to a curve variable

16

14

Y-intercept

17

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

20

Part 1

Getting Acquainted with Economics

| TEST YOURSELF | 1. Portray the following hypothetical data on a two-variable diagram: Academic Year 2000–2001 2001–2002 2002–2003 2003–2004 2004–2005

Total Enrollment 3,000 3,100 3,200 3,300 3,400

Enrollment in Economics Courses 300 325 350 375 400

Measure the slope of the resulting line, and explain what this number means. 2. From Figure 5, calculate the slope of the curve at point M.

B+ or better. He concludes from observation that the following figures are typical: Number of grades of B+ or better Number of job offers

0 1

1 3

2 4

3 5

4 6

Put these numbers into a graph like Figure 1(a). Measure and interpret the slopes between adjacent dots. 4. In Figure 6, determine the values of X and Y at point K and at point E. What do you conclude about the slopes of the lines on which K and E are located? 5. In Figure 8, interpret the economic meaning of points A and B. What do the two points have in common? What is the difference in their economic interpretation?

3. Colin believes that the number of job offers he will get depends on the number of courses in which his grade is

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

The Economy: Myth and Reality E pluribus unum (Out of many, one) MOTTO ON U .S. CU RRE N CY

T

his chapter introduces you to the U.S. economy and its role in the world. It may seem that no such introduction is necessary, for you have probably lived your entire life in the United States. Every time you work at a summer or part-time job, pay your college bills, or buy a slice of pizza, you not only participate in the American economy—you also observe something about it. But the casual impressions we acquire in our everyday lives, though sometimes correct, are often misleading. Experience shows that most Americans—not just students— either are unaware of or harbor grave misconceptions about some of the most basic economic facts. One popular myth holds that most of the goods that Americans buy are made in China. Another is that business profits account for a third of the price we pay for a typical good or service. Also, “everyone knows” that federal government jobs have grown rapidly over the past few decades. In fact, none of these things is remotely close to true. So, before we begin to develop theories of how the economy works, it is useful to get an accurate picture of what our economy is really like.

C O N T E N T S THE AMERICAN ECONOMY: A THUMBNAIL SKETCH

The American Workforce: What It Earns Capital and Its Earnings

A Private-Enterprise Economy A Relatively “Closed” Economy A Growing Economy . . . But with Bumps along the Growth Path

THE OUTPUTS: WHAT DOES AMERICA PRODUCE?

THE INPUTS: LABOR AND CAPITAL

WHAT’S MISSING FROM THE PICTURE? GOVERNMENT

The American Workforce: Who Is in It? The American Workforce: What Does It Do?

THE CENTRAL ROLE OF BUSINESS FIRMS

The Government as Business Regulator Government Expenditures Taxes in America The Government as Redistributor

CONCLUSION: IT’S A MIXED ECONOMY

The Government as Referee

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

22

Part 1

Getting Acquainted with Economics

THE AMERICAN ECONOMY: A THUMBNAIL SKETCH

SOURCE: © The New Yorker Collection, 1992 Lee Lorenz from cartoonbank.com. All Rights Reserved.

The U.S. economy is the biggest national economy on earth, for two very different reasons. First, there are a lot of us. The population of the United States is just over 300 million—making it the third most populous nation on earth after China and India. That vast total includes children, retirees, full-time students, institutionalized people, and the unemployed, none of whom produce much output. But the working population of the United States numbers about 140 million. As long as they are reasonably productive, that many people are bound to produce vast amounts of goods and services. And they do. But population is not the main reason why the U.S. economy is by far the world’s biggest. After all, India has nearly four times the population of the United States, but its economy is smaller than that “And may we continue to be worthy of consuming a disproportionate of Texas. The second reason why the U.S. economy share of this planet’s resources.” is so large is that we are a very rich country. Because American workers are among the most productive in the world, our economy produces more than $47,000 worth of goods and services for Inputs or factors of every living American—nearly $100,000 for every working American. If each of the 50 states production are the labor, was a separate country, California would be the eighth-largest national economy on earth! machinery, buildings, and natural resources used to Why are some countries (like the United States) so rich and others (like India) so poor? make outputs. That is one of the central questions facing economists. It is useful to think of an economic system as a machine that takes inputs, such as labor and other things we call factors of Outputs are the goods and production, and transforms them into outputs, or the things people want to consume. The services that consumers American economic machine performs this task with extraordinary efficiency, whereas the and others want to acquire.

U.S. Share of World GDP—It’s Nice to Be Rich 2008 Gross Domestic Product (GDP) per Capita in 7 Industrial Countries 50,000

47,500

45,000 39,200

40,000 GDP per Capita ($)

The approximately 6.8 billion people of the world produced approximately $70 trillion worth of goods and services in 2008. The United States, with only about 4.6 percent of that population, turned out approximately 21 percent of total output. As the accompanying graph shows, the United States is still the leader in goods and services, with over $47,000 worth of GDP produced per person (or per capita). Just seven major industrial economies (the United States, Japan, Germany, France, Italy, the United Kingdom, and Canada— which account for just 11 percent of global population) generated 42 percent of world output. But their share has been falling as giant nations like China and India grow rapidly.

36,700

35,500

35,000

34,100

33,300

31,400

30,000 25,000 20,000 15,000 10,000 5,000

SOURCE: International Monetary Fund, World Economic Outlook Database, October 2009, http://www.imf.org, accessed December 2009; and Central Intelligence Agency, The World Factbook, 2009. Note: Foreign GDPs are converted to U.S. dollars using exchange rates.

0 United States

Canada

United Germany Kingdom

Japan

France

Italy

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 2

23

The Economy: Myth and Reality

Indian machine runs quite inefficiently (though it is improving rapidly). Learning why this is so is one of the chief reasons to study economics. Thus, what makes the American economy the center of world attention is our unique combination of prosperity and population. There are other rich countries in the world, like Switzerland, and there are other countries with huge populations, like India. But no nation combines a huge population with high per capita income the way the United States does. Japan, with an economy well under half the size of ours, is the only nation that comes close—although China, with its immense population, is moving up rapidly. Although the United States is a rich and populous country, the 50 states certainly were not created equal. Population density varies enormously—from a high of about 1,200 people per square mile in crowded New Jersey to a low of just one person per square mile in the wide-open spaces of Alaska. Income variations are much less pronounced, but still, the average income in West Virginia is only about half that in Connecticut.

A Private-Enterprise Economy Part of the secret of America’s economic success is that free markets and private enterprise have flourished here. These days, private enterprise and capitalism are the rule, not the exception, around the globe. But the United States has taken the idea of free markets— where individuals and businesses voluntarily buy and sell things—further than almost any other country. It remains the “land of opportunity.” Every country has a mixture of public and private ownership of property. Even in the darkest days of communism, Russians owned their own personal possessions. In our country, the post office and the electricity-producing Tennessee Valley Authority are enterprises of the federal government, and many cities and states own and operate mass transit facilities and sports stadiums. But the United States stands out among the world’s nations as one of the most “privatized.” Few industrial assets are publicly owned in the United States. Even many city bus companies and almost all utilities (such as electricity, gas, and telephones) are run as private companies in the United States. In Europe, they are often government enterprises, though there is substantial movement toward transfer of government firms to private ownership. The United States also has one of the most “marketized” economies on earth. The standard measure of the total output of an economy is called gross domestic product (GDP), a term that appears frequently in the news. The share of GDP that passes through markets in the United States is enormous. Although government purchases of goods and services amount to about 20 percent of GDP, much of that is purchased from private businesses. Direct government production of goods is extremely rare in our society.

A Relatively “Closed” Economy

Gross domestic product (GDP) is a measure of the size of the economy—the total amount it produces in a year. Real GDP adjusts this measure for changes in the purchasing power of money; that is, it corrects for inflation.

All nations trade with one another, and the United States is no exception. Our annual exports exceed $1.6 trillion and our annual imports exceed $2 trillion. That’s a lot of money, and so is the gap between them. But America’s international trade often gets more attention than it deserves. The fact is that we still produce most of what we consume and consume most of what we produce, although the shares of imports and exports have been growing, as Figure 1 shows. In 1959, the average of exports and imports was only about 4 percent of GDP, a tiny fraction of the total. It has since gone up to over 15 percent. Although this is no longer negligible, it still means that almost 85 percent of what Americans buy every year is made in the United States. Among the most severe misconceptions about the U.S. economy is the myth that this country no longer manufactures anything, but imports everything from, say, China. In fact, only about 18 percent of U.S. GDP is imported, with imports from China making up less than one-seventh of this—or a little over 2 percent of GDP. It may surprise you to learn that we actually import more merchandise from Canada than we do from China. Economists use the terms open and closed to indicate how important international trade is to a nation. A common measure of “openness” is the average of exports and imports, Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

24

Part 1

Getting Acquainted with Economics

FIGURE 1 Share of U.S. Gross Domestic Product (GDP) Exported and Imported, 1959–2008

14 12 10 8 6 4 2 0 1959 1964 1969 1974 1979 1984 1989 1994 1999 2004 2009

An economy is called relatively open if its exports and imports constitute a large share of its GDP. An economy is considered relatively closed if they constitute a small share.

SOURCE: Economic Report of the President (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, various years).

Average of Exports and Imports, as a share of GDP (%)

16

expressed as a share of GDP. Thus, the Netherlands is considered an extremely open economy because it imports and exports about three-quarters of its GDP. (See Table 1.) By this criterion, the United States stands out as among the most closed economies among the advanced, industrial nations. We export and import a smaller share of GDP than all of the countries listed in the table.

A Growing Economy . . .

Openness

Netherlands Germany Canada United Kingdom Mexico Japan Russia China United States

75% 47 34 25 19 17 17 16 15

SOURCE: For United States, Bureau of Economic Analysis; for all other countries, Central Intelligence Agency, The World Factbook, https://www.cia.gov/ library/publications/the-world-factbook/index.html accessed December 2009.

The next salient fact about the U.S. economy is its growth; it gets bigger almost every year (see Figure 2). Gross domestic product in 2008 was over $14 trillion; as noted earlier, that’s over $47,000 per American. Measured in dollars of constant purchasing power, 1 the U.S. GDP was almost five times as large in 2008 as it was in 1959. Of course, there were many more people in America in 2008 than there were 49 years earlier. But even correcting for population growth, America’s real GDP per capita was about 2.8 times higher in 2008 than in 1959. That’s still not a bad performance: Living standards nearly tripled in 49 years. Looking back further, the purchasing power of the average American increased nearly A recession is a period of 600 percent over the entire twentieth century! That’s a remarkable number. To get an idea time during which the total of what it means, just think how much poorer your family would become if it started out output of the economy with an average U.S. income and then, suddenly, six dollars out of seven were taken away. falls. Most Americans at the end of the nineteenth century could TABLE 1 not afford vacations, the men had one good suit of clothing Openness of Various National Economies, 2008 which they listed in their wills, and they wrote with ink that was kept in inkwells (and that froze every winter).

NOTE: Openness calculated as the average of imports and exports as a percentage of GDP.

1

But with Bumps along the Growth Path Although the cumulative growth performance depicted in Figure 2 is impressive, America’s economic growth has been quite irregular. We have experienced alternating periods of good and bad times, which are called economic fluctuations or sometimes just business cycles. In some years—five since 1959, to be exact—GDP actually declined. Such periods of declining economic activity are called recessions.

This concept is called real GDP.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 2

The Economy: Myth and Reality

FIGURE 2 Real Gross Domestic Product (GDP) since 1959

Billions of Dollars per Year

SOURCE: Economic Report of the President (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, various years).

14,000 12,000 10,000 8,000 6,000 4,000 2,000 0 1959 1964 1969 1974 1979 1984 1989 1994 1999 2004 2009 NOTE: Real (inflation-adjusted) GDP figures are in 2005 dollars.

The bumps along the American economy’s historic growth path are barely visible in Figure 2, but they stand out more clearly in Figure 3, which displays the same data in a different way. Here we plot not the level of real GDP each year but, rather, its growth rate— the percentage change from one year to the next. Now the booms and busts that delight and distress people—and swing elections—stand out clearly. From 1983 to 1984, for example, real GDP grew by over 7 percent, which helped ensure Ronald Reagan’s landslide reelection. But from 2008 to 2009, real GDP actually dropped sharply, causing all sorts of social distress. One important consequence of these ups and downs in economic growth is that unemployment varies considerably from one year to the next (see Figure 4). During the Great Depression of the 1930s, unemployment ran as high as 25 percent of the workforce, but it fell to barely over 1 percent during World War II. Just within the past few years, the national unemployment rate has been as high as 10.1 percent (in October 2009) and as low as 3.8 percent (in April 2000). In human terms, that 6.3 percentage point difference represents approximately 10 million jobless workers. Understanding why joblessness varies so dramatically, and what we can do about it, is another major reason for studying economics. FIGURE 3

8 7 6 Annual Change in Real GDP (%)

SOURCE: Economic Report of the President (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, various years)

The Growth Rate of Real Gross Domestic Product (GDP) in the United States since 1959

1960s record expansion Boom of 1980s

5

Boom of 1990s

4 3 2 1

2001 recession

0 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 1973–74 –1 1990–91 recession recession 2008–09 –2 recession 1981–82 recession –3

NOTE: Growth rates are for 1959–1960, 1960–1961, and so on.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

25

26

Part 1

Getting Acquainted with Economics

FIGURE 4

30

Percentage of Civilian Workers Who Are Unemployed

Great Depression 25 20 1980–83 recessions

15

1973–75 recession

10 World War II

1980s boom

1960s boom

1990s boom

2008–09 recession

5 0 1929

1939

1949

1959

1969

1979

1989

1999

2009

SOURCE: Economic Report of the President (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, various years); and Bureau of the Census, Historical Statistics of the United States, Colonial Times to 1970 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1975).

The Unemployment Rate in the United States since 1929

THE INPUTS: LABOR AND CAPITAL Let’s now return to the analogy of an economy as a machine turning inputs into outputs. The most important input is human labor: the men and women who run the machines, work behind the desks, and serve you in stores.

For roughly the first quarter-century after World War II, unemployment rates in the industrialized countries of Europe were significantly lower than those in the United States. Then, in the mid-1970s, rates of joblessness in Europe leaped, with double digits becoming common. And they have been higher than U.S. unemployment rates in almost every year since. Where employment is concerned, the U.S. economy has become the envy of Europe—with the exception of the United Kingdom. Put on a comparable basis by the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics, unemployment rates in the various countries in the fall of 2008 were:

U.S. Canada Australia Japan France Germany Italy Sweden United Kingdom

5.8% 5.3 4.2 4.0 7.5 7.5 6.8 6.2 5.7

SOURCE: U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

SOURCE: © Joel Stettenheim/CORBIS

Unemployment Rates in Europe

The Economy: Myth and Reality

Chapter 2

The American Workforce: Who Is in It? We have already mentioned that about 140 million Americans hold jobs. Almost 53 percent of these workers are men; over 47 percent are women. This ratio represents a drastic change from two generations ago, when most women worked only at home (see Figure 5). Indeed, the massive entrance of women into the paid labor force was one of the major social transformations of American life during the second half of the twentieth century. In 1950, just 29 percent of women worked in the marketplace; now almost 60 percent do. As Figure 6 shows, the share of women in the labor forces of other industrial countries has also been growing. The expanding role of women in the labor market has raised many controversial questions—whether they are discriminated against (the evidence suggests that they are), whether the government should compel employers to provide maternity leave, and so on. FIGURE 5

SOURCES: Economic Report of the President (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office), 2008; Bureau of Labor Statistics, "Women in the Labor Force: A Databook (2009 edition)," http://www.bls.gov/cps/wlf-databook-2009.pdf.

The Composition of Employment by Sex, 1950 and 2008

Women 29% Men 53.3%

Women 46.7%

Men 71%

1950

2008

SOURCES: “A Survery of Women and Work,” The Economist, July 18, 1998, P. 4; and Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, Labor Force Statistics, 1985–2005, http://www.sourceoecd.org.

FIGURE 6 Working Women as a Percentage of the Labor Force, 1960 versus 2005

Sweden United States France United Kingdom Germany Netherlands Japan 2005 1960

Spain Italy 0

5

10

15

20

25

30

35

40

45

50

In contrast to women, the percentage of teenagers in the workforce has dropped significantly since its peak in the mid-1970s (see Figure 7). Young men and women aged 16 to 19 accounted for 8.6 percent of employment in 1974 but only 3.8 percent in 2008. As the baby boom gave way to the baby bust, people under 20 became scarce resources! Still,

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

27

28

Part 1

Getting Acquainted with Economics

FIGURE 7

Percentage of Total Civilian Employment

10 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1

19 5 19 0 5 19 2 5 19 4 5 19 6 5 19 8 6 19 0 6 19 2 6 19 4 6 19 6 6 19 8 7 19 0 7 19 2 7 19 4 7 19 6 7 19 8 8 19 0 8 19 2 8 19 4 8 19 6 8 19 8 9 19 0 9 19 2 9 19 4 9 19 6 9 20 8 0 20 0 0 20 2 0 20 4 0 20 6 08

0

Year

SOURCE: Economic Report of the President (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, various years).

Teenage Employment as a Percentage of Total Employment, 1950–2008

nearly 6 million teenagers hold jobs in the U.S. economy today—a number that has been pretty stable in the past few years. Most teenagers fill low-wage jobs at fast-food restaurants, amusement parks, and the like. Relatively few can be found in the nation’s factories.

The American Workforce: What Does It Do?

SOURCE: Bureau of labor statistics. Economic News Report. Employment Situation Summary www.bls.gov, accessed December 2009

What do these 140 million working Americans do? The only real answer is: almost anything you can imagine. In May 2008, America had 110,990 architects, 394,230 computer programmers, more than 899,920 carpenters, more than 2.6 million truck drivers, 553,690 lawyers, roughly 1.5 million secretaries, 174,530 kinF I GURE 8 dergarten teachers, 29,170 pediatricians, 63,030 tax preCivilian Non-Farm Payroll Employment by Sector, Nov 2009 parers, 6,900 geological engineers, 298,900 fire fighters, and 12,600 economists.2 Figure 8 shows the breakdown by sector. It holds some surprises for most people. The majority of American workers—like workers in all developed countries— produce services, not goods. In 2009, about 68 percent of all non-farm workers in the United States were employed Service producing Manufacturing 9.1% (minus government) by private service industries, whereas only about 14 per68.5% cent produced goods. These legions of service workers included about 16.5 million in educational and health Other goods services, about 17.7 million in business and professional producing services, and over 15 million in retail trade. (The biggest Government 4.8% single private employer in the country is Wal-Mart.) By 17.6% contrast, manufacturing companies in the United States employed only 12 million people, and almost a third of those worked in offices rather than in the factory. The Homer Simpson image of the typical American worker as NOTE: Numbers may not add to 100% due to rounding. a blue-collar worker is really quite misleading.

2

SOURCE: U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics, Occupational Employment and Wages, May 2008, http://www.bls.gov.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

The Economy: Myth and Reality

Chapter 2

Federal, state, and local governments employed about 22 million people but, contrary to another popular misconception, few of these civil servants work for the federal government. Federal civilian employment is about 2.7 million—about 10 percent lower than it was in the 1980s. (The armed forces employ about another 1.5 million men and women in uniform.) State and local governments provide about 19.5 million jobs—or about seven times the number of federal government jobs. In addition to the jobs categorized in Figure 8, approximately 2 million Americans work on farms and over 10 million are self-employed. As Figure 9 shows, all industrialized countries have become “service economies” in recent decades. To a considerable degree, this shift to services reflects the arrival of the “Information Age.” Activities related to computers, to research, to the transmission of information by teaching and publication, and other information-related activities are providing many of the new jobs. This means that, in the rich economies, workers who moved out of manufacturing jobs into the service sectors have not gone predominantly into lowskill jobs such as dishwashing or housecleaning. Many found employment in service jobs in which education and experience provide a great advantage. At the same time, technological change has made it possible to produce more and more manufactured products using fewer and fewer workers. Such labor-saving innovation in manufacturing has allowed a considerable share of the labor force to move out of goods-producing jobs and into services. FIGURE 9

90 Service Sector Jobs as a Percent of the Total Labor Force

SOURCES: Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, Quarterly Labour Force Statistics, various issues; and Labour Force Statistics, 1985–2005, http://www.sourceoecd.org.

The Growing Share of Service Sector Jobs, 1967 versus 2005

1967 2005

80 70

64.6

64.8

73.9 67.6

76

75.3

76.5

67.6 58.9

58.7

60 50 42.8 40 38.3

78.6

45.1

44.8

48.8

50.8

36.2

30 20 10 0 Italy

Spain Germany Japan

France

Canada Sweden United United Kingdom States

The American Workforce: What It Earns Altogether, these workers’ wages account for over 70 percent of the income that the production process generates. That figures up to an average hourly wage of over $18—plus fringe benefits like health insurance and pensions, which can contribute an additional 30 to 40 percent for some workers. Because the average workweek is about 34 hours long, a typical weekly paycheck in the United States is about $630 before taxes (but excluding the value of benefits). That is hardly a princely sum, and most college graduates can expect to earn substantially more.3 But it is typical of average wage rates in a rich country like the United States. These days, college graduates typically earn over 80 percent more than workers with only high school diplomas. SOURCE: Bureau of Labor Statistics, “Labor Force Statistics from the Current Population Survey.” Earnings by education, http://www.bls.gov.

3

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

29

30

Part 1

Getting Acquainted with Economics

Wages throughout northern Europe are similar. Indeed, workers in a number of other industrial countries now receive higher compensation than American workers do—a big change from the situation a few decades ago. According to the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics, in 2007 workers in U.S. manufacturing industries made less than those in many European countries (see Figure 10). However, U.S. compensation levels still remain above those in Japan and many other countries. FIGURE 10

55 51.38

Average Hourly Compensation Rates in Manufacturing, 2007

50

39.47 37.68 38.75 38.80

40 35

31.39 32.06 32.19

30 25

23.95

20 15 10 5 Germany

Netherlands

Sweden

Belgium

France

Italy

Canada

United States

Japan

0

SOURCE: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, Division of Foreign Labor Statistics, http://www.bls.gov.

U.S. Dollars (at purchasing power parities)

45

Capital and Its Earnings The rest of national income (after deducting the small sliver of income that goes to the owners of land and natural resources) mainly accrues to the owners of capital—the machines and buildings that make up the nation’s industrial plant. The total market value of these business assets—a tough number to estimate—is believed to be in the neighborhood of $30 trillion. Because that capital earns an average rate of return of about 10 percent before taxes, total earnings of capital—including corporate profits, interest, and all the rest—come to about $3 trillion. Public opinion polls routinely show that Americans have a distorted view of the level of business profits in our society. The man and woman on the street believe that corporate profits after tax account for about 30 percent of the price of a typical product (see the box “Public Opinion on Profits” on the next page). The right number is closer to 8 percent.

THE OUTPUTS: WHAT DOES AMERICA PRODUCE? What does all this labor and capital produce? Consumer spending accounts for about 70 percent of GDP. And what an amazing variety of goods and services it buys. American households spend roughly 66 percent of their budgets on services, with housing commanding the largest share. They also spend about $168 billion annually on their telephone bills, over $35 billion on airline tickets, and $90 billion on dentists. The other 34 percent of American budgets goes for goods—ranging from about $342 billion per year on motor vehicles to almost $60 billion on shoes.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

31

The Economy: Myth and Reality

Chapter 2

Public Opinion on Profits

* This poll was conducted in 1986. Corporate profit rates increased considerably in the 1990s and 2000s.

35 Profit per Dollar of Sales (%)

Most Americans think corporate profits are much higher than they actually are. One public opinion poll years ago found that the average citizen thought that corporate profits after taxes amounted to 32 percent of sales for the typical manufacturing company. The actual profit rate at the time was closer to 4 percent!* Interestingly, when a previous poll asked how much profit was “reasonable,” the response was 26 cents on every dollar of sales—more than six times as large as profits actually were.

32%

30 26% 25 20 15 10 3.8%

5 0

SOURCE: “Public Attitudes toward Corporate Profits,” Public Opinion Index (Princeton, NJ: Opinion Research Corporation, June 1986).

What people think is a “reasonable” corporate profit

What people estimate corporate profit is

Actual corporate profit

This leaves about 30 percent of GDP for all nonconsumption uses. That includes government services (buying such things as airplanes, guns, and the services of soldiers, teachers, and bureaucrats), business purchases of machinery and industrial structures, and consumer purchases of new houses.

THE CENTRAL ROLE OF BUSINESS FIRMS Calvin Coolidge once said that “the business of America is business.” Although this statement often has been ridiculed, he was largely right. When we peer inside the economic machine that turns inputs into outputs, we see mainly private companies. Astonishingly, the United States has more than 25 million business firms—about one for every 12 people! The owners and managers of these businesses hire people, acquire or rent capital goods, and arrange to produce things consumers want to buy. Sound simple? It isn’t. Over 80,000 businesses fail every year. A few succeed spectacularly. Some do both. Fortunately for the U.S. economy, however, the lure of riches induces hundreds of thousands of people to start new businesses every year—against the odds. A number of the biggest firms do business all over the world, just as foreign-based multinational corporations do business here. Indeed, some people claim that it is now impossible to determine the true “nationality” of a multinational corporation—which may have factories in ten or more countries, sell its wares all over the world, and have stockholders in dozens of nations. (See the box “Is That an American Company?” on the next page). Ford, for example, generates more profits abroad than at home, and the Toyota you drive was probably assembled in the United States. Firms compete with other companies in their industry. Most economists believe that this competition is the key to industrial efficiency. A sole supplier of a commodity will find it easy to make money, and may therefore fail to innovate or control costs. Its management is liable to become relaxed and sloppy. But a company besieged by dozens of competitors eager to take its business away must constantly seek ways to innovate, to cut costs, and to

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

32

Part 1

Getting Acquainted with Economics

Is That an American Company?

What’s the difference between an “American” corporation that makes or buys abroad much of what it sells around the world and a “foreign” corporation that makes or buys in the United States much of what it sells? . . . The mind struggles to keep the players straight. In 1990, Canada’s Northern Telecom was selling to its American customers telecommunications equipment made by Japan’s NTT at NTT’s factory in North Carolina. If you found that one too easy, try this: Beginning in 1991, Japan’s Mazda would be producing Ford Probes at Mazda’s plant in Flat Rock, Michigan. Some of these cars would be exported to Japan and sold there under Ford’s trademark. A Mazda-designed compact utility vehicle would be built at a Ford plant in Louisville, Kentucky, and then sold at Mazda dealerships in the United States. Nissan, meanwhile, was designing a new light truck at its San Diego, California, design center. The trucks would be assembled at Ford’s Ohio truck plant, using

panel parts fabricated by Nissan at its Tennessee factory, and then marketed by both Ford and Nissan in the United States and in Japan. Who is Ford? Nissan? Mazda?

SOURCE: © AP IMAGES/Greg Campbell

Robert Reich, who was Secretary of Labor in the Clinton administration, argued some years ago that it was already nearly impossible to define the nationality of a multinational company. Although many scholars think Reich exaggerated the point, no one doubts that he had one—nor that the nationalities of corporations have become increasingly blurred since then. He wrote in 1991:

SOURCE: Robert B. Reich, The Work of Nations (New York: Knopf, 1991), pp. 124, 131.

build a better mousetrap. The rewards for business success can be magnificent. But the punishment for failure is severe.

WHAT’S MISSING FROM THE PICTURE? GOVERNMENT Thus far, we have the following capsule summary of how the U.S. economy works: More than 25 million private businesses, energized by the profit motive, employ about 140 million workers and about $30 trillion of capital. These firms bring their enormously diverse wares to a bewildering variety of different markets, where they try to sell them to over 300 million consumers. It is in markets—places where goods and services are bought and sold—that these millions of households and businesses meet to conduct transactions, as depicted in Figure 11. Only a few of these markets are concrete physical locations, such as fish markets or stock exchanges. Most are more abstract “places,” where business may be conducted by telephone or the Internet—even if the commodity being traded is a physical object. For example, there are no centralized physical marketplaces for buying cars or computers, but there are highly competitive markets for these goods nonetheless. As Figure 11 suggests, firms use their receipts from selling goods and services in the markets for outputs to pay wages to employees and interest and profits to the people who provide capital in the markets for inputs. These income flows, in turn, enable consumers to purchase the goods and services that companies produce. This circular flow of money, goods, and factors of production lies at the center of the analysis of how the national economy works. All these activities are linked by a series of interconnected markets, some of which are highly competitive and others of which are less so.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

The Economy: Myth and Reality

Chapter 2

FIGURE 11 The Circular Flow of Goods and Money

s ture ndi es e p ervic Ex nd s a s od Go

Markets for Outputs

Sale s

Good s

re c eip ts and ser vic es

Households

Businesses

La

bo

r, c api t a l, etc. Inc om e s

Markets for Inputs

tc. c. l, e a t i et p t, , ca r s o b e a r L inte e s, Wag

All very well and good. But the story leaves out something important: the role of government, which is pervasive even in our decidedly free-market economy. Just what does government do in the U.S. economy—and why? Although an increasing number of tasks seem to get assigned to the state each year, the traditional role of government in a market economy revolves around five jobs: • • • • •

Making and enforcing the laws Regulating business Providing certain goods and services such as national defense Levying taxes to pay for these goods and services Redistributing income

Every one of these tasks is steeped in controversy and surrounded by intense political debate. We conclude this chapter with a brief look at each.

The Government as Referee For the most part, power is diffused in our economy, and people “play by the rules.” But, in the scramble for competitive advantage, disputes are bound to arise. Did Company A live up to its contract? Who owns that disputed piece of property? In addition, some unscrupulous businesses are liable to step over the line now and then—as we saw in many cases of fraud that helped bring on the debacle in sub-prime mortgages in 2007–2009. Enter the government as rule maker, referee, and arbitrator. Congress and state and local legislatures pass the laws that define the rules of the economic game. The executive branches of all three governmental levels share the responsibility for enforcing them. And the courts interpret the laws and adjudicate disputes.

The Government as Business Regulator Nothing is pure in this world of ours. Even in “free-market” economies, governments interfere with the workings of free markets in many ways and for myriad reasons. Some government activities seek to make markets work better. For example, America’s antitrust laws are used to protect competition against possible encroachment by monopoly. Some regulations seek to promote social objectives that unfettered markets do not foster—environmental regulations are a particularly clear case. But, as critics like to point out, some economic regulations have no clear rationale at all.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

33

Part 1

Getting Acquainted with Economics

We mentioned earlier that the American belief in free enterprise runs deep. For this reason, the regulatory role of government is more contentious here than in most other countries. After all, Thomas Jefferson said that government is best that governs least. Two hundred years later, Presidents Reagan, Bush (both of them), and Clinton all pledged to dismantle inappropriate regulations—and sometimes did. But the financial crisis of 2007–2009 has led to many calls for new and tighter regulations, especially in finance.

Government Expenditures The most contentious political issues often involve taxing and spending because those are the government’s most prominent roles. Democrats and Republicans, both in the White House and in Congress, have frequently battled fiercely over the federal budget. In 1995 and 1996, such disputes even led to some temporary shutdowns of the federal government. Under President Bill Clinton, the government managed to achieve a sizable surplus in its budget—meaning that tax receipts exceeded expenditures. But it didn’t last long. Today the federal budget is deeply in the red, and prospects for getting it balanced are poor. During fiscal year 2008, the federal government spent over $3.1 trillion—a sum that is literally beyond comprehension. Figure 12 shows where the money went. Over 31 percent went for pensions and income security programs, which include both social insurance programs (such as Social Security and unemployment compensation) and programs designed to assist the poor. About 21 percent went for national defense. Another 25 percent was absorbed by health-care expenditures, mainly on Medicare and Medicaid. Adding in interest on the national debt, these four functions alone accounted for over 86 percent of all federal spending. The rest went for a miscellany of other purposes including education, transportation, agriculture, housing, and foreign aid. Government spending at the state and local levels was about $2.0 trillion. Education claimed the largest share of state and local government budgets (35 percent), with health and public welfare programs a distant second (26 percent). Despite this vast outpouring of public funds, many observers believe that serious social needs remain unmet. Critics claim that our public infrastructure (such as bridges and roads) is adequate, that our educational system is lacking, that we are not spending enough on homeland defense, and so on. Although the scale and scope of government activity in the United States is substantial, it is quite moderate when we compare it to other leading economies, as we will see next.

FIGURE 12 The Allocation of Government Expenditures Federal

Interest 9.4%

State and Local

All other 13.3% All other 32.4% Pensions and Income Security 31.8%

National Defense 20.5% Health 25.0%

Education 35.2% Health and Public Welfare (includes health and welfare and social services, not disability) 26.4% Highways 6.0%

SOURCE: Bureau of Economic Analysis, NIPA Tables, Government Current Expenditures by Function, accessed Dec 2009, http://www.bea.gov

34

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

35

The Economy: Myth and Reality

Chapter 2

Taxes in America Taxes finance this array of goods and services, and sometimes it seems that the tax collector is everywhere. We have income and payroll taxes withheld from our paychecks, sales taxes added to our purchases, property taxes levied on our homes; we pay gasoline taxes, liquor taxes, and telephone taxes. Americans have always felt that taxes are both too many and too high. In the 1980s and 1990s, antitax sentiment became a dominant feature of the U.S. political scene. The old slogan “no taxation without representation” gave way to the new slogan “no new taxes.” Yet, by international standards, Americans are among the most lightly taxed people in the world. Figure 13 compares the fraction of income paid in taxes in the United States with those paid by residents of other wealthy nations. The tax share in the United States fell notably during the early years of George W. Bush’s presidency, but has since crept up a bit and threatens to go higher. FIGURE 13 The Tax Burden in Selected Countries, 2007 50

48.2 43.6

43.3 38

36.6

36.2 29.7

28.3

27.9

United States

Japan

33.3 30

Switzerland

Tax Revenues as a Percentage of GDP

40

20

Canada

Germany

United Kingdom

Netherlands

Italy

France

0 Sweden

SOURCE: www.stats.oeced.org

10

The Government as Redistributor In a market economy, people earn incomes according to what they have to sell. Unfortunately, many people have nothing to sell but unskilled labor, which commands a paltry price. Others lack even that. Such people fare poorly in unfettered markets. In extreme cases, they are homeless, hungry, and ill. Robin Hood transferred money from the rich to the poor. Some think the government should do the same; others disagree. If poverty amid riches offends your moral sensibilities—a personal judgment that each of us must make for ourselves—two basic remedial approaches are possible. The socialist idea is to force the distribution of income to be more equal by overriding the decisions of the market. “From each according to his ability, to each according to his needs” was Marx’s ideal. In practice, things were not quite so noble under socialism, but there was little doubt that incomes in the old Soviet Union were more equally distributed than those in the United States. The liberal idea is to let free markets determine the distribution of before-tax incomes, but then to use the tax system and transfer payments to reduce inequality—just as Robin Hood did. This is the rationale for, among other things, progressive taxation and antipoverty programs. Americans who support redistribution line up solidly behind the liberal approach. But which ways are the best, and how much is enough? No simple answers have emerged from many decades of debate on these highly contentious questions. Lately, as wage disparities have widened, the inequality issue has gained prominence on the national political agenda. It figured prominently in the 2008 presidential campaign, for example.

Transfer payments are sums of money that certain individuals receive as outright grants from the government rather than as payments for services rendered. A tax is progressive if the ratio of taxes to income rises as income rises.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

36

Part 1

Getting Acquainted with Economics

CONCLUSION: IT’S A MIXED ECONOMY

A mixed economy is one with some public influence over the workings of free markets. There may also be some public ownership mixed in with private property.

Ideology notwithstanding, all nations at all times blend public and private ownership of property in some proportions. All rely on markets for some purposes, but all also assign some role to government. Hence, people speak of the ubiquity of mixed economies. But mixing is not homogenization; different countries can and do blend the state and market sectors in different ways. Even today, the Russian economy is a far cry from the Italian economy, which is vastly different from that of Hong Kong. Shortly after most of you were born, a stunning historical event occurred: Communism collapsed all over Europe. For years, the formerly socialist economies suffered through a painful transition from a system in which private property, free enterprise, and markets played subsidiary roles to one in which they are central. These nations have changed the mix, if you will—and dramatically so. To understand why this transformation is at once so difficult and so important, we need to explore the main theme of this book: What does the market do well, and what does it do poorly? This task begins in the next chapter.

| SUMMARY | 5. Governments at the federal, state, and local levels employ one-sixth of the American workforce (including the armed forces). These governments finance their expenditures by taxes, which account for about 28 percent of GDP. This percentage is one of the lowest in the industrialized world.

1. The U.S. economy is the biggest national economy on earth, both because Americans are rich by world standards and because we are a populous nation. Relative to most other advanced countries, our economy is also exceptionally “privatized” and closed. 2. The U.S. economy has grown dramatically over the years. But this growth has been interrupted by periodic recessions, during which unemployment rises.

6. In addition to raising taxes and making expenditures, the government in a market economy serves as referee and enforcer of the rules, regulates business in a variety of ways, and redistributes income through taxes and transfer payments. For all these reasons, we say that we have a mixed economy, which blends private and public elements.

3. The United States has a big, diverse workforce whose composition by age and sex has been changing substantially. Relatively few workers these days work in factories or on farms; most work in service industries. 4. Employees take home most of the nation’s income. Most of the rest goes, in the forms of interest and profits, to those who provide the capital.

| KEY TERMS | closed economy

24

mixed economy

factors of production, or inputs 22

open economy

gross domestic product (GDP)

outputs

23

22

36 24

progressive tax recession

35

24

transfer payments

35

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 2

The Economy: Myth and Reality

37

| DISCUSSION QUESTIONS | 1. Which are the two biggest national economies on earth? Why are they so much bigger than the others?

4. Roughly speaking, what fraction of U.S. labor works in factories? In service businesses? In government?

2. What is meant by a “factor of production”? Have you ever sold any on a market?

5. Most American businesses are small, but most of the output is produced by large businesses. That sounds paradoxical. How can it be true?

3. Why do you think per capita income in Connecticut is nearly double that in West Virginia?

6. What is the role of government in a mixed economy?

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

The Fundamental Economic Problem: Scarcity and Choice Our necessities are few but our wants are endless. I NS CRI P TI ON ON A F ORTU NE CO OK I E

U

nderstanding what the market system does well and what it does badly is this book’s central task. To address this complex issue, we must first answer a simpler one: What do economists expect the market to accomplish? The most common answer is that the market resolves what is often called the fundamental economic problem: how best to manage the resources of society, doing as well as possible with them, despite their scarcity. All decisions are constrained by the scarcity of available resources. A dreamer may envision a world free of want, in which everyone, even in Africa and Central America, drives a BMW and eats caviar, but the earth lacks the resources needed to make that dream come true. Because resources are scarce, all economic decisions involve trade-offs. Should you use that $5 bill to buy pizza or a new writing pad for econ class? Should General Motors invest more money in improving assembly lines or in research? A well-functioning market system facilitates and guides such decisions, assigning each hour of labor and each kilowatt-hour of electricity to the task where, it is hoped, the input will best serve the public. This chapter shows how economists analyze choices like these. The same basic principles, founded on the concept of opportunity cost, apply to the decisions made by business firms, governments, and society as a whole. Many of the most basic ideas of economics, such as efficiency, division of labor, comparative advantage, exchange, and the role of markets appear here for the first time.

C O N T E N T S ISSUE: WHAT TO DO ABOUT THE BUDGET DEFICIT?

ISSUE REVISITED: COPING WITH THE BUDGET

SCARCITY, CHOICE, AND OPPORTUNITY COST

THE CONCEPT OF EFFICIENCY

DEFICIT

Opportunity Cost and Money Cost Optimal Choice: Not Just Any Choice

THE THREE COORDINATION TASKS OF ANY ECONOMY

SCARCITY AND CHOICE FOR A SINGLE FIRM

TASK 1. HOW THE MARKET FOSTERS EFFICIENT RESOURCE ALLOCATION

The Production Possibilities Frontier The Principle of Increasing Costs

TASK 2. MARKET EXCHANGE AND DECIDING HOW MUCH OF EACH GOOD TO PRODUCE TASK 3. HOW TO DISTRIBUTE THE ECONOMY’S OUTPUTS AMONG CONSUMERS

The Wonders of the Division of Labor The Amazing Principle of Comparative Advantage

SCARCITY AND CHOICE FOR THE ENTIRE SOCIETY Scarcity and Choice Elsewhere in the Economy

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

40

Part 1

Getting Acquainted with Economics

ISSUE:

WHAT TO DO ABOUT THE BUDGET DEFICIT?

SOURCE: © Hisham Ibrahim/Photodisc/Getty Images

For roughly 15 years, from the early 1980s until the late 1990s, the top economic issue of the day was how to reduce the federal budget deficit. Presidents Ronald Reagan, George H. W. Bush, and Bill Clinton all battled with Congress over tax and spending priorities. Which programs should be cut? What taxes should be raised? Then, thanks to a combination of strong economic growth and deficit-reducing policies, the budget deficit melted away like springtime snow and actually turned into a budget surplus for a few fiscal years (1998 through 2001). For a while, the need to make agonizing choices seemed to disappear—or so it seemed. But it was an illusion. Even during that brief era of budget surpluses, hard choices still had to be made. The U.S. government could not afford everything. Then, as the stock market collapsed, the economy slowed, and President George W. Bush pushed a series of tax cuts through Congress, the budget surpluses quickly turned back into deficits again—the largest deficits in our history. The fiscal questions in the 2008 presidential campaign were the familiar ones of the 1980s and 1990s. Which spending programs should be cut and which ones should be increased? Which, if any, of the Bush tax cuts should be repealed? Even a government with an annual budget of over $2 trillion was forced to set priorities and make hard choices. Even when resources are quite generous, they are never unlimited; thus, everyone must still make tough choices. An optimal decision is one that chooses the most desirable alternative among the possibilities permitted by the available resources, which are always scarce in this sense.

SCARCITY, CHOICE, AND OPPORTUNITY COST Resources are the instruments provided by nature or by people that are used to create goods and services. Natural resources include minerals, soil, water, and air. Labor is a scarce resource, partly because of time limitations (the day has only 24 hours) and partly because the number of skilled workers is limited. Factories and machines are resources made by people. These three types of resources are often referred to as land, labor, and capital. They are also called inputs or factors of production.

One of the basic themes of economics is scarcity—the fact that resources are always limited. Even Philip II, of Spanish Armada fame and ruler of one of the greatest empires in history, had to cope with frequent rebellions in his armies when he could not meet their payrolls or even get them basic provisions. He is reported to have undergone bankruptcy an astonishing eight times during his reign. In more recent years, the U.S. government has been agonizing over difficult budget decisions even though it spends more than $2 trillion annually. But the scarcity of physical resources is more fundamental than the scarcity of funds. Fuel supplies, for example, are not limitless, and some environmentalists claim that we should now be making some hard choices—such as keeping our homes cooler in winter and warmer in summer and saving gas by living closer to our jobs. Although energy may be the most widely discussed scarcity, the general principle applies to all of the earth’s resources— iron, copper, uranium, and so on. Even goods produced by human effort are in limited supply because they require fuel, labor, and other scarce resources as inputs. We can manufacture more cars, but the increased use of labor, steel, and fuel in auto production will mean that we must cut back on something else, perhaps the production of refrigerators.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 3

41

The Fundamental Economic Problem: Scarcity and Choice

This all adds up to the following fundamental principle of economics, which we will encounter again and again in this text: Virtually all resources are scarce, meaning that people have less of them than they would like. Therefore, choices must be made among a limited set of possibilities, in full recognition of the inescapable fact that a decision to have more of one thing means that people will have less of something else.

In fact, one popular definition of economics is the study of how best to use limited means to pursue unlimited ends. Although this definition, like any short statement, cannot possibly cover the sweep of the entire discipline, it does convey the flavor of the economist’s stock in trade. To illustrate the true cost of an item, consider the decision to produce additional cars and therefore to produce fewer refrigerators. Although the production of a car may cost $15,000 per vehicle, for example, its real cost to society is the refrigerators that society must forgo to get an additional car. If the labor, steel, and energy needed to manufacture a car would be sufficient to make 30 refrigerators instead of the car, the opportunity cost of a car is 30 refrigerators. The principle of opportunity cost is so important that we will spend most of this chapter elaborating on it in various ways. HOW MUCH DOES IT REALLY COST? The Principle of Opportunity Cost Economics examines the options available to households, businesses, governments, and entire societies, given the limited resources at their command. It studies the logic of how people can make optimal decisions from among competing alternatives. One overriding principle governs this logic—a principle we introduced in Chapter 1 as one of the Ideas for Beyond the Final Exam: With limited resources, a decision to have more of one thing is simultaneously a decision to have less of something else. Hence, the relevant cost of any decision is its opportunity cost—the value of the next best alternative that is given up. Optimal decision making must be based on opportunity-cost calculations.

The opportunity cost of any decision is the value of the next best alternative that the decision forces the decision maker to forgo.

IDEAS FOR BEYOND THE FINAL EXAM

Because we live in a market economy where (almost) everything has its price, students often wonder about the connection or difference between an item’s opportunity cost and its market price. This statement seems to divorce the two concepts: The true opportunity cost of a car is not its market price but the value to their potential purchasers of the other things (like refrigerators) that could have been made or purchased instead. But isn’t the opportunity cost of a car related to its money cost? The normal answer is yes. The two costs are usually closely tied “O.K. who can put a price on love? Jim?” to one another because of the way in which a market economy sets prices. Steel, for example, is used to manufacture both automobiles and refrigerators. If consumers value items that can be made with steel (such as refrigerators) highly, then economists would say that the opportunity cost of making a car is high. But, under these circumstances, strong demand for this highly valued resource will bid up its market price. In this way, a well-functioning price system will assign a high price to steel, which will make the money cost of manufacturing a car high as well. In summary: If the market functions well, goods that have high opportunity costs will also have high money costs. In turn, goods that have low opportunity costs will also have low money costs.

Nevertheless, it would be a mistake to treat opportunity costs and explicit monetary costs as identical. For one thing, sometimes the market does not function well and hence assigns prices that do not accurately reflect opportunity costs. Moreover, some valuable items may not bear explicit price tags at all. We encountered one such example in Chapter 1, where we noted that the opportunity cost of a college education may differ sharply from its explicit money cost. Why? Because one important item is typically omitted from the money-cost Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

SOURCE: © 2002 The New Yorker Collection, 1991 Jack Ziegler from cartoonbank.com. All Rights Reserved.

Opportunity Cost and Money Cost

42

Part 1

Getting Acquainted with Economics

calculation: the market value of your time; that is, the wages you could earn by working instead of attending college. Because you give up these potential wages, which can amount to $15,000 per year or more in order to acquire an education, they must be counted as a major part of the opportunity cost of going to college. Other common examples where money costs and opportunity costs diverge are goods and services that are given away “free.” For example, some early settlers of the American West destroyed natural amenities such as forests and buffalo herds, which had no market price, leaving later generations to pay the opportunity costs in terms of lost resources. Similarly, you incur no explicit monetary cost to acquire an item that is given away for free. However, if you must wait in line to get the “free” commodity, you incur an opportunity cost equal to the value of the next best use of your time.

Optimal Choice: Not Just Any Choice How do people and firms make decisions? There are many ways, some of them based on hunches with little forethought; some are even based on superstition or the advice of a fortune teller. Often, when the required information is scarce and the necessary research and calculations are costly and difficult, the decision maker will settle on the first possibility that he can “live with”—a choice that promises to yield results that are not too bad and that seem fairly safe. The decision maker may be willing to choose this course even though he recognizes that there might be other options that are better but are unknown to him. This way of deciding is called satisficing. In this book, we will assume that decision makers seek to do better than mere satisficing. Rather, we will assume that they seek to reach decisions that are optimal—decisions that do better in achieving the decision makers’ goals than any other possible choice. We will assume that the required information is available to the decision makers and we will study the procedures that enable them to determine the optimal choices. An optimal decision is one that best serves the objectives of the decision maker, whatever those objectives may be. It is selected by explicit or implicit comparison with the possible alternative choices. The term optimal does not mean that we, the observers or analysts, approve or disapprove of the objective itself.

An optimal decision for individual X is one that is selected after implicit or explicit comparison of the consequences of each of the possible choices and that is shown by analysis to be the one that most effectively promotes the goals of person X.

We will study optimal decision making by various parties—consumers, producers, and sellers—in a variety of situations. The methods of analysis for determining what choice is optimal in each case will be remarkably similar. So, if you understand one of them, you will already be well on your way to understanding them all. A technique called marginal analysis will be used for this purpose. But one fundamental idea underlies any method used for optimal decision making: To determine whether a possible decision is or is not optimal, its consequences must be compared with those of each of the other possible choices.

SCARCITY AND CHOICE FOR A SINGLE FIRM The outputs of a firm or an economy are the goods and services it produces. The inputs used by a firm or an economy are the labor, raw materials, electricity, and other resources it uses to produce its outputs.

The nature of opportunity cost is perhaps clearest in the case of a single business firm that produces two outputs from a fixed supply of inputs. Given current technology and the limited resources at its disposal, the more of one good the firm produces, the less of the other it will be able to make. Unless managers explicitly weigh the desirability of each product against the other, they are unlikely to make rational production decisions. Consider the example of Jones, a farmer whose available supplies of land, machinery, labor, and fertilizer are capable of producing the various combinations of soybeans and wheat listed in Table 1. Obviously, devoting more resources to soybean production means that Jones will produce less wheat. Table 1 indicates, for example, that if Jones grows only soybeans, the harvest will be 40,000 bushels. But if he reduces his soybean production to 30,000 bushels, he can also grow 38,000 bushels of wheat. Thus, the opportunity cost of obtaining 38,000 bushels of wheat is 10,000 fewer bushels of soybeans. Put another way, the opportunity cost of 10,000 more bushels of soybeans is 38,000 bushels of wheat. The other numbers in Table 1 have similar interpretations.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

43

The Fundamental Economic Problem: Scarcity and Choice

Chapter 3

Production Possibilities Open to a Farmer

Bushels of Soybeans

Bushels of Wheat

Label in Figure 1

40,000 30,000 20,000 10,000 0

0 38,000 52,000 60,000 65,000

A B C D E

Soybeans

TABLE 1 A 40 30 20

B Attainable region

Unattainable region C D

10 0 10

20 30 38 Wheat

E 52 60 65

NOTE: Quantities are in thousands of bushels per year.

FIGURE 1 The situation becomes a little more complicated when the objective of the farmer is to earn as large a money profit as possible, rather than maximizing quantity of wheat or soybeans. Suppose producing 38,000 bushels of wheat requires Jones to give up 10,000, bushels of soybeans and $4,000 is the profit he would earn if he chose the wheat output, whereas $1,200 is the profit offered by the soybean option (that would have to be given up if wheat specialization were decided upon). Then the opportunity cost that our farmer would incur is not the 10,000 bushels of soybeans, but the $12,000 in profits that substitution of soybean production would offer.

Production Possibilities Frontier for Production by a Single Farmer

The Production Possibilities Frontier Figure 1 presents this same information graphically. Point A indicates that one of the options available to the farmer is to produce 40,000 bushels of soybeans and 0 wheat. Thus, point A corresponds to the first line of Table 1, point B to the second line, and so on. Curves similar to AE appear frequently in this book; they are called production possibilities frontiers. Any point on or inside the production possibilities frontier is attainable because it does not entail larger outputs than currently available resources permit. Points outside the frontier, representing very large quantities of output, are figments of the imagination given current circumstances because they cannot be achieved with the available resources and technology. Because resources are limited, the production possibilities frontier always slopes downward to the right. The farmer can increase wheat production (move to the right in Figure 1) only by devoting more land and labor to growing wheat, but this choice simultaneously reduces soybean production (the curve must move downward) because less land and labor remain available for growing soybeans. Notice that, in addition to having a negative slope, our production possibilities frontier AE has another characteristic: It is “bowed outward.” What does this curvature mean? In short, as larger and larger quantities of resources are transferred from the production of one output to the production of another, the additions to the second product decline. Suppose farmer Jones initially produces only soybeans, using even land that is comparatively most productive in wheat cultivation (point A). Now he decides to switch some land from soybean production into wheat production. Which part of the land will he switch? If Jones is sensible, he will use the part that, because of its chemical content, direction in relation to sunlight, and so on, is relatively most productive in growing wheat. As he shifts to point B, soybean production falls from 40,000 bushels to 30,000 bushels as wheat production rises from 0 to 38,000 bushels. A sacrifice of only 10,000 bushels of soybeans “buys” 38,000 bushels of wheat. Imagine now that our farmer wants to produce still more wheat. Figure 1 tells us that the sacrifice of an additional 10,000 bushels of soybeans (from 30,000 bushels to 20,000 bushels) will yield only 14,000 more bushels of wheat (see point C). Why? The main reason is that inputs tend to be specialized. As we noted at point A, the farmer was using resources for soybean production that were relatively more productive in growing wheat.

A production possibilities frontier shows the different combinations of various goods, any one of which a producer can turn out, given the available resources and existing technology.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

44

Part 1

Getting Acquainted with Economics

Consequently, their relative productivity in soybean production was low. When these resources are switched to wheat production, the yield is high. This trend cannot continue forever, of course. As more wheat is produced, the farmer must utilize land and machinery with a greater productivity advantage in growing soybeans and a smaller productivity advantage in growing wheat. This is why the first 10,000 bushels of soybeans forgone “buys” the farmer 38,000 bushels of wheat, whereas the second 10,000 bushels of soybeans “buys” only 14,000 bushels of wheat. Figure 1 and Table 1 show that these returns continue to decline as wheat production expands: The next 10,000-bushel reduction in soybean production yields only 8,000 bushels of additional wheat, and so on. If the farmer’s objective is to maximize the amount of wheat or soybean product he gets out of his land and labor then, as we can see, the slope of the production possibilities frontier graphically represents the concept of opportunity cost. Between points C and B, for example, the opportunity cost of acquiring 10,000 additional bushels of soybeans is shown on the graph to be 14,000 bushels of forgone wheat; between points B and A, the opportunity cost of 10,000 bushels of soybeans is 38,000 bushels of forgone wheat. In general, as we move upward to the left along the production possibilities frontier (toward more soybeans and less wheat), the opportunity cost of soybeans in terms of wheat increases. Looking at the same thing the other way, as we move downward to the right, the opportunity cost of acquiring wheat by giving up soybeans increases—more and more soybeans must be forgone per added bushel of wheat and successive addition to wheat output occur.

The Principle of Increasing Costs The principle of increasing costs states that as the production of a good expands, the opportunity cost of producing another unit generally increases.

FIGURE 2

Black Shoes

Production Possibilities Frontier without Specialized Resources

We have just described a very general phenomenon with applications well beyond farming. The principle of increasing costs states that as the production of one good expands, the opportunity cost of producing another unit of this good generally increases. This principle is not a universal fact—exceptions do arise—but it does seem to be a technological regularity that applies to a wide range of economic activities. As our farming example suggests, the principle of increasing costs is based on the fact that resources tend to be at least somewhat specialized. So we lose some of their productivity when those resources are transferred from doing what they are relatively good at to what they are relatively bad at. In terms of diagrams such as Figure 1, the principle simply asserts that the production possibilities frontier is bowed outward. Perhaps the best way to understand this idea is to contrast it with a case in which no resources are specialized so costs do not increase as output proportion changes. Figure 2 depicts a production possibilities frontier for producing black shoes and brown shoes. Because the labor and machinery used to produce black shoes are just as good at producing brown shoes, the frontier is a straight line. If the firm cuts back its 50 production of black shoes by 10,000 pairs, it can produce 10,000 additional A pairs of brown shoes, no matter how big 40 the shift between these two outputs. It loses no productivity in the switch B 30 because resources are not specialized. C

20

D

10 0 10

20

30

Brown Shoes NOTE: Quantities are in thousands of pairs per week.

40

50

More typically, however, as a firm concentrates more of its productive capacity on one commodity, it is forced to employ inputs that are better suited to making another commodity. The firm is forced to vary the proportions in which it uses inputs because of the limited quantities of some of those inputs. This fact also explains the typical curvature of the firm’s production possibilities frontier.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 3

45

The Fundamental Economic Problem: Scarcity and Choice

SCARCITY AND CHOICE FOR THE ENTIRE SOCIETY Like an individual firm, the entire economy is also constrained by its limited resources and technology. If the public wants more aircraft and tanks, it will have to give up some boats and automobiles. If it wants to build more factories and stores, it will have to build fewer homes and sports arenas. In general: The position and shape of the production possibilities frontier that constrains society’s choices are determined by the economy’s physical resources, its skills and technology, its willingness to work, and how much it has devoted in the past to the construction of factories, research, and innovation.

FIGURE 3 Production Possibilities Frontier for the Entire Economy

Thousands of Automobiles per Year

Because so many nations have long debated whether to reduce or augment military spending, let us exemplify the nature of soci700 ety’s choices by deciding between military might (represented by B missiles) and civilian consumption (represented by automobiles). 600 Just like a single firm, the economy as a whole faces a production possibilities frontier for missiles and autos, determined by its techD 500 nology and the available resources of land, labor, capital, and raw materials. This production possibilities frontier may look like E 400 curve BC in Figure 3. If most workers are employed in auto plants, car production will be large, but the output of missiles will be small. If the economy transfers resources out of auto manufacturG 300 ing when consumer demand declines, it can, by congressional action, alter the output mix toward more missiles (the move from 200 D to E). However, something is likely to be lost in the process because physical resources are specialized. The fabric used to 100 make car seats will not help much in missile production. The principle of increasing costs strongly suggests that the production pos0 100 200 300 400 sibilities frontier curves downward toward the axes. We may even reach a point where the only resources left are Missiles per Year not very useful outside of auto manufacturing. In that case, even a large sacrifice of automobiles will get the economy few additional missiles. That is the meaning of the steep segment, FC, on the frontier. At point C, there is little additional output of missiles as compared to point F, even though at C automobile production has been given up entirely. The downward slope of society’s production possibilities frontier implies that hard choices must be made. Civilian consumption (automobiles) can be increased only by decreasing military expenditure, not by rhetoric or wishing. The curvature of the production possibilities frontier implies that as defense spending increases, it becomes progressively more expensive to “buy” additional military strength (“missiles”) in terms of the resulting sacrifice of civilian consumption.

Scarcity and Choice Elsewhere in the Economy We have emphasized that limited resources force hard choices on business managers and society as a whole, but the same type of choices arises elsewhere—in households, universities, and other nonprofit organizations, as well as the government. The nature of opportunity cost is perhaps most obvious for a household that must decide how to divide its income among the goods and services that compete for the family’s attention. If the Simpson family buys an expensive new car, they may be forced to cut back sharply on some other purchases. This fact does not make it unwise to buy the car, but it does make it unwise to buy the car until the family considers the full implications for its overall budget. If the Simpsons are to utilize their limited resources most effectively, they must recognize the opportunity costs of the car—the things they will forgo as a result— perhaps a vacation and an expensive new TV set. The decision to buy the car will be rational if the benefit to the family from the automobile (however measured) is greater than the opportunity cost—their benefit if they buy an equally expensive vacation or TV set instead. Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

F

C

500

46

Part 1

Getting Acquainted with Economics

Hard Choices in the Real World This excerpt from a recent newspaper story brings home the realities of scarcity and choice: “President Barack Obama delivered a $3.6 trillion budget blueprint to Congress Thursday. . . . The budget blueprint for fiscal year 2010 is one of the most ambitious policy prescriptions in decades, a reordering of the federal government to provide national health care, shift the energy economy away from oil and gas, and boost the federal commitment to education. . . .

exemptions and itemized deductions would bring in another $180 billion. Higher capital gains rates would bring in $118 billion. The estate tax, scheduled to be repealed next year, would instead be preserved. . . .” SOURCE: Excerpted from Jonathan Weisman, “Obama Budget Pushes Sweeping Change”, ‘The Wall Street Journal’, February 27, 2009. Reprinted by permission of The Wall Street Journal. Copyright © 2009 Dow Jones & Company, Inc. All Rights Reserved Worldwide.

SOURCE: © AP Photo/J. David Ake

Mr. Obama proposes large increases in education funding, including indexing Pell Grants for higher education to inflation and converting the popular scholarship to an automatic ‘entitlement’ program. High-speed rail would gain a $1 billion-a-year grant program, part of a larger effort to boost infrastructure spending. . . . To finance his proposals, the president has clearly chosen winners and losers—with the affluent heading the list of losers. . . . As expected, taxes will rise for singles earning $200,000 and couples earning $250,000, beginning in 2011—for a total windfall of $656 billion over 10 years. Income tax hikes would raise $339 billion alone. Limits on personal

ISSUE REVISITED

COPING WITH THE BUDGET DEFICIT

As already noted, even a rich and powerful nation like the United States must cope with the limitations implied by scarce resources. The necessity for choice imposed on governments by the limited amount they feel they can afford to spend is similar in character to the problems faced by business firms and households. For the goods and services that it buys from others, a government must prepare a budget similar to that of a very large household. For the items it produces itself—education, police protection, libraries, and so on—it faces a production possibilities frontier much like a business firm does. Even though the U.S. government spent over $2.6 trillion in 2006, some of the most acrimonious debates between then President Bush and his critics arose from disagreements about how the government’s limited resources should be allocated among competing uses. Even if unstated, the concept of opportunity cost is central to these debates.

THE CONCEPT OF EFFICIENCY So far, our discussion of scarcity and choice has assumed that either the firm or the economy always operates on its production possibilities frontier rather than below it. In other words, we have tacitly assumed that whatever the firm or economy decides to do, it does so efficiently.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

The Fundamental Economic Problem: Scarcity and Choice

47

Economists define efficiency as the absence of waste. An efficient economy wastes none of its available resources and produces the maximum amount of output that its technology permits.

A set of outputs is said to be produced efficiently if, given current technological knowledge, there is no way one can produce larger amounts of any output without using larger input amounts or giving up some quantity of another output.

Chapter 3

To see why any point on the economy’s production possibilities frontier in Figure 3 (in a choice between missiles or automobiles or some combination of the two) represents an efficient decision, suppose for a moment that society has decided to produce 300 missiles. The production possibilities frontier tells us that if 300 missiles are to be produced, then the maximum number of automobiles that can be made is 500,000 (point D in Figure 3). The economy is therefore operating efficiently only if it produces 500,000 automobiles (when it manufactures 300 missiles) rather than some smaller number of cars, such as 300,000 (as at point G). Point D is efficient, but point G is not, because the economy is capable of moving from G to D, thereby producing 200,000 more automobiles without giving up any missiles (or anything else). Clearly, failure to take advantage of the option of choosing point D rather than point G constitutes a wasted opportunity—an inefficiency. Note that the concept of efficiency does not tell us which point on the production possibilities frontier is best. Rather, it tells us only that any point below the frontier cannot be best, because any such point represents wasted resources. For example, should society ever find itself at a point such as G, the necessity of making hard choices would (temporarily) disappear. It would be possible to increase production of both missiles and automobiles by moving to a point such as E. Why, then, would a society ever find itself at a point below its production possibilities frontier? Why are resources wasted in real life? The most important reason in today’s economy is unemployment. When many workers are unemployed, the economy must be at a point such as G, below the frontier, because by putting the unemployed to work in each industry, the economy could produce both more missiles and more automobiles. The economy would then move from point G to the right (more missiles) and upward (more automobiles) toward a point such as E on the production possibilities frontier. Only when no resources are wasted is the economy operating on the frontier. Inefficiency occurs in other ways, too. A prime example is assigning inputs to the wrong task—as when wheat is grown on land best suited to soybean cultivation. Another important type of inefficiency occurs when large firms produce goods that smaller enterprises could make better because they can pay closer attention to detail, or when small firms produce outputs best suited to large-scale production. Some other examples are the outright waste that occurs because of favoritism (for example, promotion of an incompetent brother-in-law to a job he cannot do very well) or restrictive labor practices (for example, requiring a railroad to keep a fireman on a diesel-electric locomotive where there is no longer a fire to tend). A particularly deplorable form of waste is caused by discrimination against minority or female workers. When a job is given, for example, to a white male in preference to an African-American woman who is more qualified, society sacrifices potential output and the entire community is apt to be affected adversely. Every one of these inefficiencies means that the community obtains less output than it could have, given the available inputs.

THE THREE COORDINATION TASKS OF ANY ECONOMY In deciding how to allocate its scarce resources, every society must somehow make three sorts of decisions: • First, as we have emphasized, it must figure out how to utilize its resources efficiently; that is, it must find a way to reach its production possibilities frontier. • Second, it must decide which of the possible combinations of goods to produce—how many missiles, automobiles, and so on; that is, it must select one specific point on

Allocation of resources refers to society’s decisions on how to divide up its scarce input resources among the different outputs produced in the economy and among the different firms or other organizations that produce those outputs.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

48

Part 1

Getting Acquainted with Economics

the production possibilities frontier among all of the points (that is, all of the output combinations) on the frontier. • Third, it must decide how much of the total output of each good to distribute to each person, doing so in a sensible way that does not assign meat to vegetarians and wine to teetotalers. There are many ways in which societies can and do make each of these decisions— to which economists often refer as how, what, and to whom? For example, a central planner may tell people how to produce, what to produce, and what to consume, as the authorities used to do, at least to some extent, in the former Soviet Union. But in a market economy, no one group or individual makes all such resource allocation decisions explicitly. Rather, consumer demands and production costs allocate resources automatically and anonymously through a system of prices and markets. As the formerly socialist countries learned, markets do an impressively effective job in carrying out these tasks. For our introduction to the ways in which markets do all this, let’s consider each task in turn.

TASK 1. HOW THE MARKET FOSTERS EFFICIENT RESOURCE ALLOCATION Production efficiency is one of the economy’s three basic tasks, and societies pursue it in many ways. However, one source of efficiency is so fundamental that we must single it out for special attention: the tremendous productivity gains that stem from specialization.

The Wonders of the Division of Labor Division of labor means breaking up a task into a number of smaller, more specialized tasks so that each worker can become more adept at a particular job.

Adam Smith, the founder of modern economics, first marveled at how division of labor raises efficiency and productivity when he visited a pin factory. In a famous passage near the beginning of his monumental book The Wealth of Nations (1776), he described what he saw: One man draws out the wire, another straightens it, a third cuts it, a fourth points it, a fifth grinds it at the top for receiving the head. To make the head requires two or three distinct operations; to put it on is a peculiar business, to whiten the pins is another; it is even a trade by itself to put them into the paper.1

SOURCE: © Courtesy of the Library of Congress

Smith observed that by dividing the work to be done in this way, each worker became quite skilled in a particular specialty, and the productivity of the group of workers as a whole was greatly enhanced. As Smith related it:

1 2

I have seen a small manufactory of this kind where ten men only were employed. . . . Those ten persons . . . could make among them upwards of forty-eight thousand pins in a day. . . . But if they had all wrought separately and independently . . . they certainly could not each of them have made twenty, perhaps not one pin in a day.2 In other words, through the miracle of division of labor and specialization, 10 workers accomplished what might otherwise have required thousands. This was one of the secrets of the Industrial Revolution, which helped lift humanity out of the abject poverty that had been its lot for centuries.

Adam Smith, The Wealth of Nations (New York: Random House, 1937), p. 4. Ibid., p. 5.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 3

49

The Fundamental Economic Problem: Scarcity and Choice

The Amazing Principle of Comparative Advantage Specialization in production fosters efficiency in an even more profound sense. Adam Smith noticed that how goods are produced can make a huge difference to productivity, but so can which goods are produced. The reason is that people (and businesses and nations) have different abilities. Some can repair automobiles, whereas others are wizards with numbers. Some are handy with computers, and others can cook. An economy will be most efficient if people specialize in doing what they do best and then trade with one another, so that the accountant gets her car repaired and the computer programmer gets to eat tasty and nutritious meals. This much is obvious. What is less obvious—and is one of the great ideas of economics— is that two people (or two businesses or two countries) can generally gain from trade even if one of them is more efficient than the other in producing everything. A simple example will help explain why. Some lawyers can type better than their administrative assistants. Should such a lawyer fire her assistant and do her own typing? Not likely. Even though the lawyer may type better than the assistant, good judgment tells her to concentrate on practicing law and leave the typing to a lower-paid assistant. Why? Because the opportunity cost of an hour devoted to typing is the amount that she could earn from an hour less spent with clients, which is a far more lucrative activity. This example illustrates the principle of comparative advantage at work. The lawyer specializes in arguing cases despite her advantage as a typist because she has a still greater advantage as an attorney. She suffers some direct loss by leaving the typing to a less efficient employee, but she more than makes up for that loss by the income she earns selling her legal services to clients. Precisely the same principle applies to nations. As we shall learn in greater detail in Chapter 34, comparative advantage underlies the economic analysis of international trade patterns. A country that is particularly adept at producing certain items—such as aircraft in the United States, coffee in Brazil, and oil in Saudi Arabia—should specialize in those activities, producing more than it wants for its own use. The country can then take the money it earns from its exports and purchase from other nations items that it does not make for itself. And this is still true if one of the trading nations is the most efficient producer of almost everything. The underlying logic is precisely the same as in our lawyer-typist example. The United States might, for example, be better than South Korea at manufacturing both computers and television sets. But if the United States is vastly more efficient at producing computers, but only slightly more efficient at making TV sets, it pays for the United States to specialize in computer manufacturing, for South Korea to specialize in TV production, and for the two countries to trade. This principle, called the law of comparative advantage, was discovered by David Ricardo, another giant in the history of economic analysis, almost 200 years ago. It is one of the Ideas for Beyond the Final Exam introduced in Chapter 1. THE SURPRISING PRINCIPLE OF COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE Even if one country (or one worker) is worse than another country (or another worker) in the production of every good, it is said to have a comparative advantage in making the good at which it is least inefficient—compared to the other country. Ricardo discovered that two countries can gain by trading even if one country is more efficient than another in the production of every commodity. Precisely the same logic applies to individual workers or to businesses. In determining the most efficient patterns of production and trade, it is comparative advantage that matters. Thus, a country can gain by importing a good from abroad even if that good can be produced more efficiently at home. Such imports make sense if they enable the country to specialize in producing those goods at which it is even more efficient. And the other, less efficient country should specialize in exporting the goods in whose production it is least inefficient.

One country is said to have a comparative advantage over another in the production of a particular good relative to other goods if it produces that good less inefficiently than it produces other goods, as compared with the other country.

IDEAS FOR BEYOND THE FINAL EXAM

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

50

Part 1

Getting Acquainted with Economics

TASK 2. MARKET EXCHANGE AND DECIDING HOW MUCH OF EACH GOOD TO PRODUCE The gains from specialization are welcome, but they create a problem: With specialization, people no longer produce only what they want to consume themselves. The workers in Adam Smith’s pin factory had no use for the thousands of pins they produced each day; they wanted to trade them for things like food, clothing, and shelter. Similarly, the administrative assistant in our law office example has no personal use for the legal briefs he types. Thus, specialization requires some mechanism by which workers producing pins can exchange their wares with workers producing such things as cloth and potatoes and office workers can turn their typing skills into things they want to consume. Without a system of exchange, the productivity miracle achieved by comparative advantage and the division of labor would do society little good, because each producer in an efficient arrangement would be left with only the commodities in whose production its comparative efficiency was greatest and would have no other goods to consume. With it, standards of living have risen enormously.

Although people can and do trade goods for other goods, a system of exchange works better when everyone agrees to use some common item (such as pieces of paper with unique markings printed on them) for buying and selling things. Enter money. Then workers in pin factories, for example, can be paid in money rather than in pins, and they can use this money to purchase cloth and potatoes. Textile workers and farmers can do the same. In a market in which trading is carried out by means of exchange between money and goods or services, the market mechanism also makes the second of our three crucial decisions: how much of each good should be produced with the resources that are available to the economy. For what happens is that if more widgets are produced than consumers want to buy at current prices, those who make widgets will be left with unsold widgets on their hands. Widget price will be driven down, and manufacturers will be forced to cut production, with some being driven out of business altogether. The opposite will happen if producers supply fewer widgets than consumers want at the prevailing prices. Then prices will be driven up by scarcity and manufacturers will be led to increase their output. In this way, the output and price of each and every commodity will be driven toward levels at which supply matches demand or comes very close to it. That is how the market automatically deals with the second critical decision: how much of each commodity will be produced by the economy given the economy’s productive capacity (as shown by the production possibility frontier).

TASK 3. HOW TO DISTRIBUTE THE ECONOMY’S OUTPUTS AMONG CONSUMERS

A market system is a form of economic organization in which resource allocation decisions are left to individual producers and consumers acting in their own best interests without central direction.

These two phenomena—specialization and exchange (assisted by money)—working in tandem led to vast increases in the abundance that the more prosperous economies of the world were able to supply. But that leaves us with the third basic issue: What forces allow those outputs to be distributed among the population in reasonable ways? What forces establish a smoothly functioning system of exchange so that people can first exploit their comparative advantages and then acquire what they want to consume? One alternative is to have a central authority telling people what to do. Adam Smith explained and extolled yet another way of organizing and coordinating economic activity—markets and prices can coordinate those activities. Smith noted that people are adept at pursuing their own self-interests and that a market system harnesses this self-interest remarkably well. As he put it—with clear religious overtones—in doing what is best for themselves, people are “led by an invisible hand” to promote the economic well-being of society as a whole. Those of us who live in a well-functioning market economy like that found in the United States tend to take the achievements of the market for granted, much like the daily rising and setting of the sun. Few bother to think about, say, the reason why Hawaiian pineapples show up daily in Vermont supermarkets in quantities desired by Vermont consumers. The

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

The Fundamental Economic Problem: Scarcity and Choice

market deals with this issue through the profit motive, which guides firms’ output decisions, matching quantities produced to consumer preferences. A rise in the price of wheat because of increased demand for bread, for example, will persuade farmers to produce more wheat and devote less of their land to soybeans. Such a price system also distributes goods among consumers in accord with their tastes and preferences, using voluntary exchange to determine who gets what. Consumers spend their income on the things they like best (among those they can afford). Vegetarians do not waste their income on beef, and teetotalers do not spend money on gin. So consumers, by controlling their spending patterns, can ensure that the goods they buy at the supermarket are compatible with their preferences. That is how the market mechanism ensures that the products of the economy are divided among consumers in a rational manner, meaning that this distribution tends to fit in with the preferences of the different purchasers. But there is at least one problem here; the ability to buy goods is hardly divided equally. Workers with valuable skills and owners of scarce resources can sell what they have at attractive prices. With the incomes they earn, they can purchase generous amounts of goods and services. Those who are less successful in selling what they own receive lower incomes and so can afford to buy less. In extreme cases, they may suffer severe deprivation. The past few pages explain, in broad terms, how a market economy solves the three basic problems facing any society: how to produce any given combination of goods efficiently, how to select an appropriate combination of goods to produce, and how to distribute these goods sensibly among people. As we proceed through the following chapters, you will learn much more about these issues. You will see that they constitute the central theme that permeates not only this text but the work of economists in general. As you progress through this book, keep in mind two questions: • What does the market do well? • What does it do poorly? There are numerous answers to both questions, as you will learn in subsequent chapters. Society has many important goals. Some of them, such as producing goods and services with maximum efficiency (minimum waste), can be achieved extraordinarily well by letting markets operate more or less freely.

Free markets will not, however, achieve all of society’s goals. For example, they often have trouble keeping unemployment low. In fact, the unfettered operations of markets may even run counter to some goals, such as protection of the environment. Many observers also believe that markets do not necessarily distribute income in accord with ethical or moral norms. Even in cases in which markets do not perform well, there may be ways of harnessing the power of the market mechanism to remedy its own deficiencies, as you will learn in later chapters. Economic debates often have political and ideological overtones. So we will close this chapter by emphasizing that the central theme we have just outlined is neither a defense of nor an attack on the capitalist system. Nor is it a “conservative” position. One does not have to be a conservative to recognize that the market mechanism can be an extraordinarily helpful instrument for the pursuit of economic goals. Most of the formerly socialist countries of Europe have been working hard to “marketize” their Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

51

SOURCE: © Plush Studios/Blend Images/Jupiterimages

Chapter 3

52

Part 1

Getting Acquainted with Economics

economies, and even the communist People’s Republic of China has made huge strides in that direction. The point is not to confuse ends with means in deciding how much to rely on market forces. Liberals and conservatives surely have different goals, but the means chosen to pursue these goals should, for the most part, be chosen on the basis of how effective the selected means are, not on some ideological prejudgments. Even Karl Marx emphasized that the market is remarkably efficient at producing an abundance of goods and services that had never been seen in precapitalist history. Such wealth can be used to promote conservative goals, such as reducing tax rates, or to facilitate goals favored by liberals, such as providing more generous public aid for the poor. Certainly the market cannot deal with every economic problem. Indeed, we have just noted that the market is the source of a number of significant problems. Even so, the evidence accumulated over centuries leads economists to believe that most economic problems are best handled by market techniques. The analysis in this book is intended to help you identify both the objectives that the market mechanism can reliably achieve and those that it will fail to promote, or at least not promote very effectively. We urge you to forget the slogans you have heard—whether from the left or from the right—and make up your own mind after learning the material in this book.

| SUMMARY | 1. Supplies of all resources are limited. Because resources are scarce, an optimal decision is one that chooses the best alternative among the options that are possible with the available resources.

7. A firm or an economy that ends up at a point below its production possibilities frontier is using its resources inefficiently or wastefully. This is what happens, for example, when there is unemployment.

2. With limited resources, a decision to obtain more of one item is also a decision to give up some of another. The value of what we give up is called the opportunity cost of what we get. The opportunity cost is the true cost of any decision. This is one of the Ideas for Beyond the Final Exam.

8. Economists define efficiency as the absence of waste. It is achieved primarily by the gains in productivity brought about through specialization that exploits division of labor and comparative advantage and by a system of exchange.

3. When markets function effectively, firms are led to use resources efficiently and to produce the things that consumers want most. In such cases, opportunity costs and money costs (prices) correspond closely. When the market performs poorly, or when important, socially costly items are provided without charging an appropriate price, or are given away free, opportunity costs and money costs can diverge. 4. A firm’s production possibilities frontier shows the combinations of goods it can produce, given the current technology and the resources at its disposal. The frontier is usually bowed outward because resources tend to be specialized. 5. The principle of increasing costs states that as the production of one good expands, the opportunity cost of producing another unit of that good generally increases. 6. Like a firm, the economy as a whole has a production possibilities frontier whose position is determined by its technology and by the available resources of land, labor, capital, and raw materials.

9. Two countries (or two people) can gain by specializing in the activity in which each has a comparative advantage and then trading with one another. These gains from trade remain available even if one country is inferior at producing everything but specializes in producing those items at which it is least inefficient. This so-called principle of comparative advantage is one of our Ideas for Beyond the Final Exam. 10. If an exchange between two individuals is voluntary, both parties must benefit, even if no additional goods are produced. This is another of the Ideas for Beyond the Final Exam. 11. Every economic system must find a way to answer three basic questions: How can goods be produced most efficiently? How much of each good should be produced? How should goods be distributed among users? 12. The market system works very well in solving some of society’s basic problems, but it fails to remedy others and may, indeed, create some of its own. Where and how it succeeds and fails constitute the central theme of this book and characterize the work of economists in general.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

53

The Fundamental Economic Problem: Scarcity and Choice

Chapter 3

| KEY TERMS | allocation of scarce resources comparative advantage division of labor efficiency

47

49

48

47

inputs 42 market system

outputs 50

42

principle of increasing costs

44

opportunity cost

41

production possibilities frontier 43

optimal decision

42

resources

40

| TEST YOURSELF | 1. A person rents a house for $24,000 per year. The house can be purchased for $200,000, and the tenant has this much money in a bank account that pays 4 percent interest per year. Is buying the house a good deal for the tenant? Where does opportunity cost enter the picture?

3. Consider two alternatives for Stromboli in 2009. In case (a), its inhabitants eat 60 million pizzas and build 6,000 pizza ovens. In case (b), the population eats 15 million pizzas but builds 18,000 ovens. Which case will lead to a more generous production possibilities frontier for Stromboli in 2009?

2. Graphically show the production possibilities frontier for the nation of Stromboli, using the data given in the following table. Does the principle of increasing cost hold in Stromboli?

4. Jasmine’s Snack Shop sells two brands of potato chips. She produces them by buying them from a wholesale supplier. Brand X costs Jasmine $1 per bag, and Brand Y costs her $1.40. Draw Jasmine’s production possibilities frontier if she has $280 budgeted to spend on the purchase of potato chips from the wholesaler. Why is it not “bowed out”?

Stromboli’s 2004 Production Possibilities Pizzas per Year

Pizza Ovens per Year

75,000,000 60,000,000 45,000,000 30,000,000 15,000,000 0

0 6,000 11,000 15,000 18,000 18,000

| DISCUSSION QUESTIONS | 1. Discuss the resource limitations that affect a. the poorest person on earth b. Bill Gates, the richest person on earth c. a farmer in Kansas d. the government of Indonesia 2. If you were president of your college, what would you change if your budget were cut by 10 percent? By 25 percent? By 50 percent? 3. If you were to leave college, what things would change in your life? What, then, is the opportunity cost of your education?

Union. Try to describe how decisions on the number of chickens to be raised, and the amount of each feed to use in raising them, were made under the old communist regime. If the farm is now privately owned, how does the market guide the decisions that used to be made by the central planning agency? 5. The United States is one of the world’s wealthiest countries. Think of a recent case in which the decisions of the U.S. government were severely constrained by scarcity. Describe the trade-offs that were involved. What were the opportunity costs of the decisions that were actually made?

4. Raising chickens requires several types of feed, such as corn and soy meal. Consider a farm in the former Soviet

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Supply and Demand: An Initial Look The free enterprise system is absolutely too important to be left to the voluntary action of the marketplace. FLORI DA CONGRE S SM AN RI CHARD KEL LY, 1 9 7 9

I

n this chapter, we study the economist’s most basic investigative tool: the mechanism of supply and demand. Whether your econ course concentrates on macroeconomics or microeconomics, you will find that the so-called law of supply and demand is a fundamental tool of economic analysis. Economists use supply and demand analysis to study issues as diverse as inflation and unemployment, the effects of taxes on prices, government regulation of business, and environmental protection. Supply and demand curves—graphs that relate price to quantity supplied and quantity demanded, respectively—show how prices and quantities are determined in a free market.1 A major theme of the chapter is that governments around the world and throughout recorded history have tampered with the price mechanism. As we will see, these bouts with Adam Smith’s “invisible hand” have produced undesirable side effects that often surprised and dismayed the authorities. The invisible hand fights back!

C O N T E N T S PUZZLE: WHAT HAPPENED TO OIL PRICES?

SUPPLY AND DEMAND EQUILIBRIUM

THE INVISIBLE HAND

The Law of Supply and Demand

DEMAND AND QUANTITY DEMANDED The Demand Schedule The Demand Curve Shifts of the Demand Curve

SUPPLY AND QUANTITY SUPPLIED The Supply Schedule and the Supply Curve Shifts of the Supply Curve

EFFECTS OF DEMAND SHIFT ON SUPPLYDEMAND EQUILIBRIUM SUPPLY SHIFTS AND SUPPLY-DEMAND EQUILIBRIUM PUZZLE RESOLVED: THOSE LEAPING OIL PRICES Application: Who Really Pays That Tax?

BATTLING THE INVISIBLE HAND: THE MARKET FIGHTS BACK Restraining the Market Mechanism: Price Ceilings Case Study: Rent Controls in New York City Restraining the Market Mechanism: Price Floors Case Study: Farm Price Supports and the Case of Sugar Prices A Can of Worms

A SIMPLE BUT POWERFUL LESSON

1 This chapter, like much of the rest of this book, uses many graphs like those described in the appendix to Chapter 1. If you have difficulties with these graphs, we suggest that you review that material before proceeding.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Part 1

Getting Acquainted with Economics

PUZZLE:

WHAT HAPPENED TO OIL PRICES?

Since 1949, the dollars of purchasing power that a buyer had to pay to buy a barrel of oil had remained remarkably steady, and gasoline had generally remained a bargain. But during two exceptional time periods—one from about 1975 through 1985 and one beginning in 2003—oil prices exploded, and filling up the automobile gas tank became painful to consumers. Clearly, supply and demand changes must have been behind these developments, but what led them to change so much and so suddenly? Later in the chapter, we will provide excerpts from a newspaper story about how dramatic and unexpected events can suddenly shift supply and will help to bring the analysis of this chapter to life.

SOURCE: © AP Images/Paul Sakuma

56

THE INVISIBLE HAND

Invisible hand is a phrase used by Adam Smith to describe how, by pursuing their own self-interests, people in a market system are “led by an invisible hand” to promote the well-being of the community.

Adam Smith, the father of modern economic analysis, greatly admired the price system. He marveled at its accomplishments—both as an efficient producer of goods and as a guarantor that consumers’ preferences are obeyed. Although many people since Smith’s time have shared his enthusiasm for the concept of the invisible hand, many have not. Smith’s contemporaries in the American colonies, for example, were often unhappy with the prices produced by free markets and thought they could do better by legislative decree. Such attempts failed, as explained in the accompanying box “Price Controls at Valley Forge.” In countless other instances, the public was outraged by the prices charged on the open market, particularly in the case of housing rents, interest rates, and insurance rates. Attempts to control interest rates (which are the price of borrowing money) go back hundreds of years before the birth of Christ, at least to the code of laws compiled under the Babylonian king Hammurabi in about 1800 B.C. Our historical legacy also includes a rather long list of price ceilings on foods and other products imposed in the reign of Diocletian, emperor of the declining Roman Empire. More recently, Americans have been offered the “protection” of a variety of price controls. Laws have placed ceilings on some prices (such as rents) to protect buyers, whereas legislation has placed floors under other prices (such as farm products) to protect sellers. Yet, somehow, everything such regulation touches seems to end up in even greater disarray than it was before. Despite rent controls, rents in New York City have soared. Despite laws against “scalping,” tickets for popular shows and sports events sell at tremendous premiums—tickets to the Super Bowl, for example, often fetch thousands of dollars on the “gray” market. To understand what goes wrong when we tamper with markets, we must first learn how they operate unfettered. This chapter takes a first step in that direction by studying the machinery of supply and demand. Then, at the end of the chapter, we return to the issue of price controls. Every market has both buyers and sellers. We begin our analysis on the consumers’ side of the market.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 4

57

Supply and Demand: An Initial Look

George Washington, the history books tell us, was beset by many enemies during the winter of 1777–1778, including the British, their Hessian mercenaries, and the merciless winter weather. However, he had another enemy that the history books ignore—an enemy that meant well but almost destroyed his army at Valley Forge. As the following excerpt explains, that enemy was the Pennsylvania legislature: In Pennsylvania, where the main force of Washington’s army was quartered . . . the legislature . . . decided to try a period of price control limited to those commodities needed for use by the army. . . . The result might have been anticipated by those with some knowledge of the trials and tribulations of other states. The prices of uncontrolled goods, mostly imported, rose to record heights. Most farmers kept back their produce, refusing to sell at what they regarded as an unfair price. Some who had large families to take care of even secretly sold their food to the British, who paid in gold. After the disastrous winter at Valley Forge when Washington’s army nearly starved to death (thanks largely to these wellintentioned but misdirected laws), the ill-fated experiment in price controls was finally ended. The Continental Congress on June 4, 1778, adopted the following resolution: “Whereas . . . it hath been found by experience that limitations upon the prices of commodities are not only ineffectual for

SOURCE: Engraving “Men Gathering Wood at Valley Forge. “ Metropolitan Museum of Art, bequest of Charles Allen Munn, 1924 [24.90.1828]. All Rights Reserved, The Metropolitan Museum of Art.

Price Controls at Valley Forge

the purposes proposed, but likewise productive of very evil consequences . . . resolved, that it be recommended to the several states to repeal or suspend all laws or resolutions within the said states respectively limiting, regulating or restraining the Price of any Article, Manufacture or Commodity.” SOURCE: Robert L. Schuettinger and Eamonn F. Butler, Forty Centuries of Wage and Price Controls (Washington, DC: Heritage Foundation, 1979), p. 41. Reprinted by permission.

DEMAND AND QUANTITY DEMANDED People commonly think of consumer demands as fixed amounts. For example, when product designers propose a new computer model, management asks: “What is its market potential?”; that is, just how many are likely to be sold? Similarly, government bureaus conduct studies to determine how many engineers or doctors the United States will require (demand) in subsequent years. Economists respond that such questions are not well posed—that there is no single answer to such a question. Rather, they say, the “market potential” for computers or the number of engineers that will be “required” depends on a great number of influences, including the price charged for each. The quantity demanded of any product normally depends on its price. Quantity demanded also depends on a number of other determinants, including population size, consumer incomes, tastes, and the prices of other products.

Because prices play a central role in a market economy, we begin our study of demand by focusing on how quantity demanded depends on price. A little later, we will bring the other determinants of quantity demanded back into the picture. For now, we will consider all influences other than price to be fixed. This assumption, often expressed as “other things being equal,” is used in much of economic analysis. As an example of the relationship between price and demand, let’s think about the quantity of beef demanded. If the price of beef is very high, its “market potential” may be very small. People will find ways to get along with less beef, perhaps by switching to pork or fish. If the price of beef declines, people will tend to eat more beef. They may serve it more frequently or eat larger portions or switch away from fish. Thus:

The quantity demanded is the number of units of a good that consumers are willing and can afford to buy over a specified period of time.

There is no one demand figure for beef, or for computers, or for engineers. Rather, there is a different quantity demanded at each possible price, all other influences being held constant.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

58

Getting Acquainted with Economics

Part 1

The Demand Schedule A demand schedule is a table showing how the quantity demanded of some product during a specified period of time changes as the price of that product changes, holding all other determinants of quantity demanded constant. A demand curve is a graphical depiction of a demand schedule. It shows how the quantity demanded of some product will change as the price of that product changes during a specified period of time, holding all other determinants of quantity demanded constant.

Table 1 shows how such information for beef can be recorded TABLE 1 in a demand schedule. It indicates how much beef conDemand Schedule for Beef sumers in a particular area are willing and able to buy at difPrice Quantity Label in ferent possible prices during a specified period of time, other per Pound Demanded Figure 1 things held equal. Specifically, the table shows the quantity $7.50 45 A of beef that will be demanded in a year at each possible price 7.40 50 B ranging from $6.90 to $7.50 per pound. At a relatively low 7.30 55 C price, such as $7.00 per pound, customers wish to purchase 7.20 60 E 70 (million) pounds per year. But if the price were to rise 7.10 65 F to, say, $7.40 per pound, quantity demanded would fall to 7.00 70 G 6.90 75 H 50 million pounds. Common sense tells us why this happens.2 First, as prices NOTE: Quantity is in pounds per year. rise, some customers will reduce the quantity of beef they consume. Second, higher prices will induce some customers to drop out of the market entirely—for example, by switching to pork or fish. On both counts, quantity demanded will decline as the price rises. As the price of an item rises, the quantity demanded normally falls. As the price falls, the quantity demanded normally rises, all other things held constant.

The Demand Curve

F I GURE 1 Demand Curve for Beef

D $7.50

A B

Price per Pound

7.40

C

7.30

E

7.20

F

7.10

G

7.00

H 6.90 D 0

45

50

55

60 65 70 Quantity Demanded in Millions of Pounds per Year

75

The information contained in Table 1 can be summarized in a graph like Figure 1, which is called a demand curve. Each point in the graph corresponds to a line in the table. This curve shows the relationship between price and quantity demanded. For example, it tells us that to sell 55 million pounds per year, the price must be $7.10 per pound. This relationship is shown at point G in Figure 1. If the price were $7.40, however, consumers would demand only 50 million pounds (point B). Because the quantity demanded declines as the price increases, the demand curve has a negative slope.3 Notice the last phrase in the definitions of the demand schedule and the demand curve: “holding all other determinants of quantity demanded constant.” What are some of these “other things,” and how do they affect the demand curve?

Shifts of the Demand Curve The quantity of beef demanded is subject to a variety of influences other than the price of beef. Changes in population size and characteristics, consumer incomes and tastes, and the prices of alternative products such as pork and fish presumably change the quantity of beef demanded, even if the price of beef does not change. Because the demand curve for beef depicts only the relationship between the quantity of beef demanded and the price of beef, holding all other factors constant, a change in beef

2 3

This commonsense answer is examined more fully in later chapters. If you need to review the concept of slope, refer back to Chapter 1’s appendix.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

59

Supply and Demand: An Initial Look

Chapter 4

price moves the market for beef from one point on the demand curve to another point on the same curve. However, a change in any of these other influences on demand causes a shift of the entire demand curve. More generally: A change in the price of a good produces a movement along a fixed demand curve. By contrast, a change in any other variable that influences quantity demanded produces a shift of the entire demand curve.

If consumers want to buy more beef at every given price than they wanted previously, the demand curve shifts to the right (or outward). If they desire less at every given price, the demand curve shifts to the left (or inward toward the origin). Figure 2 shows this distinction graphically. If the price of beef falls from $7.30 to $7.10 per pound, and quantity demanded rises accordingly, we move along demand curve D0D0 from point C to point F, as shown by the blue arrow. If, on the other hand, consumers suddenly decide that they like beef better than before, or if they embrace a study that reports the health benefits of beef, the entire demand curve shifts outward from D0D0 to D1D1, as indicated by the brown arrows, meaning that at any given price consumers are now willing to buy more beef than before. To make this general idea more concrete, and to show some of its many applications, let us consider some specific examples of those “other things” that can shift demand curves.

A shift in a demand curve occurs when any relevant variable other than price changes. If consumers want to buy more at any and all given prices than they wanted previously, the demand curve shifts to the right (or outward). If they desire less at any given price, the demand curve shifts to the left (or inward).

FI GURE 2 Movements along versus Shifts of a Demand Curve

Consumer Incomes If average D1 D0 Price per Pound

incomes rise, consumers will purchase more of most goods, including beef, even if the prices of those goods remain the same. That is, increases in income normally shift demand curves outward to the right, as depicted in Figure 3(a), where the demand curve shifts outward from D0D0 to D1D1, establishing a new price and output quantity.

$7.30

7.10

C

F D1

Population Population growth afD0 fects quantity demanded in more or less the same way as increases in avQuantity Demanded in Millions of Pounds per Year erage incomes. For instance, a larger population will presumably want to consume more beef, even if the price of beef and average incomes do not change, thus shifting the entire demand curve to the right, as in Figure 3(a). The equilibrium price and quantity both rise. Increases in particular population segments can also elicit shifts in demand—for example, the United States experienced a miniature population boom between the late 1970s and mid-1990s. This group (which is dubbed Generation Y and includes most users of this book) has sparked higher demand for such items as cell phones and video games. In Figure 3(b), we see that a decrease in population should shift the demand curve for beef to the left, from D0D0 to D2D2.

Consumer Preferences If the beef industry mounts a successful advertising campaign extolling the benefits of eating beef, families may decide to buy more at any given price. If so, the entire demand curve for beef would shift to the right, as in Figure 3(a). Alternatively, a medical report on the dangers of high cholesterol may persuade consumers to eat less beef, thereby shifting the demand curve to the left, as in Figure 3(b). Again, these are general phenomena: If consumer preferences shift in favor of a particular item, its demand curve will shift outward to the right, as in Figure 3(a).

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

60

Part 1

Getting Acquainted with Economics

F I GURE 3 Shifts of the Demand Curve

D1 D2

M D1 D2

An example is the ever-shifting “rage” in children’s toys—be it Yu-Gi-Oh! cards, electronic Elmo dolls, or the latest video games. These items become the object of desperate hunts as parents snap them up for their offspring, and stores are unable to keep up with the demand.

Prices and Availability of Related Goods Because pork, fish, and chicken are popular products that compete with beef, a change in the price of any of these other items can be expected to shift the demand curve for beef. If any of these alternative

Volatility in Electricity Prices

Critics point to opportunities for suppliers to interfere in the market system, including the withholding of power or limiting of production during periods of high demand, leading to skyrocketing prices. “Shutting down a power plant in July is like the mall closing on the weekend before Christmas, but in July last year, 20 percent of generating capacity was shut down in California,” said Robert McCullough, an economist whose Oregon consulting business is advising some of those contending in lawsuits that prices are being manipulated.

1,500

Price of Electricity

Rising fuel costs are one major reason. . . . Another factor is the very nature of electricity, which must be produced, transmitted and consumed in an instant . . . electricity cannot be held in inventory.

2,000

SOURCE: © AP Images/Paul Sakuma

The following newspaper story excerpts highlight the volatility of the electricity industry and its susceptibility to manipulation of the supply-demand mechanism and soaring prices. Although the industry was deregulated more than a decade ago, electricity prices have generally not fallen and, in many cases, have risen sharply. The Federal Energy Regulatory Commission contends that allowing competition among producers should guarantee the lowest possible price. Why have electricity prices not fallen, unlike other previously regulated industries?

1,000

500

100 80 60 40 20 0

JUNE

JULY

AUGUST

NOTE: Quantity is in billions of quarts per year.

SOURCE: “Flaws Seen In Market for Utilities; Power Play: The Bidding Game” by David Cay Johnston, The New York Times, Late Edition (East Coast), November 21, 2006, p.C1.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 4

61

Supply and Demand: An Initial Look

items becomes cheaper, some consumers will switch away from beef. Thus, the demand curve for beef will shift to the left, as in Figure 3(b). Other price changes may shift the demand curve for beef in the opposite direction. For example, suppose that hamburger buns and ketchup become less expensive. This may induce some consumers to eat more beef and thus shift the demand curve for beef to the right, as in Figure 3(a). In general: Increases in the prices of goods that are substitutes for the good in question (as pork, fish, and chicken are for beef ) move the demand curve to the right. Increases in the prices of goods that are normally used together with the good in question (such as hamburger buns and beef ) shift the demand curve to the left.

This is just what happened when a frost wiped out almost half of Brazil’s coffee bean harvest in 1995. The three largest U.S. coffee producers raised their prices by 45 percent, and, as a result, the demand curve for alternative beverages such as tea shifted to the right. Then in 1998, coffee prices dropped about 34 percent, which in turn caused the demand curve for tea to shift toward the left (or toward the origin). Although the preceding list does not exhaust the possible influences on quantity demanded, we have said enough to suggest the principles followed by demand and shifts of demand. Let’s turn now to the supply side of the market.

SUPPLY AND QUANTITY SUPPLIED Like quantity demanded, the quantity of beef that is supplied by business firms such as farms is not a fixed number; it also depends on many things. Obviously, we expect more beef to be supplied if there are more farms or more cows per farm. Cows may provide less meat if bad weather deprives them of their feed. As before, however, let’s turn our attention first to the relationship between the price and quantity of beef supplied. Economists generally suppose that a higher price calls forth a greater quantity supplied. Why? Remember our analysis of the principle of increasing costs in Chapter 3 (page 44). According to that principle, as more of any farmer’s (or the nation’s) resources are devoted to beef production, the opportunity cost of obtaining another pound of beef increases. Farmers will therefore find it profitable to increase beef production only if they can sell the beef at a higher price—high enough to cover the additional costs incurred to expand production. In other words, it normally will take higher prices to persuade farmers to raise beef production. This idea is quite general and applies to the supply of most goods and services.4 As long as suppliers want to make profits and the principle of increasing costs holds:

The quantity supplied is the number of units that sellers want to sell over a specified period of time.

As the price of any commodity rises, the quantity supplied normally rises. As the price falls, the quantity supplied normally falls.

The Supply Schedule and the Supply Curve Table 2 shows the relationship between the price of beef and its quantity supplied. Tables such as this one are called supply schedules; they show how much sellers are willing to provide during a specified period at alternative possible prices. This particular supply schedule tells us that a low price like $7.00 per pound will induce suppliers to provide only 50 million pounds, whereas a higher price like $7.30 will induce them to provide much more—55 million pounds.

4

A supply schedule is a table showing how the quantity supplied of some product changes as the price of that product changes during a specified period of time, holding all other determinants of quantity supplied constant.

This analysis is carried out in much greater detail in later chapters.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

62

Part 1

Getting Acquainted with Economics

F I GURE 4

TABLE 2

Supply Curve for Beef

Supply Schedule for Beef a

$7.50

S b

Price per Pound

7.40 c 7.30 e 7.20 f 7.10

Price per Pound

Quantity Supplied

Label in Figure 4

$7.50 7.40 7.30 7.20 7.10 7.00 6.90

90 80 70 60 50 40 30

a b c e f g h

g NOTE: Quantity is in pounds per year.

7.00 h 6.90 0

S 30

A supply curve is a graphical depiction of a supply schedule. It shows how the quantity supplied of a product will change as the price of that product changes during a specified period of time, holding all other determinants of quantity supplied constant.

40

50 60 70 80 Quantity Supplied in Millions of Pounds per Year

90

As you might have guessed, when such information is plotted on a graph, it is called a supply curve. Figure 4 is the supply curve corresponding to the supply schedule in Table 2, showing the relationship between the price of beef and the quantity supplied. It slopes upward—it has a positive slope—because quantity supplied is higher when price is higher. Notice again the same phrase in the definition: “holding all other determinants of quantity supplied constant.” What are these “other determinants”?

Shifts of the Supply Curve Like quantity demanded, the quantity supplied in a market typically responds to many influences other than price. The weather, the cost of feed, the number and size of farms, and a variety of other factors all influence how much beef will be brought to market. Because the supply curve depicts only the relationship between the price of beef and the quantity of beef supplied, holding all other influences constant, a change in any of these other determinants of quantity supplied will cause the entire supply curve to shift. That is: A change in the price of the good causes a movement along a fixed supply curve. Price is not the only influence on quantity supplied, however. If any of these other influences change, the entire supply curve shifts.

Figure 5 depicts this distinction graphically. A rise in price from $7.10 to $7.30 will raise quantity supplied by moving along supply curve S0S0 from point f to point c. Any rise in quantity supplied attributable to an influence other than price, however, will shift the entire supply curve outward to the right, from S0S0 to S1S1, as shown by the brown arrows. Let us consider what some of these other influences are and how they shift the supply curve.

Size of the Industry We begin with the most obvious influence. If more farmers enter the beef industry, the quantity supplied at any given price will increase. For example, if each farm provides 60,000 pounds of beef per year at a price of $7.10 per pound, then 100,000 farmers would provide 600 million pounds, but 130,000 farmers would provide 780,000 million. Thus, when more farms are in the industry, the quantity of beef supplied will be greater at any given price—and hence the supply curve will move farther to the right.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

S0 S1

Price per Pound

Figure 6(a) illustrates the effect of an expansion of the industry from 100,000 farms to 130,000 farms—a rightward shift of the supply curve from S0 S0 to S 1 S 1 . Figure 6(b) illustrates the opposite case: a contraction of the industry from 100,000 farms to 62,500 farms. The supply curve shifts inward to the left, from S0S 0 to S2 S2 . Even if no farmers enter or leave the industry, results like those depicted in Figure 6 can be produced by expansion or contraction of the existing farms.

63

Supply and Demand: An Initial Look

Chapter 4

c

$7.30

f 7.10

S0 S1 Quantity Supplied in Millions of Pounds per Year

Technological Progress Another influence that shifts supply curves is technological

FI GURE 5

change. Suppose an enterprising farmer invents a new growth hormone that increases the body mass of cattle. Thereafter, at any given price, farms will be able to produce more beef; that is, the supply curve will shift outward to the right, as in Figure 6(a). This example, again, illustrates a general influence that applies to most industries:

Movements along versus Shifts of a Supply Curve

Technological progress that reduces costs will shift the supply curve outward to the right.

Automakers, for example, have been able to reduce production costs since industrial technology invented robots that can be programmed to work on several different car models. This technological advance has shifted the supply curve outward.

Prices of Inputs Changes in input prices also shift supply curves. Suppose a drought raises the price of animal feed. Farmers will have to pay more to keep their cows alive and healthy and consequently will no longer be able to provide the same quantity of beef at each possible price. This example illustrates that Increases in the prices of inputs that suppliers must buy will shift the supply curve inward to the left.

FIGU R E 6 Shifts of the Supply Curve

S2

D S0

S0

S0

V Price

Price

S1

U

E

S2 S1

D

S0 Quantity (a)

Quantity (b)

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

64

Part 1

Getting Acquainted with Economics

Prices of Related Outputs Ranchers sell hides as well as meat. If leather prices rise sharply, ranchers may decide not to fatten their cattle as much as they used to, before bringing them to market, thereby reducing the quantity of beef supplied. On a supplydemand diagram, the supply curve would then shift inward, as in Figure 6(b). Similar phenomena occur in other industries, and sometimes the effect goes the other way. For example, suppose that the price of beef goes up, which increases the quantity of meat supplied. That, in turn, will raise the number of cowhides supplied even if the price of leather does not change. Thus, a rise in the price of beef will lead to a rightward shift in the supply curve of leather. In general: A change in the price of one good produced by a multiproduct industry may be expected to shift the supply curves of other goods produced by that industry.

SUPPLY AND DEMAND EQUILIBRIUM

A supply-demand diagram graphs the supply and demand curves together. It also determines the equilibrium price and quantity.

To analyze how the free market determines price, we must compare the desires of consumers (demand) with the desires of producers (supply) to see whether the two plans are consistent. Table 3 and Figure 7 help us do this. Table 3 brings together the demand schedule from Table 1 and the supply schedule from Table 2. Similarly, Figure 7 puts the demand curve from Figure 1 and the supply curve from Figure 4 on a single graph. Such graphs are called supply-demand diagrams, and you will encounter many of them in this book. Notice that, for reasons already discussed, the demand curve has a negative slope and the supply curve has a positive slope. That is generally true of supply-demand diagrams. In a free market, price and quantity are determined by the intersection of the supply and demand curves. At only one point in Figure 7, point E, do the supply curve and the demand curve intersect. At the price corresponding to point E, which is $7.20 per pound, the quantity supplied and the quantity demanded are both 60 million pounds per year. This means that at a price of $7.20 per pound, consumers are willing to buy exactly what producers are willing to sell. At a lower price, such as $7.00 per pound, only 40 million pounds of beef will be supplied (point g), whereas 70 million pounds will be demanded (point G).

F I GURE 7

TABLE 3

Supply-Demand Equilibrium

Determination of the Equilibrium Price and Quantity of Beef D

a

A

$7.50

Price per Pound

7.40 7.30 E 7.20 7.10 g

G

7.00 6.90 0

S

S

Price per Pound

Quantity Demanded

Quantity Supplied

Surplus or Shortage

Price Direction

$7.50 7.40 7.30 7.20 7.10 7.00 6.90

45 50 55 60 65 70 75

90 80 70 60 50 40 30

Surplus Surplus Surplus Neither Shortage Shortage Shortage

Fall Fall Fall Unchanged Rise Rise Rise

D 30

40

50

60

70

80

90

Quantity in Millions of Pounds per Year

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 4

65

Supply and Demand: An Initial Look

Thus, quantity demanded will exceed quantity supplied. There will be a shortage equal to 70 minus 40, or 30 million pounds. Price will thus be driven up by unsatisfied demand. Alternatively, at a higher price, such as $7.50 per pound, quantity supplied will be 90 million pounds (point a) and quantity demanded will be only 45 million (point A). Quantity supplied will exceed quantity demanded—creating a surplus equal to 90 minus 45, or 45 million pounds. The unsold output can then be expected to push the price down. Because $7.20 is the only price in this graph at which quantity supplied and quantity demanded are equal, we say that $7.20 per pound is the equilibrium price (or the “market clearing” price) in this market. Similarly, 60 million pounds per year is the equilibrium quantity of beef. The term equilibrium merits a little explanation, because it arises so frequently in economic analysis. An equilibrium is a situation in which there are no inherent forces that produce change. Think, for example, of a pendulum resting at its center point. If no outside force (such as a person’s hand) comes to push it, the pendulum will remain exactly where it is; it is therefore in equilibrium. If you give the pendulum a shove, however, its equilibrium will be disturbed and it will start to move. When it reaches the top of its arc, the pendulum will, for an instant, be at rest again. This point is not an equilibrium position, for the force of gravity will pull the pendulum downward. Thereafter, gravity and friction will govern its motion from side to side. Eventually, the pendulum will return to its original position. The fact that the pendulum tends to return to its original position is described by saying that this position is a stable equilibrium. That position is also the only equilibrium position of the pendulum. At any other point, inherent forces will cause the pendulum to move. The concept of equilibrium in economics is similar and can be illustrated by our supply-and-demand example. Why is no price other than $7.20 an equilibrium price in Table 3 or Figure 7? What forces will change any other price? Consider first a low price such as $7.00, at which quantity demanded (70 million pounds) exceeds quantity supplied (40 million pounds). If the price were this low, many frustrated customers would be unable to purchase the quantities they desired. In their scramble for the available supply of beef, some would offer to pay more. As customers sought to outbid one another, the market price would be forced up. Thus, a price below the equilibrium price cannot persist in a free market because a shortage sets in motion powerful economic forces that push the price upward. Similar forces operate in the opposite direction if the market price exceeds the equilibrium price. If, for example, the price should somehow reach $7.50, Table 3 tells us that quantity supplied (90 million pounds) would far exceed the quantity demanded (45 million pounds). Producers would be unable to sell their desired quantities of beef at the prevailing price, and some would undercut their competitors by reducing price. Such competitive price cutting would continue as long as the surplus remained—that is, as long as quantity supplied exceeded quantity demanded. Thus, a price above the equilibrium price cannot persist indefinitely. We are left with a clear conclusion. The price of $7.20 per pound and the quantity of 60 million pounds per year constitute the only price-quantity combination that does not sow the seeds of its own destruction. It is thus the only equilibrium for this market. Any lower price must rise, and any higher price must fall. It is as if natural economic forces place a magnet at point E that attracts the market, just as gravity attracts a pendulum. The pendulum analogy is worth pursuing further. Most pendulums are more frequently in motion than at rest. However, unless they are repeatedly buffeted by outside forces (which, of course, is exactly what happens to economic equilibria in reality), pendulums gradually return to their resting points. The same is true of price and quantity in a free market. They are moved about by shifts in the supply and demand curves that we have already described. As a consequence, markets are not always in equilibrium. But, if nothing interferes with them, experience shows that they normally move toward equilibrium.

A shortage is an excess of quantity demanded over quantity supplied. When there is a shortage, buyers cannot purchase the quantities they desire at the current price. A surplus is an excess of quantity supplied over quantity demanded. When there is a surplus, sellers cannot sell the quantities they desire to supply at the current price. An equilibrium is a situation in which there are no inherent forces that produce change. Changes away from an equilibrium position will occur only as a result of “outside events” that disturb the status quo.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

66

Part 1

Getting Acquainted with Economics

The law of supply and demand states that in a free market the forces of supply and demand generally push the price toward the level at which quantity supplied and quantity demanded are equal.

The Law of Supply and Demand In a free market, the forces of supply and demand generally push the price toward its equilibrium level, the price at which quantity supplied and quantity demanded are equal. Like most economic “laws,” some markets will occasionally disobey the law of supply and demand. Markets sometimes display shortages or surpluses for long periods of time. Prices sometimes fail to move toward equilibrium. But the “law” is a fair generalization that is right far more often than it is wrong.

EFFECTS OF DEMAND SHIFTS ON SUPPLY-DEMAND EQUILIBRIUM Figure 3 showed how developments other than changes in price—such as increases in consumer income—can shift the demand curve. We saw that a rise in income, for example, will shift the demand curve to the right, meaning that at any given price, consumers—with their increased purchasing power—will buy more of the good than before. This, in turn, will move the equilibrium point, changing both market price and quantity sold. This market adjustment is shown in Figure 8(a). It adds a supply curve to Figure 3(a) so that we can see what happens to the supply-demand equilibrium. In the example in the graph, the quantity demanded at the old equilibrium price of $7.20 increases from 60 million pounds per year (point E on the demand curve D0D0) to 75 million pounds per year (point R on the demand curve D1D1). We know that $7.20 is no longer the equilibrium price, because at this price quantity demanded (75 million pounds) exceeds quantity supplied (60 million pounds). To restore equilibrium, the price must rise. The new equilibrium occurs at point T, the intersection point of the supply curve and the shifted demand curve, where the price is $7.30 per pound and both quantities demanded and supplied are 70 million pounds per year. This example illustrates a general result, which is true when the supply curve slopes upward: Any influence that makes the demand curve shift outward to the right, and does not affect an upward-sloped supply curve, will raise the equilibrium price and the equilibrium quantity.5

F I GURE 8 The Effects of Shifts of the Demand Curve

D1 S T $7.30 E 7.20

D0 Price per Pound

Price per Pound

D0

R

S

D2

E $7.20

L

M

7.10

D1 D0

S

60 7075 Quantity (a)

D0 S

D2 45 50 60 Quantity (b)

NOTE: Quantity is in millions of pounds per year.

5 For example, when incomes rise rapidly, in many developing countries the demand curves for a variety of consumer goods shift rapidly outward to the right. In Japan, for example, the demand for used Levi’s jeans and Nike running shoes from the United States skyrocketed in the early 1990s as status-conscious Japanese consumers searched for outlets for their then-rising incomes.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

67

Supply and Demand: An Initial Look

Chapter 4

The Ups and Downs of Milk Consumption The following excerpt from a U.S. Department of Agriculture publication discusses some of the things that have affected the consumption of milk in the last century.

SOURCE: Judy Putnam and Jane Allshouse, “Trends in U.S. Per Capita Consumption of Dairy Products, 1909 to 2001,” Amber Waves: The Economics of Food, Farming, Natural Resources and Rural America, June 2003, U.S. Department of Agriculture, available at http://www.usda.gov.

Americans are switching to lower fat milks 40 Gallons per person

In 1909, Americans consumed a total of 34 gallons of fluid milk per person—27 gallons of whole milk and 7 gallons of milks lower in fat than whole milk, mostly buttermilk. . . . Fluid milk consumption shot up from 34 gallons per person in 1941 to a peak of 45 gallons per person in 1945. War production lifted Americans’ incomes but curbed civilian production and the goods consumers could buy. Many food items were rationed, including meats, butter and sugar. Milk was not rationed, and consumption soared. Since 1945, however, milk consumption has fallen steadily, reaching a record low of just under 23 gallons per person in 2001 (the latest year for which data are available). Steep declines in consumption of whole milk and buttermilk far outpaced an increase in other lower fat milks. By 2001, Americans were consuming less than 8 gallons per person of whole milk, compared with nearly 41 gallons in 1945 and 25 gallons in 1970. In contrast, per capita consumption of total lower fat milks was 15 gallons in 2001, up from 4 gallons in 1945 and 6 gallons

in 1970. These changes are consistent with increased public concern about cholesterol, saturated fat, and calories. However, decline in per capita consumption of fluid milk also may be attributed to competition from other beverages, especially carbonated soft drinks and bottled water, a smaller percentage of children and adolescents in the U.S., and a more ethnically diverse population whose diet does not normally include milk.

Whole milk

30 Other lower fat milks 20 10 0 1909

Buttermilk 1916

1923

1930

1937

1944

1951

1958

1965

1972

1979

1986

1993

2000

Lower fat milks include: buttermilk (1.5 percent fat), plain and flavored reduced fat milk (2 percent fat), low-fat milk (1 percent fat), nonfat milk, and yogurt made from these milks (except frozen yogurt).

Everything works in reverse if consumer incomes fall. Figure 8(b) depicts a leftward (inward) shift of the demand curve that results from a decline in consumer incomes. For example, the quantity demanded at the previous equilibrium price ($7.20) falls from 60 million pounds (point E) to 45 million pounds (point L on the demand curve D2D2). The initial price is now too high and must fall. The new equilibrium will eventually be established at point M, where the price is $7.10 and both quantity demanded and quantity supplied are 50 million pounds. In general: Any influence that shifts the demand curve inward to the left, and that does not affect the supply curve, will lower both the equilibrium price and the equilibrium quantity.

SUPPLY SHIFTS AND SUPPLY-DEMAND EQUILIBRIUM A story precisely analogous to that of the effects of a demand shift on equilibrium price and quantity applies to supply shifts. Figure 6 described the effects on the supply curve of beef if the number of farms increases. Figure 9(a) now adds a demand curve to the supply curves of Figure 6 so that we can see the supply-demand equilibrium. Notice that at the initial price of $7.20, the quantity supplied after the shift is 780 million pounds (point I on the supply curve S1S1), which is 30 percent more than the original quantity demanded of 600 million pounds (point E on the supply curve S0S0). We can see from the graph that the price of $7.20 is too high to be the equilibrium price; the price must fall. The new equilibrium point is J, where the price is $7.10 per pound and the quantity is 650 million pounds per year. In general: Any change that shifts the supply curve outward to the right, and does not affect the demand curve, will lower the equilibrium price and raise the equilibrium quantity.

This must always be true if the industry’s demand curve has a negative slope, because the greater quantity supplied can be sold only if the price is decreased so as to induce customers to buy more.6 The cellular phone industry is a case in point. As more providers Graphically, whenever a positively sloped curve shifts to the right, its intersection point with a negatively sloping curve must always move lower. Just try drawing it yourself.

6

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

68

Part 1

Getting Acquainted with Economics

F I GURE 9 Effects of Shifts of the Supply Curve S2 D S0

E

I

$7.20 J 7.10

S1

V Price per Pound

Price per Pound

D $7.40

S0 E

U 7.20

S2

S0

S0

S1

D

D 60 Quantity (a)

65

78

37.5

50 60 Quantity (b)

have entered the industry, the cost of cellular service has plummeted. Some cellular carriers have even given away telephones as sign-up bonuses. Figure 9(b) illustrates the opposite case: a contraction of the industry. The supply curve shifts inward to the left and equilibrium moves from point E to point V, where the price is $7.40 and quantity is 500 million pounds per year. In general: Any influence that shifts the supply curve to the left, and does not affect the demand curve, will raise the equilibrium price and reduce the equilibrium quantity.

Many outside forces can disturb equilibrium in a market by shifting the demand curve or the supply curve, either temporarily or permanently. In 1998, for example, gasoline prices dropped because a recession in Asia shifted the demand curve downward, as did a reduction in use of petroleum that resulted from a mild winter. In the summer of 1998, severely hot weather and lack of rain damaged the cotton crop in the United States, shifting the supply curve downward. Such outside influences change the equilibrium price and quantity. If you look again at Figures 8 and 9, you can see clearly that any event that causes either the demand curve or the supply curve to shift will also change the equilibrium price and quantity.

PUZZLE RESOLVED:

THOSE LEAPING OIL PRICES

The disturbing increases in the price of gasoline, and of the oil from which it is made, is attributable to large shifts in both demand and supply conditions. Americans are, for example, driving more and are buying gas-guzzling vehicles, and the resulting upward shift in the demand curve raises price. Instability in the Middle East and Russia has undermined supply, and that also raised prices. We have seen the results at the gas pumps. The following newspaper story describes a sensational sort of change in supply conditions: Aug. 10 (Bloomberg)—BP Plc and its partners in the Prudhoe Bay oil field in Alaska will spend about $170 million inspecting and repairing corroded pipelines that shut most of the production from the largest U.S. oil field. Including costs to clean up and repair a line that leaked in March, the “rough estimate” rises to about $200 million, said Kemp Copeland, field manager for BP’s Prudhoe Bay operations. The figures include the cost of replacing 16 miles of feeder pipeline in the field. The worst cost to BP will probably be the hit to its reputation, said Mark Gilman, an analyst at The Benchmark Company LLC in New York, who rates the shares “sell.” Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

69

Supply and Demand: An Initial Look

Chapter 4

“At some point this is going to prove very costly, as you’re going to be competing with folks whose reputation has not been subject to the same degree of punishment,” Gilman, who owns a “small” number of BP shares, said today in a phone interview. The Prudhoe Bay shutdown is the latest blow for Chief Executive Officer John Browne, who faces a grand jury probe for an earlier Alaska spill, charges of market manipulation in the U.S. propane industry and fines from a Texas refinery blast that killed 15 workers. BP, which gets 40 percent of its sales from the U.S., last month said it will boost spending there to improve safety and maintenance. London-based BP Plc said today it will know by the start of next week whether it can keep operating the western half of the field, which is currently producing as much as 137,000 barrels of oil a day. The entire field pumps 400,000 barrels a day, or 8 percent of U.S. output, when fully operational.

LOOKING FOR STEEL SUPPLIES BP is asking suppliers U.S. Steel Corp. and Nippon Steel Corp. for faster delivery to a total of 51,000 feet of pipe it has already ordered for the repairs, BP Alaska President Steve Marshall said in conference call on Aug. 8. The pipe is scheduled to be delivered in October the earliest. A supplier for another 30,000 feet of 24-inch pipe and 52,000 feet of 18-inch pipe is still needed, said Marshall. BP, Houston-based ConocoPhillips and Exxon Mobil Corp. of Irving, Texas, are joint owners in the Prudhoe Bay field. ConocoPhillips, the third-largest U.S. oil company, earlier today declared force majeure on oil deliveries from Prudhoe Bay. Force majeure allows companies to avoid penalties for failing to fulfill contracts because of unforeseen events. ConocoPhillips sells its Alaskan crude oil to refineries and brokers, according to spokesman Bill Tanner. SOURCE: Ian McKinnon and Sonja Franklin, “BP Says Prudhoe Bay Repair Costs May Be $200 Million,” with reporting by Jim Kennett in Houston. Editor: Jordan (rsd).

Application: Who Really Pays That Tax? Supply-and-demand analysis offers insights that may not be readily apparent. Here is an example. Suppose your state legislature raises the gasoline tax by 10 cents per gallon. Service station operators will then have to collect 10 additional FIGURE 10 cents in taxes on every gallon they pump. They will conWho Pays for a New Tax on Products?

D

Price per Gallon

sider this higher tax as an addition to their costs and will pass it on to you and other consumers by raising the price of gas by 10 cents per gallon. Right? No, wrong—or rather, partly wrong. The gas station owners would certainly like to pass on the entire tax to buyers, but the market mechanism will allow them to shift only part of it—perhaps 6 cents per gallon. They will then be stuck with the remainder— 4 cents in our example. Figure 10, which is just another supply-demand graph, shows why. The demand curve is the blue curve DD. The supply curve before the tax is the black curve S0S0. Before the new tax, the equilibrium point is E0 and the price is $2.54. We can interpret the supply curve as telling us at what price sellers are willing to provide any given quantity. For example, they are willing to supply quantity Q1 5 50 million gallons per year if the price is $2.54 per gallon.

S1 M

$2.64 E1

S0

2.60

2.54 S1

E0

D

S0 Q2

Q1

30 50 Millions of Gallons per Year

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

70

Part 1

Getting Acquainted with Economics

So what happens as a result of the new tax? Because they must now turn 10 cents per gallon over to the government, gas station owners will be willing to supply any given quantity only if they get 10 cents more per gallon than before. Therefore, to get them to supply quantity Q1 5 50 million gallons, a price of $2.54 per gallon will no longer suffice. Only a price of $2.64 per gallon will now induce them to supply 50 million gallons. Thus, at quantity Q1 5 50, the point on the supply curve will move up by 10 cents, from point E0 to point M. Because firms will insist on the same 10-cent price increase for any other quantity they supply, the entire supply curve will shift up by the 10-cent tax—from the black curve S0S0 to the new brick-colored supply curve S1S1. And, as a result, the supply-demand equilibrium point will move from E0 to E1 and the price will increase from $2.54 to $2.60. The supply curve shift may give the impression that gas station owners have succeeded in passing the entire 10-cent increase on to consumers—the distance from E0 to M—but look again. The equilibrium price has only gone up from $2.54 to $2.60. That is, the price has risen by only 6 cents, not by the full 10-cent amount of the tax. The gas station will have to absorb the remaining 4 cents of the tax. Now this really looks as though we have pulled a fast one on you—a magician’s sleight of hand. After all, the supply curve has shifted upward by the full amount of the tax, and yet the resulting price increase has covered only part of the tax rise. However, a second look reveals that, like most apparent acts of magic, this one has a simple explanation. The explanation arises from the demand side of the supply-demand mechanism. The negative slope of the demand curve means that when prices rise, at least some consumers will reduce the quantity of gasoline they demand. That will force sellers to give up part of the price increase. In other words, firms must absorb the part of the tax—4 cents—that consumers are unwilling to pay. But note that the equilibrium quantity Q1 has fallen from 50 million gallons to Q2 5 30 million gallons—so both consumers and suppliers lose out in some sense. This example is not an oddball case. Indeed, the result is almost always true. The cost of any increase in a tax on any commodity will usually be paid partly by the consumer and partly by the seller. This is so no matter whether the legislature says that it is imposing the tax on the sellers or on the buyers. Whichever way it is phrased, the economics are the same: The supply-demand mechanism ensures that the tax will be shared by both of the parties.

BATTLING THE INVISIBLE HAND: THE MARKET FIGHTS BACK

IDEAS FOR BEYOND THE FINAL EXAM

As we noted in our Ideas for Beyond the Final Exam in Chapter 1, lawmakers and rulers have often been dissatisfied with the outcomes of free markets. From Rome to Reno, and from biblical times to the space age, they have battled the invisible hand. Sometimes, rather than trying to adjust the workings of the market, governments have tried to raise or lower the prices of specific commodities by decree. In many such cases, the authorities felt that market prices were, in some sense, immorally low or immorally high. Penalties were therefore imposed on anyone offering the commodities in question at prices above or below those established by the authorities. Such legally imposed constraints on prices are called “price ceilings” and “price floors.” To see their result, we will focus on the use of price ceilings.

Restraining the Market Mechanism: Price Ceilings A price ceiling is a maximum that the price charged for a commodity cannot legally exceed.

The market has proven itself a formidable foe that strongly resists attempts to get around its decisions. In case after case where legal price ceilings are imposed, virtually the same series of consequences ensues: 1. A persistent shortage develops because quantity demanded exceeds quantity supplied. Queuing (people waiting in lines), direct rationing (with everyone getting a fixed allotment), or any of a variety of other devices, usually inefficient and unpleasant, must substitute for the distribution process provided by the price mechanism. Example: Rampant shortages in Eastern Europe and the former Soviet Union helped precipitate the revolts that ended communism.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 4

Supply and Demand: An Initial Look

71

P OLICY D E B AT E

Economic Aspects of the War on Drugs

SOURCE: © AP Images/Angela Gaul

For years now, the U.S. government has engaged in a highly publicized “war on drugs.” Billions of dollars have been spent on trying to stop illegal drugs at the country’s borders. In some sense, interdiction has succeeded: Federal agents have seized literally tons of cocaine and other drugs. Yet these efforts have made barely a dent in the flow of drugs to America’s city streets. Simple economic reasoning explains why. When drug interdiction works, it shifts the supply curve of drugs to the left, thereby driving up street prices. But that, in turn, raises the rewards for potential smugglers and attracts more criminals into the “industry,” which shifts the supply curve back to the right. The net result is that increased shipments of drugs to U.S. shores replace much of what the authorities confiscate. This is why many economists believe that any successful antidrug program must concentrate on reducing demand, which would lower the street price of drugs, not on reducing supply, which can only raise it. Some people suggest that the government should go even further and legalize many drugs. Although this idea remains a highly controversial position that few are ready to endorse, the reasoning behind it is straightforward. A stunningly high fraction of all the violent crimes committed in America—especially robberies and murders—are drug-related. One

major reason is that street prices of drugs are so high that addicts must steal to get the money, and drug traffickers are all too willing to kill to protect their highly profitable “businesses.” How would things differ if drugs were legal? Because South American farmers earn pennies for drugs that sell for hundreds of dollars on the streets of Los Angeles and New York, we may safely assume that legalized drugs would be vastly cheaper. In fact, according to one estimate, a dose of cocaine would cost less than 50 cents. That, proponents point out, would reduce drug-related crimes dramatically. When, for example, was the last time you heard of a gang killing connected with the distribution of cigarettes or alcoholic beverages? The argument against legalization of drugs is largely moral: Should the state sanction potentially lethal substances? But there is an economic aspect to this position as well: The vastly lower street prices of drugs that would surely follow legalization would increase drug use. Thus, although legalization would almost certainly reduce crime, it may also produce more addicts. The key question here is, How many more addicts? (No one has a good answer.) If you think the increase in quantity demanded would be large, you are unlikely to find legalization an attractive option.

2. An illegal, or “black” market often arises to supply the commodity. Usually some individuals are willing to take the risks involved in meeting unsatisfied demands illegally. Example: Although most states ban the practice, ticket “scalping” (the sale of tickets at higher than regular prices) occurs at most popular sporting events and rock concerts. 3. The prices charged on illegal markets are almost certainly higher than those that would prevail in free markets. After all, lawbreakers expect some compensation for the risk of being caught and punished. Example: Illegal drugs are normally quite expensive. (See the accompanying Policy Debate box “Economic Aspects of the War on Drugs.”) 4. A substantial portion of the price falls into the hands of the illicit supplier instead of going to those who produce the good or perform the service. Example: A constant complaint during the public hearings that marked the history of theaterticket price controls in New York City was that the “ice” (the illegal excess charge) fell into the hands of ticket scalpers rather than going to those who invested in, produced, or acted in the play. 5. Investment in the industry generally dries up. Because price ceilings reduce the monetary returns that investors can legally earn, less money will be invested in industries that are subject to price controls. Even fear of impending price controls can have this effect. Example: Price controls on farm products in Zambia have prompted peasant farmers and large agricultural conglomerates alike to cut back production rather than grow crops at a loss. The result has been thousands of lost jobs and widespread food shortages. Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

72

Part 1

Getting Acquainted with Economics

Case Study: Rent Controls in New York City

SOURCE: © The New Yorker Collection, 1994 Richard Cline from cartoonbank.com. All Rights Reserved.

Rent per Month

These points and others are best illustrated by considering a concrete example involving price ceilings. New York is the only major city in the United States that has continuously legislated rent controls in much of its rental housing, since World War II. Rent controls, of course, are intended to protect the consumer from high rents. But most FIGURE 11 economists believe that rent control does not help the cities or their residents and that, Supply-Demand in the long run, it leaves almost everyone worse off. Elementary supply-demand analyDiagram for Rental sis shows us why. Housing Figure 11 is a supply-demand diagram for rental units in New York. Curve DD is the demand curve and S curve SS is the supply curve. Without controls, equiD librium would be at point E, where rents average $2,000 per month and 3 million housing units are occupied. If rent controls are effective, the ceiling price Market E rent must be below the equilibrium price of $2,000. But $2,000 with a low rent ceiling, such as $1,200, the quantity of housing demanded will be 3.5 million units (point B), Rent C ceiling whereas the quantity supplied will be only 2.5 million B 1,200 units (point C). S D The diagram shows a shortage of 1 million apart0 2.5 3 3.5 ments. This theoretical concept of a “shortage” maniMillions of Dwellings fests itself in New York City as an abnormally low Rented per Month vacancy rate, that is, a low share of unoccupied apartments available for rental—typically about half the national urban average. Naturally, rent controls have spawned a lively black market in New York. The black market raises the effective price of rent-controlled apartments in many ways, including bribes, so-called key money paid to move up on a waiting list, or the requirement that prospective tenants purchase worthless furniture at inflated prices. According to Figure 11, rent controls reduce the quantity supplied from 3 million to 2.5 million apartments. How does this reduction show up in New York? First, some property owners, discouraged by the low rents, have converted apartment buildings into office space or other uses. Second, some apartments have been inadequately maintained. After all, rent controls create a shortage, which makes even dilapidated apartments easy to rent. Third, some landlords have actually abandoned their buildings rather than pay rising tax and fuel bills. These abandoned buildings rapidly become eyesores and eventually pose threats to public health and safety. An important implication of these last observations is that rent controls—and price controls more generally—harm consumers in ways that offset part or all of the benefits to those who are fortunate enough to find and acquire at lower prices the product that the reduced prices has made scarce. Tenants must undergo long waits and undertake time-consuming searches to find an apartment. The apartment they obtain is likely to be poorly maintained or even decrepit, and normal landlord services are apt to disappear. Thus, even for the lucky beneficiaries, rent control is always far less of a bargain than the reduced monthly payments make them appear to be. The same problems generally apply with other forms of price control as well. With all of these problems, why does rent control persist in New York City? And why do other cities sometimes move in the same direction? Part of the explanation is that most people simply do not understand the problems that rent controls create. Another part is “If you leave me, you know, you’ll never see that landlords are unpopular politically. But a third, and very this kind of rent again.”

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 4

73

Supply and Demand: An Initial Look

important, part of the explanation is that not everyone is hurt by rent controls—and those who benefit from controls fight hard to preserve them. In New York, for example, many tenants pay rents that are only a fraction of what their apartments would fetch on the open market. They are, naturally enough, quite happy with this situation. This last point illustrates another very general phenomenon: Virtually every price ceiling or floor creates a class of people that benefits from the regulations. These people use their political influence to protect their gains by preserving the status quo, which is one reason why it is so difficult to eliminate price ceilings or floors.

Restraining the Market Mechanism: Price Floors Interferences with the market mechanism are not always designed to keep prices low. Agricultural price supports and minimum wage laws are two notable examples in which the law keeps prices above free-market levels. Such price floors are typically accompanied by a standard series of symptoms: 1. A surplus develops as sellers cannot find enough buyers. Example: Surpluses of various agricultural products have been a persistent—and costly—problem for the U.S. government. The problem is even worse in the European Union (EU), where the common agricultural policy holds prices even higher. One source estimates that this policy accounts for half of all EU spending.7 2. Where goods, rather than services, are involved, the surplus creates a problem of disposal. Something must be done about the excess of quantity supplied over quantity demanded. Example: The U.S. government has often been forced to purchase, store, and then dispose of large amounts of surplus agricultural commodities. 3. To get around the regulations, sellers may offer discounts in disguised—and often unwanted—forms. Example: Back when airline fares were regulated by the government, airlines offered more and better food and more stylishly uniformed flight attendants instead of lowering fares. Today, the food is worse, but tickets cost much less. 4. Regulations that keep prices artificially high encourage overinvestment in the industry. Even inefficient businesses whose high operating costs would doom them in an unrestricted market can survive beneath the shelter of a generous price floor. Example: This is why the airline and trucking industries both went through painful “shakeouts” of the weaker companies in the 1980s, after they were deregulated and allowed to charge market-determined prices.

A price floor is a legal minimum below which the price charged for a commodity is not permitted to fall.

Once again, a specific example is useful for understanding how price floors work.

Case Study: Farm Price Supports and the Case of Sugar Prices America’s extensive program of farm price supports began in 1933 as a “temporary method of dealing with an emergency”—in the years of the Great Depression, farmers were going broke in droves. These price supports are still with us today, even though farmers account for less than 2 percent of the U.S. workforce.8 One of the consequences of these price supports has been the creation of unsellable surpluses—more output of crops such as grains than consumers were willing to buy at the inflated prices yielded by the supports. Warehouses were filled to overflowing. New storage facilities had to be built, and the government was forced to set up programs in

The Economist, February 20, 1999. Under major legislation passed in 1996, many agricultural price supports were supposed to be phased out over a seven-year period. In reality, many support programs, especially that for sugar, have changed little. 7 8

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Part 1

Getting Acquainted with Economics

which grain from the unmanageable surpluses was shipped to poor foreign countries to combat malnutrition and starvation in those nations. Realistically, if price supports are to be effective in keeping prices above the equilibrium level, then someone must be prepared to purchase the surpluses that invariably result. Otherwise, those surpluses will somehow find their way into the market and drive down prices, undermining the price support program. In the United States (and elsewhere), the buyer of the surpluses has usually turned out to be the government, which makes its purchases at the expense of taxpayers who are forced to pay twice—once through taxes to finance the government purchases and a second time in the form of higher prices for the farm products bought by the American public. One of the more controversial farm price supports involves the U.S. sugar industry. Sugar producers receive low-interest loans from the federal government and a guarantee that the price of sugar will not fall below a certain level. In a market economy such as that found in the United States, Congress cannot simply set prices by decree; rather, it must take some action to enforce the price floor. In the case of sugar, that “something” is limiting both domestic production and foreign imports, thereby shifting the supply curve inward to the left. Figure 12 shows the mechanics involved in this price floor. Government policies shift the supply curve inward from S0S0 to S1S1 and drive the U.S. price up from 25¢ to 50¢ per pound. The more the supply curve shifts inward, the higher the price. FIGURE 12 S1

Supporting the Price of Sugar

D

S0

50¢ Price

74

25¢

S1 D

S0 Quantity

The sugar industry obviously benefits from the price-control program, but consumers pay for it in the form of higher prices for sugar and sugar-filled products such as soft drinks, candy bars, and cookies. Although estimates vary, the federal sugar price support program appears to cost consumers approximately $1.5 billion per year. If all of this sounds a bit abstract to you, take a look at the ingredients in a U.S.-made soft drink. Instead of sugar, you will likely find “high-fructose corn syrup” listed as a sweetener. Foreign producers generally use sugar, but sugar is simply too expensive to be used for this purpose in the United States.

A Can of Worms Our two case studies—rent controls and sugar price supports—illustrate some of the major side effects of price floors and ceilings but barely hint at others. Difficulties arise that

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 4

Supply and Demand: An Initial Look

we have not even mentioned, for the market mechanism is a tough bird that imposes suitable retribution on those who seek to evade it by government decree. Here is a partial list of other problems that may arise when prices are controlled.

Favoritism and Corruption When price ceilings or floors create shortages or surpluses, someone must decide who gets to buy or sell the limited quantity that is available. This decision-making process can lead to discrimination along racial or religious lines, political favoritism, or corruption in government. For example, many prices were held at artificially low levels in the former Soviet Union, making queuing for certain goods quite common. Even so, Communist Party officials and other favored groups were somehow able to purchase the scarce commodities that others could not get. Unenforceability Attempts to limit prices are almost certain to fail in industries with numerous suppliers, simply because the regulating agency must monitor the behavior of so many sellers. People will usually find ways to evade or violate the law, and something like the free-market price will generally reappear. However, there is an important difference: Because the evasion process, whatever its form, will have some operating costs, those costs must be borne by someone. Normally, that someone is the consumer, who must pay higher prices to the suppliers for taking the risk of breaking the law. Auxiliary Restrictions Fears that a system of price controls will break down invariably lead to regulations designed to shore up the shaky edifice. Consumers may be told when and from whom they are permitted to buy. The powers of the police and the courts may be used to prevent the entry of new suppliers. Occasionally, an intricate system of market subdivision is imposed, giving each class of firms a protected sphere in which others are not permitted to operate. For example, in New York City, there are laws banning conversion of rent-controlled apartments to condominiums.

Limitation of Volume of Transactions To the extent that controls succeed in affecting prices, they can be expected to reduce the volume of transactions. Curiously, this is true regardless of whether the regulated price is above or below the free-market equilibrium price. If it is set above the equilibrium price, the quantity demanded will be below the equilibrium quantity. On the other hand, if the imposed price is set below the freemarket level, the quantity supplied will be reduced. Because sales volume cannot exceed either the quantity supplied or the quantity demanded, a reduction in the volume of transactions is the result.9 Misallocation of Resources Departures from free-market prices are likely to result in misuse of the economy’s resources because the connection between production costs and prices is broken. For example, Russian farmers used to feed their farm animals bread instead of unprocessed grains because price ceilings kept the price of bread ludicrously low. In addition, just as more complex locks lead to more sophisticated burglary tools, more complex regulations lead to the use of yet more resources for their avoidance. Economists put it this way: Free markets are capable of dealing efficiently with the three basic coordination tasks outlined in Chapter 3: deciding what to produce, how to produce it, and to whom the goods should be distributed. Price controls throw a monkey wrench into the market mechanism. Although the market is surely not flawless, and government interferences often have praiseworthy goals, good intentions are not enough. Any government that sets out to repair what it sees as a defect in the market mechanism runs the risk of causing even more serious damage elsewhere. As a prominent economist 9

See Discussion Question 4 at the end of this chapter.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

75

76

Part 1

Getting Acquainted with Economics

once quipped, societies that are too willing to interfere with the operation of free markets soon find that the invisible hand is nowhere to be seen.

A SIMPLE BUT POWERFUL LESSON Astonishing as it may seem, many people in authority do not understand the law of supply and demand, or they act as if it does not exist. For example, a few years ago The New York Times carried a dramatic front-page picture of the president of Kenya setting fire to a large pile of elephant tusks that had been confiscated from poachers. The accompanying story explained that the burning was intended as a symbolic act to persuade the world to halt the ivory trade.10 One may certainly doubt whether the burning really touched the hearts of criminal poachers, but one economic effect was clear: By reducing the supply of ivory on the world market, the burning of tusks forced up the price of ivory, which raised the illicit rewards reaped by those who slaughter elephants. That could only encourage more poaching—precisely the opposite of what the Kenyan government sought to accomplish.

| SUMMARY | 1. An attempt to use government regulations to force prices above or below their equilibrium levels is likely to lead to shortages or surpluses, to black markets in which goods are sold at illegal prices, and to a variety of other problems. The market always strikes back at attempts to repeal the law of supply and demand. 2. The quantity of a product that is demanded is not a fixed number. Rather, quantity demanded depends on such influences as the price of the product, consumer incomes, and the prices of other products. 3. The relationship between quantity demanded and price, holding all other things constant, can be displayed graphically on a demand curve. 4. For most products, the higher the price, the lower the quantity demanded. As a result, the demand curve usually has a negative slope. 5. The quantity of a product that is supplied depends on its price and many other influences. A supply curve is a graphical representation of the relationship between quantity supplied and price, holding all other influences constant. 6. For most products, supply curves have positive slopes, meaning that higher prices lead to supply of greater quantities. 7. A change in quantity demanded that is caused by a change in the price of the good is represented by a movement along a fixed demand curve. A change in

10

quantity demanded that is caused by a change in any other determinant of quantity demanded is represented by a shift of the demand curve. 8. This same distinction applies to the supply curve: Changes in price lead to movements along a fixed supply curve; changes in other determinants of quantity supplied lead to shifts of the entire supply curve. 9. A market is said to be in equilibrium when quantity supplied is equal to quantity demanded. The equilibrium price and quantity are shown by the point on the supply-demand graph where the supply and demand curves intersect. The law of supply and demand states that price and quantity tend to gravitate to this point in a free market. 10. Changes in consumer incomes, tastes, technology, prices of competing products, and many other influences lead to shifts in either the demand curve or the supply curve and produce changes in price and quantity that can be determined from supply-demand diagrams. 11. A tax on a good generally leads to a rise in the price at which the taxed product is sold. The rise in price is generally less than the tax, so consumers usually pay less than the entire tax. 12. Consumers generally pay only part of a tax because the resulting rise in price leads them to buy less and the cut in the quantity they demand helps to force price down.

The New York Times, July 19, 1989.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

77

Supply and Demand: An Initial Look

Chapter 4

| KEY TERMS | demand curve

58

demand schedule equilibrium

price ceiling 58

price floor

65

invisible hand

70

shortage

73

supply curve

quantity demanded

56

quantity supplied

law of supply and demand

66

65

57

61

shift in a demand curve

62

supply schedule 61 supply-demand diagram 59

surplus

64

65

| TEST YOURSELF | 1. What shapes would you expect for demand curves for the following: a. A medicine that means life or death for a patient b. French fries in a food court with kiosks offering many types of food 2. The following are the assumed supply and demand schedules for hamburgers in Collegetown:

Demand Schedule

Price $2.75 2.50 2.25 2.00 1.75 1.50

Quantity Demanded per Year (thousands) 14 18 22 26 30 34

Price $170 210 250 300 330 370

Quantity Demanded per Year (millions)

Quantity Supplied per Year (millions)

43 39 35 31 27 23

27 31 35 39 43 47

Supply Schedule

Price $2.75 2.50 2.25 2.00 1.75 1.50

Quantity Supplied per Year (thousands) 32 30 28 26 24 22

a. Plot the supply and demand curves and indicate the equilibrium price and quantity. b. What effect would a decrease in the price of beef (a hamburger input) have on the equilibrium price and quantity of hamburgers, assuming all other things remained constant? Explain your answer with the help of a diagram. c. What effect would an increase in the price of pizza (a substitute commodity) have on the equilibrium price and quantity of hamburgers, assuming again that all other things remain constant? Use a diagram in your answer.

b. Now suppose that it becomes unfashionable to ride a bicycle, so that the quantity demanded at each price falls by 9 million bikes per year. What is the new equilibrium price and quantity? Show this solution graphically. Explain why the quantity falls by less than 9 million bikes per year. c. Suppose instead that several major bicycle producers go out of business, thereby reducing the quantity supplied by 9 million bikes at every price. Find the new equilibrium price and quantity, and show it graphically. Explain again why quantity falls by less than 9 million. d. What are the equilibrium price and quantity if the shifts described in Test Yourself Questions 3(b) and 3(c) happen at the same time? 4. The following table summarizes information about the market for principles of economics textbooks:

Price

Quantity Demanded per Year

Quantity Supplied per Year

$45 55 65 75 85

4,300 2,300 1,300 800 650

300 700 1,300 2,100 3,100

3. Suppose the supply and demand schedules for bicycles are as they appear in the following table. a. Graph these curves and show the equilibrium price and quantity.

a. What is the market equilibrium price and quantity of textbooks?

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

78

Part 1

Getting Acquainted with Economics

b. To quell outrage over tuition increases, the college places a $55 limit on the price of textbooks. How many textbooks will be sold now?

the government decides to fight cholesterol by levying a tax of 50 cents per pound on sales of beef. Follow these steps to analyze the effects of the tax:

c. While the price limit is still in effect, automated publishing increases the efficiency of textbook production. Show graphically the likely effect of this innovation on the market price and quantity.

a. Construct the new supply schedule (to replace Table 2) that relates quantity supplied to the price that consumers pay.

5. How are the following demand curves likely to shift in response to the indicated changes?

b. Graph the new supply curve constructed in Test Yourself Question 7(a) on the supply-demand diagram depicted in Figure 7.

a. The effect of a drought on the demand curve for umbrellas

c. Does the tax succeed in its goal of reducing the consumption of beef?

b. The effect of higher popcorn prices on the demand curve for movie tickets

d. Is the price rise greater than, equal to, or less than the 50 cent tax?

c. The effect on the demand curve for coffee of a decline in the price of Coca-Cola

e. Who actually pays the tax, consumers or producers? (This may be a good question to discuss in class.)

6. The two accompanying diagrams show supply and demand curves for two substitute commodities: tapes and compact discs (CDs).

8. (More difficult) The demand and supply curves for T-shirts in Touristtown, U.S.A., are given by the following equations: Q 5 24,000 2 500P

D0

S0

S0

D0 Quantity Compact Discs (a)

where P is measured in dollars and Q is the number of T-shirts sold per year. a. Find the equilibrium price and quantity algebraically.

Price

S0

Price

D0

Q 5 6,000 1 1,000P

S0

D0 Quantity Tapes (b)

b. If tourists decide they do not really like T-shirts that much, which of the following might be the new demand curve? Q 5 21,000 2 500P

Q 5 27,000 2 500P

Find the equilibrium price and quantity after the shift of the demand curve. a. On the right-hand diagram, show what happens when rising raw material prices make it costlier to produce tapes. b. On the left-hand diagram, show what happens to the market for CDs. 7. Consider the market for beef discussed in this chapter (Tables 1 through 4 and Figures 1 and 8). Suppose that

c. If, instead, two new stores that sell T-shirts open up in town, which of the following might be the new supply curve? Q 5 4,000 1 1,000P

Q 5 9,000 1 1,000P

Find the equilibrium price and quantity after the shift of the supply curve.

| DISCUSSION QUESTIONS | 1. How often do you rent videos? Would you do so more often if a rental cost half as much? Distinguish between your demand curve for home videos and your “quantity demanded” at the current price. 2. Discuss the likely effects of the following: a. Rent ceilings on the market for apartments b. Floors under wheat prices on the market for wheat Use supply-demand diagrams to show what may happen in each case. 3. U.S. government price supports for milk led to an unceasing surplus of milk. In an effort to reduce the surplus about a decade ago, Congress offered to pay dairy

farmers to slaughter cows. Use two diagrams, one for the milk market and one for the meat market, to illustrate how this policy should have affected the price of meat. (Assume that meat is sold in an unregulated market.) 4. It is claimed in this chapter that either price floors or price ceilings reduce the actual quantity exchanged in a market. Use a diagram or diagrams to test this conclusion, and explain the common sense behind it. 5. The same rightward shift of the demand curve may produce a very small or a very large increase in quantity, depending on the slope of the supply curve. Explain this conclusion with diagrams.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 4

11

Supply and Demand: An Initial Look

79

6. In 1981, when regulations were holding the price of natural gas below its free-market level, then-Congressman Jack Kemp of New York said the following in an interview with The New York Times: “We need to decontrol natural gas, and get production of natural gas up to a higher level so we can bring down the price.”11 Evaluate the congressman’s statement.

working women grew by 11 percent. During this time, average wages for men grew by 20 percent, whereas average wages for women grew by 25 percent. Which of the following two explanations seems more consistent with the data?

7. From 1990 to 1997 in the United States, the number of working men grew by 6.7 percent; the number of

b. Discrimination against women declined, raising the relative (to men) demand for female workers.

a. Women decided to work more, raising their relative supply (relative to men).

The New York Times, December 24, 1981.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Part

THE Building Blocks of Demand and Supply

T

he next four chapters describe and analyze the basic building blocks with which economists analyze markets and their two essential elements: buyers (consumers) and sellers (producers). As in a piece of machinery, all the parts of a market operate simultaneously together, so there is no logical place to begin the story. Furthermore, the heart of the story is not found in the individual components, but in the way they fit together. The four central microeconomics chapters start off with the separate components but then assemble them into a working model of how firms determine price and output simultaneously. Then Chapter 9 deals with stocks and bonds as tools that help business firms obtain the finances they need to operate and as earnings opportunities for potential investors in firms.

C H A P T E R S 5 | Consumer Choice:

8 | Output, Price, and Profit:

6 | Demand and Elasticity

9 | Investing in Business:

Individual and Market Demand

7 | Production, Inputs, and

The Importance of Marginal Analysis Stocks and Bonds

Cost: Building Blocks for Supply Analysis

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Consumer Choice: Individual and Market Demand Everything is worth what its purchaser will pay for it. P U BL I L I U S SY RU S ( 1ST CENTURY

B . C .)

Y

ou are about to start a new year in college, and your favorite clothing store is having a sale. So you decide to stock up on jeans. How do you decide how many pairs to buy? How is your decision affected by the price of the jeans and the amount of money you earned in your summer job? How can you get the most for your money? Economic analysis provides some rational ways to make these decisions. Do you think about your decision as an economist would, either consciously or unconsciously? Should you? By the end of the chapter, you will be able to analyze such purchase decisions using concepts called utility and marginal analysis. Chapter 4 introduced you to the idea of supply and demand and the use of supply and demand curves to analyze how markets determine prices and quantities of products sold. This chapter will investigate the underpinnings of the demand curve, which, as we have already seen, shows us half of the market picture.

C O N T E N T S PUZZLE: WHY SHOULDN’T WATER BE WORTH MORE THAN DIAMONDS?

CONSUMER CHOICE AS A TRADE-OFF: OPPORTUNITY COST

SCARCITY AND DEMAND

Consumer’s Surplus: The Net Gain from a Purchase

UTILITY: A TOOL TO ANALYZE PURCHASE DECISIONS

PUZZLE: RESOLVING THE DIAMOND–WATER PUZZLE

The Purpose of Utility Analysis: Analyzing How People Behave, Not What They Think Total versus Marginal Utility The “Law” of Diminishing Marginal Utility Using Marginal Utility: The Optimal Purchase Rule From Diminishing Marginal Utility to DownwardSloping Demand Curves

Income and Quantity Demanded

BEHAVIORAL ECONOMICS: ARE ECONOMIC DECISIONS REALLY MADE “RATIONALLY”?

| APPENDIX | Analyzing Consumer Choice Graphically: Indifference Curve Analysis

FROM INDIVIDUAL DEMAND CURVES TO MARKET DEMAND CURVES

Properties of the Budget Line Changes in the Budget Line What the Consumer Prefers: Properties of the Indifference Curve The Slopes of Indifference Curves and Budget Lines Tangency Conditions Consequences of Income Changes: Inferior Goods Consequences of Price Changes: Deriving the Demand Curve

Market Demand Curves as a Horizontal Sum of the Demand Curves of Individual Buyers The “Law” of Demand Exceptions to the “Law” of Demand

Geometry of Available Choices: The Budget Line

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

The Building Blocks of Demand and Supply

PUZZLE:

WHY SHOULDN’T WATER BE WORTH MORE THAN DIAMONDS?

When Adam Smith lectured at the University of Glasgow in the 1760s, he introduced the study of demand by posing a puzzle. Common sense, he said, suggests that the price of a commodity must somehow depend on what that good is worth to consumers—on the amount of utility that the commodity offers. Yet, Smith pointed out, some cases suggest that a good’s utility may have little influence on its price. Smith cited diamonds and water as examples. He noted that water has enormous value to most consumers; indeed, its availability can be a matter of life and death. Yet water often sells at a very low price or is even free of charge, whereas diamonds sell for very high prices even though few people would consider them necessities. We will soon be in a position to see how marginal analysis, the powerful method of analysis introduced in this chapter, helps to resolve this paradox.

SCARCITY AND DEMAND When economists use the term demand, they do not mean mere wishes, needs, requirements, or preferences. Rather, demand refers to actions of consumers who, so to speak, put their money where their mouths are. Demand assumes that consumers can pay for the goods in question and that they are also willing to pay out the necessary money. Some of us may, for example, dream of owning a racehorse or a Lear jet, but only a few wealthy individuals can turn such fantasies into effective demands. Any individual consumer’s choices are subject to one overriding constraint that is at least partly beyond that consumer’s control: The individual has only a limited income available to spend. This scarcity of income is the obvious reason why less affluent consumers demand fewer computers, trips to foreign countries, and expensive restaurant meals than wealthy consumers do. The scarcity of income affects even the richest of all spenders—the government. The U.S. government spends billions of dollars on the armed services, education, and a variety of other services, but governments rarely, if ever, have the funds to buy everything they want. Because income is limited (and thus is a scarce resource), any consumer’s purchase decisions for different commodities must be interdependent. The number of movies that Jane can afford to see depends on the amount she spends on new clothing. If John’s parents have just sunk a lot of money into an expensive addition to their home, they may have to give up a vacation trip. Thus, no one can truly understand the demand curves for movies and clothing, or for homes and vacation trips, without considering demand curves for alternative goods. The quantity of movies demanded, for example, probably depends not only on ticket prices but also on the prices of clothing. Thus, a big sale on shirts might induce Jane to splurge on several, leaving her with little or no cash to spend on movies. So, an analysis of consumer demand that focuses on only one commodity at a time leaves out an essential part of the story. Nevertheless, to make the analysis easier to follow, we begin by considering products in isolation. That is, we employ what is called “partial analysis,” using a Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

SOURCE: © Comstock Images/Jupiterimages

Part 2

SOURCE: Larry Larminer/Brand X Pictures/Jupiterimages

84

Chapter 5

Consumer Choice: Individual and Market Demand

standard simplifying assumption. This assumption requires that all other variables remain unchanged. Later in the chapter and in the appendix, we will tell a fuller story.

SOURCE: © The New Yorker Collection, 1992 Mick Stevens from cartoonbank.com. All Rights Reserved.

UTILITY: A TOOL TO ANALYZE PURCHASE DECISIONS In the American economy, millions of consumers make millions of decisions every day. You decide to buy a movie ticket instead of a paperback novel. Your roommate decides to buy two tubes of toothpaste rather than one tube or three tubes. How do people make these decisions? Economists have constructed a simple theory of consumer choice based on the hypothesis that each consumer spends income in the way that yields the greatest amount of satisfaction, or utility. This seems to be a reasonable starting point, because it says only that people do what they prefer. To make the theory operational, we need a way to measure utility. A century ago, economists envisioned utility as an indicator of the pleasure a person derives from consuming some set of goods, and they thought that utility could be measured directly in some kind of psychological units (sometimes called utils) after somehow reading the consumer’s mind. Gradually, they came to realize that this was an unnecessary and, perhaps, impossible task. How many utils did you get from the last movie you saw? You probably cannot answer that question because you have no idea what a util is. Neither does anyone else. But you may be able to answer a different question like, “How many hamburgers would you give up to get that movie ticket?” If you answer “three,” no one can say how many utils you get from seeing a film, but they can say that you get more from the movie than from a single hamburger. When economists approach the issue in this manner, hamburgers, rather than the more vague “utility,” become the unit of measurement. They can say that the utility of a movie (to you) is three hamburgers. Early in the twentieth century, economists concluded that this indirect way of measuring consumer benefit gave them all they needed to build a theory of consumer choice. One can measure the benefit of a movie ticket by asking how much of some other commodity (like hamburgers) you are willing to give up for it. Any commodity will do for this purpose, but the simplest, most commonly used choice, and the one that we will use in this book, is money.1 So we will use phrases like “the money utility of a pair of shoes” to mean how large an amount of money the individual in question is willing to give up for those shoes.

The Purpose of Utility Analysis: Analyzing How People Behave, Not What They Think Here, a very important warning is required: Money (or hamburgers, for that matter) is an imperfect measure of utility. The reason is that measuring utility by means of money is like measuring the length of a table with a rubber yardstick. The value of a dollar changes— sometimes a great deal—depending on circumstances. For example, if you win $10 million in the lottery, an additional dollar can confidently be expected to add much less to your wellbeing than it would have one week earlier. After you hit the jackpot, you may not hesitate to spend $9 on a hamburger, whereas before you would not have spent more than $3. This difference does not mean that you now love hamburgers three times as much as before. Consequently, although we use money as an indicator of utility in this book, it should not be taken as an accurate indicator of consumers’ psychological attitude toward the goods they buy. So why do we use the concept of money utility? There are two good reasons. First, we do know how to approach measuring it (see next section), although we do not know how to measure what is going on inside the consumer’s mind. Second, and much more important, it Note to Instructors: You will recognize that, although not using the terms, we are distinguishing here between neoclassical cardinal utility and ordinal utility. Moreover, throughout the book, marginal utility in money terms (or money marginal utility) is used as a synonym for the marginal rate of substitution between money and the commodity.

1

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

85

86

Part 2

The Building Blocks of Demand and Supply

is extremely useful for analyzing demand behavior—what consumers will spend to buy some good, even though it is not a good indicator of what is going on deep inside their brains.

Total versus Marginal Utility Thus, we define the total monetary utility of a particular bundle of goods to a particular consumer as the largest sum of money that person will voluntarily give up in exchange for those goods. For example, imagine that you love pizza and are planning to buy four pizzas for a party you are hosting. You are, as usual, a bit low on cash. Taking this into account, you decide that you are willing to buy the four pies if they cost up to $52 in total, but you’re not willing to pay more than $52. As economists, we then say that the total utility of four pizzas to you is $52, the maximum amount you are willing to spend to have them. Total monetary utility (from which we will drop the word monetary from here on) measures your dollar evaluation of the benefit that you derive from your total purchases of some commodity during some selected period of time. Total utility is what really matters to you. But to understand which decisions most effectively promote total utility, we must The marginal utility of a make use of a related concept, marginal (monetary) utility. This concept is not a measure commodity to a consumer of the amount of benefit you get from your purchase decision but, rather, provides a tool (measured in money terms) with which you can analyze how much of a commodity that you must buy to make your is the maximum amount of total utility as large as possible. Your marginal utility of some good, X, is defined as the admoney that she or he is dition to total utility that you derive by consuming one more unit of X .2 If you consumed two willing to pay for one more pizzas last month, marginal utility indicates how much additional pleasure you would unit of that commodity. have received by increasing your consumption to three pizzas. Before showing how marginal utility helps to find what quantity of purchases makes total utility as large as possible, we must first discuss how these two figures are calculated TAB LE 1 and just what they mean. Your Total and Marginal Utility for Pizza This Month Table 1 helps to clarify the distinction between marginal and (1) (2) (3) (4) total utility and shows how the two are related. The first two Quantity Total Point in columns show how much total utility (measured in money terms) (Q) Pizzas Utility Marginal Utility Figure you derive from various quantities of pizza, ranging from zero to per Month (TU) (MU) 5 (DTU/D Q) 1 eight per month. For example, a single pizza pie is worth (no 0 $0.00 more than) $15 to you, two are worth $28 in total, and so on. The A $15.00 1 15.00 marginal utility is the difference between any two successive total B 13.00 2 28.00 utility figures. For example, assuming you have consumed three C 12.50 3 40.50 pizzas (worth $40.50 to you), suppose an additional pie brings D 11.50 4 52.00 your total utility to $52. Your marginal utility is thus the differE 8.00 5 60.00 ence between the two, or $11.50. F 5.00 6 65.00 Remember: Whenever we use the terms total utility and marginal G 3.00 7 68.00 utility, we define them in terms of the consumer’s willingness to H 0.00 8 68.00 part with money for the commodity, not in some unobservable (and imaginary) psychological units. NOTE: Each entry in Column (3) is the difference between successive entries in The total monetary utility of a quantity of a good to a consumer (measured in money terms) is the maximum amount of money that he or she is willing to give up in exchange for it.

Column (2). This is what is indicated by the zigzag lines.

The “Law” of Diminishing Marginal Utility With these definitions, we can now propose a simple hypothesis about consumer tastes: The more of a good a consumer has, the less marginal utility an additional unit contributes to overall satisfaction, if all other things remain unchanged.

Economists use this plausible proposition widely. The idea is based on the assumption that every person has a hierarchy of uses for a particular commodity. All of these uses are valuable, but some are more valuable than others. Take pizza, for example. Perhaps you consider your own appetite for pizza first—you buy enough pizza to satiate your own personal taste for it. But pizza may also provide you with an opportunity to satisfy your

For those of you who have taken a course in differential calculus it may help to recognize that “marginal utility” is just another name for the first derivative of total utility with respect to (an increase in) the quantity of the commodity consumed.

2

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 5

87

Consumer Choice: Individual and Market Demand

As a rule, as a person acquires more of a commodity, total utility increases and marginal utility from that good decreases, all other things being equal. In particular, when a commodity is very scarce, economists expect it to have a high marginal utility, even though it may provide little total utility because people have so little of the item.

Using Marginal Utility: The Optimal Purchase Rule Now let us use the concept of marginal utility to analyze consumer choices. Consumers must always choose among the many commodities that

The “law” of diminishing marginal utility asserts that additional units of a commodity are worth less and less to a consumer in money terms. As the individual’s consumption increases, the marginal utility of each additional unit declines.

FI GURE 1 A Marginal Utility (or Demand) Curve: Your Demand for Pizza This Month

SOURCE: © The New Yorker Collection, 2001 Robert Mankoff from cartoonbank.com. All rights reserved.

Marginal Utility (Price) per Pizza

social needs. So instead of eating all the pizza you buy, you decide to have a pizza party. First on your guest list may be your boyfriend or girlfriend. Next priority is your roommate, and, if you feel really flush, you may even invite your economics instructor! So, if you buy only one pizza, you eat it yourself. If you buy a second pizza, you share it with your friend. A third is shared with your roommate, and so on. The point is: Each pizza contributes something to your satisfaction, but each additional pizza contributes less (measured in terms of money) than its predecessor because it satisfies a lower-priority use. This idea, in essence, is the logic behind the “law” of diminishing marginal utility, which asserts that the more of a commodity you already possess, the smaller the amount of (marginal) utility you derive from acquisition of yet another unit of the commodity. The third column of Table 1 illustrates this concept. The marginal utility (abbreviated MU) of the first pizza is $15; that is, you are willing to pay up to $15 for the first pie. The second is worth no more than $13 to you, the third pizza only $12.50, and so on, until you are willing to pay only $5 for the sixth pizza (the MU of that pizza is $5). Figure 1, a marginal utility curve, shows a graph of the numbers in the first and third columns of Table 1. For example, point D indicates that the MU $16 A 15 of a fourth pizza is $11.50. So, at any higher price, 14 B you will not buy a fourth pizza. C 13 Note that the curve for marginal utility has a nega12 D P 11 tive slope; this is yet another way of representing the P 10 assertion that marginal utility diminishes as the pos9 E sessed quantity of the good rises. Like most laws, 8 7 however, the “law” of diminishing marginal utility 6 has exceptions. Some people feel that the value to F 5 them of getting one more unit of some good rises 4 G 3 rather than falls as they acquire more of that item. This 2 can be so when the person is consumed by or ad1 H dicted to that product. Stamp collectors and alco0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 holics provide good examples. The stamp collector who has a few stamps may consider the acquisition Number of Pizzas per Month of one more to be mildly amusing. The person who has a large and valuable collection may be prepared to go to the ends of the earth for another stamp. Similarly, an alcoholic who finds the first beer quite pleasant may find the fourth or fifth to be absolutely irresistible. Economists generally treat such cases of increasing marginal utility as anomalies. For most goods and most people, marginal utility declines as consumption increases. Table 1 illustrates another noteworthy relationship. Observe that as someone buys more and more units of the commodity—that is, as that person moves further down the table—the total utility numbers get larger and larger, whereas the marginal utility numbers get smaller and smaller. The reasons should now be fairly clear. The marginal utility numbers keep declining, as the “law” of diminishing marginal utility tells us they will, but total utility keeps rising so long as marginal utility remains positive. A person who owns ten compact disks, other things being equal, is better off (has higher total utility) than a person who possesses only nine, as long as the MU of the tenth CD is positive. In summary:

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

88

Part 2

The Building Blocks of Demand and Supply

Total Net Utility

compete for their limited supply of dollars. How can you use the idea of utility to help you understand the purchase choices permitted by those dollars that best serve your preferences? You can obviously choose among many different quantities of pizza, any of which will add to your total utility. But which of these quantities will yield the greatest net benefits? If pizza were all that you were considering buying, in theory the choice would involve a simple calculation. We would need a statistical table that listed all of the alternative numbers of pizzas that you may conceivably buy. The table should indicate the net utility that each possible choice yields. That is, it should include the total utility that you would get from a particular number of pizzas, minus the utility of the other purchases you would forgo by having to pay for them—their opportunity cost. We could then simply read your optimal choice from this imaginary table—the number of pizzas that would give you the highest net utility number. Even in theory, calculating optimal decisions is, unfortunately, more difficult than that. No real table of net utilities exists; an increase in expenditure on pizzas would mean less money available for clothing or movies, and you must balance the benefits of spending on each of these items against spending on the others. All of this means that we must find a more effective technique to determine optimal pizza purchases (as well as purchases of Marginal analysis is a clothing, entertainment, and other things). That technique is marginal analysis. method for calculating To see how marginal analysis helps to explain how consumers determine their optimal optimal choices—the purchase decisions, first recall our assumption that you are trying to maximize the total choices that best promote net utility you obtain from your pizza purchases. That is, you are trying to select the numthe decision maker’s ber of pies that maximizes the total utility the pizzas provide you minus the total utility you objective. It works by give up with the money you must pay for them. testing whether, and by We can compare the analysis of the optimal decision-making process to the process of how much, a small change in a decision will move climbing a hill. First, imagine that you consider the possibility of buying only one pizza. things toward or away from Then suppose you consider buying two pizzas, and so on. If two pizzas give you a higher the goal. total net utility than one pizza, you may think of yourself as moving higher up the total net utility hill. Buying more pizzas enables you to ascend that hill higher and higher, until at some quantity you reach the top—the optimal purchase quantity. Then, if you buy any more, you will have overshot the peak and begun to descend the hill. F I GURE 2 Figure 2 shows such a hill and describes how your total net utility changes when you Finding Your Optimal change the number of pizzas you buy. It shows the upward-sloping part of the hill, where Pizza Purchase the number of purchases has not yet brought you to the top. Then it shows the point (M) Quantity: Maximizing at which you have bought enough pizzas to make your net utility as large as possible (the Total Net Utility peak occurs at four pizzas). At any point to the right of M, you have overshot the optimal purchase. You are on the downward side of the hill because you have $9 bought more than enough pizzas to best serve your interests; you have bought too M Total net 8 many to maximize your net utility. utility hill 7 How does marginal analysis help you to find that optimal purchase quantity, 6 and how does it warn you if you are planning to purchase too little (so that you are 5 4 still on the ascending portion of the hill) or too much (so that you are descending)? 3 The numerical example in Table 1 will help reveal the answers. The marginal utility 2 of, for example, a third pizza is $12.50. This means that the total utility you obtain 1 0 from three pizzas ($40.50) is exactly $12.50 higher than the total utility you get from 21 two pizzas ($28). As long as marginal utility is a positive number, the more you pur22 1 2 3 4 5 6 chase, the more total utility you will get. That shows the benefit side of the purchase, but such a transaction also has a Number of Pizzas debit side—the amount you must pay for the purchase. Suppose that the price is $11 per pizza. Then the marginal net utility of the third pizza is marginal utility miTotal Net Utility equals Total Utility minus Total Expenditure (Price 3 Quantity) nus price, $12.50 minus $11, or $1.50. This is the amount that the third pizza adds to your total net utility. (See the third and fourth lines of Table 1.) So you really are better off with three pizzas than with two. We can generalize the logic of the previous paragraph to show how marginal analysis solves the problem of finding the optimal purchase quantity, given the price of the commodity being purchased: IDEAS FOR BEYOND THE FINAL EXAM

RULE 1: If marginal net utility is positive, the consumer must be buying too small a quantity to maximize total net utility. Because marginal utility exceeds price, the

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Consumer Choice: Individual and Market Demand

Chapter 5

consumer can increase total net utility further by buying (at least) one more unit of the product. In other words, since marginal net utility (which is marginal utility minus price) tells us how much the purchase of an additional unit raises or lowers total net utility, a positive marginal net utility means that total net utility is still going uphill. The consumer has not yet bought enough to get to the top of the hill. RULE 2: No purchase quantity for which marginal net utility is a negative number can ever be optimal. In such a case, a buyer can get a higher total net utility by cutting back the purchase quantity. The purchaser would have climbed too far on the net utility hill, passing the topmost point and beginning to descend.

This leaves only one option. The consumer cannot be at the top of the hill if marginal net utility (MU 2 P) is greater than zero—that is, if MU is greater than P. Similarly, the purchase quantity cannot be optimal if marginal net utility at that quantity (MU 2 P) is less than zero—that is, if MU is less than P. The purchase quantity can be optimal, giving the consumer the highest possible total net utility, only if Marginal net utility 5 MU 2 P 5 0; that is, if MU 5 P

Consequently, the hypothesis that the consumer chooses purchases to make the largest net contribution to total utility leads to the following optimal purchase rule: It always pays the consumer to buy more of any commodity whose marginal utility (measured in money) exceeds its price and less of any commodity whose marginal utility is less than its price. When possible, the consumer should buy a quantity of each good at which price (P) and marginal utility (MU) are exactly equal—that is, at which MU 5 P because only these quantities will maximize the net total utility that the consumer gains from purchases, given the fact that these decisions must divide available money among all purchases.3

Notice that, although the consumer really cares about maximizing total net utility (and marginal utility is not the goal), we have used marginal analysis as a guide to the optimal purchase quantity. Marginal analysis serves only as an analytic method—as a means to an end. This goal is maximization of total net utility, not marginal utility or marginal net utility. In Chapter 8, after several other applications of marginal analysis, we will generalize the discussion to show how thinking “at the margin” allows us to make optimal decisions in a wide variety of fields besides consumer purchases. Let’s briefly review graphically how the underlying logic of the marginal way of thinking leads to the optimal purchase rule, MU 5 P. Refer back to the graph of marginal utilities of pizzas (Figure 1). Suppose that Paul’s Pizza Parlor currently sells pizzas at a price of $11 (the dashed line PP in the graph). At this price, five pizzas (point E) is not an optimal purchase because the $8 marginal utility of the fifth pizza is less than its $11 price. You would be better off buying only four pizzas because that choice would save $11 with only an $8 loss in utility—a net gain of $3—from the decision to buy one less pizza. You should note that, in practice, there may not exist a number of pizzas at which MU is exactly equal to P. In our example, the fourth pizza is worth $11.50, whereas the fifth pizza is worth $8—neither of them is exactly equal to their $11 price. If you could purchase an appropriate, in-between quantity (say, 4.38 pizzas), then MU would, indeed, exactly equal P. But Paul’s Pizza Parlor will not sell you 4.38 pizzas, so you must do the best you can. You buy four pizzas, for which MU comes as close as possible to equality with P. The rule for optimal purchases states that you should not buy a quantity at which MU is higher than price (points like A, B, and C in Figure 1) because a larger purchase would Economists can equate a dollar price with marginal utility only because they measure marginal utility in money terms (or, as they more commonly state, because they deal with the marginal rate of substitution of money for the commodity). If marginal utility were measured in some psychological units not directly translatable into money terms, a comparison of P and MU would have no meaning. However, MU could also be measured in terms of any commodity other than money. (Example: How many pizzas are you willing to trade for an additional ticket to a basketball game?)

3

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

89

90

Part 2

The Building Blocks of Demand and Supply

make you even better off. Similarly, you should not end up at points E, F, G, and H, at which MU is below price, because you would be better off buying less. Rather, you should buy four pizzas (point D), where P 5 MU (approximately). Thus, marginal analysis leads naturally to the rule for optimal purchase quantities: The decision to purchase a quantity of a good that leaves marginal utility greater than price cannot maximize total net utility, because buying an additional unit would add more to total utility than it would increase cost. Similarly, it cannot be optimal for the consumer to buy a quantity of a good that leaves marginal utility less than price, because then a reduction in the quantity purchased would save more money than it would sacrifice in utility. Consequently, the consumer can maximize total net utility only if the purchase quantity brings marginal utility as close as possible to equality with price.

Note that price is an objective, observable figure determined by the market, whereas marginal utility is subjective and reflects consumer tastes. Because individual consumers lack the power to influence the price, they must adjust purchase quantities to make their subjective marginal utility of each good equal to the price given by the market.

From Diminishing Marginal Utility to Downward-Sloping Demand Curves We will see next that the marginal utility curve and the demand curve of a consumer who maximizes total net utility are one and the same. The two curves are identical. This observation enables us to use the optimal purchase rule to show that the “law” of diminishing marginal utility implies that demand curves typically slope downward to the right; that is, they have negative slopes.4 To do this, we use the list of marginal utilities in Table 1 to determine how many pizzas you would buy at any particular price. For example, we see that at a price of $8, it pays for you to buy five pizzas, because the MU of the fifth pizza ordered is $8. Table 2 gives several alternative prices and the optimal purchase quantity corresponding TABLE 2 to each price derived in just this way. (To make sure you understand the logic behind the List of Optimal Quantities optimal purchase rule, verify that the entries in the right column of Table 2 are, in fact, of Pizza for You to Purchase at Alternative Prices correct.) This table, which was initially interpreted as a marginal utility schedule, can also to be interpreted as a demand schedule, because it tells us what quantity of the good Quantity of Pizzas the consumer in question will demand at each price, the exact function of a consumer’s Price Purchased per Month demand schedule. This demand schedule appears graphically as the demand curve shown $ 3.00 7 in Figure 1. This demand curve is also simply the brick-colored marginal utility curve. 5.00 6 This is so because at any given price, the curve tells us what quantity of the good 8.00 5 11.50 4 the consumer will want to buy (the quantity at which marginal utility is equal to the 12.50 3 given price), and that is just how a demand curve is defined. So the curve in the 13.00 2 graph must be a demand curve. But the curve also tells us the marginal utility at any 15.00 1 such quantity, so it is also a marginal utility curve. You can also see its negative slope NOTE: For simplicity of explanation, the in the graph, which is a characteristic of demand curves. prices shown have been chosen to equal the marginal utilities in Table 1. In-between Let’s examine the logic underlying the negatively sloped demand curve a bit prices would make the optimal choices more carefully. Suppose you are purchasing the optimal number of pizzas, at which involve fractions of pizzas (say, 2.6 pizzas). price equals marginal utility. But then, if the price falls, you will find that your marginal utility for that product is now above the newly reduced price. For example, Table 1 indicates that at a price of $12.50 per pizza, you would optimally buy three pizzas, because the MU of the fourth pizza is only $11.50. If price falls below $11.50, it then pays to purchase more—it pays to buy the fourth pizza because its MU now exceeds its price. The marginal utility of the next (fifth) pizza is only $8. Thus, if the price falls below $8, it would pay you to buy that fifth pizza. So, the lower the price, the more the consumer will find it advantageous to buy, which is what is meant by saying that the demand curve has a negative slope. Note the critical role that the “law” of diminishing marginal utility plays here. If P falls, a consumer who wishes to maximize total utility must buy more, to the point that 4

If you need to review the concept of slope, refer to the discussion of graphic analysis in Chapter 1’s appendix.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 5

91

Consumer Choice: Individual and Market Demand

5

Richard H. Thaler, Quasi Rational Economics (New York: Russell Sage Foundation, 1992), pp. 148–150.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Instru s /Texa P Im E: © A C SOUR

Thus, in this problem both groups were really being told they could save $5 on the price of a product if they took a 20-minute trip to another store. Yet, depending on an irrelevant fact, whether the product was a cheap or an expensive model, the number of persons willing to make the same trip to save the same amount of money was very different. The point is that human purchase decisions are affected by the environment in which the decision is made, and not only by the price and marginal utility of the purchase.5 There are many examples—here are two. Two groups of people were asked what they would do if, desperately thirsty after coming off a long walk in the desert, they saw a place selling a cold beer for $10. The first group was told it was a luxury hotel, and the members of the group enthusiastically elected to purchase it, but the other group was told that the beer was sold by a shabby grocery store at the same high price, and they indignantly refused

to wsFo PRNe ages/

One group of subjects received the information in parentheses, and the other received the information in brackets. . . . [Problem 1]. Imagine that you are about to purchase. . . . a calculator for ($15)[$125]. The calculator salesman informs you that the calculator you wish to buy is on sale for ($10)[$120] at the other branch of the store, located a 20-minute drive away. Would you make the trip to the other store? The responses to the two versions of this problem were quite different. When the calculator cost $125 only 29 percent of the subjects said they would make the trip, whereas 68 percent said they would go when the calculator cost only $15.

ments

MU falls enough to equal the new lower price. According to the “law” of diminishing marginal utility, the only way to do this is to increase the quantity purchased. Although this explanation is a bit abstract, we can easily rephrase it in practical terms. We have noted that individuals put commodities to various uses, each of which has a different priority. For you, buying a pizza for your date has a higher priority than using the pizza to feed your roommate. If the price of pizzas is high, it makes sense for you to buy only enough for the high-priority uses—those that offer high marginal utilities. When price declines, however, it pays to purchase more of the good—enough for some lower-priority uses. The same general assumption about consumer psychology underlies both the “law” of diminishing marginal utility and the negative slope of the demand curve. They are really two different ways of describing the same assumed attitudes of the consumer. Indeed, it may well have struck you that this chapter’s discussion of the consumer’s decision process—equating price and marginal utility—does not resemble the thought processes of any consumer you have ever met. Buyers may seem to make decisions much more instinctively and without any calculation of marginal utilities or anything like them. That is true— yet it need not undermine the pertinence of the discussion. When you give a command to your computer, you actually activate some electronic switches and start some operations in what is referred to as binary code. Most computer users do not know they are having this effect and do not care, yet they are activating binary code nevertheless, and the analysis of the computation process does not misrepresent the facts by describing this sequence. In the same way, if a shopper divides her purchasing power among various purchase options in a way that yields the largest possible utility for her money, she must be following the rules of marginal analysis, even though she is totally unaware of this choice. A growing body of experimental evidence, however, has pointed out some persistent deviations between reality and the picture of consumer behavior provided by marginal analysis. Experimental studies by groups of economists and psychologists have turned up many examples of behavior that seem to violate the optimal purchase rule. For instance, one study offered two groups of respondents what were really identical options, presumably yielding similar marginal utilities. Despite this equality, depending on differences in some irrelevant information that was also provided to the respondents, the two groups made very different choices.

92

Part 2

The Building Blocks of Demand and Supply

the offer. Here are individuals who, having purchased a bottle of wine for $15 some 20 years earlier and learning that such bottles now sell for $800, will not try to sell their bottle (suggesting it is worth more than $800 to them) but will also refuse to buy another at the current price (suggesting it is worth less than $800 to them). One can go on and on with examples of consumers not behaving as economic theory describes. But do such actions make a substantial difference to the performance of the economy? For example, would the price of the old wine fall substantially if most of the people who still own bottles offered them for sale? The answer is sometimes. But sometimes the market mechanism offsets the effects of such “irrationality.” A striking illustration arose when President Dwight Eisenhower had a heart attack. The next morning, the bottom dropped out of the stock market. Brokers were besieged by terrified investors who demanded immediate sale of their stockholdings at whatever price they could fetch. But there were many other potential stock buyers who recognized that, even if the president did not survive, there would be no radical change in the U.S. economy. The collapse of the market was an opportunity to acquire valuable securities at bargain prices, and they bought. By the next day, the market had fully recovered, and the effect of the irrational terror of the sellers of the previous day had evaporated. The bottom line is that human behavior is often far from the “rational decision making” assumed by the theory, but that does not always make a big difference in the behavior of the market.

BEHAVIORAL ECONOMICS: ARE ECONOMIC DECISIONS REALLY MADE “RATIONALLY”? Economic theory has traditionally focused on optimality in decision making. What bundle of supermarket purchases maximizes the consumer’s utility? What business decisions maximize company profits? In recent years, a number of economists and psychologists have questioned the implied assumption that economic decisions are made rationally, after careful calculation and comparison of the payoffs in terms of the decision makers’ goals. As you might expect, they have found much evidence of behavior that is inconsistent with economists’ typical rationality assumptions. This research has led to a school of thought called behavioral economics that investigates how consumers and other economic decision makers really behave.

CONSUMER CHOICE AS A TRADE-OFF: OPPORTUNITY COST We have expressed the optimal purchase rule as the principle guiding a decision about how much of one commodity to buy. However, we have already observed that the scarcity of income lurking in the background turns every decision into a trade-off. Given each consumer’s limited income, a decision to buy a new car usually means giving up some travel or postponing furniture purchases. The money that the consumer gives up when making a purchase—the expenditure on that purchase—is only one measure of the true underlying cost—what must be given up in exchange, and that is what we have defined as the opportunity cost of the purchase.

IDEAS FOR BEYOND THE FINAL EXAM

HOW MUCH DOES IT REALLY COST? The real cost is the opportunity cost of the purchase—the commodities that we must give up as a result of the purchase decision. This opportunity-cost calculation has already been noted in one of our Ideas for Beyond the Final Exam—we must always consider the real cost of our purchase decisions, which take into account how much of other things they force us to forgo. Any decision to buy implies some such trade-off because scarcity constrains all economic decisions. Although their dilemmas may not inspire much pity, even billionaires face very real trade-offs: Invest $200 million in an office building, or go for the $300 million baseball team?

This last example has another important implication. The trade-off from a consumer’s purchase decision does not always involve giving up another consumer good. This is true, Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 5

93

Consumer Choice: Individual and Market Demand

for example, of the choice between consumption and saving. Consider a high school student who is deciding whether to buy a new car or to save the money to pay for college. If she saves the money, it can grow by earning interest, so that the original amount plus interest earned will be available to pay for tuition and board three years later. A decision to cut down on consumption now and put the money into the bank means that the student will be wealthier in the future because of the interest she will earn. This, in turn, will enable the student to afford more of her college expenses at the future date when those expenses arise. So the opportunity cost of a new car today is the forgone opportunity to save funds for the future. We conclude: From the viewpoint of economic analysis, the true cost of any purchase is the opportunity cost of that purchase, rather than the amount of money that is spent on it.

The opportunity cost of a purchase can be either higher or lower than its price. For example, if your computer cost you $1,800, but the purchase required you to take off two hours from your job that pays $20 per hour, the true cost of the computer—that is, the opportunity cost—is the amount of goods you could have bought with $1,840 (the $1,800 price plus the $40 in earnings that the purchase of the computer required you to give up). In this case, the opportunity cost ($1,840, measured in money terms) is higher than the price of the purchase ($1,800). (For an example in which price is higher than opportunity cost, see Test Yourself Question 4 at the end of the chapter.)

Consumer’s Surplus: The Net Gain from a Purchase The optimal purchase rule, MU (approximately) 5 P, assumes that the consumer always tries to maximize the money value of the total utility from the purchase minus the amount spent to make that purchase.6 Thus, any difference between the price consumers actually pay for a commodity and the price they would be willing to pay for that item represents a net utility gain in some sense. Economists give the name consumer’s surplus to that difference—that is, to the net gain in total utility that a purchase brings to a buyer. The consumer is trying to make the purchase decisions that maximize Consumer’s surplus 5 Total utility (in money terms) 2 Total expenditures

Thus, just as economists assume that business firms maximize total profit (equal to total revenue minus total cost), they assume that consumers maximize consumer’s surplus; that is, the difference between the total utility of the purchased commodity and the amount that consumers spend on it. The concept of consumer’s surplus seems to suggest that the consumer gains some sort of free bonus, or surplus, for every purchase. In many cases, this idea seems absurd. How can it be true, particularly for goods whose prices seem to be outrageous? We hinted at the answer in Chapter 1, where we observed that, if there is no cheating, both parties must gain from a voluntary exchange or else one of them will refuse to participate. The same must be true when a consumer makes a voluntary purchase from a supermarket or an appliance store. If the consumer did not expect a net gain from the transaction, he or she would simply not bother to buy the good. Even if the seller were to “overcharge” by some standard, that would merely reduce the size of the consumer’s net gain, not eliminate it entirely. If the seller is so greedy as to charge a price that wipes out the net gain altogether, the punishment will fit the crime: The consumer will refuse to buy, and the greedy seller’s would-be gains will never materialize. The basic principle states that every purchase that is not on the borderline—that is, every purchase except those about which the consumer is indifferent—must yield some consumer’s surplus. But how large is that surplus? At least in theory, it can be measured with the aid of a table or graph of marginal utilities (Table 1 and Figure 1). Suppose that, as in our earlier example, the price of a large pizza is $11 and you purchase four pizzas. Table 3 reproduces the marginal utility numbers from Table 1. It shows that the first pizza is worth $15 to you,

6

Consumer’s surplus is the difference between the value to the consumer of the quantity of Commodity X purchased and the amount that the market requires the consumer to pay for that quantity of X.

Again, in practice, the consumer can often only approximately equate MU and P.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

94

Part 2

The Building Blocks of Demand and Supply

so at the $11 price, you reap a net gain (surplus) of $15 minus $11, or $4, by buying that pizza. The second pizza also brings you some surplus, but less than the first one does, because the marginal utility diminishes. Specifically, the second pizza provides a surplus of $13 minus $11, or $2. Reasoning in the same way, the third pizza gives you a surplus of $12.50 minus $11, or $1.50. It is only the fourth serving—the last one that you purchase— that offers little or no surplus because, by the optimal purchase rule, the marginal utility of the last unit is approximately equal to its price. We can now easily determine the total consumer’s surplus that you obtain by buying four pizzas. It is simply the sum of the surpluses received from each pizza. Table 3 shows that this consumer’s total surplus is $4 1 $2 1 $1.50 1 $0.50 5 $8

This way of looking at the optimal purchase rule shows why a buyer must always gain some consumer’s surplus if buying more than one unit of a good. Note that the price of each unit remains the same, but the marginal utility diminishes as more units are purchased. The last unit bought yields only a tiny consumer’s surplus because MU (approximately) 5 P, but all prior units must have had TABLE 3 marginal utilities greater than the MU of the last unit because of diCalculating Marginal Net Utility (Marginal minishing marginal utility. Consumer's Surplus) from Your Pizza Purchases We can be more precise about the calculation of the consumer’s Marginal Marginal Net surplus with the help of a graph showing marginal utility as a set of Quantity Utility Price Utility (Surplus) bars. The bars labeled A, B, C, and D in Figure 3 come from the cor0 responding points on the marginal utility curve (demand curve) in $15.00 $11.00 $4.00 1 Figure 1. The consumer’s surplus from each pizza equals the mar13.00 11.00 2.00 2 ginal utility of that pizza minus the price paid for it. By represent12.50 11.00 1.50 ing consumer’s surplus graphically, we can determine just how 3 11.50 11.00 0.50 much surplus was obtained from the entire purchase by measuring 4 Total $8.00 the area between the marginal utility curve and the horizontal line representing the price of pizzas—in this case, the horizontal line PP represents the (fixed) $11 price. In Figure 3, the bar whose upper-right corner is labeled A represents the $15 marginal utility derived from the first pizza; the same interpretation applies to bars B, C, and D. Clearly, the first serving purchased yields a consumer’s surplus of $4, indicated by the shaded part of bar A. The height of that part of the bar is equal to the $15 marginal utility minus the $11 price. In the same way, the next two shaded areas represent the surpluses offered by the second and third pizzas. The fourth pizza has the smallest shaded area because the height representing marginal utility is (as close as you can get to being) equal to the height representing price. Sum up the shaded areas in the graph to obtain, once

Graphic Calculation of Consumer’s Surplus

Marginal Utility and Price per Pizza

F I GURE 3 $16 $15.00 Marginal utility (demand) curve A 15 14 B $13.00 $12.50 C 13 $4.00 $11.50 D 12 $2.00 $1.50 $0.50 11 P P 10 9 $8.00 E 8 7 6 $5.00 F 5 4 $3.00 3 G 2 1 $0 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 Number of Pizzas Purchased per Month

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 5

Consumer Choice: Individual and Market Demand

again, the total consumer’s surplus ($4 1 $2 1 $1.50 1 $0.50 5 $8) from a four-pizza purchase. The consumer’s surplus derived from buying a certain number of units of a good is obtained graphically by drawing the person’s demand curve as a set of bars whose heights represent the marginal utilities of the corresponding quantities of the good and then drawing a horizontal line whose height is the price of the good. The sum of the heights of the bars above the horizontal line—that is, the area of the demand (marginal utility) bars above that horizontal line—measures the total consumer’s surplus that the purchase yields.

PUZZLE:

RESOLVING THE DIAMOND–WATER PUZZLE

We can now use marginal utility analysis to analyze Adam Smith’s paradox (which he was never able to explain) that diamonds are very expensive, whereas water is generally very cheap, even though water seems to offer far more utility. The resolution of the diamond–water puzzle is based on the distinction between marginal and total utility. The total utility of water—its role as a necessity of life—is indeed much higher than that of diamonds, but price, as we have seen, is not related directly to total utility. Rather, the optimal purchase rule tells us that price tends to equal marginal utility. We have every reason to expect the marginal utility of water to be very low, whereas the marginal utility of a diamond is very high. Given normal conditions, water is comparatively cheap to provide, so its price is generally quite low. Consumers thus use correspondingly large quantities of water. The principle of diminishing marginal utility, therefore, pushes down the marginal utility of water for a typical household to a low level. As the consumer’s surplus diagram (Figure 3) suggests, this also means that its total utility is likely to be high. In contrast, high-quality diamonds are scarce (partly because a monopoly keeps them so). As a result, the quantity of diamonds consumed is not large enough to drive down the MU of diamonds very far, so buyers of such luxuries must pay high prices for them. As a commodity becomes more scarce, its marginal utility and its market price rise, regardless of the size of its total utility. Also, as we have seen, because so little of the commodity is consumed, its total utility is likely to be comparatively low, despite its large marginal utility. Thus, like many paradoxes, the diamond–water puzzle has a straightforward explanation. In this case, all one has to remember is that Scarcity raises price and marginal utility, but it generally reduces total utility. And although total utility measures the benefits consumers get from their consumption, it is marginal utility that is equal (approximately) to price.

Income and Quantity Demanded Our application of marginal analysis has enabled us to examine the relationship between the price of a commodity and the quantity that will be purchased. But things other than price also influence the amount of a good that a consumer will purchase. As an example, we’ll look at how quantity demanded responds to changes in income. To be concrete, consider what happens to the number of ballpoint pens consumers will buy when their real income rises. It may seem almost certain that they will buy more ballpoint pens than before, but that is not necessarily so. A rise in real income can either increase or decrease the quantity of any particular good purchased. Why might an increase in income lead a consumer to buy fewer ballpoint pens? People buy some goods and services only because they cannot afford anything better. They may purchase used cars instead of new ones. They may use inexpensive ballpoint pens instead

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

95

96

Part 2

The Building Blocks of Demand and Supply

of finely crafted fountain pens or buy clothing secondhand instead of new. If their real incomes rise, they may then drop out of the used car market and buy brand-new automobiles or buy more fountain pens and fewer ballpoint pens. Thus, a rise in real income will reduce the quantities of cheap pens and used cars demanded. Economists have given the rather descriptive name inferior goods to the class of commodities for which quantity demanded falls when income rises. The upshot of this discussion is that economists cannot draw definite conclusions about the effects of a rise in consumer incomes on quantity demanded. But for most commodities, if incomes rise and prices do not change, quantity demanded will increase. Such an item is often called a normal good.

An inferior good is a commodity whose quantity demanded falls when the purchaser’s real income rises, all other things remaining equal.

FROM INDIVIDUAL DEMAND CURVES TO MARKET DEMAND CURVES So far in this chapter, we have studied how individual demand curves are obtained from the logic of consumer choice. To understand how the market system works, we must derive the relationship between price and quantity demanded in the market as a whole—the market demand curve. For example, the demand for laptops in Cleveland, Ohio, is described by such a demand curve. It is this market demand curve that plays a key role in the supplydemand analysis of price and output determination that we studied in Chapter 4.

A market demand curve shows how the total quantity of some product demanded by all consumers in the market during a specified period of time changes as the price of that product changes, holding all other things constant.

Market Demand Curves as a Horizontal Sum of the Demand Curves of Individual Buyers If each individual pays no attention to other people’s purchase decisions when making his or her own, then we can easily derive the market demand curve from consumers’ individual demand curves: As we will see next, we simply add the individual consumers’ demand curves, as shown in Figure 4. The figure gives the individual demand curves DD and ZZ for two people, Alex and Naomi, and the total (market) demand curve, MM. Alex and Naomi are both consumers of the product. We can derive this market demand curve in the following straightforward way: Step 1: Pick any relevant price, say, $10. Step 2: At that price, determine Alex’s quantity demanded (9 units) from his demand curve in Panel (a) of Figure 4 and Naomi’s quantity demanded (6 units) from her demand curve in Panel (b) of Figure 4. Note that these quantities are indicated by the line segment labeled AA for Alex and that labeled NN for Naomi. Step 3: Add Naomi’s and Alex’s quantities demanded at the $10 price (segment AA 1 segment NN 5 9 1 6 5 15) to yield the total quantity demanded by the market at that price. This gives segment CC, with total quantity demanded

The Relationship between Total Market Demand and the Demand of Individual Consumers within That Market

$10

A

N

A

M

Naomi’s demand

Price

Price

D

Z

Alex’s demand

Market demand K

Price

F I GURE 4

C

N

C 9

0

9 Quantity Demanded (a)

6 M

Z

D 0

6 Quantity Demanded (b)

0

15 Quantity Demanded (c)

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 5

97

Consumer Choice: Individual and Market Demand

equal to 15 units, in Panel (c) of Figure 4. Notice that the addition constitutes a horizontal movement in the graph because we are adding quantities purchased, and those quantities are measured by horizontal distances from the zero points of each of the graphs. Now repeat the process for each alternative price to obtain other points on the market demand curve until the shape of the entire curve MM appears. (The sharp angle at point K on the market curve occurs because that point corresponds to the price at which Alex, whose demand pattern is different from Naomi’s, first enters the market. At any higher price, only Naomi is willing to buy anything.) That is all there is to the adding-up process. (Question: What would happen to the market demand curve if, say, another consumer entered the market?)

The “Law” of Demand Just as in the case of an individual’s demand curve, we expect the total quantity demanded by the market to move in the opposite direction from price, so the slope of the market demand curve will also be negative. Economists call this relationship the “law” of demand. Notice that we have put the word law in quotation marks. By now you will have observed that economic laws are not always obeyed, and we shall see in a moment that the “law” of demand is not without exceptions. But first let us see why the “law” usually holds. Earlier in this chapter, we explained that individual demand curves usually slope downward because of the “law” of diminishing marginal utility. If individual demand curves slope downward, then the preceding discussion of the adding-up process implies that market demand curves must also slope downward. This is just common sense; if every consumer in the market buys fewer pizzas when the price of pizza rises, then the total quantity demanded in the market must surely fall. But market demand curves may slope downward even if individual demand curves do not, because not all consumers are alike. Consider two examples where the individual’s demand curve does not slope downward. If a bookstore reduces the price of a popular novel, it may draw many new customers, but few of the customers who already own a copy will buy a second one, despite the reduced price. Similarly, true devotees of pizza may maintain their pizza purchases unchanged even if prices rise to exorbitant levels, whereas others would not eat pizza even if you gave it to them free of charge. But the market demand curves for books and pizzas can still have a negative slope. As the price of pizza rises, less enthusiastic pizza eaters may drop out of the market entirely, leaving the expensive pie to the more devoted consumers. Thus, the quantity demanded declines as price rises, simply because higher prices induce more people to give up pizza completely. And for many commodities, lower prices encourage new customers to come into the market (for example, new book buyers), and it is these “fair-weather” customers (rather than the negative slope of individual demand curves) who can be most important for the “law” of demand. This is also illustrated in Figure 4, in which only Naomi will buy the product at a price higher than D. At a price lower than D, Alex will also purchase the product. Hence, below point K, the market demand curve lies farther to the right than it would have if Alex had not entered the market. Put another way, a rise in price from a level below D to a level above D would cut quantity demanded for two reasons: (1) because Naomi’s demand curve has a negative slope and (2) because it would drive Alex out of the market. We conclude, therefore, that the “law” of demand stands on fairly solid ground. If individual demand curves slope downward, then the market demand curve surely will, too. Furthermore, the market demand curve may slope downward even when individual demand curves do not.

The “law” of demand states that a lower price generally increases the amount of a commodity that people in a market are willing to buy and also tends to increase the number of buyers. Therefore, for most goods, market demand curves have negative slopes.

Exceptions to the “Law” of Demand Some exceptions to the “law” of demand have been noted. One common exception occurs when people judge quality on the basis of price—they perceive a more expensive

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

98

Part 2

The Building Blocks of Demand and Supply

commodity as offering better quality. For example, many people buy name-brand aspirin, even if right next to it on the drugstore shelf they see an unbranded, generic aspirin with an identical chemical formula selling at half the price. The consumers who do buy the name-brand aspirin may well use comparative price to judge the relative qualities of different brands. They may prefer Brand X to Brand Y because X is slightly more expensive. If Brand X were to reduce its price below that of Brand Y, consumers might assume that it was no longer superior and actually reduce their purchases of X. Another possible cause of an upward-sloping demand curve is snob appeal. If part of the reason for purchasing a $300,000 Rolls-Royce is to advertise one’s wealth, a decrease in the car’s price may actually reduce sales, even if the quality of the car remains unchanged. Other types of exceptions have also been noted by economists, but for most commodities, it seems quite reasonable to assume that demand curves have negative slopes, an assumption that is supported by the data. This chapter has begun to take us behind the demand curve, to discuss how it is determined by the preferences of individual consumers. Chapter 6 will explore the demand curve further by examining other things that determine its shape and the implications of that shape for consumer behavior.

| SUMMARY | 1. Economists distinguish between total and marginal utility. Total utility, or the benefit consumers derive from a purchase, is measured by the maximum amount of money they would give up to obtain the good. Rational consumers seek to maximize (net) total utility, or consumer’s surplus: the total utility derived from a commodity minus the value of the money spent in buying it. 2. Marginal utility is the maximum amount of money that a consumer is willing to pay for an additional unit of a particular commodity. Marginal utility is useful in calculating the set of purchases that maximizes net total utility. This illustrates one of our Ideas for Beyond the Final Exam. 3. The “law” of diminishing marginal utility is a psychological hypothesis stating that as a consumer acquires more of a commodity, the marginal utility of additional units of the commodity decreases. 4. To maximize the total utility obtained by spending money on Commodity X, given the fact that other goods can be purchased only with the money that remains after buying X, the consumer must purchase a quantity of X such that the price equals (or approximately equals) the commodity’s marginal utility (in monetary terms). 5. If the consumer acts to maximize utility, and if the marginal utility of some good declines when purchased in larger quantities, then the consumer’s demand curve for the good will have a negative slope. A reduction in price will induce the consumer to purchase more units, leading to a lower marginal utility. 6. Abundant goods tend to have low prices and low marginal utilities regardless of whether their total

utilities are high or low. That is why water can have a lower price than diamonds despite its higher total utility. 7. An inferior good, such as secondhand clothing, is a commodity of which consumers buy less when they get richer, all other things held equal. 8. Consumers usually earn a surplus when they purchase a commodity voluntarily. This means that the quantity of the good that they buy is worth more to them than the money they give up in exchange for it. Otherwise, they would not buy it. That is why consumer’s surplus is normally positive. 9. As another of our Ideas for Beyond the Final Exam, “How Much Does It Really Cost?,” tells us, the true economic cost of the purchase of Commodity X is its opportunity cost—that is, the value of the alternative purchases that the acquisition of X requires the consumer to forgo. The money value of the opportunity cost of a unit of good X can be higher or lower than the price of X. 10. A rise in a consumer’s income can push quantity demanded either up or down. For normal goods, a rise in income raises the quantity demanded; for inferior goods, which are generally purchased in an effort to save money, a higher income reduces the quantity demanded. 11. The demand curve for an entire market is obtained by taking a horizontal sum of the demand curves of all individuals who buy or consider buying in that market. This sum is obtained by adding up, for each price, the quantity of the commodity in question that every such consumer is willing to purchase at that price.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 5

99

Consumer Choice: Individual and Market Demand

| KEY TERMS | consumer’s surplus inferior good

93

96

“law” of demand

97

“law” of diminishing marginal utility 87

marginal utility

market demand curve

96

marginal analysis

total monetary utility

86

88

86

| TEST YOURSELF | 1. Which gives you greater total utility: 14 gallons of water per day or 22 gallons per day? Why? 2. At which level do you get greater marginal utility: 14 gallons per day or 22 gallons per day? Why? 3. Which of the following items are likely to be normal goods for a typical consumer? Which are likely to be inferior goods? a. Expensive perfume b. Paper plates c. Secondhand clothing d. Overseas trips 4. Emily buys an air conditioner that costs $700. Because the air in her home is cleaner, its use saves her $250 in curtain cleaning costs over the lifetime of the air conditioner. In money terms, what is the opportunity cost of the air conditioner?

5. Suppose that strawberries sell for $3 per basket. Jim is considering whether to buy zero, one, two, three, or four baskets. On your own, create a plausible set of total and marginal utility numbers for the different quantities of strawberries (as we did for pizza in Table 1), and arrange them in a table. From your table, calculate how many baskets Jim would buy. 6. Draw a graph showing the consumer’s surplus Jim would get from his strawberry purchase in Test Yourself Question 5, and check your answer with the help of your marginal utility table. 7. Consider a market with two consumers, Jasmine and Jim. Draw a demand curve for each of the two consumers, and use those curves to construct the demand curve for the entire market.

| DISCUSSION QUESTIONS | 1. Describe some of the different ways you use water. Which would you give up if the price of water were to rise a little? If it were to rise by a fairly large amount? If it were to rise by a very large amount? 2. Suppose that you wanted to measure the marginal utility of a commodity to a consumer by directly determining the consumer’s psychological attitude or strength of feeling toward the commodity rather than by seeing how much money the consumer would give up for the commodity. Why would you find it difficult to make such a psychological measurement?

good that its price equals its marginal utility, the consumer could not possibly be behaving optimally. Rather, they say, the consumer would be better off quitting while ahead or buying a quantity such that marginal utility is much greater than price. What is wrong with this argument? (Hint: What opportunity would the consumer then miss? Is it maximization of marginal or total utility that serves the consumer’s interests?) 4. What inferior goods do you purchase? Why do you buy them? Do you think you will continue to buy them when your income is higher?

3. Some people who do not understand the optimal purchase rule argue that if a consumer buys so much of a

| APPENDIX | Analyzing Consumer Choice Graphically: Indifference Curve Analysis The consumer demand analysis presented in this chapter, although correct as far as it goes, has (at least) one shortcoming: By treating the consumer’s decision about the purchase of each commodity as an isolated event, it conceals the fact that consumers must choose among commodities because of their limited budgets. The analysis so far does not explicitly indicate the hard choice behind every purchase decision—the sacrifice of some goods to obtain others.

The idea is included implicitly, of course, because the purchase of any commodity involves a trade-off between that good and money. If you spend more money on rent, you have less to spend on entertainment. If you buy more clothing, you have less money for food. But to represent the consumer’s choice problem explicitly, economists have invented two geometric devices, the budget line and the indifference curve, which are described in this appendix.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

100

Part 2

The Building Blocks of Demand and Supply

GEOMETRY OF AVAILABLE CHOICES: THE BUDGET LINE

TABLE 4 Alternative Purchase Combinations for a $12 Budget

Boxes of Rubber Bands (at $3 each)

Expenditure on Rubber Bands

Remaining Funds

0 1 2 3 4

$0 3 6 9 12

$12 9 6 3 0

Pounds of Cheese (at $2 each) 6 4.5 3 1.5 0

Label in Figure 5

A B C D E

If a straight line connects points A through E, the brown line in the diagram, it traces all possible ways to divide the $12 between the two goods. For example, at point D, if the consumer buys three boxes of rubber bands, he will have enough money left to purchase only 11⁄2 pounds of cheese. This is readily seen to be correct from Table 4. Line AE is therefore called the budget line.

A Budget Line

7 A Pounds of Cheese

Suppose, for simplicity, that only two commodities are produced in the world: cheese and rubber bands. The decision problem of any household is then to allocate its income between these two goods. Clearly, the more it spends on one, the less it can have of the other. But just what is the trade-off? A numerical example will answer this question and introduce the graphical device that economists use to portray the trade-off. Suppose that cheese costs $2 per pound, boxes of rubber bands sell at $3 each, and a consumer has $12 at his disposal. He obviously has a variety of choices, as displayed in Table 4. For example, if he buys no rubber bands, the consumer can go home with six pounds of cheese, and so on. Each of the combinations of cheese and rubber bands that the consumer can afford can be shown in a diagram in which the axes measure the quantities purchased of each commodity. In Figure 5, pounds of cheese are measured along the vertical axis, the number of boxes of rubber bands is measured along the horizontal axis, and a labeled point represents each of the combinations enumerated in Table 4. This budget line AE shows the possible combinations of cheese and rubber bands that the consumer can buy with $12 if cheese costs $2 per pound and a box of rubber bands costs $3. For example, point A corresponds to spending everything on cheese; point E corresponds to spending everything on rubber bands. At intermediate points on the budget line (such as C), the consumer buys some of both goods (at C, two boxes of rubber bands and three pounds of cheese), which together use up the $12 available.

FIGURE 5

6 5

G

B

4 C

3 2

D

K

1 E 0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

Boxes of Rubber Bands

The budget line for a household graphically represents all possible combinations of two commodities that it can purchase, given the prices of the commodities and some fixed amount of money at its disposal.

Properties of the Budget Line Let us now use r to represent the number of boxes of rubber bands purchased by the consumer and c to indicate the amount of cheese that he acquires. Thus, at $2 per pound, he spends on cheese a total of $2 times the number of pounds of cheese bought, or $2c. Similarly, the consumer spends $3r on rubber bands, making a total of $2c plus $3r, which must equal $12 if he spends the entire $12 on the two commodities. Thus, 2c 1 3r 5 12 is the equation of the budget line. It is also the equation of the straight line drawn in the diagram.7 Note also that the budget line represents the maximum amounts of the commodities that the consumer can afford. Thus, for any given purchase of rubber bands, it indicates the greatest amount of cheese that his money can buy. If the consumer wants to be thrifty, he can choose to end up at a point below the budget line, such as K. Clearly, then, the choices he has available include not only those points on the budget line, AE, but also any point in the shaded triangle formed by that line and the two axes, because at any such point the consumer buys smaller quantities of cheese and/or rubber bands than at points on AE and so spends less than the available $12. By contrast, points above the budget line, such as G, are not available to the You may have noticed one problem that arises in this formulation. If every point on the budget line AE is a possible way for the consumer to spend his money, he must be able to buy fractional boxes of rubber bands. Perhaps the purchase of 1Ω boxes can be interpreted to include a down payment of $1.50 on a box of rubber bands to be purchased on the next shopping trip! 7

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

consumer, given his limited budget. A bundle of five pounds of cheese and two boxes of rubber bands would cost $16, which is more than he has to spend.

FIGURE 7 The Effect of Price Changes on the Budget Line

7

The position of the budget line is determined by two types of data: the prices of the commodities purchased and the income at the buyer’s disposal. We can complete our discussion of the graphics of the budget line by examining briefly how a change in either prices or income affects the location of that line. Obviously, any increase in the income of the household increases the range of options available to it. Specifically, increases in income produce parallel shifts in the budget line, as shown in Figure 6. The reason is simple: An increase in available income of, say, 50 percent, if spent entirely on these two goods, would permit the consumer’s family to purchase exactly 50 percent more of either commodity. Point A in Figure 5 would shift upward by 50 percent of its distance from the origin, whereas point E would move to the right by 50 percent.8 Figure 6 shows three such budget lines corresponding to incomes of $9, $12, and $18, respectively. Finally, we can ask what happens to the budget line when the price of some commodity changes. In Figure 7, when the price of the rubber bands

6

FIGU R E 6 The Effect of Income Changes on the Budget Line

U

Pounds of Cheese

8 7 6 5

A

Income = $18

D

4

Income = $12

Pounds of Cheese

Changes in the Budget Line

9

101

Consumer Choice: Individual and Market Demand

Chapter 5

A

5 Rubber band price = $3.00 Rubber band price = $1.50

4 3 2 1 0

1

2

3

E 4

H 5

6

7

8

Boxes of Rubber Bands

decreases, the budget line moves outward, but the move is no longer parallel because the point on the cheese axis remains fixed. Once again, the reason is fairly straightforward. A 50 percent reduction in the price of rubber bands (from $3.00 to $1.50) permits the consumer to buy twice as many boxes of rubber bands with his $12 as before: Point E moves rightward to point H, where the buyer can obtain eight boxes of rubber bands. However, since the price of cheese has not changed, the amount of cheese that can be bought for $12 is unaffected, meaning that the end of the budget line at point A does not move. This gives the general result about the determination of the budget line: A reduction in the price of one of the two commodities swings the budget line outward along the axis representing the quantity of that item while leaving the location of the other end of the line unchanged. Thus a fall in the price of rubber bands from $3.00 to $1.50 swings the price line from AE to blue line AH. This happens because at the higher price, $12 buys only four boxes of rubber bands, but at the lower price, it can buy eight boxes.

3 2

Income = $9

1 0

1

2

N 3

E 4

5

P 6

7

8

Boxes of Rubber Bands

An algebraic proof is simple. Let M (which is initially $12) be the amount of money available to the consumer’s household. The equation of the budget line can be solved for c, obtaining c 5 2(3/2)r 1 M/2. This equation corresponds to a straight line with a slope of 23/2 and a vertical intercept of M/2. A change in M, the quantity of money available, will not change the slope of the budget line; rather, it will lead to parallel shifts in that line.

8

WHAT THE CONSUMER PREFERS: PROPERTIES OF THE INDIFFERENCE CURVE The budget line indicates what choices are available to the consumer, given the size of his income and the commodity prices fixed by the market. Next, we must examine the consumer’s preferences to determine which of these available possibilities he will choose with the given income and prices. After much investigation, economists have determined what they believe to be the minimum amount of information they need about a purchaser in order to analyze his choices. Economists only need to know how a

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

102

The Building Blocks of Demand and Supply

Part 2

consumer ranks alternative bundles of available commodities, deciding which of every relevant pair of bundles he likes better but making no effort to find out how much more he likes the preferred bundle. Suppose, for instance, that the consumer can choose between two bundles of goods, Bundle W, which contains three boxes of rubber bands and one pound of cheese, and Bundle T, which contains two boxes of rubber bands and three pounds of cheese. The economist wants to know for this purpose only whether the consumer prefers W to T or T to W, or whether he is indifferent about which one he gets. Note that the analysis requires no information about the degree of preference— whether the consumer is wildly more enthusiastic about one of the bundles or just prefers it slightly. Graphically, the preference information is provided by a group of curves called indifference curves (Figure 8). An indifference curve connects all combinations of the commodities that are equally desirable to the consumer.

Any point on the diagram represents a combination of cheese and rubber bands. (For example, point T on indifference curve Ib represents two boxes of rubber bands and three pounds of cheese.) Any two points on the same indifference curve (for example, S and W, on indifference curve Ia) represent two combinations of the goods that the consumer likes equally well. If two points, such as T and W, lie on different indifference curves, the consumer prefers the one on the higher indifference curve. Before we examine these curves, let us see how to interpret one. A single point on an indifference curve says nothing about preferences. For example, point R on curve Ia simply represents the bundle of goods composed of four boxes of rubber bands and F I GURE 8 Three Indifference Curves for Cheese and Rubber Bands

Pounds of Cheese

7 6 5 U

4 T

3 2

IC

S

1

R

W 0

1

2

Ib Ia

3

4

5

6

7

Boxes of Rubber Bands

8

1⁄2

pound of cheese. It does not suggest that the consumer is indifferent between 1⁄2 pound of cheese and four boxes of rubber bands. For the curve to indicate anything, one must consider at least two of its points—for example, points S and W. An indifference curve, by definition, represents all such combinations that provide equal total utility to the consumer. We do not know yet which bundle, among all of the bundles he can afford, the consumer will choose to buy; this analysis indicates only that a change in which of two such bundles the consumer selects will make him neither better off nor worse off, in terms of the items received. Before using indifference curves to analyze the consumer’s choices, one must examine a few of its properties. Most important is the fact that As long as the consumer desires more of each of the goods in question, every point on a higher indifference curve (that is, a curve farther from the origin in the graph) will be preferred to any point on a lower indifference curve.

In other words, among indifference curves, higher is better. The reason is obvious. Given two indifference curves, say, Ib and Ic in Figure 8, the higher curve will contain points lying above and to the right of some points on the lower curve. Thus, point U on curve Ic lies above and to the right of point T on curve Ib. This means that the consumer gets more rubber bands and more cheese at U than at T. Assuming that he desires both commodities, the consumer must prefer U to T. Because every point on curve Ic is, by definition, equal in desirability to point U, and the same relation holds for point T and all other points along curve Ib, the consumer will prefer every point on curve Ic to any point on curve Ib. This implies a second property of indifference curves: They never intersect. This is so because if an indifference curve, say, Ib, is anywhere above another indifference curve, say, Ia, then Ib must be above Ia everywhere, because every point on Ib is preferred to every point on Ia. Another property that characterizes the indifference curve is its negative slope. Again, this holds only if the consumer wants more of both commodities. Consider two points, such as S and R, on the same indifference curve. If the consumer is indifferent between them, one point cannot represent more of both commodities than the other point. Given that point S represents more cheese than point R, R must offer more rubber bands than S, or the consumer would not be indifferent about which he gets. As a result, any movement toward the point with the larger number of rubber bands implies a decrease in the quantity of cheese. The curve will always slope downhill toward the right, giving a negative slope.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Consumer Choice: Individual and Market Demand

Chapter 5

A final property of indifference curves is the nature of their curvature—the way they round toward the axes. They are drawn “bowed in”—they flatten out (they become less and less steep) as they extend from left to right. To understand why this is so, we must first examine the economic interpretation of the slope of an indifference curve.

THE SLOPES OF INDIFFERENCE CURVES AND BUDGET LINES In Figure 9, the average slope of the indifference curve between points M and N is represented by RM/RN. The slope of an indifference curve, referred to as the marginal rate of substitution (MRS) between the commodities, represents the maximum amount of one commodity that the consumer is willing to give up in exchange for one more unit of another commodity.

RM is the quantity of cheese that the consumer gives up in moving from M to N. Similarly, RN is the increased number of boxes of rubber bands acquired in this move. Because the consumer is indifferent between bundles M and N, the gain of RN rubber bands must just suffice to compensate him for the loss of RM pounds of cheese. Thus, the ratio RM/RN represents the terms on which the consumer is willing—according to his own preference—to trade one good for the other. If RM/RN equals 2, the consumer is willing to give up (no more than) two pounds of cheese for one additional box of rubber bands.

FIGU R E 9 Slopes of a Budget Line and an Indifference Curve

I

Pounds of Cheese

M

B

R

N m D

n r

E

I F

B 0

Boxes of Rubber Bands

103

The slope of the budget line, BB, in Figure 9 is also a rate of exchange between cheese and rubber bands, but it no longer reflects the consumer’s subjective willingness to trade. Rather, the slope represents the rate of exchange that the market offers to the consumer when he gives up money in exchange for cheese and rubber bands. Recall that the budget line represents all commodity combinations that a consumer can get by spending a fixed amount of money. The budget line is, therefore, a curve of constant expenditure. At current prices, if the consumer reduces his purchase of cheese by amount DE in Figure 9, he will save just enough money to buy an additional amount, EF, of rubber bands, because at points D and F he is spending the same total number of dollars. The slope of a budget line is the amount of one commodity that the market requires an individual to give up to obtain one additional unit of another commodity without any change in the amount of money spent.

The slopes of the two types of curves, then, are perfectly analogous in their meaning. The slope of the indifference curve indicates the terms on which the consumer is willing to trade one commodity for another, whereas the slope of the budget line reports the terms on which the market allows the consumer to trade one good for another. It is useful to carry our interpretation of the slope of the budget line one step further. Common sense suggests that the market’s rate of exchange between cheese and rubber bands should be related to their prices, pc and pr, and it is easy to show that this is so. Specifically, the slope of the budget line is equal to the ratio of the prices of the two commodities. To see why, note that if the consumer gives up one box of rubber bands, he has pr more dollars to spend on cheese. But the quantity of cheese this money will enable him to buy is inversely related to its price; that is, the lower the price of cheese, the more cheese that money can buy—each dollar permits him to buy 1/pc pounds of cheese. So the additional pr dollars the consumer has available when he forgoes the purchase of one box of rubber bands permit him to buy pr times 1/pc 5 pr/pc more pounds of cheese. Thus, the slope of the budget line, which indicates how much additional cheese the consumer can buy when he gives up one box of rubber bands, is pr/pc. Before returning to our main subject, the study of consumer choice, we pause briefly and use our interpretation of the slope of the indifference curve to discuss the third of the properties of the indifference curve—its characteristic curvature—which we left unexplained earlier. The shape of indifference curves means that the slope decreases with movement from left to right. In Figure 9, at point m, toward the right of the diagram, the consumer is willing to give up

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

104

The Building Blocks of Demand and Supply

Part 2

far less cheese for one more box of rubber bands (quantity rm) than he is willing to trade at point M, toward the left. This situation occurs because at M the consumer initially has a large quantity of cheese and few rubber bands, whereas at m his initial stock of cheese is low and he has many rubber bands. In general terms, the curvature premise on which indifference curves are usually drawn asserts that consumers are relatively eager to trade away some part of what they own of a commodity of which they have a large amount but are more reluctant to trade away part of the goods of which they hold small quantities. This psychological premise underlies the curvature of the indifference curve. We can now use our indifference curve apparatus to analyze how the consumer chooses among the combinations that he can afford to buy—that is, the combinations of rubber bands and cheese shown by the budget line. Figure 10 brings together in the same diagram the budget line from Figure 5 and the indifference curves from Figure 8.

Tangency Conditions Because, according to the first of the properties of indifference curves, the consumer prefers higher curves to lower ones, he will go to the point on the budget line that lies on the highest indifference curve attainable. This will be point T on indifference curve Ib. He can afford no other point that he likes as well. For example, neither point K below the budget line nor point W on the budget line puts the consumer on such a high indifference curve. Further, any point on an indifference curve above Ib, such as point U, is out of the question because it lies beyond his financial means. We end up with a simple rule of consumer choice:

FIGURE 10 Optimal Consumer Choice

Pounds of Cheese

7

Ic

I Ib 6 a 5

U

4

Consumers will get the most benefit from their money when they choose combinations of commodities whose marginal rates of substitution equal the ratios of their prices.

It is worth reviewing the logic behind this conclusion. Why is it not advisable for the consumer to stop at a point such as W, where the marginal rate of substitution (slope of the indifference curve) is less than the price ratio (slope of the budget line)? By moving upward and to the left from W along his budget line, he can instead take advantage of market opportunities to obtain a commodity bundle that he likes better. This will always be true, for example, if the amount of cheese the consumer is personally willing to exchange for a box of rubber bands (the slope of the indifference curve) is greater than the amount of cheese for which the box of rubber bands trades on the market (the slope of the budget line).

Consequences of Income Changes: Inferior Goods

K

1 0

We can see why only the point of tangency, T (two boxes of rubber bands and three pounds of cheese), will give the consumer the largest utility that his money can buy. Suppose that the consumer were instead to consider buying 31⁄2 boxes of rubber bands and one pound of cheese. This would put him at point W on the budget line and on the indifference curve Ia. By buying fewer rubber bands and more cheese (a move upward and to the left on the budget line), he could get to another indifference curve, Ib, that would be higher and therefore more desirable without spending any more money. It clearly does not pay to end up at W. Only the point of tangency, T, leaves no room for further improvement. At a point of tangency, where the consumer’s benefits from purchasing cheese and rubber bands are maximized, the slope of the budget line equals the slope of the indifference curve. This is true by the definition of a point of tangency. We have just seen that the slope of the indifference curve is the marginal rate of substitution between cheese and rubber bands and that the slope of the budget line is the ratio of the prices of rubber bands and cheese. We can therefore restate the requirement for the optimal division of the consumer’s money between the two commodities in slightly more technical language:

T

3 2

Consumers will select the most desired combination of goods obtainable for their money. The choice will be that point on the budget line at which the budget line is tangent to an indifference curve.

W 1

2

3

4

5

6

Boxes of Rubber Bands

7

Now consider what happens to the consumer’s purchases after a rise in income. We know that a rise in income produces a parallel outward shift in the budget line, such as the shift from BB to CC in Figure 11. The

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Consequences of Price Changes: Deriving the Demand Curve

FIGURE 11 Effects of a Rise in Income When Neither Good Is Inferior

C Optimal consumption curve

Pounds of Cheese

B

E T I2 I1 B 0

1

2

3

C

4

Boxes of Rubber Bands

quantity of rubber bands demanded rises from three to four boxes, and the quantity demanded of cheese increases as well. This change moves the consumer’s equilibrium from tangency point T to tangency point E on a higher indifference curve. A rise in income may or may not increase the demand for a commodity. In Figure 11, the rise in income does lead the consumer to buy more cheese and more rubber bands, but indifference curves need not always be positioned in a way that yields this sort of result. In Figure 12, as the consumer’s budget line rises from BB to CC, the tangency point moves leftward from H to G. As a result, when his income rises, the consumer actually buys fewer rubber bands. This implies that for this consumer rubber bands are an inferior good.

Finally, we come to the main question underlying demand curves: How does a consumer’s choice change if the price of one good changes? We explained earlier that a reduction in the price of a box of rubber bands causes the budget line to swing outward along the horizontal axis while leaving its vertical intercept unchanged. In Figure 13, we depict the effect of a decline in the price of rubber bands on the quantity of rubber bands demanded. As the price of rubber bands falls, the budget line swings from BC to BD. The tangency points, T and E, also move in a corresponding direction, causing the quantity demanded to rise from two to three boxes. The price of rubber bands has fallen and the quantity demanded has risen, so the demand curve for rubber bands has a negative slope. The desired purchase of rubber bands increases from two to three boxes, and the desired purchase of cheese also increases, from 3 pounds to 33⁄4 pounds. The demand curve for rubber bands can be constructed directly from Figure 13. Point T shows that the consumer will buy two boxes of rubber bands when the price of a box is $3.00. Point E indicates that when the price falls to $1.50, quantity demanded rises to three boxes of rubber bands.9 These two pieces of information are shown in Figure 14 as points t and e on the demand curve for rubber bands. By examining the effects of other possible prices for rubber bands (other budget lines emanating from point B in Figure 13), we can find all the other points on the demand curve in FIGURE 13 Consequences of Price Changes

FIGURE 12 6

Pounds of Cheese

Pounds of Cheese

Effects of a Rise in Income When Rubber Bands Are an Inferior Good

C

105

Consumer Choice: Individual and Market Demand

Chapter 5

Optimal consumption curve

B

E

3 34–

T

3

B G C 0

2

3

4

D 8

Boxes of Rubber Bands H

B 0

1

2

3

4

Boxes of Rubber Bands

C How do we know that the price of rubber bands corresponding to the budget line BD is $1.50? Because the $12.00 total budget will purchase at most eight boxes (point D), the price per box must be $12.00/8 5 $1.50.

9

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

106

The Building Blocks of Demand and Supply

Part 2

exactly the same way. The demand curve is derived from the indifference curve by varying the price of the commodity to see the effects of all other possible prices. The indifference curve diagram also brings out an important idea that the demand curve does not show. A change in the price of rubber bands also has consequences for the quantity of cheese demanded because it affects the amount of money left over for cheese purchases. In the example illustrated in Figure 13, the decrease in the price of rubber bands increases the demand for cheese from 3 to 33⁄4 pounds.

FIGURE 14

Price of Rubber Bands per Box

Deriving the Demand Curve for Rubber Bands

D $4.00 t

3.00

e

1.50

D 1

2

3

4

Quantity of Rubber Bands Demanded (boxes)

| SUMMARY | 1. Indifference curve analysis permits economists to study the interrelationships of the demands for two (or more) commodities. 2. The basic tools of indifference curve analysis are the consumer’s budget line and indifference curves. 3. A budget line shows all combinations of two commodities that the consumer can afford, given the prices of the commodities and the amount of money the consumer has available to spend. 4. The budget line is a straight line whose slope equals the ratio of the prices of the commodities. A change in price changes the slope of the budget line. A change in the consumer’s income causes a parallel shift in the budget line. 5. Two points on an indifference curve represent two combinations of commodities such that the consumer does not prefer one combination over the other.

6. Indifference curves normally have negative slopes and are bowed in toward the origin. The slope of an indifference curve indicates how much of one commodity the consumer is willing to give up to get an additional unit of the other commodity. 7. The consumer will choose the point on the budget line that gets him to the highest attainable indifference curve. Normally this will occur at the point of tangency between the two curves. This point indicates the combination of commodities that gives the consumer the greatest benefits for the amount of money he has available to spend. 8. The consumer’s demand curve can be derived from his indifference curve.

| KEY TERMS | budget line 100 indifference curve

slope of a budget line

103

102

slope of an indifference curve (marginal rate of substitution) 103

| TEST YOURSELF | 1. John Q. Public spends all of his income on gasoline and hot dogs. Draw his budget line under several conditions:

a. Approximately how much gasoline and how many hot dogs will Mr. Public buy?

a. His income is $100, and one gallon of gasoline and one hot dog each cost $2.

b. How will these choices change if his income increases to $140? Is either good an inferior good?

b. His income is $150, and the two prices remain the same.

c. How will these choices change if gasoline price rises to $3.00 per gallon?

c. His income is $100, hot dogs cost $2 each, and gasoline costs $2.50 per gallon. 2. Draw some hypothetical indifference curves for John Q. Public on a diagram identical to the one you constructed for Test Yourself Question 1.

3. Explain the information that the slope of an indifference curve conveys about a consumer’s preferences. Use this relationship to explain the typical U-shaped curvature of indifference curves.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Demand and Elasticity A high cross elasticity of demand [between two goods indicates that they] compete in the same market. [This can prevent a supplier of one of the products] from possessing monopoly power over price. U . S. S U P R E ME C OURT, D UP ONT C ELLOP HANE D EC I S I ON , 1 9 5 6

I

n this chapter, we continue our study of demand and demand curves, which we began in the previous chapter. Here we explain the way economists measure how much quantity demanded responds to price changes and what such responsiveness implies about the revenue that producers will receive if they change prices. In particular, we introduce and explain an important concept called elasticity that economists use to examine the relationship between quantity demanded and price.

C O N T E N T S ISSUE: WILL TAXING CIGARETTES MAKE TEENAGERS STOP SMOKING?

ISSUE REVISITED: WILL A CIGARETTE TAX DECREASE TEENAGE SMOKING SIGNIFICANTLY?

REAL-WORLD APPLICATION: POLAROID VERSUS KODAK

ELASTICITY: THE MEASURE OF RESPONSIVENESS

WHAT DETERMINES DEMAND ELASTICITY?

IN CONCLUSION

ELASTICITY AS A GENERAL CONCEPT

| APPENDIX | How Can We Find a Legitimate Demand Curve from Historical Statistics?

Price Elasticity of Demand and the Shapes of Demand Curves

PRICE ELASTICITY OF DEMAND: ITS EFFECT ON TOTAL REVENUE AND TOTAL EXPENDITURE

Income Elasticity Price Elasticity of Supply Cross Elasticity of Demand

THE TIME PERIOD OF THE DEMAND CURVE AND ECONOMIC DECISION MAKING

An Illustration: Did the Advertising Program Work? How Can We Find a Legitimate Demand Curve from the Statistics?

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Part 2

The Building Blocks of Demand and Supply

ISSUE:

WILL TAXING CIGARETTES MAKE TEENAGERS STOP SMOKING?

Public health experts believe that increasing taxes on cigarettes can be a major weapon in the battle to cut teenage smoking. Imagine yourself on a panel of consultants helping a congressional committee draft new legislation to deal with this issue. As the youngest member of the group, you are asked for your opinion about how effective a big tax increase on cigarettes would be in persuading young people to stop smoking. How would you respond? What sorts of statistical data, if any, would you use to help form your opinion? How might you go about analyzing the relevant numbers? This chapter will help you answer such questions. As often happens in economics, we will see that careful investigation brings some surprises. This is true in the case of taxes to discourage teenage smoking. A tax on cigarettes may actually benefit teenagers’—and other citizens’—health. And it will, of course, benefit government finances by bringing in more tax money. Nothing surprising so far. Instead, the surprise is this: The more effective the tax is in curbing teenage smoking, the less beneficial it will be to the government’s finances, and vice versa; the more the tax benefits the government, the less it will contribute to health. The concept of elasticity of demand will make this point clearer.

SOURCE: © Reed Kaestner/Corbis

108

ELASTICITY: THE MEASURE OF RESPONSIVENESS Governments, business firms, supermarkets, and law courts all need a way to measure how responsive demand is to price changes—for example, will a 10 percent cut in the price of commodity X increase quantity of X demanded a little or a lot? Economists measure the responsiveness of quantity demanded to price changes via a concept called elasticity. Marketers sometimes use estimates of elasticity to decide how to price their products or whether to add new product models. A relatively flat demand curve like Figure 1(a)

F I GURE 1 Hypothetical Demand Curves for Film

Df

DS b

$20

a 10

Df

Price per Package

Price per Package

$20

B

A

10

DS

0

1.5 Quantity Demanded (a)

4

0

3

4

Quantity Demanded (b)

NOTE: Quantities are in millions of packages of film per year.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

109

Demand and Elasticity

Chapter 6

indicates that consumers respond sharply to a change in price—the quantity they demand falls by 2.5 units (from 4 units to 1.5 units) when price rises $10. That is, they demand or buy much less of the product when price rises even a little bit. Such a “touchy” curve is called elastic or highly elastic. A relatively steep demand curve like Figure 1(b), which indicates that consumers respond hardly at all to a price change, is called inelastic. In this graph, a $10 price rise cuts quantity demanded by only 1 unit. The precise measure used for this purpose is called the price elasticity of demand, or simply the elasticity of demand. We define elasticity of demand as the ratio of the percentage change in quantity demanded to the associated percentage change in price. Demand is called elastic if, say, a 10 percent rise in price reduces quantity demanded by more than 10 percent. Demand is called inelastic if such a rise in price reduces quantity demanded by less than 10 percent. Why do we need these definitions to analyze the responsiveness to price shown by a particular demand curve? At first, it may seem that the slope of the demand curve conveys the needed information: Curve DsDs is much steeper than curve DfDf in Figure 1, so any given change in price appears to correspond to a much smaller change in quantity demanded in Figure 1(b) than in Figure 1(a). For this reason, it is tempting to call demand in Panel (a) “more elastic.” Slope will not do the job because the slope of any curve depends on the particular units of measurement, and economists use no standardized units of measurement. For example, cloth output may be measured in yards or in meters, milk in quarts or liters, and coal in tons or hundred-weights. Figure 2(a) brings out this point explicitly. In this graph, we return to a pizza example like that in Chapter 5, measuring quantity demanded in terms of pizzas and price in dollars per pizza. A fall in price from $14 to $10 per large pizza (points A and B) raises quantity demanded at Paul’s Pizza Parlor from 280 pizzas to 360 per week—that is, by 80 pizzas. Now look at Figure 2(b), which provides exactly the same information but measures quantity demanded in slices of pizza rather than whole pizzas (with one pizza yielding eight slices). Here, the same price change as before increases quantity demanded, from 8 3 280 5 2,240 slices to 8 3 360 5 2,880 slices—that is, by 640 slices, rather than by 80 pizzas. Visually, the increase in quantity demanded looks eight times as great in Panel (b) as in Panel (a), but all that has changed is the unit of measurement. The 640-unit increase in

The (price) elasticity of demand is the ratio of the percentage change in quantity demanded to the percentage change in price that brings about the change in quantity demanded.

FI GURE 2

$18 17 16 15 14 13 12 11 10 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1

D A Price per Pizza

Price per Pizza

The Sensitivity of Slope to Units of Measurement at Paul’s Pizza Parlor

B

D

0 280 500 360

1,000 1,500 2,000 2,500 3,000

$18 17 16 15 14 13 12 11 10 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 0

D A

B D

500

1,000 1,500 2,000 2,500 3,000 2,240 2,880

Pizzas per Week

Slices of Pizza per Week

(a)

(b)

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

110

Part 2

The Building Blocks of Demand and Supply

Figure 2(b) represents the same increase in quantity demanded as the 80-unit increase in Figure 2(a). Just as you get different numbers for a given rise in temperature, depending on whether you measure it in Celsius or Fahrenheit, so the slopes of demand curves differ, depending on whether you measure quantity in pizzas or in pizza slices. Clearly, then, slope does not really measure responsiveness of quantity demanded to price, because the measure changes whenever the units of measurement change. Economists created the elasticity concept precisely in response to this problem. Elasticity measures responsiveness on the basis of percentage changes in price and quantity rather than on absolute changes. The elasticity formula solves the units problem because percentages are unaffected by units of measurement. If the government defense budget doubles, it goes up by 100 percent, whether measured in millions or billions of dollars. If demand for pizza triples, it rises by 200 percent, whether we measure the quantity demanded in number of pies or slices. The elasticity formula given earlier therefore expresses both the change in quantity demanded and the change in price as percentages.1 Furthermore, elasticity calculates the change in quantity demanded as a percentage of the average of the two quantities: the quantity demanded before the change in price has occurred (Q0) and the quantity demanded after the price change (Q1). In our example, the “before” pizza purchase is 280 (Q0), the quantity sold after the price fall is 360 (Q1), and the average of these two numbers is 320. The increase in number of pizzas bought is 80 pizzas, which is 25 percent of the 320 average of the sales before and after the price change. So 25 percent is the number we use as the purchase increase measure in our elasticity calculation. This procedure is a useful compromise between viewing the change in quantity demanded (80 pizzas) as a percentage of the initial quantity (280) or as a percentage of the final quantity (360). Similarly, the change in price is expressed as a percentage of the average of the “before” and “after” prices, so that, in effect, it represents elasticity at the price halfway between those two prices; that is, the price falls by $4 (from $14 to $10). Because $4 is 33 percent of the average of $14 (P0) and $10 (P1) (that is, $12), we say that in this case a 33 percent fall in price led to a 25 percent rise in quantity of pizza demanded. To summarize, the elasticity formula has two basic attributes: • Each of the changes with which it deals is measured as a percentage change. • Each of the percentage changes is calculated in terms of the average values of the

before and after quantities and prices.

In addition, economists often adjust the price elasticity of demand formula in a third way. Note that when the price increases, the quantity demanded usually declines. Thus, when the price change is a positive number, the quantity change will normally be a negative number; when the price change is a negative number, the quantity change will normally be a positive number. As a consequence, the ratio of the two percentage changes will be a negative number. We customarily express elasticity as a positive number, however. Hence: • Each percentage change is taken as an “absolute value,” meaning that the calculation

drops all minus signs.2

The remainder of this section involves fairly technical computational issues. On a first reading, you may prefer to go directly to the new section that begins on the next page. 2 This third attribute of the elasticity formula—the removal of all minus signs—applies only when the formula is used to measure the responsiveness of quantity demanded of product X to a change in the price of product X. Later in the chapter, we will show that similar formulas are used to measure the responsiveness between other pairs of variables. For example, the elasticity of supply uses a similar formula to measure the responsiveness of quantity supplied to price. In such cases, it is not customary to drop minus signs when calculating elasticity. The reasons will become clearer later in the chapter. 1

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

111

Demand and Elasticity

Chapter 6

We can now state the formula for price elasticity of demand, keeping all three features of the formula in mind: Change in quantity demanded, expressed as a percentage Price elasticity of demand 5 of the average of the before and after quantities divided by the corresponding percentage change in price.

In our example: Elasticity of demand for pizzas 5 1 Q12Q0 2 /average of Q0 and Q1 1 P12P0 2 /average of P0 and P1

5

80/320 25% 5 5 0.76 1 approximately 2 4/12 33%

Price Elasticity of Demand and the Shapes of Demand Curves We noted earlier that looks can be deceiving in some demand curves because their units of measurement are arbitrary. Economists have provided the elasticity formula to overcome that problem. Nonetheless, the shape of a demand curve does convey some information about its elasticity. Let’s see what information some demand curve shapes give with the aid of Figure 3.

1. Perfectly Elastic Demand Curves Panel (a) of Figure 3 depicts a horizontal demand curve. Such a curve is called perfectly elastic (or infinitely elastic). At any price higher than $0.75, quantity demanded will drop to zero; that is, the comparative change in quantity demanded will be infinitely large. Perfect elasticity typically occurs when many producers sell a product and consumers can switch easily from one seller to another if any particular producer raises the price. For example, suppose you and the other students in your economics class are required to buy a newspaper every day to keep up with economic events. If news dealer X, from whom you have been buying the newspaper, raises the price from 75 cents to 80 cents, but the competitor, Y, across the street keeps the old price, then X may lose all her newspaper customers to Y. This situation is likely to prevail whenever an acceptable rival product is available at the going price (75 cents in the diagram). In cases in which no one will pay more than the going price, the seller will lose all of her customers if she raises her price by even a penny. FI GURE 3 Demand Curves with Different Elasticities

$0.75

D

$6 4 3

Quantity Demanded

D 90 Quantity Demanded

(a)

(b)

0

0

Straightline demand A curve

D

C

1 0

2

B

B' D 7

Quantity Demanded (c)

$30 20

A' C' 4 5

Unitelastic demand curve

D Price

D

“Perfectly inelastic” demand curve

Price

Price

“Perfectly elastic” demand curve

Price

D

S T

10 0

U 7

14

D U'

Quantity Demanded (d)

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

112

Part 2

The Building Blocks of Demand and Supply

2. Perfectly Inelastic Demand Curves Figure 3(b) shows the opposite extreme: a completely vertical demand curve. Such a curve is called perfectly inelastic throughout because its elasticity is zero at every point on the curve. Because quantity demanded remains at 90 units no matter what the price, the percentage change in quantity is always zero, and hence the elasticity (which equals percentage change in quantity divided by percentage change in price) is always zero. In this case, consumer purchases do not respond at all to any change in price. Vertical demand curves, such as the one shown in Figure 3(b), occur when a commodity is very inexpensive. For example, you probably will not buy more rubber bands if their prices fall. The demand curve may also be vertical when consumers consider the item in question to be an absolute necessity. For example, if your roommate’s grandfather has a heart attack, the family will buy whatever medicine the doctor prescribes, regardless of the price, and will not purchase any more even if the price falls. 3. (Seemingly Simple) Straight-Line Demand Curves Figure 3(c) depicts a case between these two extremes: a straight-line demand curve that runs neither vertically nor horizontally. Note that, although the slope of a straight-line demand curve remains constant throughout its length, its elasticity does not. For example, the elasticity of demand between points A and B in Figure 3(c) is Change in Q as a percentage of average Q 2/3 66.67% 5 5 5 1.67 Change in P as a percentage of average P 2/5 40%

The elasticity of demand between points A’ and B’ is 2 as a percentage of 6 33.33 percent 5 5 0.33 2 as a percentage of 2 100 percent

The general point is that

A demand curve is elastic when a given percentage price change leads to a larger percentage change in quantity demanded. A demand curve is inelastic when a given percentage price change leads to a smaller percentage change in quantity demanded. A demand curve is unit-elastic when a given percentage price change leads to the same percentage change in quantity demanded.

Along a straight-line demand curve, the price elasticity of demand grows steadily smaller as you move from left to right. That is so because the quantity keeps getting larger, so that a given numerical change in quantity becomes an ever-smaller percentage change. But, simultaneously, the price keeps going lower, so that a given numerical change in price becomes an ever-larger percentage change. So, as one moves from left to right along the demand curve, the numerator of the elasticity fraction keeps falling and the denominator keeps growing larger; thus the fraction that is the elasticity formula keeps declining.

4. Unit-Elastic Demand Curves If the elasticity of a straight-line demand curve varies from one part of the curve to another, what does a demand curve with the same elasticity throughout its length look like? For reasons explained in the next section, it has the general shape indicated in Figure 3(d). That panel shows a curve with elasticity equal to 1 throughout (a unit-elastic demand curve). A unit-elastic demand curve bends in the middle toward the origin of the graph—at either end, it moves closer and closer to the axes but never touches or crosses them. As we have noted, a curve with an elasticity greater than 1 is called an elastic demand curve (one for which the percentage change in quantity demanded will be greater than the percentage change in price); a curve whose elasticity is less than 1 is known as an inelastic curve. When elasticity is exactly 1, economists say that the curve is unit-elastic. Real-world price elasticities of demand seem to vary considerably from product to product. Because people can get along without them, moderately luxurious goods, such

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 6

as expensive vacations, are generally more price elastic—people give them up more readily when their prices rise—than goods such as milk and shirts, which are considered necessities. Products with close substitutes, such as Coke and Pepsi, tend to have relatively high elasticities because if one soft drink becomes expensive, many of its consumers will switch to the other. Also, the elasticities of demand for goods that business firms buy, such as raw materials and machinery, tend to be higher on the whole than those for consumers’ goods. This is because competition forces firms to buy their supplies wherever they can get them most cheaply. The exception occurs when a firm requires a particular input for which no reasonable substitutes exist or the available substitutes are substantially inferior. Table 1 gives actual statistical estimates of elasticities for some industries in the economy.

113

Demand and Elasticity

TABLE 1 Estimates of Price Elasticities

Product

Price Elasticity

Industrial chemicals Shoe repairs and cleaning Food, tobacco, and beverages Newspapers and magazines Data processing, precision and optical instruments Medical care and hospitalization insurance Metal products Purchased meals (excluding alcoholic beverages) Electricity (household utility) Boats, pleasure aircraft Public transportation China, tableware

0.4 0.4 0.5 0.5 0.7 0.8 1.1 1.6 1.9 2.4 3.5 8.8

SOURCES: H. S. Houthakker and Lester D. Taylor, Consumer Demand in the United States, 2d ed. (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1970), pp. 153–158; and Joachim Möller, “Income and Price Elasticities in Different Sectors of the Economy: An Analysis of Structural Change for Germany, the UK and the USA,” in Thjis ten Raa and Ronald Schettkat (eds.), The Growth of Service Industries: The Paradox of Exploding Costs and Persistent Demand, 2001, pp.167–208.

PRICE ELASTICITY OF DEMAND: ITS EFFECT ON TOTAL REVENUE AND TOTAL EXPENDITURE Aside from its role as a measure of the responsiveness of demand to a change in price, elasticity serves a second, very important purpose. As a real illustration at the end of this chapter will show, a firm often wants to know whether an increase in price will increase or decrease its total revenue—the money it obtains from sales to its customers. The price elasticity of demand provides a simple guide to the answer: If demand for the seller’s product is elastic, a price increase will actually decrease total revenue. If demand is exactly unit-elastic, a rise in price will leave total revenue unaffected. If demand is inelastic, a rise in price will raise total revenue. The opposite changes will occur when price falls.

A corresponding story must be true about the expenditures made by the buyers of the product. After all, the expenditures of the buyers are exactly the same thing as the revenues of the seller. These relationships between elasticity and total revenue hold because total revenue (or expenditure) equals price times quantity demanded, P 3 Q, and because a drop in price has two opposing effects on the two components of that formula. It decreases P, and, if the demand curve is negatively sloped, it increases Q. The first effect decreases revenues by cutting the amount of money that consumers spend on each unit of the good. The second effect increases revenues by raising the number of units of the good that the firm sells. The net effect on total revenue (or total expenditure) depends on the elasticity. If price goes down by 10 percent and quantity demanded increases by 10 percent (a case of unit elasticity), the two effects cancel out: P 3 Q remains constant. In contrast, if price goes down by 10 percent and quantity demanded rises by 15 percent (a case of elastic demand), P 3 Q increases. Finally, if a 10 percent price fall leads to only a 5 percent rise in quantity demanded (inelastic demand), P 3 Q falls. We can easily see the relationship between elasticity and total revenue in a graph. First, note that The total revenue (or expenditure) represented by any point on a demand curve (any price-quantity combination), such as point S in Figure 4, equals the area of the rectangle under that point (the area of rectangle 0RST in the figure). This is true because the

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

114

The Building Blocks of Demand and Supply

Part 2

F I GURE 4 An Elastic Demand Curve

$6

Price

5

D R

S

W

4 3 2 1 T 0

4

area of a rectangle equals its height times the width, or 0R 3 RS in Figure 4. Clearly, that is price times quantity, which is exactly total revenue.

To illustrate the connection between elasticity and consumer expenditure, Figure 4 shows an elastic portion of a demand curve, DD. In this figure, when price falls, quantity demanded rises by a greater percentage, increasing total expenditure. At a price of $6 per unit, the quantity sold is V 4 units, so total expenditure is 4 3 $6 5 $24, represented by D the vertical rectangle whose upper-right corner is point S. When price falls to $5 per unit, 12 units are sold. Consequently, the new expenditure ($60 5 $5 3 12), measured by the rectangle 0WVU, exceeds the old expenditure. In contrast, Figure 3(d), the unit-elastic demand curve, shows constant expenditures even though price changes. Total spending is $140 whether the price is $20 and 7 units are sold U (point S) or the price is $10 and 14 units are sold (point T). 12 This discussion also indicates why a unit-elastic demand Quantity Demanded curve must have the shape depicted in Figure 3(d), hugging the axes closer and closer but never touching or crossing them. When demand is unit-elastic, total expenditure must be the same at every point on the curve; that is, it must equal $140 at point S and point T and point U in Figure 3(d). Suppose that at point U (or some other point on the curve), the demand curve were to touch the horizontal axis, meaning that the price would equal zero. Then total expenditure would be zero, not $140. Therefore, if the demand curve remains unit-elastic along its entire length, it can never cross the horizontal axis (where P 5 0). By the same reasoning, it cannot cross the vertical axis (where Q 5 0). Because the slope of the demand curve is negative, any unit-elastic curve simply must get closer and closer to the axes as it moves away from its middle points, as illustrated in Figure 3(d), though it will never touch either axis. We can now see why demand elasticity is so important for business decisions. A firm should not jump to the conclusion that a price increase will automatically add to its profits, or it may find that consumers take their revenge by cutting back a great deal on their purchases. In fact, if its demand curve is elastic, a firm that raises price will end up selling so many fewer units that its total revenue will actually fall, even though it makes more money than before on each unit it sells. Price cuts can also be hazardous—if the elasticity of demand is low. For example, among adult smokers cigarettes have an estimated price elasticity of between 0.25 and 0.50 meaning that we can expect a 10 percent drop in price to induce only a 2.5–5 percent rise in demand.3 This relationship may explain why, when Philip Morris cut the price of Marlboros by about 18 percent, the company’s profits dropped by 25 percent within months. Thus, the strategic value to a business firm of a price rise or a price cut depends very much on the elasticity of demand for its product. But elasticity tells us only how a price change affects a firm’s revenues; we must also consider the effect of costs on the firm’s output decisions, as we will do in Chapter 8.

ISSUE REVISITED:

WILL A CIGARETTE TAX DECREASE TEENAGE SMOKING SIGNIFICANTLY?

We’re back to the issue with which we began this chapter: Will a tax on cigarettes, which increases their price, effectively reduce teenage smoking? We can express the answer to this question in terms of the price elasticity of demand for cigarettes by teenagers. If that demand elasticity is high, the 3 Source: Frank J. Chaloupka, K. Michael Cummings, Christopher P. Morley, and Judith K. Horan, “Tax, Price and Cigarette Smoking: Evidence from the Tobacco Documents and Implications for Tobacco Company Marketing Strategies,” Tobacco Control, 11 (Supplement 1), (2002), pp. i62–i72.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 6

Demand and Elasticity

tax will be effective, because a small increase in cigarette taxes will lead to a sharp cut in purchases by teenagers. The opposite will clearly be true if this demand elasticity is small. It turns out that young people are more sensitive to price increases than adult smokers. The estimates of teenagers’ price elasticity of demand for cigarettes range from about 0.5 all the way up to 1.7.4 This means that if, for example, a tax on cigarettes raises their price by 10 percent, the number of teenage smokers will fall by somewhere between 5 and 17 percent. As we just noted, adults have been found to have a price elasticity of demand for cigarettes of between 0.25 and 0.50—their response to the 10 percent increase in the price of cigarettes will be a decrease of only 2.5–5 percent in the number of adult smokers. So we can expect that a substantial tax on cigarettes that resulted in a significant price increase would cause a higher percentage of teenagers than adults to stop smoking.

We said earlier in the chapter that if a cigarette tax program failed to curb teen smoking, it would benefit the government’s tax collectors a great deal. On the other hand, if the program successfully curbed teenage smoking, then government finances would benefit only a little. The logic of this argument should now be clear. If teen cigarette demand were inelastic, the tax program would fail to make a dent in teen smoking. That would mean that many teenagers would continue to buy cigarettes and government tax revenue would grow substantially as a result of the rise in tax rate. But when elasticity is high, a price rise decreases total revenue (in this case, the amount of tax revenues collected) because quantity demanded falls by a greater percentage than the price rises. That is, with an elastic demand, relatively few teen smokers will remain after the tax increase, so there will be few of them to pay the new taxes. The government will “lose out.” Of course, in this case the tax seeks to change behavior, so the government would no doubt rejoice at its small revenues!

WHAT DETERMINES DEMAND ELASTICITY? What kinds of goods have elastic demand curves, meaning that quantity demanded responds strongly to price? What kinds of goods have inelastic demand curves? Several influences affect consumers’ sensitivity to price changes.

1. Nature of the Good Necessities, such as basic foodstuffs, normally have relatively inelastic demand curves, meaning that the quantities consumers demand of these products respond very little to price changes. For example, people buy roughly the same quantity of potatoes even when the price of potatoes rises. One study estimated that the price elasticity of demand for potatoes is just 0.3, meaning that when the price rises 10 percent, the quantity of potatoes purchased falls only 3 percent. In contrast, many luxury goods, such as restaurant meals, have rather elastic demand curves. One estimate found that the price elasticity of demand for restaurant meals is 1.6, so that we can expect a 10 percent price rise to cut purchases by 16 percent.

2. Availability of Close Substitutes If consumers can easily obtain an acceptable substitute for a product whose price increases, they will switch readily. Thus, when the

Source: Lisa M. Powell, John A. Tauras, and Hana Ross, “The Importance of Peer Effects, Cigarette Prices and Tobacco Control Policies for Youth Smoking Behavior,” Journal of Health Economics, 24, no. 5 (September 2005), pp. 950–968. 4

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

115

Part 2

The Building Blocks of Demand and Supply

market offers close substitutes for a given product, its demand will be more elastic. Substitutability is often a critical determinant of elasticity. The demand for gasoline is inelastic because we cannot easily run a car without it, but the demand for any particular brand of gasoline is extremely elastic, because other brands will work just as well. This example suggests a general principle: The demand for narrowly defined commodities (such as romaine lettuce) is more elastic than the demand for more broadly defined commodities (such as vegetables).

3. Share of Consumer’s Budget The

SOURCE: SELLING SHORT, June 11, 1981, © Universal Press Syndicate. Reprinted with permission. All Rights Reserved.

116

share of the consumer’s budget represented by the purchase of a particular item also affects its elasticity. Very inexpensive items that absorb little of a consumer’s budget tend to have inelastic demand curves. Who is going to buy fewer paper clips if their price rises 10 percent? Hardly anyone. However, many families will be forced to postpone buying a new car, or will buy a used car instead, if auto prices go up by 10 percent.

4. Passage of Time The time period is relevant because the demand for many products is more elastic in the long run than in the short run. For example, when the price of home heating oil rose in the 1970s, some homeowners switched from oil heat to gas heat. Very few of them switched immediately, however, because they needed to retrofit their furnaces to accommodate the other fuel. So, the short-term demand for oil for home heating was quite inelastic. As time passed and more homeowners had the opportunity to purchase and install new furnaces, the demand curve gradually became more elastic.

ELASTICITY AS A GENERAL CONCEPT So far we have looked only at how quantity demanded responds to price changes—that is, the price elasticity of demand. But elasticity has a more general use in measuring how any one economic variable responds to changes in another. From our earlier discussion, we know that a firm will be keenly interested in the price elasticity of its demand curve, but its interest in demand does not end there. As we have noted, quantity demanded depends on other things besides price. Business firms will be interested in consumer responsiveness to changes in these variables as well.

1. Income Elasticity

Income elasticity of demand is the ratio of the percentage change in quantity demanded to the percentage change in income.

For example, quantity demanded depends on consumer incomes. A business firm’s managers will, therefore, want to know how much a change in consumer income will affect the quantity of its product demanded. Fortunately, an elasticity measure can be helpful here, too. An increase in consumer incomes clearly raises the amounts of most goods that consumers will demand. To measure the response, economists use the income elasticity of demand, which is the ratio of the percentage change in quantity demanded to the percentage change in income. For example, foreign travel is quite income-elastic, with middle-income and higher-income people traveling abroad much more extensively than poor people. In contrast, blue jeans, worn by rich and poor alike, show little demand increase as income increases.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 6

117

Demand and Elasticity

2. Price Elasticity of Supply Economists also use elasticity to measure other responses. For example, to measure the response of quantity supplied to a change in price, we use the price elasticity of supply— defined as the ratio of the percentage change in quantity supplied to the percentage change in price, for example, by what percent the supply of wheat increases when the price (at the time of planting) goes up by, say, 7 percent. The logic and analysis of all such elasticity concepts are, of course, perfectly analogous to those for price elasticity of demand.

3. Cross Elasticity of Demand Consumers’ demands for many products are substantially affected by the quantities and prices of other available products. This brings us to the important concept called cross elasticity of demand, which measures how much the demand for product X is affected by a change in the price of another good, Y. This elasticity number is significantly affected by the fact that some products make other products more desirable, but some products decrease consumer demand for other products. There are some products that just naturally go together; for example, for many consumers cream and sugar increase the desirability of coffee, and vice versa. The same is true of mustard or ketchup and hamburgers. In some extreme cases, neither product ordinarily has any use without the other—automobiles and tires, shoes and shoelaces, and so on. Such goods, each of which makes the other more valuable, are called complements. The demand curves of complements are interrelated; that is, a rise in the price of coffee is likely to reduce the quantity of sugar demanded. Why? When coffee prices rise, people drink less coffee and therefore demand less sugar to sweeten it. The opposite will be true of a fall in coffee prices. A similar relationship holds for other complementary goods. At the other extreme, some goods make other goods less valuable. These products are called substitutes. Ownership of a motorcycle, for example, may decrease one’s desire for a bicycle. If your pantry is stocked with cans of tuna fish, you are less likely to rush out and buy cans of salmon. As you may expect, demand curves for substitutes are also related, but in the opposite direction. When the price of motorcycles falls, people may desire fewer bicycles, so the quantity of bicycles demanded falls while that for motorcycles rises. When the price of salmon goes up, people may eat more tuna. Economists use cross elasticity of demand to determine whether two products are substitutes or complements. This measure is defined much like the ordinary price elasticity of demand, except that instead of measuring the responsiveness of the quantity demanded of, say, coffee, to a change in its own price, cross elasticity of demand measures how quantity demanded of one good (coffee) responds to a change in the price of another, say, sugar. For example, if a 20 percent rise in the price of sugar reduces the quantity of coffee demanded by 5 percent (a change of minus 5 percent in quantity demanded), then the cross elasticity of demand will be Percentage change in quantity of coffee demanded 25% 5 5 20.25 Percentage change in sugar price 20%

Two goods are called complements if an increase in the quantity consumed of one increases the quantity demanded of the other, all other things remaining constant. Two goods are called substitutes if an increase in the quantity consumed of one cuts the quantity demanded of the other, all other things remaining constant. The cross elasticity of demand for product X to a change in the price of another product, Y, is the ratio of the percentage change in quantity demanded of X to the percentage change in the price of Y that brings about the change in quantity demanded.

Obviously, cross elasticity is important for business firms, especially when rival firms’ prices are concerned. American Airlines, for example, knows all too well that it will lose customers if it does not match price cuts by Continental or United. Coke and Pepsi provide another clear case in which cross elasticity of demand is crucial, but firms other than direct competitors may well take a substantial interest in cross elasticity. For example, the prices of DVD players and DVD rentals may profoundly affect the quantity of theater tickets that consumers demand.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

118

Part 2

The Building Blocks of Demand and Supply

The cross elasticity of demand measure underlies the following rule about complements and substitutes: If two goods are substitutes, a rise in the price of one of them tends to increase the quantity demanded of the other, so their cross elasticities of demand will normally be positive. If two goods are complements, a rise in the price of one of them tends to decrease the quantity demanded of the other item, so their cross elasticities will normally be negative. Notice that, because cross elasticities can be positive or negative, we do not customarily drop minus signs as we do in a calculation of the ordinary price elasticity of demand.

This result is really a matter of common sense. If the price of a good rises and buyers can find a substitute, they will tend to switch to the substitute. If the price of Japanesemade cameras goes up and the price of American-made cameras does not, at least some people will switch to the American product. Thus, a rise in the price of Japanese cameras causes a rise in the quantity of American cameras demanded. Both percentage changes are positive numbers and so their ratio—the cross elasticity of demand—is also positive. However, if two goods are complements, a rise in the price of one will discourage both its own use and use of the complementary good. Automobiles and car radios are obviously complements. A large increase in automobile prices will depress car sales, and this in turn will reduce sales of car radios. Thus, a positive percentage change in the price of cars leads to a negative percentage change in the quantity of car radios demanded. The ratio of these numbers—the cross elasticity of demand for cars and radios—is therefore negative. In practice, courts of law often evaluate cross elasticity of demand to determine whether particular business firms face strong competition that can prevent them from overcharging consumers—hence, the quotation from the U.S. Supreme Court at the beginning of this chapter. The quotation is one of the earliest examples of the courts using the concept of cross elasticities. It tells us that if two substitute (that is, rival) products have a high cross elasticity of demand (for example, between McDonald’s and Burger King), then neither firm can raise its price much without losing customers to the other. In such a case, no one can legitimately claim that either firm has a monopoly. If a rise in Firm X’s price causes its consumers to switch in droves to a Firm Y’s product, then the cross elasticity of demand for Firm Y’s product with respect to the price of Firm X’s product will be high. That, in turn, means that competition is really powerful enough to prevent Firm X from raising its price arbitrarily. This relationship explains why cross elasticity is used so often in litigation before courts or government regulatory agencies when the degree of competition is an important issue, because the higher the cross elasticity of demand between two products, the stronger must be the competition between them. So cross elasticity is an effective measure of the strength of such competition. The cross elasticity issue keeps coming up in the antitrust context whenever courts need to determine whether or not a firm has monopoly power. For example, in a 2007 dispute between Sun Microsystems and Versata Enterprises, Versata’s claim charging monopolistic behavior by Sun Microsystems was dismissed because Versata failed to adequately address cross elasticities. The issue also appeared when the United States Federal Trade Commission challenged a merger between Whole Foods Market and Wild Oats Markets, claiming that the combination would create a monopoly. (See “How Large Is A Firm’s Market Share? Cross Elasticity as a Test,” on page 119, for more on cross elasticity.)

THE TIME PERIOD OF THE DEMAND CURVE AND ECONOMIC DECISION MAKING One more important feature of a demand curve does not appear on a graph. A demand curve indicates, at each possible price, the quantity of the good that is demanded during a particular time period; that is, all of the alternative prices considered in a demand curve must refer to the same time period. Economists do not compare a price of $10 for Commodity X in January with a price of $8 in September.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 6

Demand and Elasticity

119

How Large Is a Firm’s Market Share? Cross Elasticity as a Test whether it included conventional supermarkets, as well. If two products have a high and positive cross elasticity, they must be close enough substitutes to compete closely; that is, they must be in the same market. But how large must the cross elasticity be before the court decides that two products are in the same market? Although the law has not established a clear elasticity benchmark to determine whether a particular firm is in a relevant market, several courts have determined that a very high cross elasticity number clearly indicates effective competition between two products, meaning that the two items must be in the same market. SOURCE: FTC v. Whole Foods Market, Inc., 548 F.3d 1028 (D.C. Cir. 2008).

SOURCE: © Jon Fisher/Workbook Stock/Jupiterimages

A firm’s “market share” is often a crucial element in antitrust lawsuits (see Chapter 13) for a simple reason. If the firm supplies no more than, say, 20 percent of the industry’s output, courts and regulators presume that the firm is not a monopoly, as its customers can switch their business to competitors if the firm tries to charge too high a price. On the other hand, if the defendant firm in the lawsuit accounts for 90 percent of the industry’s output, courts may have good reason to worry about monopoly power (which we cover in Chapter 11). Such court cases often provide lively debates in which the defendant firms try to prove that they have very small market shares and the plaintiffs seek to establish the opposite. Each side knows how much the defendant firm actually produces and sells, so what do they find to argue about? The dispute is about the size of the total relevant market, which clearly affects the magnitude of the firm’s market share. Ambiguity arises here because different firms do not produce identical products. For instance, are Rice Krispies in the same market as Cheerios? And how about Quaker Oatmeal, which users eat hot? What about frozen waffles? Are all of these products part of the same market? If they are, then the overall market is large, and each seller therefore has a smaller share. If these products are in different markets, the opposite will be true. Many observers argue, as the Supreme Court did in the famous DuPont cellophane case, that one proper criterion for determining the borders of the relevant market is cross elasticity of demand. More recently, in 2008, this issue reappeared in the government’s suit challenging Whole Foods Market’s acquisition of Wild Oats Markets, a case which hinged largely on whether the relevant market consisted of only “premium, natural and organic supermarkets” or

This feature imparts a peculiar character to the demand curve and complicates statistical calculations. For obvious reasons, actual observed data show different prices and quantities only for different dates. Statistical data may show, for example, the one price that prevailed in January and another that occurred at a later date, when that price had changed. Why, then, do economists adopt the apparently peculiar approach of dealing in a demand curve only with the hypothetical prices that may conceivably occur (as alternative An optimal decision is possibilities) in one and the same time period? The answer is that the demand curve’s the one that best serves the strictly defined time dimension arises inescapably from the logic of decision making and objectives of the decision the use of demand curves as a tool in attempts to reach an optimal decision—the decision maker, whatever those objectives may be. It is that moves the decision maker as close to the goal as is possible under the circumstances. When a business seeks to price one of its products for, say, the following six months, it selected by explicit or must consider the range of alternative prices available for that six-month period and the implicit comparison with the possible alternative consequences of each of these possible prices. For example, if management is reasonably choices. The term optimal certain that the best price for the six-month period lies somewhere between $3.50 and connotes neither approval $5.00, it should perhaps consider each of four possibilities—$3.50, $4.00, $4.50, and nor disapproval of the $5.00—and estimate how much it can expect to sell at each of these potential prices dur- objective itself. ing that given six-month period. The result of these estimates may appear in a format similar to that of the following table: Potential Six-Month Expected Quantity This table supplies managers with the information that they need to make Price Demanded optimal pricing decisions. Because the price selected will be the one at which $3.50 75,000 goods are sold during the period in question, all the prices considered in that 4.00 73,000 decision must be alternative possible prices for that same period. The table 4.50 70,000 therefore also contains precisely the information an economist uses to draw a 5.00 60,000 demand curve.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

120

Part 2

The Building Blocks of Demand and Supply

The demand curve describes a set of hypothetical quantity responses to a set of potential prices, but the firm can actually charge only one of these prices. All of the points on the demand curve refer to alternative possibilities for the same time period—the period for which the decision is to be made.

Thus, a demand curve of the sort just described is not just an abstract notion that is useful primarily in academic discussions. Rather, it offers precisely the information that businesses or government agencies need to make rational decisions. However, the fact that all points on the demand curve are hypothetical possibilities for the same period of time causes problems for statistical estimation of demand curves. These problems are discussed in the appendix to this chapter.

REAL-WORLD APPLICATION: POLAROID VERSUS KODAK5 Let’s look at an example from the real world to show how the elasticity concept helps to resolve a concrete problem rather different from those we have been discussing. In 1989, a lengthy trial in a U.S. district court resulted in a judgment against the photographic products manufacturing company Eastman-Kodak for patent infringement of technology that rival firm Polaroid had designed. The court then set out to determine the amount of money Kodak owed Polaroid for its patent infringement during the 10-year period 1976 to 1986, when Kodak had sold very similar instant cameras and film. The key issue was how much profit Polaroid had lost as a result of Kodak’s entry into the field of instant photography, because that would determine how much Kodak would be required to pay Polaroid. Both price elasticity of demand and cross elasticity of demand played crucial roles in the court’s decisions. The court needed accurate estimates of the price elasticity of demand to determine whether the explosive growth in instant camera sales between 1976 and 1979 was mainly attributable to the fall in price that resulted from Kodak’s competition or was attributable to Kodak’s good reputation and the resulting rise in consumer confidence in the quality of instant cameras. If the latter were true, then Polaroid might actually have benefited from Kodak’s entry into the instant camera market rather than losing profits, because Kodak’s presence in the market would have increased the total number of potential customers aware of and eager to try instant cameras. After 1980, instant camera and film sales began to drop sharply. On this issue, the cross elasticity of demand between instant and conventional (35-millimeter) cameras and film was crucial to the explanation. Why? Because the decline in the instant camera market occurred just as the prices of 35-millimeter cameras, film, developing, and printing all began to fall significantly. So, if the decline in Polaroid’s overall sales was attributable to the decreasing cost of 35-millimeter photography, then Kodak’s instant photography activity was not to blame. In that case, the amount that Kodak would be required to pay to Polaroid would decrease significantly. But if the cross elasticity of demand between 35-millimeter photography prices and the demand for instant cameras and film was low, then the cause of the decline in Polaroid’s sales might well have been Kodak’s patent-infringing activity—thus adding to the damage compensation payments to which Polaroid was entitled. On the basis of its elasticity calculations, Polaroid at one point claimed that Kodak was obligated to pay it $9 billion or more. Kodak, however, claimed that it owed Polaroid something in the neighborhood of $450 million. A lot of money was at stake. The judge’s verdict came out with a number very close to Kodak’s figure.

Here it should be pointed out that William Baumol was a witness in this court case, testifying on behalf of Kodak.

5

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

121

Demand and Elasticity

Chapter 6

IN CONCLUSION In this chapter, we have continued our study of the demand side of the market. Rather than focusing on what underlies demand formation, as we did in Chapter 5, we applied demand analysis to business decisions. Most notably, we described and analyzed the economist’s measure of the responsiveness of consumer demand to changes in price, and we showed how this assessment determines the effect of a firm’s price change on the revenues of that enterprise. We illustrated how these concepts throw light not only on business sales and revenues but also on a number of rather different issues, such as smoking and health, the effectiveness of competition among business firms as studied by courts of law, and the determination of penalties for patent infringement. In the next chapter, we turn to the supply side of the market and move a step closer to completing the framework we need to understand how markets work.

| SUMMARY | 1. To measure the responsiveness of the quantity demanded to price, economists calculate the elasticity of demand, which is defined as the percentage change in quantity demanded divided by the percentage change in price, after elimination of the minus sign. 2. If demand is elastic (elasticity is greater than 1), then a rise in price will reduce total expenditures on the product (5 sellers’ total revenue). If demand is unit-elastic (elasticity is equal to 1), then a rise in price will not change total expenditures. If demand is inelastic (elasticity is less than 1), then a rise in price will increase total expenditure. 3. Goods that make each other more desirable (hot dogs and mustard, wristwatches and watch straps) are called complements. When two goods are such that when consumers get more of one of them, they want less of the

other (steaks and hamburgers, Coke and Pepsi), economists call those goods substitutes. 4. Cross elasticity of demand is defined as the percentage change in the quantity demanded of one good divided by the percentage change in the price of another good. Two substitute products normally have a positive cross elasticity of demand. Two complementary products normally have a negative cross elasticity of demand. 5. A rise in the price of one of two substitute products can be expected to shift the demand curve of the other product to the right. A rise in the price of one of two complementary goods tends to shift the other good’s demand curve to the left. 6. All points on a demand curve refer to the same time period—the time during which the price that is being decided upon or otherwise considered will be in effect.

| KEY TERMS | complements

117

cross elasticity of demand (price) elasticity of demand

117 109

elastic, inelastic, and unit-elastic demand curves 112 income elasticity of demand

optimal decision substitutes

119

117

116

| TEST YOURSELF | 1. What variables other than price and advertising are likely to affect the quantity demanded of a product? 2. Describe the probable shifts in the demand curves for a. Airplane trips when airlines’ on-time performance improves b. Automobiles when airplane fares increase c. Automobiles when gasoline prices increase d. Electricity when the average temperature in the United States rises during a particular year (Note: The demand curve for electricity in Maine and the

demand curve for electricity in Florida should respond in different ways. Why?) 3. Taxes on particular goods discourage their consumption. Economists say that such taxes “distort consumer demands.” In terms of the elasticity of demand or elasticity of supply for the commodities in question, what sort of goods would you choose to tax to achieve the following objectives? a. Collect a large amount of tax revenue b. Distort demand as little as possible

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

122

Part 2

The Building Blocks of Demand and Supply

c. Discourage consumption of harmful commodities d. Discourage production of polluting commodities 4. Give examples of commodities whose demand you would expect to be elastic and commodities whose demand you would expect to be inelastic. 5. A rise in the price of a certain commodity from $20 to $25 reduces quantity demanded from 25,000 to 10,000 units. Calculate the price elasticity of demand. 6. If the price elasticity of demand for gasoline is 0.3 and the current price is $3.20 per gallon, what rise in the price of gasoline will reduce its consumption by 10 percent?

7. Which of the following product pairs would you expect to be substitutes, and which would you expect to be complements? a. Shoes and sneakers b. Gasoline and sport-utility vehicles c. Bread and butter d. Instant camera film and regular camera film 8. For each of the product pairs given in Test Yourself Question 7, what would you guess about the products’ cross elasticity of demand? a. Do you expect it to be positive or negative? b. Do you expect it to be a large or small number? Why?

| DISCUSSION QUESTIONS | 1. Explain why elasticity of demand is measured in percentages.

5. Name some events that will cause a demand curve to shift.

2. Explain why the elasticity of demand formula normally eliminates minus signs.

6. Explain why the following statement is true: “A firm with a demand curve that is inelastic at its current output level can always increase its profits by raising its price and selling less.” (Hint: Refer back to the discussion of elasticity and total expenditure/total revenue on pages 113–114.)

3. Explain why the elasticity of a straight-line demand curve varies from one part of the curve to another. 4. A rise in the price of a product whose demand is elastic will reduce the total revenue of the firm. Explain.

| APPENDIX | How Can We Find a Legitimate Demand Curve from Historical Statistics? The peculiar time dimension of the demand curve, in conjunction with the fact that many variables other than price influence quantity demanded, makes it surprisingly difficult to derive a product’s demand curve from historical statistical data. Specialists can and often do derive such estimates, but the task is full of booby traps and usually requires advanced statistical methods and interpretation. This appendix seeks to warn you about the booby traps. It implies, for example, that if you become the marketing manager of a business firm after you graduate from college and you need demand analysis, you will need experts to do the job. This appendix will also show you some mistakes to look for as you interpret the results, if you have reason to doubt the qualifications of the statisticians you hire to calculate or forecast your demand curve. It also gives an intuitive explanation of the legitimate ways in which demand curves may be determined from the statistics. The most obvious way to go about estimating a demand curve statistically is to collect a set of figures on prices and quantities sold in different periods, like those given in Table 2. These points can be plotted on a diagram with price and quantity on the axes, as shown in Figure 5. We can then draw a line (the dashed line TT) that comes as close as possible to connecting

these points (labeled Jan., Feb., and so on), and in this graph the line follows them reasonably well. This line may therefore appear to approximate the demand curve that we are seeking, but unfortunately line TT, which summarizes the data for different points of time, may bear no relationship to the true demand curve. Let us see why, and get some idea as to what can be done about it. You may notice that the prices and quantities represented by the historical points in Figure 5 refer to different periods of time, and that each point on the graph represents an actual (not hypothetical) price and quantity sold at a particular period of time (for example, one point gives the data for January, another for February, and so on). The distinction is significant. Over the entire period covered by the historical data (January through May), the true demand curve, which is what an economist really needs to analyze decision TABLE 2 Historical Data on Price and Quantity

January

February

Quantity Sold 95,000 Price $7.20

91,500 $8.00

March

April

95,000 90,000 $7.70 $8.00

May 91,000 $8.20

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

123

Demand and Elasticity

Chapter 6

FIGU R E 5

FIGURE 6

Plot of Historical Data on Price and Quantity

Plot of Historical Data and True Demand Curves for January, February, and March

Average Price

8.00

T

May $8.20

Feb. April

T F

R

Feb.

8.00

7.80

R

S March

7.60

Average Price

$8.20

7.40 Jan.

7.20 7.00

W

S

7.80

March

M

M

7.60

F J

7.40 7.20

T

Jan.

J

7.00 T 0

90

91

92

93

94

95

96

97

98

Quantity Demanded in Thousands

0

90

91

92

93

94

95

96

97

98

Quantity Demanded in Thousands

problems, may well have shifted because of changes in some of the other variables affecting quantity demanded. The actual events may appear as shown in Figure 6. In January, the demand curve was given by JJ, but by February the curve had shifted to FF, by March to MM, and so on. This figure shows a separate and distinct demand curve for each of the relevant months, and none of them needs to resemble the line we drew as a plot of historical data, TT. In fact, the slope of the historical plot curve, TT, can be very different from the slopes of the true underlying demand curves, as is the case in Figure 6. As a consequence, the decision maker can be seriously misled if she selects her price on the basis of the historical data. She may, for example, think that quantity demanded is quite insensitive to changes in price (as the steepness of line TT seems to indicate), and so may conclude that a price reduction is not advisable. In fact, the true demand curves show that a price reduction would increase quantity demanded substantially, because they are much more elastic than the shape of the estimated line TT in Figure 5 would suggest. For example, if the decision maker were to charge a price of $7.80 rather than $8.00 in February, the historical plot would lead her to expect a rise in quantity demanded of only 1,000 units. (Compare point R, with sales of 91,500 units, and point S, with sales of 92,500 units, in Figure 5.) The true demand curve for February (line FF in Figure 6), however, indicates an increase in sales of 2,500 units (from point R, with sales of 91,500 units, to point W, with sales of 94,000 units). A manager who based her decision on the historical plot,

rather than on the true February demand curve, might be led into serious error. Nevertheless, it is astonishing how often people make this mistake in practice, even when using apparently sophisticated techniques.

AN ILLUSTRATION: DID THE ADVERTISING PROGRAM WORK? Some years ago, one of the largest producers of packaged foods in the United States conducted a statistical study to judge the effectiveness of its advertising expenditures, which amounted to nearly $100 million per year. A company statistician collected year-by-year figures on company sales and advertising outlays and discovered, to his delight, that they showed a remarkably close relationship to one another: Quantity demanded always rose as advertising rose. The trouble was that the relationship seemed just too perfect. In economics, data about demand and any one of the elements that influence it almost never show such a neat pattern. Human tastes and other pertinent influences are too variable to permit such regularity. Suspicious company executives asked one of the authors of this book to examine the analysis. A little thought showed that the suspiciously close statistical relationship between sales and advertising expenditures resulted from a disregard for the principles just presented. The investigator had, in fact, constructed a graph of historical data on sales and advertising expenditure, analogous to TT in Figures 5 and 6 and therefore not necessarily similar to the truly relevant relationship.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

124

Part 2

The Building Blocks of Demand and Supply

have much effect on their sales. In fact, it is reasonable to assume that the quantity of umbrellas demanded in a year depends largely on two influences: their price and the amount of rainfall. As we know, a change in price will lead to a movement along the demand curve without shifting it. Heavy rains will shift the demand curve outward, because people will need to buy more umbrellas, whereas the curve will shift inward in a drought year. Ideally, we would like to find some dates when the demand curve stayed in the same position but the supply curve shifted so that we can obtain a number of different equilibrium points, all of which lie on or near the same demand curve. Suppose that rainfall in St. Louis was as given in Table 3 for the period 2001–2009 and that prices and quantities of umbrellas sold in those years were as indicated by the dots in Figure 7. Notice, first, that in years in which rainfall was highest, such as 2005 and 2009, the dots in the graph lie farthest to the right, whereas the dots for low-rain years lie toward the left, meaning that in rainier years more umbrellas were sold, as our hypothesis about the effect of rain on sales suggests. More important for our purposes, for the four years 2001, 2003, 2004, and 2008, rainfall was about the same—nearly 27 inches. Thus, the demand curve did not shift from one of these years to the next. It is reasonable to conclude that the dots for these four years fell close to the same true demand curve.

It became apparent, after study of the situation, that the stability of the relationship actually arose from the fact that, in the past, the company had based its advertising spending on its sales, automatically allocating a fixed percentage of its sales revenues to advertising. The historical relationship between advertising and demand therefore described only the company’s budgeting practices, not the effectiveness of its advertising program. It showed the effect of sales on advertising, not the effect of advertising on sales, which was the desired information. If the firm’s management had used this curve in planning future advertising campaigns, it might have made some regrettable decisions. The moral of the story: Avoid the use of purely historical curves like TT in making economic decisions.

HOW CAN WE FIND A LEGITIMATE DEMAND CURVE FROM THE STATISTICS? The trouble with the discussion so far is that it tells you only what you cannot legitimately do, but business executives and economists often need information about demand curves—for example, to analyze a pricing decision for next April. How can the true demand curves be found? In practice, statisticians use complex methods that go well beyond what we can cover in an introductory course. Nevertheless, we can (and will) give you a feeling for the advanced methods used by statisticians via a simple illustration in which a straightforward approach helps to locate the demand curve statistically. The problem described in this appendix occurs because demand curves and supply curves (like other curves in economics) shift from time to time. They always shift for some reason, however. As we saw in the chapter, they shift because quantity demanded or supplied is influenced by variables other than price, such as advertising, consumer incomes, and so forth. Recognizing this relationship can help us track down the demand curve—if we can determine the “other things” that affect the demand for, say, widgets, and observe when those other things changed and when they did not, we can infer when the demand curve may have been moving and when it probably wasn’t. Consider the demand for umbrellas. Umbrellas are rarely advertised and are relatively inexpensive, so neither advertising nor consumer incomes should

FIGURE 7 Legitimate Demand Curve Estimation from Statistical Data

S 08 D 2008 Price

S 01 S 2002

2006 S

2001

2007 S 04 2009 2005 S 03

2004

2003 S

D S

Quantity of Umbrellas Sold

TABLE 3 Year

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

Inches of rain

26

18

28

29

35

20

32

27

34

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 6

But the dots for those four years are quite far apart from one another. This separation means that in those years, with the demand curve in the same position, the supply curve must have been shifting. So, if we wish, we can check this supposition statistically, by observing that the supply curve can be expected to shift when there is a change in the cost of the raw materials that go into the production of umbrellas—cloth, steel for the ribs, and plastic for the handles. Changes in this cost variable can be expected to shift the supply curve but not the demand curve, because consumers do not even know these cost numbers. So, just as the rainfall data indicated in what years the demand curve probably moved and when it did not, the input price data can give us such information about the supply curve. To see this, imagine that we have a year-by-year table for those input costs similar to the table for rainfall (the cost table is not shown here); and suppose it tells us that in the four years of interest (2001, 2003, 2004, and 2008), those costs were very different from one another. We can infer that the supply curves in those years were quite different even though, as we

Demand and Elasticity

125

have just seen, the demand curve was unchanging in the same years. Accordingly, the graph shows line DD drawn close to these four dots, with their four supply curves—SS01, SS03, SS04, and SS08—also going through the corresponding points, which are the equilibrium points for those four years. We can therefore infer that all four points are close to the same demand curve and can therefore legitimately interpret DD as a valid statistical estimate of the true demand curve for those years. We derived it by recognizing as irrelevant the dots for the years with much higher or much lower rainfall amounts, in which the demand curve can be expected to have shifted, and by drawing the statistical demand curve through the relevant dots—those that, according to the data on the variables that shift the curves, were probably generated by different supply curves but a common demand curve. The actual methods used to derive statistical demand curves are far more complex. The underlying logic, however, is analogous to that of the process used in this example.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Production, Inputs, and Cost: Building Blocks for Supply Analysis Of course, that’s only an estimate. The actual cost will be higher. AU TO M ECHANI C TO CU S TOM E R

S

uppose you take a summer job working for Al’s Building Contractors, a producer of standardized, inexpensive garages. On your first day of work, you find that Al has bought or signed contracts to buy enough lumber, electric wiring, tools, and other materials to meet his estimated needs for the next two years. The only input choice that has not been made is the number of carpenters that he will hire. So Al is left with only one decision about input purchases: How many carpenters should he sign up for his company? In this chapter, we explore this kind of decision and answer the following question: What input choice constitutes the most profitable way for a business firm to produce its output? When firms make their supply (output) decisions, they examine the likely demand for the products they create. We have already studied demand in the last two chapters, but to understand the firm’s decisions about the supply side of its markets, we must also study its production costs. A firm’s costs depend on the quantities of labor, raw materials, machinery, and other inputs that it buys and on the price it pays for each input. This chapter examines how businesses can select optimal input combinations—that is, the combinations that enable firms to produce whatever output they decide on at the minimum cost for that output. We will discuss the firm’s profit-seeking decisions about output and price in Chapter 8. To make the analysis of optimal input quantities easier to follow, we approach this task in two stages. We begin the chapter with the simpler case, in which the firm can vary the quantity of only one input while all other input quantities are already determined. This assumption vastly simplifies the analysis and enables us to answer two key questions: • How does the quantity of input affect the quantity of output? • How can the firm select the optimal quantity of an input? After that, we deal with the more realistic case where the firm simultaneously selects the quantities of several inputs. We will use the results of that analysis to deduce the firm’s cost curves that will ultimately lead us to analysis of the supply curves that play so important a role in the supply-demand mechanism that we have already discussed.1

C O N T E N T S PUZZLE: HOW CAN WE TELL IF LARGE FIRMS ARE MORE EFFICIENT?

SHORT-RUN VERSUS LONG-RUN COSTS: WHAT MAKES AN INPUT VARIABLE? The Economic Short Run versus the Economic Long Run Fixed Costs and Variable Costs

PRODUCTION, INPUT CHOICE, AND COST WITH ONE VARIABLE INPUT Total, Average, and Marginal Physical Products Marginal Physical Product and the “Law” of Diminishing Marginal Returns The Optimal Quantity of an Input and Diminishing Returns 1

MULTIPLE INPUT DECISIONS: THE CHOICE OF OPTIMAL INPUT COMBINATIONS Substitutability: The Choice of Input Proportions The Marginal Rule for Optimal Input Proportions Changes in Input Prices and Optimal Input Proportions

COST AND ITS DEPENDENCE ON OUTPUT Input Quantities and Total, Average, and Marginal Cost Curves The Law of Diminishing Marginal Productivity and the U-Shaped Average Cost Curve The Average Cost Curve in the Short and Long Run

ECONOMIES OF SCALE The “Law” of Diminishing Returns and Returns to Scale Historical Costs versus Analytical Cost Curves

PUZZLE: RESOLVING THE ECONOMIES OF SCALE PUZZLE Cost Minimization in Theory and Practice

| APPENDIX | Production Indifference Curves Characteristics of the Production Indifference Curves, or Isoquants The Choice of Input Combinations Cost Minimization, Expansion Path, and Cost Curves

Some instructors may prefer to postpone discussion of this topic until later in the course.

127

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

128

Part 2

The Building Blocks of Demand and Supply

PUZZLE:

HOW CAN WE TELL IF LARGE FIRMS ARE MORE EFFICIENT?

SOURCE: AT&T. Recent figures are authors’ estimates.

Annual Average Investment Cost per Telephone Circuit Mile

Modern industrial societies enjoy cost advantages as a result of automation, assembly lines, and sophisticated machinery, all of which often reduce production costs dramatically. But in industries in which equipment with such enormous capacity requires a very large investment, small companies will be unable to reap many of these benefits of modern technology. Only large firms will be able to take advantage of the associated cost savings. When firms can take advantage of such economies of scale, as economists call them, production costs per unit will decline as output expands. The relationship between large size and low costs does not always fit every industry. Sometimes the courts must decide whether a giant firm should be broken up into smaller units. The most celebrated case of this kind involved American Telephone and Telegraph Company (AT&T), which had a monopoly over most of the phone service in F I GURE 1 the United States for nearly 50 years.2 Government agencies and analysts who urged a Historical Costs for breakup of AT&T argued that such a giant firm has great economic power and deprives Long-Distance consumers of the benefits of competition. Opponents of the breakup, including AT&T itTelephone self, pointed out that if AT&T’s large size brought significant economies of scale, then Transmissions smaller firms would be much less efficient producers than the larger one and costs to consumers would have to be correspondingly higher. Who was right? $100 Historical To settle the issue, the courts needed to cost curve know whether AT&T had significant eco75 nomies of scale. Sometimes data like those shown in 50 Figure 1 are offered to the courts when they consider such cases. The data in the 25 figure, which were provided by AT&T, indicate that as the volume of telephone 0 messages rose after 1942, the capital cost 1940 1945 1950 1955 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2004 of long-distance communication by telephone dropped enormously and eventuYear ally fell below 8 percent of its 1942 level. Economists maintain that this graph does Note: Figures are in dollars per year. not constitute legitimate evidence, one way or another, about the presence of economies of scale. Why do they say this? At the end of this chapter, we will study precisely what is wrong with the evidence presented in Figure 1 and consider what sort of evidence really would legitimately have determined whether AT&T had economies of scale.

SHORT-RUN VERSUS LONG-RUN COSTS: WHAT MAKES AN INPUT VARIABLE? As firms make input and output decisions, their actions are limited by previous commitments to equipment, plant, and other production matters. At any point in time, many input choices are precommitted by past decisions. If, for example, a firm purchased machinery a year ago, it has committed itself to that production decision for the remainder of the

2 AT&T is a descendant of the original Bell Telephone Company, affectionately known as “Ma Bell.” The company relinquished the use of the name “Bell” when it was forced by the courts to divest itself of its 22 regional companies in 1982. The companies were reorganized into the “Baby Bells”—seven regional phone companies called Nynex, Bell Atlantic, Ameritech, Bell-South, Southwestern Bell, USWest, and Pacific Telesis Group. In the 1990s, several of these “Baby Bells” merged once again (Bell Atlantic, for example, bough Nynex in 1996). Since then, the consolidation has continued. In 2000, Bell Atlantic bought GTE and changed its name to Verizon. Then, in 2005, Verizon acquired MCI. In the same year, Southwestern Bell (SBC Communications) bought the parent company of the “Baby Bells,” AT&T (along with Cingular), and is now known as AT&T Inc.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 7

129

Production, Inputs, and Cost: Building Blocks for Supply Analysis

machine’s economic life, unless the company is willing to take the loss involved in replacing that equipment sooner. An economist would say that these temporarily unalterable capital commitments are not variable for the time period in question. Firms that employ unionized labor forces may also incur costs that are temporarily not variable if labor contracts commit the firms to employing a certain number of employees or to using employees for a required number of weeks per year. Costs are not variable for some period if they are set by a longer-term financial commitment, such as a contract to buy a raw material, lease a warehouse, or invest in equipment that cannot be resold or transferred without substantial loss of the investment. Even if the firm has not paid for these commitments ahead of time, legally it must still pay for the contracted goods or services.

The Economic Short Run versus the Economic Long Run A two-year-old machine with a nine-year economic life can be an inescapable commitment and therefore represent a cost that is not variable for the next seven years. But that investment is not an unchangeable commitment in plans that extend beyond those seven years, because by then it may benefit the firm to replace the machine in any case. Economists summarize this notion by speaking of two different “runs” (or periods of time) for decision making: the short run and the long run. These terms recur time and again throughout this book. In the short run, firms have relatively little opportunity to change production processes so as to adopt the most efficient way of producing their current outputs, because plant sizes and other input quantities have largely been predetermined by past decisions. Managers may be able to hire more workers to work overtime and buy more supplies, but they can’t easily increase factory size, even if sales turn out to be much greater than expected. Over the long run, however, all such inputs, including plant size, become adjustable. As an example, let’s examine Al’s Building Contractors and consider the number of carpenters that it hires, the amount of lumber that it purchases, and the amounts of the other inputs that it buys. Suppose the company has signed a five-year rental contract for the warehouse space in which it stores its lumber. Ultimately—that is, in the long run—the firm may be able to reduce the amount of warehouse space to which it is committed, and if warehouse space in the area is scarce in the long run, more can be built. Once he has signed the warehouse contract, Al has relatively little immediate discretion over its capacity. Over a longer planning horizon, however, Al will need to replace the original contract, and he will be free to decide all over again how large a warehouse to rent or construct. Much the same is true of large industrial firms. Companies have little control over their plant and equipment capacities in the short run. But with some advance planning, they can acquire different types of machines, redesign factories, and make other choices. For instance, General Motors continued producing the Chevrolet Caprice and other big, rearwheel-drive cars at its plant in Arlington, Texas, for the 1995 and 1996 model years even though the vehicles were not selling well. That was partly because the company knew that it would need time to convert the plant to manufacture its popular full-size pickup trucks, which were in short supply. By the 1997 model year, however, GM engineers were able to convert the plant to truck production. Note that the short run and the long run do not refer to the same time periods for all firms; rather, those periods vary in length, depending on the nature of each firm’s commitments. If, for example, the firm can change its workforce every week, its machines every two years, and its factory every twenty years, then twenty years will be the long run, and any period less than twenty years will constitute the short run.

Fixed Costs and Variable Costs This distinction between the short run and the long run also determines which of the firm’s costs rise or fall when there is a change in the amount of output produced by the firm. Some costs cannot be varied no matter how long the period in question. These are called fixed costs, and they arise when some types of inputs can be bought only in big batches

The short run is a period of time during which some of the firm’s cost commitments will not have ended. The long run is a period of time long enough for all of the firm’s current commitments to come to an end.

A fixed cost is the cost of an input whose quantity does not rise when output goes up, one that the firm requires to produce any output at all. The total cost of such indivisible inputs does not change when the output changes. Any other cost of the firm’s operation is called a variable cost.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

130

The Building Blocks of Demand and Supply

Part 2

or when inputs have a large productive capacity. For example, there is no such thing as a “mini” automobile assembly line capable of producing two cars per week, and, except for extreme luxury models, it is impractical to turn out automobiles without an assembly line. For these reasons, the fixed cost of automobile manufacturing includes the cost of the smallest (least expensive) assembly line that the firm can acquire. These costs are called fixed because the total amount of money spent in buying the assembly line does not vary, whether it is used to produce 10 cars or 100 cars each day, so long as the output quantity does not exceed the assembly line’s capacity. In the short run, some other costs behave very much as fixed costs do; in other words, they are predetermined by previous decisions and are temporarily fixed. But in the long run, firms can change both their capital and labor commitments, which causes more costs to become variable. We will have more to say about fixed and variable costs as we examine other key input and cost relationships.

PRODUCTION, INPUT CHOICE, AND COST WITH ONE VARIABLE INPUT In reality, all businesses use many different inputs whose quantities must be decided. Nevertheless, we will begin our discussion with the short-run case in which there is only a single input that is variable—that is, in which the quantities of all other inputs will not be changed. In doing so, we are trying to replicate in our theoretical analysis what physicists or biologists do in the laboratory when they conduct a controlled experiment: changing just one variable at a time to enable us to see the influence of that one variable in isolation. Thus, we will study the effects of variation in the quantity of one input under the assumption that all other things remain unchanged—that is, other things being equal. TABLE 1 Total Physical Product Schedule for Al’s Building Company

(1)

(2)

Number of Carpenters

Total Product (Garages per Year)

0 1 2 3 4 5 6

0 4 12 24 32 35 30

Total, Average, and Marginal Physical Products We begin the analysis with the first of the firm’s three main questions: What is the relationship between the quantity of inputs utilized and the quantity of production? Al has studied how many of its inexpensive standardized garages his firm can turn out in a year, depending on the number of carpenters it uses. The relevant data are displayed in Table 1. The table begins by confirming the commonsense observation that garages cannot be built without labor. Thus, output is zero when Al hires zero labor input (see the first line of the table). After that, the table shows the rising total garage outputs that additional amounts of labor yield, assuming that the firm’s employees work on one garage at a time and, after it is finished, move on to the next garage. For instance, with a one-carpenter input, total output is 4 garages per year; with two carpenters helping one another and specializing in different tasks, annual output can be increased to 12 garages. After five carpenters are employed in building a garage, they begin to get in one another’s way. As a result, employment of a sixth carpenter actually reduces output from 35 to 30 garages.

Total Physical Product The data in Table 1 appear graphically in Figure 2, which is The firm’s total physical product (TPP) is the amount of output it obtains in total from a given quantity of input. The average physical product (APP) is the total physical product (TPP) divided by the quantity of input. Thus, APP 5 TPP/X, where X 5 the quantity of input.

called a total physical product (TPP) curve. This curve reports how many garages Al can produce with different quantities of carpenters, holding the quantities of all other inputs constant.

Average Physical Product To understand more about how the number of carpenters contributes to output, Al can use two other physical product relationships given in Table 2. The average physical product (APP) measures output per unit of input; it is simply the total physical product divided by the quantity of variable input used—the number of garages produced in a year per carpenter employed. For Al’s firm, it is the total number of garages produced in a year divided by the number of carpenters hired. APP is shown in column (5) of Table 2. For example, because four carpenters can turn out 32 garages annually, the APP of four carpenters is 32/4, or 8 garages per carpenter.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

131

Production, Inputs, and Cost: Building Blocks for Supply Analysis

Chapter 7

FIGU R E 2

TABLE 2

Total Physical Product with Different Quantities of Carpenters Used by Al’s Firm

Al’s Product Schedules: Total, Average, and Marginal Physical Product and Marginal Revenue Product

40

(1)

(2)

(3)

F

Total Output in Garages per Year

35 32 30

E

Marginal Total Physical Physical Product Product (Garages Number (Garages per of per added Carpenters year) carpenter)

G TPP D

25 20 15

C

0 1 2 3 4 5 6

10 B

5 A 0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

Quantity of Carpenters per Year

0 4 12 24 32 35 30

4 8 12 8 3 25

(4)

(5)

Marginal Revenue Product (Thousands of $ per year per added carpenter)

Average Physical Product (Garages per carpenter)

$ 60 120 180 120 45 275

0 4 6 8 8 7 5

Note: Each entry in column (3) is the difference between successive entries in column (2). This is what is indicated by the zigzag lines.

Marginal Physical Product To decide how many carpenters to hire, Al should know how many additional garages to expect from each additional carpenter.3 This concept is The marginal physical known as marginal physical product (MPP), and Al can calculate it from the total physi- product (MPP) of an input is the increase in total output cal product data using the same method we introduced to derive marginal utility from that results from a one-unit total utility in Chapter 5. For example, the marginal physical product of the fourth carpen- increase in the input quantity, ter is the total output when Al uses four carpenters minus the total output when he hires holding the amounts of all only three carpenters. That is, the MPP of the fourth carpenter 5 32 2 24 5 8 garages. We other inputs constant. calculate the other MPP entries in the third column of Table 2 in exactly the same way. Figure 3 displays these numbers in a graph called a marginal physical 14 product curve. Negative Increasing Diminishing 12

Marginal Physical Product and the “Law” of Diminishing Marginal Returns

marginal returns

marginal returns

8 6 MPP in Garages per Year

The shape of the marginal physical product curve in Figure 3 has important implications for Al’s garage building. Compare the TPP curve in Figure 2 with the MPP curve in Figure 3. The MPP curve can be described as the curve that reports the rate at which the TPP curve is changing. MPP is equal to the slope of the TPP curve4 because it tells us how much of an increase in garage output results from each additional carpenter Al hires. Thus, until input reaches three carpenters, the marginal physical product of carpenters increases when Al hires more of them. That is, TPP increases at

marginal returns

10

4 2 0 –2 –4 –6

MPP 0

1

2 3 4 5 Number of Carpenters

6

7

FI GURE 3 If you have studied any calculus, you will recognize “marginal physical product,” which is in essence the first derivative of number of garages produced with respect to number of carpenters hired. 4 The same is true of any total and marginal curves: at any output level the marginal is the slope of the total curve. For example, the slope of an individual’s total utility curve when he has five apples is the change in his total utility when he acquires a sixth apple. But that, by definition, is the marginal utility of the sixth apple. 3

Al’s Marginal Physical Product (MPP) Curve

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

132

Part 2

The Building Blocks of Demand and Supply

an increasing rate (its slope becomes steeper) between points A and D in Figure 2. Between three carpenters and five carpenters, the MPP (the slope of TPP) decreases but still has positive values throughout (that is, it lies above the horizontal axis). Consequently, in this range, TPP is still increasing (its slope, MPP, is greater than zero), but its rate of increase is slower (its slope, MPP, is still positive, but is a declining positive number). That is, in this region, between points D and F in Figure 2, each additional carpenter contributes garage output but adds less than the previous carpenter added. Beyond five carpenters, to the right of point F in Figure 2, the MPP of carpenters actually becomes negative: The total physical product curve starts to decrease as additional carpenters get in one another’s way. Figure 3 is divided into three zones to illustrate these three cases. Note that the marginal returns to additional carpenters increase at first and then diminish. This is the typical pattern, and it parallels what we said about the utility of consumption in Chapter 5. Each additional unit adds some production, but at a decreasing rate. In the leftmost zone of Figure 3 (the region of increasing marginal returns), each additional carpenter adds more to TPP than the previous one did.

IDEAS FOR BEYOND THE FINAL EXAM

The “law” of diminishing marginal returns, which has played a key role in economics for two centuries, states that an increase in the amount of any one input, holding the amounts of all others constant, ultimately leads to lower marginal returns to the expanding input.

This so-called law rests simply on observed facts; economists did not deduce the relationship analytically. Returns to a single input usually diminish because of the “law” of variable input proportions. When the quantity of one input increases while all others remain constant, the variable input whose quantity increases gradually becomes more abundant relative to the others and gradually becomes overabundant. (For example, the proportion of labor increases and the proportions of other inputs, such as lumber, decrease.) As Al uses more carpenters with fixed quantities of other inputs, the proportion of labor time to other inputs becomes unbalanced. Adding more carpenter time does little good and eventually begins to harm production. At this last point, the marginal physical product of carpenters becomes negative. Many real-world cases seem to follow the law of variable input proportions. In China, for instance, farmers have been using increasingly more fertilizer as they try to produce larger grain harvests to feed the country’s burgeoning population. Although its consumption of fertilizer is four times higher than it was 15 years ago, China’s grain output has increased by only 50 percent. This relationship certainly suggests that fertilizer use has reached the zone of diminishing returns.

The Optimal Quantity of an Input and Diminishing Returns We can now address the second question that all firms must ask as they make production decisions: How can the firm select the optimal quantity of an input? To answer this question, look again at the first and third columns of Table 2, which show the firm’s marginal physical product schedule. We will assume for now that a carpenter is paid $50,000 per year and that Al can sell his inexpensive garages for $15,000 each. Now suppose that Al is considering using just one carpenter. Is this choice optimal? Does it maximize his profits? To answer this question we have to consider not only how many garages an additional carpenter provides but also the money value of each garage; that is, we must first translate the marginal physical product into its money equivalent. In this case, the monetary evaluation of TPP shows that the answer is no, one carpenter is not enough to maximize profit, because the marginal physical product of a second carpenter is 8 garages per year, the second entry in marginal physical product column (3) of Table 2. At a price of $15,000 per garage, this extra output would add $120,000 to total revenue. Because the added revenue exceeds the $50,000 cost of the second carpenter, the firm comes out ahead by $120,000 2 $50,000, or $70,000 per year.

Marginal Revenue Product and Input Prices The additional money revenue that a firm receives when it increases the quantity of some input by one unit is called the input’s

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Production, Inputs, and Cost: Building Blocks for Supply Analysis

133

marginal revenue product (MRP). If Al’s garages sell at a fixed price, say $15,000, the marginal revenue product of the input equals its marginal physical product multiplied by the output price:

The marginal revenue product (MRP) of an input is the additional revenue that the producer earns from the increased sales when it uses an additional unit of the input.

Chapter 7

MRP 5 MPP 3 Price of output

For example, we have just shown that the marginal revenue product of the second carpenter is $120,000, which we obtained by multiplying the MPP of 8 garages by the price of $15,000 per garage. The other MRP entries in column (4) of Table 2 are calculated in the same way. The MRP concept enables us to formulate a simple rule for the optimal use of any input. Specifically: When the marginal revenue product of an input exceeds its price, it pays the firm to use more of that input. Similarly, when the marginal revenue product of the input is less than its price, it pays the firm to use less of that input.

Let’s test this rule in the case of Al’s garages. We have observed that two carpenters cannot be the optimal input because the MRP of a second carpenter ($120,000) exceeds his wages ($50,000). What about a third carpenter? Table 2 shows that the MRP of the third carpenter (12 3 $15,000 5 $180,000) also exceeds his wages; thus, stopping at three carpenters also is not optimal. The same is true for a fourth carpenter, because his MRP of $120,000 still exceeds his $50,000 price. The situation is different with a fifth carpenter, however. Hiring a fifth carpenter is not a good idea because his MRP, which is 3 3 $15,000 5 $45,000, is less than his $50,000 cost. Thus, the optimal number of carpenters for Al to hire is four, yielding a total output of 32 garages. Notice the crucial role of diminishing returns in this analysis. When the marginal physical product of carpenter begins to decline, the money value of that product falls as well—that is, the marginal revenue product also declines. The producer always profits by expanding input use until diminishing returns set in and reduce the MRP to the price of the input. So Al should stop increasing his carpenter purchases when MRP falls to the price of a carpenter. A common expression suggests that it does not pay to continue doing something “beyond the point of diminishing returns.” As we see from this analysis, quite to the contrary, it normally does pay to do so! The firm has employed the proper amount of input only when diminishing returns reduce the marginal revenue product of the input to the level of its price, because then the firm will be wasting no opportunity to add to its total profit. Thus, the optimal quantity of an input is that at which MRP equals its price (P). In symbols: MRP 5 P of input

The logic of this analysis is exactly the same as that used in our discussion of marginal utility and price in Chapter 5. Al is trying to maximize profits—the difference between the total revenue yielded by his carpenter input and the total cost of buying that input. To do so, he must increase his carpenter usage to the point where price equals marginal revenue product, just as an optimizing consumer keeps buying until price equals marginal utility.

MULTIPLE INPUT DECISIONS: THE CHOICE OF OPTIMAL INPUT COMBINATIONS5 Up to this point we have simplified our analysis by assuming that the firm can change the quantity of only one of its inputs and that the price the product can command does not change, no matter how large a quantity the producer offers for sale (the fixed price is $15,000 for Al’s garages). Of course, neither of these assumptions is true in reality. In Chapter 8, we will explore the effect of product quantity decisions on prices by bringing

Instructors may want to teach this part of the chapter (up to page 133) now, or they may prefer to wait until they come to Chapters 19 and 20 on the determination of wages, interest rates, profit, and rent.

5

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

134

Part 2

The Building Blocks of Demand and Supply

The “law” of diminishing marginal returns crops up a lot in ordinary life, not just in the world of business. Consider Jason and his study habits: He has a tendency to procrastinate and then cram for exams the night before he takes them, pulling “all-nighters” regularly. How might an economist describe Jason’s payoff from an additional hour of study in the wee hours of the morning, relative to that of Colin, who studies for two hours every night?

SOURCE: © PNC/Brand X Pictures/Jupiterimages

Closer to Home: The Diminishing Marginal Returns to Studying

in the demand curve. First we must deal with the obvious fact that a firm must decide on the quantities of each of the many inputs it uses, not just one input at a time. That is, Al must decide not only how many carpenters to hire but how much lumber and how many tools to buy. Both of the latter decisions clearly depend on the number of carpenters in his team. So, once again, we must examine the two basic and closely interrelated issues: production levels and optimal input quantities. But this time, we will allow the firm to select the quantities of many inputs. By expanding our analysis in this way, we can study a key issue: how a firm, by its choice of production method (also called its production technology), can make up for decreased availability of one input by using more of another input.

Substitutability: The Choice of Input Proportions Just as we found it useful to start the analysis with physical output or product in the onevariable-input case, we will start with physical production in the multiple-variable-input case. Firms can choose among alternative types of technology to produce any given product. Many people mistakenly believe that management really has very little choice when selecting its input proportions. Technological considerations alone, they believe, dictate such choices. For example, a particular type of furniture-cutting machine may require two operators working for an hour on a certain amount of wood to make five desks—no more and no less. But this way of looking at the possibilities is an overly narrow view of the matter. In reality, the furniture manufacturer can choose among several alternative production processes for making desks. For example, simpler and cheaper machines might be able to change the same pile of wood into five desks, but only by using more than two hours of labor. Or, the firm might choose to create the desks with simple hand tools, which would require many more workers and no machinery at all. The firm will seek the method of production that is least costly. In advanced industrial societies, where labor is expensive and machinery is cheap, it may pay to use the most automated process. For example, Caterpillar, a U.S. heavy-vehicle and machinery producer, curbed its high labor costs by investing in computers that enabled it to manufacture twice as many truck engines with the same number of people. However, in less developed countries, where machinery is scarce and labor is abundant, making things by hand may be the most economical solution. An interesting example can be found in rural India, where company records are often still handwritten, not computerized, as is widely true in the United States. We conclude that firms can generally substitute one input for another. A firm can produce the same number of desks with less labor, if it is prepared to sink more money into

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 7

Production, Inputs, and Cost: Building Blocks for Supply Analysis

machinery. Whether or not it pays to make such a substitution depends on the relative costs of labor and machinery. Several general conclusions follow from this discussion: • Normally, a firm can choose among different technological options to produce a particular volume of output. Technological considerations rarely fix input proportions immutably. • Given a target production level, a firm that cuts down on the use of one input (say, labor) will normally have to increase its use of another input (say, machinery). This trade-off is what we mean when we speak of substituting one input for another. • The combination of inputs that represents the least costly way to produce the desired level of output depends on the relative prices of the various inputs.

The Marginal Rule for Optimal Input Proportions Choosing the input proportions that minimize the cost of producing a given output is really a matter of common sense. To understand why, let us turn, once again, to marginal analysis of the decision. As before, Al is considering whether to buy more expensive tools that will enable him to produce his garages using fewer carpenters or to do the reverse. The two inputs, tools and carpenters, are substitutes; if the firm spends more on tools, it needs fewer carpenters. But the tools are not perfect substitutes for labor. Tools need carpenters to operate them, and tools are not endowed with the judgment and common sense that are needed if something goes wrong. Of course, a carpenter without tools is also not very productive, so Al gains a considerable benefit by acquiring balanced relative quantities of the two inputs. If he uses too much of one and too little of the other, the output of the firm will suffer. In other words, it is reasonable to assume that diminishing returns will accompany excessive substitution of either input for the other. As he substitutes more and more labor for expensive machinery, the marginal physical product of the added labor will begin to decline. How should Al decide whether to spend more on tools and less on labor, or vice versa? The obvious—and correct—answer is that he should compare what he gets for his money by spending, say, $100 more on labor or on tools. If he gets more (a greater marginal revenue product) by spending this amount on labor than by spending it on tools, clearly it pays Al to spend that money on labor rather than on tools. In that case, it pays him to spend somewhat less on tools than he had been planning to do and to transfer the money he thereby saves to purchasing more carpenter labor. So we have the following three conclusions: 1. If the marginal revenue product of the additional labor that Al gets by spending, say, a dollar more on carpenters is greater than the marginal revenue product he receives from spending the same amount on tools, he should change his plans and devote more of his spending to labor than he had planned and less to tools. 2. If the marginal revenue product of an additional dollar spent on labor is less than the marginal revenue product of an additional dollar spent on tools, Al should increase his spending on tools and cut his planned spending on labor. 3. If the marginal revenue products of an additional dollar spent on either labor or tools are the same, Al should stick to his current purchase plans. There is nothing to be gained by switching the proportions of his spending on the two inputs.6 There is only one more step. Suppose, for example, that the MRP per dollar is greater for labor than that for tools. Then, as we have just seen, Al should spend more money on labor than originally planned and less on tools. But where should this switch in spending stop? Should the transfer of funds continue until Al stops spending on tools altogether, because the MRP per dollar is greater for labor than for tools? Such an answer makes no Calculation of the marginal revenue product per dollar spent on an input is easy if we know the marginal revenue product of the input and the price of the input. For example, we know from Table 2 that the MRP of a third carpenter is $180,000 and his wage is $50,000. Thus, his MRP per dollar spent on his wages is $180,000/$50,000 5 $3.60. More generally, the MRP per dollar spent on any input, X, is the MRP of X divided by the price of X. 6

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

135

136

Part 2

The Building Blocks of Demand and Supply

We have just discussed how a firm can determine the most economical input combination for any given level of output. This analysis does not apply only to business enterprises. Nonprofit organizations such as your own college are interested in finding the least costly ways to accomplish a variety of tasks (for example, maintaining the grounds and buildings); government agencies (sometimes) seek to meet their objectives at minimum costs; even in the home, we can find many ways to save money. Thus, our present analysis of cost minimization is widely applicable.

SOURCE: © Michael Malyszko/Taxi/Getty Images

Beyond Farms and Firms: The General Rule for Optimal Input Proportions

sense—a worker without tools is not very productive. The correct answer is that, by the “law” of diminishing returns, when Al buys more and more carpenter time, the initially higher MRP of carpenters will decline. As he spends less and less on tools, tools will become scarcer and more valuable and their initially lower MRP will rise. So, as Al transfers more money from tools to carpenters, the MRPs per dollar for the inputs will get closer and closer to one another, and they will eventually meet, which is when the proportions of Al’s spending allocated to the two inputs will have reached the optimal level. At that point, there is no way he can get more for his money by changing the proportions of those inputs that he hires or buys.

Changes in Input Prices and Optimal Input Proportions The commonsense reasoning behind the rule for optimal input proportions leads to an important conclusion. Let’s say that Al is producing seven garages at minimum cost. Suppose that the wage of a carpenter falls, but the price of tools remains the same. This means that a dollar will now buy a larger quantity of labor than before, thus increasing the marginal revenue product per dollar spent on carpenters—a dollar will now buy more carpenter labor and more of its product than it did before. But because tool prices have not changed, the marginal revenue product obtainable by spending an additional dollar on tools will also be unchanged. So, if Al had previously devoted the right proportions to spending on carpenters and spending on tools, that will no longer be true. If, previously, the marginal revenue product per dollar spent on carpenters equaled the marginal revenue product per dollar spent on tools, this relationship will have changed so that Marginal revenue product per dollar spent on carpenters > Marginal revenue product per dollar spent on tools

That is, the proportion between the two inputs will no longer be optimal. Clearly, Al will be better off if he increases his spending on carpenters and reduces his spending on tools. Looked at another way, to restore optimality, the MRP per dollar spent on carpenters must fall to match the MRP per dollar spent on tools. But, by the “law” of diminishing returns, the MRP of carpenters will fall when the use of carpenters is increased. Thus, a fall in the price of carpenters prompts Al to use more carpenter time, and if the increase is

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 7

Production, Inputs, and Cost: Building Blocks for Supply Analysis

sufficiently large, it will restore equality in the marginal revenue products per dollar spent on the two inputs. In general, we have the commonsense result that As any one input becomes more costly relative to competing inputs, the firm is likely to substitute one input for another—that is, to use less of the input that has become more expensive and to use more of competing inputs.

COST AND ITS DEPENDENCE ON OUTPUT Having analyzed how the firm decides on its input quantities, we now take the next step toward our analysis of the implications for pricing and output quantity of the product it sells to consumers. For this purpose, the firm needs to know, among other things, how much it will cost to produce different output quantities. Clearly, this cost—the amount of money that the firm spends on production—will depend on how much it produces and what quantities of input it will need to do the job. How do we measure the cost relationships?

Input Quantities and Total, Average, and Marginal Cost Curves We must turn now to the third of the three main questions that a firm must ask: How do we derive the firm’s cost relationships from the input decisions that we have just explained? We will use these cost relationships when we analyze the firm’s output and pricing decisions in Chapter 8, in which we will study the last of the main components of our analysis of the market mechanism: How much of its product or service should the profitmaximizing firm produce? The most desirable output quantity for the firm clearly depends on how costs change as output varies. Economists typically display and analyze such information in the form of cost curves. Indeed, because we will use marginal analysis again in our discussion, we will need three different cost curves: the total cost curve, the average cost curve, and the marginal cost curve. These curves follow directly from the nature of production. The technological production relationships for garage-building dictate the amount of carpenter time, the type and quantity of tools, the amount of lumber, and the quantities of the other inputs that Al uses to produce any given number of garages. This technological relationship for carpenters appeared earlier in Figure 2. From these data on carpenter usage and the price of a carpenter, plus similar information on tools, lumber, and other inputs, and the decision on the optimal proportions among those inputs, Al can determine how much it will cost to produce any given number of garages. Therefore, the relevant cost relationships depend directly on the production relationships we have just discussed. The calculation of the firm’s total costs from its physical product schedule that we use here assumes that the firm cannot influence the market price of carpenters or the prices of other inputs, because these are fixed by union contracts and other such influences. Using this assumption, let us begin with the portion of the cost calculation that applies to carpenters. The method is simple: For each quantity of output, record from Table 1 or Figure 2 the number of carpenters required to produce it. Then multiply that quantity of carpenters by the assumed annual average wage of $50,000.

Total Costs In addition to the cost of carpenters, Al must spend money on his other inputs, such as tools and lumber. Furthermore, his costs must include the opportunity costs of any inputs that Al himself contributes—such as his own labor, which he could have used to earn wages by taking a job in another firm, and his own capital that he has invested in the firm, which he could have invested, say, in interest-paying government bonds. The costs of the other inputs are calculated, essentially, in the same manner as the cost of carpenters—by determining the quantity of each input that will optimally

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

137

138

Part 2

The Building Blocks of Demand and Supply

be used in producing any given number of garages and then multiplying that input quantity by its price. To calculate the total cost Al must cover to build, say, four garages per year, we have the following simple formula: The total cost of four garages 5 (The number of carpenters used 3 The wage per carpenter) 1 (The amount of lumber that will be used 3 The price of lumber) 1 (The number of pounds of nails that will be used 3 The price of nails) 1 . . .

Using this calculation and data such as those in Table 1, we obtain directly the total costs for different output quantities shown in Table 3. For example, row (4), column (2), of Table 3 indicates that if he wants to produce three garages per year, Al needs to purchase quantiTABLE 3 ties of labor time, lumber, and other inputs Al’s (Variable) Cost Schedules whose total cost is $54,000. The other numbers (1) (2) (3) (4) in the second column of Table 3 are interpreted Marginal similarly. To summarize the story: Total Variable Average Variable Cost Variable Total Cost (Thousands Cost Product (Thousands of $ per (Thousands (Garages of $ added of $ per per year) per year) garage) garage) 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

$0 28 44 54 62 68 75 84 100 132 178

$28 16 10 8 6 7 9 16 32 46

$0 28 22 18 15.5 13.6 12.5 12 12.5 14.7 (approx.) 17.8

The marginal product relationships enable the firm to determine the input proportions and quantities needed to produce any given output at lowest total cost. From those input quantities and the prices of the inputs, we can determine the total cost (TC) of producing any level of output. Thus, the relationship of total cost to output is determined by the technological production relationships between inputs and outputs and by input prices.

Total, Average, and Marginal Cost Curves

Two other cost curves—the average cost (AC) and marginal cost (MC) curves—provide information crucial for our analysis. We can calculate these curves directly from the total cost curve, just as Table 2 calculated average and marginal physical product from total physical product. For any given output, average cost is defined as total cost divided by quantity produced. For example, Table 3 shows that the total cost of producing seven garages is $84,000, so the average cost is $84,000/7, or $12,000 per garage. Similarly, we define the marginal cost as the increase in total cost that arises from the production of an additional garage. For example, the marginal cost of the fifth garage is the difference between the total cost of producing five garages, $68,000, and the total cost of producing four garages, $62,000; that is, the marginal cost of the fifth garage is $6,000. Figure 4 shows all three curves—the total, average, and marginal cost curves. The TC curve is generally assumed to rise fairly steadily as the firm’s output increases. After all, Al cannot expect to produce eight garages at a lower total cost than he can produce five, six, or seven garages. The AC curve and the MC curve both look roughly like the letter U—first going downhill, then gradually turning uphill again. We will explore the reason for and implications of this U-shape later in the chapter. So far, we have taken into account only the variable costs, or the costs that depend on the number of garages Al’s firm builds. That’s why these costs are labeled as “variable” in the table and the graph. But there are other costs, such as the rent Al pays for the company office, that are fixed; that is, they stay the same in total, no matter how many garages he produces, at least within some limits. Of course, Al cannot obtain these fixedcost inputs for free. Their costs, however, are constants—they are positive numbers and not zero.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 7

Production, Inputs, and Cost: Building Blocks for Supply Analysis

Total Fixed Cost and Average Fixed Cost Curves Although variable costs are

139

Marginal Variable Cost per Added Garage (thousands $)

Average Variable Cost per Garage (thousands $)

Total Variable Cost per Year (thousands $)

FI GURE 4 only part of combined total costs (which include both fixed and variable costs), the Al’s Total Variable Cost, Average Variable total and average cost curves that include both types of costs have the same general Cost, and Marginal shape as those shown in Figure 4. In contrast, the curves that record total fixed costs Variable Cost (TFC) and average fixed costs (AFC) have very special shapes, illustrated in Figure 5. By definition, TFC remains the same whether the firm produces a little or a 200 lot—so long as it produces something. As a result, any TVC 180 Total (Variable) TFC curve is a horizontal straight line like the one 160 Cost 140 shown in Figure 5(a). It has the same height at every 120 output. 100 Average fixed cost, however, gets smaller and 80 60 smaller as output increases, because AFC (which equals 40 TFC/Q) (where Q represents quantity of output) falls as 20 output (the denominator) rises for constant TFC. Busi0 2 4 6 8 10 nesspeople typically put the point another way: Any increase in output spreads the fixed cost (which they often Quantity of Garages (a) call “overhead”) among more units, meaning that less of it is carried by any one unit. For example, suppose that Al’s firm’s total fixed cost is $12,000 per year. When 30 C he produces only two garages, the entire $12,000 of 25 fixed cost must be borne by those two garages; that is, Average (Variable) the average fixed cost is $6,000 per garage. But if Al proCost 20 AVC duces three garages, the fixed cost per garage falls to 15 $4,000 5 $12,000/3 (Table 4). D AFC can never reach zero. Even if Al were to pro10 duce one million garages per year, each garage would 5 have to bear, on average, one-millionth of the TFC— which is still a positive number (although minuscule). 2 4 6 8 10 0 It follows that the AFC curve gets lower and lower as Quantity of Garages output increases, moving closer and closer to the hori(b) zontal axis but never crossing it. This pattern appears in Figure 5(b). Finally, we may note that marginal fixed costs MVC 50 exhibit a very simple behavior: Marginal fixed costs are 45 always zero. Building an additional garage does not 40 add a penny to Al’s annual office rent, which is 35 30 fixed at $12,000, according to the lease. Looked at Marginal (Variable) 25 Cost another way, because the total fixed cost stays 20 unchanged at $12,000, no matter how many garages 15 10 are produced, the marginal fixed cost of, say, a fifth 5 garage is the total fixed cost of five garages minus 2 4 6 8 10 0 the total fixed cost of four garages 5 $12,000 2 $12,000 5 0. Quantity of Garages (c) Having divided costs into fixed costs (FC) and variable costs (VC), we can express corresponding rules for Note: Quantity is in garages per year. total average and marginal costs: TC 5 TFC + TVC AC 5 AFC + AVC MC 5 MFC + MVC 5 0 + MVC 5 MVC

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

140

The Building Blocks of Demand and Supply

Part 2

F I GURE 5

TABLE 4

Fixed Costs: Total and Average

Al’s Fixed Costs

14

(1)

(2)

Number of Garages

Total Fixed Cost (Thousands of $ per year)

0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

$ 12 12 12 12 12 12 12 12 12 12 12

Total Fixed Cost per Year (thousands of $)

TFC 12 10 8 6 4 2 0

1

2

3

4

5 6 Output (a)

7

8

9

10

Average Fixed Cost per Garage (thousands of $)

14

(3)

(4)

Marginal Fixed Cost

Average Fixed Cost (Thousands of $ per garage)

$0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0

— $ 12 6 4 3 2.4 2 1.7 1.5 1.33 1.2

12 10 8

The Law of Diminishing Marginal Productivity and the U-Shaped Average Cost Curve

6 4

0

The preceding discussion of fixed and variable costs enables us to consider the configuration of the average cost curve and the production implications of its typical 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 Output U-shape. The typical curve looks like Figure 4(b) and is (b) roughly U-shaped: The left-hand portion of the curve is downward-sloping and the right-hand portion is upwardsloping. AC declines when output increases in the lefthand portion of the curve for two reasons. The first reason makes intuitive sense and pertains to the fixed-cost portion of AC and the fact that these fixed costs are divided over more units of product as output increases. As Figure 5(b) shows, the average fixed-cost curve always falls as output increases, and it falls very sharply at the left-hand end of the AFC curve. Because AC equals AFC plus average variable costs (AVC), the AC curve for virtually any product contains a fixed-cost portion, AFC, which falls steeply at first when output increases. So, as these fixed costs are spread over more units as output increases, the AC curve for any product should have a downward-sloping portion such as CD in Figure 4(b), which is characterized by decreasing average cost. The second reason why AC curves have a downward-sloping section relates to changing input proportions. As the firm increases the quantity of one input while holding other inputs constant, the marginal physical product relationship tells us that MPP will first rise. As a result, average costs will decrease. For example, if Al is using very few carpenters relative to the amounts of other inputs, a rise in the quantity of carpenters will, at first, yield increasing additions to output (in the range of increasing marginal physical product of carpenters illustrated in the left-hand part of Figure 3). As the quantity produced increases, the average cost of output falls. Now look at any point to the right of point D in Figure 4(b). Average cost rises as output increases along this section of the curve. Why does the portion of the curve with decreasing AC end? Although it may not seem very important in our example, increasing administrative costs are a major source of increasing average cost in practice. AFC

2 1

2

3

NOTE: Output is in garages per year.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 7

141

Production, Inputs, and Cost: Building Blocks for Supply Analysis

Sheer size makes firms more complicated to run. Large firms tend to be relatively bureaucratic, impersonal, and costly to manage. As a firm becomes very large and loses top management’s personal touch, bureaucratic costs ultimately rise disproportionately. Typically, this change ultimately drives average cost upward. The output at which average costs stop decreasing and begin to rise varies from industry to industry. Other things being equal, the greater the relative size of fixed costs, the higher the output at which the switch-over occurs.7 For example, it occurs at a much larger volume of output in automobile production than in farming, which is why no farms are as big as even the smallest auto producer. Automobile producers must be larger than farms because the fixed costs of automobile production are far greater than those in farming, so spreading the fixed cost over an increasing number of units of output keeps AC falling far longer in auto production than in farming. Thus, although firms in both industries may have U-shaped AC curves, the bottom of the U occurs at a far larger output in auto production than in farming. The AC curve for a typical firm is U-shaped. We can attribute its downward-sloping segment to increasing marginal physical products and to the fact that the firm spreads its fixed costs over ever-larger quantities of outputs. Similarly, we can attribute the upwardsloping segment primarily to the disproportionate rise in administrative costs that occurs as firms grow large.

The Average Cost Curve in the Short and Long Run At the beginning of this chapter, we observed that some inputs are variable and some are precommitted, depending on the pertinent time horizon. It follows that The average (and marginal and total) cost curve depends on the firm’s planning horizon— how far into the future it tries to look when making its plans. The average (and total) cost curve for the long run differs from that for the short run because, in the long run, input quantities generally become variable.

Average Cost per Pound of Chicken

We can, in fact, be much more specific about the relationships between the short-run and long-run average cost curves. Consider, as an example, the capacity of Naomi’s poultry farm. In the short run, she can choose to raise, at most, only the number of chickens that she can crowd into her coops’ current capacity. Of course, she can always build more chicken coops; however, FIGURE 6 if it turns out that the coops are much larger than she needs, Short-Run and Long-Run Average Cost Curves Naomi cannot simply undo the excessive space and get back the money that she has spent on it. But, in the long run, when they need to be replaced, she can choose among new coops of different sizes. If she constructs a smaller coop, Naomi’s AC curve looks like curve SL in Figure 6. That means that if she is pleasantly S surprised as sales grow to 100 pounds of chicken per week, average cost will be $0.40 per pound of chicken (point V). She L U B V may then wish she had built bigger coops with an AC curve of $0.40 0.35 T BG, which would have enabled her to cut the cost per pound W of chicken to $0.35 (point W). In the short run, though, Naomi can do nothing about this decision; the AC curve remains SL. 0 40 100 Similarly, had she built the larger coops, the short-run AC curve would be BG, and the farm would be committed to this Output in Pounds of Chicken cost curve even if her sales were to decline sharply.

Empirical evidence confirms this view, although it suggests that the bottom of the U is often long and flat. That is to say, a considerable range of outputs often fall between the regions of decreasing and increasing average cost. In this intermediate region, the AC curve is approximately horizontal, meaning that, in this range, AC does not change when output increases.

7

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

G

142

Part 2

The Building Blocks of Demand and Supply

In the long run, however, Naomi must replace the coops, and she is free to decide their size all over again. If Naomi expects sales of 100 pounds of chicken per week, she will construct larger coops and have an average cost of $0.35 per pound of chicken (point W). If she expects sales of only 40 pounds of chicken per week, she will arrange for smaller buildings with an average cost of $0.40 per pound of chicken (point U). In sum, in the long run, a firm will select the plant size (that is, the short-run AC curve) that is most economical for the output level that it expects to produce. The longrun average cost curve therefore consists of all of the lower segments of the short-run AC curves. In Figure 6, this composite curve is the brick-colored curve, STG. The long-run average cost curve shows the lowest possible short-run average cost corresponding to each output level.

ECONOMIES OF SCALE

Production is said to involve economies of scale, also referred to as increasing returns to scale, if, when all input quantities are increased by X percent, the quantity of output rises by more than X percent.

We have now put together the basic tools we need to address the question posed at the beginning of this chapter: Does a large firm benefit from substantial economies of scale that allow it to operate more efficiently than smaller firms? To answer this question, we need a precise definition of this concept. An enterprise’s scale of operation arises from the quantities of the various inputs that it uses. Consider what happens when the firm doubles its scale of operations. For example, suppose Al’s garage-building firm were to double the number of carpenters, the amount of lumber, the number of tools, and the quantity of every other input that it uses. Suppose as a result that the number of garages built per year increased from 12 to 26; that is, output more than doubled. Because output goes up by a greater percentage than the increase in each of the inputs, Al’s production is said to be characterized by increasing returns to scale (or economies of scale), at least in this range of input and output quantities. Economies of scale affect operations in many modern industries. Where they exist, they give larger firms cost advantages over smaller ones and thereby foster large firm sizes. Automobile production and telecommunications are two common examples of industries that enjoy significant economies of scale. Predictably, firms in these industries are, indeed, huge. Technology generally determines whether a specific economic activity is characterized by economies of scale. One particularly clear example of a way in which this can happen is provided by warehouse space. Imagine two warehouses, each shaped like a perfect cube, where the length, width, and height of Warehouse 2 are twice as large as the corresponding measurements for Warehouse 1. Now remember your high school geometry. The surface area of any side of a cube is equal to the square of its length. Therefore, the amount of material needed to build Warehouse 2 will be 22, or four times as great as that needed for Warehouse 1. However, because the volume of a cube is equal to the cube of its length, Warehouse 2 will have 23, or eight times, as much storage space as Warehouse 1. Thus, in a cubic building, multiplying the input quantities by 4 leads to eight times the storage space—an example of strongly increasing returns to scale. This example is, of course, oversimplified. It omits such complications as the need for stronger supports in taller buildings, the increased difficulty of moving goods in and out of taller buildings, and the like. Still, the basic idea is correct, and the example shows why, up to a point, the very nature of warehousing creates technological relationships that lead to economies of scale. Our definition of economies of scale, although based on the type of production, relates closely to the shape of the long-run average cost curve. Notice that the definition requires that a doubling of every input must bring about more than a doubling of output. If all input quantities are doubled, total cost must double, but if output more than doubles when

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

143

Production, Inputs, and Cost: Building Blocks for Supply Analysis

Chapter 7

input quantities are doubled, then cost per unit (average cost) must decline when output increases. In other words: Production relationships with economies of scale lead to long-run average cost curves that decline as output expands.

Figure 7(a) depicts a decreasing average cost curve but shows only one of three possible shapes that the long-run average cost curve can take. Figure 7(b) shows the curve for constant returns to scale. Here, if all input quantities double, both total cost (TC) and the quantity of output (Q) double, so average cost (AC 5 TC/Q) remains constant. There is also a third possibility. Output may also increase, but less than double, when all inputs double. This case of decreasing returns to scale leads to a rising long-run average cost curve like the one depicted in Figure 7(c). The figure reveals a close association between the slope of the AC curve and the nature of the firm’s returns to scale. Note that the same production function can display increasing returns to scale in some ranges, constant returns to scale in other ranges, and decreasing returns to scale in yet others. This is true of all the U-shaped average cost curves we have discussed, as shown in Figure 4(b).

The “Law” of Diminishing Returns and Returns to Scale Earlier in this chapter, we discussed the “law” of diminishing marginal returns. Is there any relationship between economies of scale and the phenomenon of diminishing returns? At first, the two ideas may seem contradictory. After all, if a producer gets diminishing returns from her inputs as she uses more of each of them, doesn’t it follow that by using more of every input, she must encounter decreasing returns to scale? In fact, the two principles do not contradict one another, for they deal with fundamentally different issues. • Returns to a single input. This asks the question, How much does output expand if a firm increases the quantity of just one input, holding all other input quantities unchanged? • Returns to scale. Here the question is, How much does output expand if all inputs are increased simultaneously by the same percentage?

AC

Quantity of Output (a)

Constant returns to scale

AC

Quantity of Output (b)

Long-Run Average Cost

Increasing returns to scale

Long-Run Average Cost

Long-Run Average Cost

The “law” of diminishing returns pertains to the first question, because it examines the effects of increasing only one input at a time. It is plausible that the firm will encounter diminishing returns as this one input becomes relatively overabundant as compared to the quantities of the firm’s other inputs. Thus, for example, the addition of too much carpenter time relative to a given quantity of lumber will contribute relatively little to total garage production, yielding diminishing returns. To get the most benefit out of the hiring of an additional carpenter, the firm needs to acquire more tools and raw materials.

FI GURE 7 Three Possible Shapes for the Long-Run Average Cost Curve

Decreasing returns to scale

AC

Quantity of Output (c)

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

144

Part 2

The Building Blocks of Demand and Supply

Returns to scale pertain to proportionate increases in all inputs and therefore answer the second question. If Al doubles carpenter time and all other inputs as well, the carpenters need not become redundant. However, increasing the amount of one input without expanding any other inputs clearly threatens redundancy of the expanded item, even in a factory where simultaneous expansion of all inputs will lead to a very big jump in output. Thus, the “law” of diminishing returns (to a single input) is compatible with any sort of returns to scale. In summary: Returns to scale and returns to a single input (holding all other inputs constant) refer to two distinct aspects of a firm’s technology. A production function that displays diminishing returns to a single input may show diminishing, constant, or increasing returns when all input quantities are increased proportionately.

Historical Costs versus Analytical Cost Curves In Chapter 5, we noted that all points on a demand curve pertain to the same period of time. Decision makers must use this common time period for the analysis of an optimal decision for a given period, because the demand curve describes the alternative choices available for the period of time to which the decision will apply. The same is true of a cost curve. All points on a cost curve pertain to exactly the same time period, because the graph examines the cost of each alternative output level that the firm can choose for that period, thus providing the information needed to compare the alternatives and their consequences and thereby to make an optimal decision for that period. It follows that a graph of historical data on prices and quantities at different points in time is normally not the cost curve that the decision maker needs. This observation will help us resolve the problem posed at the beginning of the chapter, which raised the question whether declining historical costs were evidence of economies of scale as information needed to decide on the optimal size of the firm in question. All points on any of the cost curves used in economic analysis refer to the same period of time.

One point on an auto manufacturer’s cost curve may show, for example, how much it would cost the firm to produce 2.5 million cars during 2011. Another point on the same curve may show what would happen to the firm’s costs if, instead, it were to produce 3 million cars in that same year. Such a curve is called an analytical cost curve or, when there is no possibility of confusion, simply a cost curve. This curve must be distinguished from a diagram of historical costs, which shows how costs have changed from year to year. The different points on an analytical cost curve represent alternative possibilities, all for the same time period. In 2011, the car manufacturer will produce either 2.5 million or 3 million cars (or some other amount), but certainly not both. Thus, at most, only one point on this cost curve will ever be observed. The company may, indeed, produce 2.5 million cars in 2011 and 3 million cars in 2012, but the 2012 data are not relevant to the 2011 cost curve that is used to analyze the 2011 output decision. By the time 2012 comes around, the cost curve may have shifted, so the 2012 cost figure will not apply to the 2011 cost curve. A different sort of graph can, of course, indicate year by year how costs and outputs vary. Such a graph, which gathers together the statistics for a number of different periods, is not, however, a cost curve as defined by economists. An example of such a diagram of historical costs appeared in Figure 1. Why do economists rarely use historical cost diagrams and instead deal primarily with analytical cost curves, which are more abstract, more challenging to explain, and more difficult to estimate statistically? The answer is that analysis of real policy problems—such as the desirability of having a single supplier of telephone services for the entire market—leaves no choice in the matter. Rational decisions require analytical cost curves. Let’s see why.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

PUZZLE:R

145

Production, Inputs, and Cost: Building Blocks for Supply Analysis

Chapter 7

RESOLVING THE ECONOMIES OF SCALE PUZZLE

Recall the problem that we introduced early in the chapter. We examined the divestiture of AT&T’s components and concluded that, to determine whether it made sense to break up such a large company, economists would have to know whether the industry provided economies of scale. Among the data offered as evidence was a graph that showed a precipitous drop in the capital cost of long-distance communications as the volume of calls rose after 1942. But we did not answer a more pertinent question: Why didn’t this information constitute legitimate evidence about the presence or absence of economies of scale? It all boils down to the following: To determine whether a single large firm can provide telephone service more cheaply in, say, 2007 than a number of smaller firms can, we must compare the costs of both large-scale and small-scale production in 2007. It does no good to compare the cost of a large supplier in 2007 with its own costs as a smaller firm back in 1942, because that cannot possibly provide the needed information. The cost situation in 1942 is irrelevant for today’s decision between large and small suppliers, because no small firm today would use the obsolete techniques employed in 1942. Since the 1940s, great technical progress has taken the telephone industry from ordinary open-wire circuits to microwave systems, telecommunications satellites, coaxial cables of enormous capacity, and fiber optics. As a result, the entire analytical cost curve of telecommunications must have shifted downward quite dramatically from year to year. Innovation must have reduced not only the cost of large-scale operations but also the cost of smaller-scale operations. Until decision makers compare the costs of large and small suppliers today, they cannot make a rational choice between single-firm and multifirm production. It is the analytical cost curve, all of whose points refer to the same period, that, by definition, supplies this information. Figures 8 and 9 show two extreme hypothetical cases: one that entails true economies of scale and one that does not. Both are based on the same historical cost data (in black) with their very sharply declining costs. (This curve is reproduced from Figure 1.) They also show (in brick and blue) two possible average cost (AC) curves, one for 1942 and one for 2007. In Figure 8, the analytical AC curve has shifted downward very sharply from 1942 to 2007, as technological change reduced all costs. Moreover, both of the AC curves slope downward to the right, meaning that, in either year, a larger firm has lower average costs. Thus, the situation shown in Figure 8 really does entail scale economies, so that one large firm can serve the market at lower cost than many small ones. Now look at Figure 9, which shows exactly the same historical costs as Figure 8. Here, however, both analytical AC curves are U-shaped. In particular, the 2007 AC curve has its minimum point at an output level, A, that is less than one-half of the current output, B, of the large supplier. Thus, the shape of the analytical cost curves does not show economies of scale. This means that, for the situation shown in Figure 9, a smaller company can produce more cheaply than a large one can. In this case, one cannot justify

Cost per Unit

FI GUR E 8 $100 75

A

1942 analytical cost curve

50 25

Declining Historical Cost Curve with the Analytical Average Cost Curve Also Declining in Each Year

Historical cost curve

2007 analytical cost curve B

0 Quantity of Output

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

146

Part 2

The Building Blocks of Demand and Supply

F I GURE 9 $100 Cost per Unit

Declining Historical Cost Curve with U-Shaped Analytical Cost Curves in Each Year

75 50 25

1942 analytical cost curve Historical cost curve 2007 analytical cost curve

B A

0 Quantity of Output

domination of the market by a single large firm on the grounds that its costs are lower— despite the sharp downward trend of historical costs. In sum, the behavior of historical costs reveals nothing about the cost advantages or disadvantages of a single large firm. More generally: Because a diagram of historical costs does not compare the costs of large and small firms at the same point in time, it cannot be used to determine whether an industry provides economies of large-scale production. Only the analytical cost curve can supply this information.

In the case of telephone service, some estimates indicate that economies of largescale production do indeed exist. Presumably because of this influence, 20 years after the Bell telephone system’s breakup, the typical firm providing traditional longdistance telephone service is still very large, with AT&T and Verizon dominating the industry. Yet half a dozen or so other smaller firms still compete in this arena. It is perhaps ironic that a substantial proportion of the “Baby Bell” local telephone companies that were pulled away from AT&T by the courts in 1982 have recombined in order to obtain cost and other advantages of larger size. Cellular and Internet-based longdistance service has also gained ground at a rapid pace.

Cost Minimization in Theory and Practice Lest you be tempted to run out and open a business, confident that you now understand how to minimize costs, we should point out that business decisions are a good deal more complicated than we have indicated here. Rare is the business executive who knows for sure the exact shapes of marginal physical product schedules, or the precise nature of cost curves. No one can provide an instruction book for instant success in business. What we have presented here is, instead, a set of principles that constitutes a guide to the logic of good decision making. Business management has been described as the art of making critical decisions on the basis of inadequate information, and our complex and ever-changing world often leaves people no alternative but to make educated guesses. Actual business decisions will at best approximate the cost-minimizing ideal outlined in this chapter. Certainly, practicing managers will make mistakes, but when they do their jobs well and the market system functions smoothly, the approximation may prove amazingly good. Although no system is perfect, inducing firms to produce the output they select at the lowest possible cost is undoubtedly one of the jobs the market system does best. Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 7

Production, Inputs, and Cost: Building Blocks for Supply Analysis

147

P OLICY D E B AT E

Should Water Be Provided to Western Farmers at Subsidized Prices? increase now would be tantamount to confiscating their investments. Recent small price increases for water have, in fact, encouraged farmers to utilize water-saving methods such as drip irrigation, with some farmers now eager to sell their resulting surplus water to California cities. State water authorities are working toward creating a market for farmers, cities, and private businesses to buy and sell water. This shows how higher prices can sometimes benefit society, but it also illustrates how it can raise issues of fairness to some of the persons affected.

SOURCE: © Bob Rowan; Progressive Image/CORBIS

Farmers in the western United States use a great deal of water. Because most of the area’s climate is high desert, agriculture there requires artificial irrigation—indeed, water is critical. In California, for example, farmers use 30 million acre-feet of water a year (almost 10 trillion gallons) to irrigate their crops—about 80 percent of that state’s developed water supply. Yet western farmers and ranchers have traditionally paid very low prices for the water they use. Government controls have kept the price of water used for agriculture artificially low, so California farmers pay only a small fraction of the price that urban residents pay for water. Even during droughts, farmers in that state continued to use vast quantities of water, while residents in the cities were forced to ration. This situation has given rise to an intense debate between farmers and environmentalists. There is no question that water is scarce in the western states, exacerbated by an increase in population, leading to predictions of a looming shortage of disastrous proportions. It is also clear that farmers pay a price that is much lower than the true marginal cost of water, particularly because that cost includes a very high opportunity cost—that is, the value of the other uses of water that must be forgone as a result of its extensive employment in agriculture. As analysis in this chapter shows, a low price for an input increases the amount that producers use, and there is little doubt that the low price of water substantially increases its consumption by western farmers. Environmentalists and economists have joined forces in arguing that western water users should pay prices that cover its true marginal cost. Indeed, it has been suggested that at such a price any shortage would simply disappear. But the farmers argue that long practice entitles them to continued low water prices and that low prices in the past induced them to invest extensively in their agricultural properties, so that a price

SOURCES: Dean E. Murphy, “Water Contract Renewals Stir Debate Between Environmentalists and Farmers in California,” The New York Times, December 15, 2004, p. A.22; James Flanigan, “Creating a Free-Flowing Market to Buy, Sell Water,” Los Angeles Times, October 24, 2001, http://www.latimes.com; “California’s Economy: The Real Trouble,” The Economist, July 28, 2001, p. 31; and California Department of Water Resources, http://www.owue.water.ca.gov.

| SUMMARY | 1. A firm’s total cost curve shows its lowest possible cost of producing any given quantity of output. This curve is derived from the input combination that the firm uses to produce any given output and the prices of the inputs.

5. Average and marginal variable cost curves tend to be U-shaped, meaning that these costs decline up to a certain level of output and then begin to rise again at larger output quantities.

2. The marginal physical product (MPP) of an input is the increase in total output resulting from a one-unit increase in that input, holding the quantities of all other inputs constant.

6. The long run is a period sufficiently long for the firm’s plant to require replacement and for all of its current contractual commitments to expire. The short run is any period briefer than the long run.

3. The ”law” of diminishing marginal returns states that if a firm increases the amount of one input (holding all other input quantities constant), the marginal physical product of the expanding input will eventually begin to decline.

7. Fixed costs are costs whose total amounts do not vary when output increases. All other costs are called variable costs. Some costs are variable in the long run but not in the short run.

4. To maximize profits, a firm must purchase an input up to the point at which diminishing returns reduce the input’s marginal revenue product (MRP) to equal its price (P 5 MRP 5 MPP 3 price).

8. At all levels of output, the total fixed cost (TFC) curve is horizontal and the average fixed cost (AFC) curve declines toward the horizontal axis but never crosses it.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

148

Part 2

The Building Blocks of Demand and Supply

9. TC 5 TFC + TVC; AC 5 AFC + AVC; MFC 5 0. 10. It is usually possible to produce the same quantity of output in a variety of ways by substituting more of one input for less of another input. Firms normally seek the combination of inputs that offers the least costly way to produce any given output. 11. A firm that wants to minimize costs will select input quantities at which the ratios of the marginal revenue product of each input to the input’s price—its MRP per dollar—are equal for all inputs. 12. If a doubling of all the firm’s inputs just doubles its output, the firm is said to have constant returns to scale. If a

doubling of all inputs leads to more than twice as much output, it has increasing returns to scale (or economies of scale). If a doubling of inputs produces less than a doubling of output, the firm has decreasing returns to scale. 13. With increasing returns to scale, the firm’s long-run average costs are decreasing; constant returns to scale are associated with constant long-run average costs; decreasing returns to scale are associated with increasing long-run average costs. 14. Economists cannot tell if an industry offers economies of scale (increasing returns to scale) simply by inspecting a diagram of historical cost data. Only the underlying analytical cost curve can supply this information.

| KEY TERMS | average physical product (APP) 130 economies of scale (increasing returns to scale) 142 fixed cost long run

129 129

marginal physical product (MPP) 131

total physical product (TPP) variable cost

130

129

marginal revenue product (MRP) 133 short run

129

| TEST YOURSELF | 1. A firm’s total fixed cost is $360,000. Construct a table of its total and average fixed costs for output levels varying from zero to 6 units. Draw the corresponding TFC and AFC curves. 2. With the following data, calculate the firm’s AVC and MVC and draw the graphs for TVC, AVC, and MVC. Why is MVC the same as MC? Total Quantity Variable Costs 1 2 3 4 5 6

$40,000 80,000 120,000 176,000 240,000 360,000

3. From the data in Test Yourself Questions 1 and 2, calculate TC and AC for each of the output levels from 1 to 6 units and draw the two graphs. 4. If a firm’s commitments in 2008 include machinery that will need replacement in 5 years, a factory building rented for 12 years, and a 3-year union contract specifying how many workers it must employ, when, from its point of view in 2008, does the firm’s long run begin? 5. If the marginal revenue product of a gallon of oil used as input by a firm is $2.20 and the price of oil is $2.07 per gallon, what can the firm do to increase its profits?

6. A firm hires two workers and rents 15 acres of land for a season. It produces 150,000 bushels of crop. If it had doubled its land and labor, production would have been 325,000 bushels. Does it have constant, decreasing, or increasing returns to scale? 7. Suppose that wages are $20,000 per season per person and land rent per acre is $3,000. Calculate the average cost of 150,000 bushels and the average cost of 325,000 bushels, using the figures in Test Yourself Question 6. (Note that average costs increase when output increases.) What connection do these figures have with the firm’s returns to scale? 8. Naomi has stockpiled a great deal of chicken feed. Suppose now that she buys more chicks, but not more chicken feed, and divides the feed she has evenly among the larger number of chickens. What is likely to happen to the marginal physical product of feed? What, therefore, is the role of input proportions in the determination of marginal physical product? 9. Labor costs $12 per hour. Nine workers produce 180 bushels of product per hour, whereas 10 workers produce 196 bushels. Land rents for $1,200 per acre per year. With 10 acres worked by nine workers, the marginal physical product of an acre of land is 1,400 bushels per year. Does the farmer minimize costs by hiring nine workers and renting 10 acres of land? If not, which input should he use in larger relative quantity? 10. Suppose that Al’s total costs increase by $5,000 per year at every output level. Show in Table 2 how this change affects his total and average costs.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 7

149

Production, Inputs, and Cost: Building Blocks for Supply Analysis

| DISCUSSION QUESTION | 1. A firm experiences a sudden increase in the demand for its product. In the short run, it must operate longer hours and pay higher overtime wage rates to satisfy this new demand. In the long run, the firm can install more machines instead of operating fewer machines for longer hours. Which do you think will be lower, the

short-run or the long-run average cost of the increased output? How is your answer affected by the fact that the long-run average cost includes the new machines the firm buys, whereas the short-run average cost includes no machine purchases?

| APPENDIX | Production Indifference Curves

A production indifference curve (sometimes called an isoquant) is a curve showing all the different quantities of two inputs that are just sufficient to produce a given quantity of output.

Figure 10 represents different quantities of labor and capital capable of producing given amounts of wheat. The figure shows three indifference curves: one for the production of 220,000 bushels of wheat, one for 240,000 bushels, and one for 260,000 bushels. The indifference curve labeled 220,000 bushels indicates that a farm can generate an output of 220,000 bushels of wheat using any one of the combinations of inputs represented by points on that curve. For example, it can employ 10 years of labor and 200 acres of land (point A) or the labor–land combination shown by point B on the same curve. Because it lies considerably below and to the right of point B, point A represents a productive process that uses more labor and less land. Points A and B can be considered technologically indifferent because each represents a bundle of inputs just capable of yielding the same quantity of finished goods. However, “indifference” in this sense does not mean that the producer will be unable to decide between input combinations A and B. Input prices will permit the producer to arrive at a decision. The production indifference curves in a diagram such as Figure 10 show for each combination of inputs how much output can be produced. Because production indifference curves are drawn in two dimensions, they represent only two inputs at a time. In more realistic situations, firms are likely to need more than two inputs,

FIGURE 10 A Production Indifference Map

Quantity of Land in Acres

To describe a production function—that is, the relationship between input combinations and the size of a firm’s total output—economists use a graphic device called the production indifference curve. Each indifference curve indicates all combinations of input quantities just capable of producing a given quantity of output; thus, a separate indifference curve corresponds to each possible quantity of output. These production indifference curves are perfectly analogous to the consumer indifference curves discussed in the appendix to Chapter 5.

B

600

D

400 200

260,000 bushels A

C

E 0

3

5

7

240,000 bushels 220,000 bushels

10

Quantity of Labor in Years

so, to study the subject, economists must conduct an algebraic analysis. Even so, all the principles we need to analyze such a situation can be derived from the twovariable case.

CHARACTERISTICS OF THE PRODUCTION INDIFFERENCE CURVES, OR ISOQUANTS Before discussing input pricing and quantity decisions, we first examine what is known about the shapes of production indifference curves. Characteristic 1: Higher curves correspond to larger outputs. Points on a higher indifference curve represent larger quantities of both inputs than the corresponding points on a lower curve. Thus, a higher curve represents a larger output. Characteristic 2: An indifference curve will generally have a negative slope. It goes downhill as we move toward the right. Thus, if a firm reduces the quantity of one input, and if it does not want to cut production, it must use more of another input.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Part 2

The Building Blocks of Demand and Supply

Characteristic 3: An indifference curve is typically assumed to curve inward toward the origin near its middle. This shape reflects the “law” of diminishing returns to a single input. For example, in Figure 10, points B, D, and A represent three different input combinations capable of producing the same quantity of output. At point B, the firm uses a large amount of land and relatively little labor, whereas the opposite is true at point A. Point D is intermediate between the two.

Now consider the choice among these input combinations. When the farmer considers moving from point B to point D, he gives up 200 acres of land and instead hires 2 additional years of labor. Similarly, the move from D to A involves giving up another 200 acres of land. This time, however, hiring an additional 2 years of labor does not make up for the reduced use of land. Diminishing returns to labor as the farmer hires more and more workers to replace more and more land means that the farm now needs a much larger quantity of additional labor—5 person-years rather than 2—to make up for the reduction in the use of land. Without such diminishing returns, the indifference curve would have been a straight line, DE. The curvature of the indifference curve through points D and A reflects diminishing returns to substitution of inputs.

THE CHOICE OF INPUT COMBINATIONS A production indifference curve describes only the input combinations that can produce a given output; it indicates just what is technologically possible. To decide which of the available options suits its purposes best, a business needs the corresponding cost information: the relative prices of the inputs. The budget line in Figure 11 represents all equally costly input combinations for a firm. For example, if farmhands are paid $9,000 per year and land rents for $1,000 per acre per year, then a farmer who spends $360,000 can hire 40 farmhands but rent no land (point K), or he can rent 360 acres but have no money left for farmhands (point J). It is undoubtedly more sensible to pick some intermediate point on his budget line at which he divides the $360,000 between the two inputs. The slope of the budget line represents the amount of land the farmer must give up if he wants to hire one more worker without increasing his budget. A budget line is the locus of all points representing every input combination of inputs that the producer can afford to buy with a given amount of money and given input prices.

If the prices of the inputs do not change, then the slope of the budget line will not change anywhere in the graph. It will be the same at every point on a given

FIGURE 11 A Budget Line

Quantity of Land in Acres

150

360 J

K 40 Number of Workers

budget line, and it will be the same on the $360,000 budget line as on the $400,000 budget line or on the budget line for any other level of spending. For if the price of hiring a worker is nine times as high as the cost of renting an acre, then the farmer must rent nine fewer acres to hire an additional farmhand without changing the total amount of money he spends on these inputs. Thus, the slope will be acres given up per added farmhand 5 29/1 5 29. With the input prices given, the slope of any budget line does not change and the slopes of the different budget lines for different amounts of expenditures are all the same. Two results follow: (1) The budget lines are straight lines because their slopes remain the same throughout their length, and (2) because they all have the same slope, the budget lines in the graph will all be parallel, as in Figure 12. A firm that is seeking to minimize costs does not necessarily have a fixed budget. Instead, it wants to produce a given quantity of output (say, 240,000 bushels) with the smallest possible budget. Figure 12 combines the indifference curve for 240,000 bushels from Figure 10 with a variety of budget lines similar to JK in Figure 11. The firm’s task is to find the lowest budget line that will allow it to reach the 240,000-bushel indifference curve. Clearly, an expenditure of $270,000 is too little; no point on the budget line, AB, permits production of 240,000 bushels. Similarly, an expenditure of $450,000 is too much, because the firm can produce its target level of output more cheaply. The solution is at point T where the farmer uses 15 workers and 225 acres of land to produce the 240,000 bushels of wheat. That budget line, the one that is tangent to the relevant indifference curve, is evidently the lowest budget line that meets

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

151

Production, Inputs, and Cost: Building Blocks for Supply Analysis

Chapter 7

FIGURE 12

FIGURE 13

Cost Minimization

The Firm’s Expansion Path

B'

360

J

Quantity of Land in Acres

Quantity of Land in Acres

450

$450,000 270 A T

225

$360,000

E S'

B T

B 30

K 40

300,000 bushels

S

240,000 bushels

$270,000

15

J

E

240,000 bushels 200,000 bushels $270,000

50

0

10 15

B

K

B'

Number of Workers

Number of Workers

the indifference curve anywhere, so it represents the lowest-cost input combination capable of producing the desired output. In general: The least costly way to produce any given level of output is indicated by the point of tangency between a budget line and the production indifference curve corresponding to that level of output.

COST MINIMIZATION, EXPANSION PATH, AND COST CURVES Figure 12 shows how to determine the input combination that minimizes the cost of producing 240,000 bushels of output. The farmer can repeat this procedure exactly for any other output quantity, such as 200,000 bushels or 300,000 bushels. In each case, we draw the corresponding production indifference curve and find the lowest budget line that permits the farm to produce that much. For example, in Figure 13, budget line BB is tangent to the indifference curve for 200,000 units of output; similarly, budget line JK is tangent to the indifference curve for 240,000 bushels; and budget line B’B’ is tangent to the indifference curve for 300,000 units of output. This gives us three tangency points: S, which gives the input combination that produces a 200,000-bushel output at lowest cost; T, which gives the same information for a 240,000-bushel output; and S’, which indicates the cost-minimizing input combination for the production of 300,000 bushels. This process can be repeated for as many other levels of output as we like. For each such output we draw the corresponding production indifference curve and find its point of tangency with a budget line. The brick-colored

curve EE in Figure 13 connects all of the cost-minimizing points; that is, it is the locus of S, T, S’, and all other points of tangency between a production indifference curve and a budget line. Curve EE is called the firm’s expansion path. The expansion path is the locus of the firm’s costminimizing input combinations for all relevant output levels.

Point T in Figure 12 shows the quantity of output (given by the production indifference curve through that point) and the total cost (shown by the tangent budget line). Similarly, we can determine the output and total cost for every other point on the expansion path, EE, in Figure 13. For example, at point S, output is 200,000 bushels and total cost is $270,000. These data are precisely the sort of information we need to find the firm’s total cost curve; that is, they are the sort of information contained in Table 3, which is the source of the total cost curve and the average and marginal cost curves in Figure 4. Thus: The points of tangency between a firm’s production indifference curves and its budget lines yield its expansion path, which shows the firm’s cost-minimizing input combination for each pertinent output level. This information also yields the output and total cost for each point on the expansion path, which is what we need to draw the firm’s cost curves.

Suppose that the cost of renting land increases and the wage rate of labor decreases. These changes mean that the budget lines will differ from those depicted in Figure 12. Specifically, with land becoming more expensive, any given sum of money will rent fewer acres, so the intercept of each budget line on the vertical (land) axis will

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

152

Part 2

The Building Blocks of Demand and Supply

shift downward. Conversely, with cheaper labor, any given sum of money will buy more labor, so the intercept of the budget line on the horizontal (labor) axis will shift to the right. Figure 14 depicts a series of budget lines corresponding to a $1,500 per acre rental rate for land and a $6,000 annual wage for labor. If input prices change, the combination of inputs that minimizes costs will normally change. In this diagram, the land rent at $1,500 per acre is more than it was in Figure 12, whereas labor costs $6,000 per year (less than in Figure 12). As a result, these budget lines are less steep than those shown in Figure 12, and point E now represents the least costly way to produce 240,000 bushels of wheat. To assist you in seeing how things change, Figure 15 combines, in a single graph, budget line JK and

tangency point T from Figure 12 with budget line WV and tangency point E from Figure 14. When land becomes more expensive and labor becomes cheaper, the budget lines (such as JK) become less steep than they were previously (see WV). As a result, the least costly way to produce 240,000 bushels shifts from point T to point E, at which the firm uses more labor and less land. As common sense suggests, when the price of one input rises in comparison with that of another, it will pay the firm to use less of the more expensive input and more of the other input. In addition to substituting one input for another, a change in the price of an input may induce the firm to alter its level of output. We will cover this subject in the next chapter.

Optimal Input Choice at a Different Set of Input Prices

How Changes in Input Prices Affect Input Proportions

300 240

W

180 E

240,000 bushels 45

V 60

Quantity of Land in Acres

FIGURE 15

Quantity of Land in Acres

FIGURE 14

J

W

T E 240,000 bushels

75

K V Quantity of Labor in Years

Quantity of Labor in Years

| SUMMARY | 1. A production relationship can be described by a series of production indifference curves, each of which shows all input combinations capable of producing a specified amount of output. 2. As long as each input has a positive marginal physical product, production indifference curves will have negative slopes and the higher curves will represent larger amounts of output than the lower curves. Because of diminishing returns, these curves characteristically bend toward the origin near the middle. 3. The optimal input combination for any given level of output is indicated by the point of tangency between a budget line and the corresponding production indifference curve.

4. The firm’s expansion path shows, for each of its possible output levels, the combination of input quantities that minimizes the cost of producing that output. 5. Total cost for each output level can be derived from the production indifference curves and the budget lines tangent to them along the expansion path. These figures can be used to determine the firm’s total cost, average cost, and marginal cost curves. 6. When input prices change, firms will normally use more of the input that becomes relatively less expensive and less of the input that becomes relatively more expensive.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 7

Production, Inputs, and Cost: Building Blocks for Supply Analysis

153

| KEY TERMS | budget line

150

expansion path

151

production indifference curve

149

| TEST YOURSELF | 1. Compound Consolidated Corporation (CCC) produces containers using two inputs: labor and glue. If labor costs $10 per hour and glue costs $5 per gallon, draw CCC’s budget line for a total expenditure of $100,000. In this same diagram, sketch a production indifference curve indicating that CCC can produce no more than 1,000 containers with this expenditure.

2. With respect to Test Yourself Question 1, suppose that wages rise to $20 per hour and glue prices rise to $6 per gallon. How are CCC’s optimal input proportions likely to change? (Use a diagram to explain your answer.) 3. What happens to the location of the expansion path of the firm in Test Yourself Question 2?

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

OUTPUT, PRICE, AND PROFIT: THE IMPORTANCE OF MARGINAL ANALYSIS Business is a good game. . . . You keep score with money. NOL AN BU SNEL L , F OU NDER OF ATA RI ( AN EARLY VI DEO GAM E MA KE R)

S

uppose you become president of a firm that makes video games. One of your most critical decisions will be how many video games to produce and at what price to offer them for sale. The owners of the company presumably want to make as much profit as possible. This chapter explores the logic underlying the decisions that lead to achievement of this goal. With this chapter, we cap off our discussion of the fundamental building blocks of microeconomics. Chapters 5 and 6 dealt with the behavior of consumers. Chapter 7 introduced the other main participant in microeconomics, the firm. The firm’s two main roles are, first, to produce its product efficiently and, second, to sell that product at a profit. Chapter 7 described production decisions and demonstrated that this process yields cost data. We will soon see in the current chapter that this is cost information the firm’s management needs to determine the price and output of its product that will yield a profit as high as market conditions permit. In Chapter 9, we will discuss stocks and bonds as instruments that enable business firms to obtain the money needed to finance their production and sales activities and as an earnings opportunity for individuals who consider investing in firms. Throughout Part 2, we have described how firms and consumers can make optimal decisions, meaning that their decisions go as far as possible, given the circumstances, to promote the consumer’s and producer’s goals. In this chapter, we will continue to assume that business firms seek primarily to maximize total profit, just as we assumed that consumers maximize utility. (See the box “Do Firms Really Maximize Profits?” on the following page, for a discussion of other objectives of business firms.)

C O N T E N T S PUZZLE: CAN A COMPANY MAKE A PROFIT BY SELLING BELOW ITS COSTS?

Maximization of Total Profit Profit Maximization: A Graphical Interpretation

PRICE AND QUANTITY: ONE DECISION, NOT TWO

MARGINAL ANALYSIS AND MAXIMIZATION OF TOTAL PROFIT

TOTAL PROFIT: KEEP YOUR EYE ON THE GOAL

Marginal Revenue and Marginal Cost: Guides to Optimization Finding the Optimal Price from Optimal Output

ECONOMIC PROFIT AND OPTIMAL DECISION MAKING Total, Average, and Marginal Revenue Total, Average, and Marginal Cost

GENERALIZATION: THE LOGIC OF MARGINAL ANALYSIS AND MAXIMIZATION Application: Fixed Cost and the ProfitMaximizing Price

PUZZLE RESOLVED: USING MARGINAL ANALYSIS TO UNRAVEL THE CASE OF THE “UNPROFITABLE” CALCULATOR

CONCLUSION: THE FUNDAMENTAL ROLE OF MARGINAL ANALYSIS THE THEORY AND REALITY: A WORD OF CAUTION | APPENDIX | The Relationships Among Total, Average, and Marginal Data Graphical Representation of Marginal and Average Curves

155

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

156

Part 2

The Building Blocks of Demand and Supply

Do Firms Really Maximize Profits?

An optimal decision is one which, among all the decisions that are actually possible, best achieves the decision maker’s goals. For example, if profit is the sole objective of some firm, the price that makes the firm’s profit as large as possible is optimal for that company.

Herbert Simon of Carnegie-Mellon University, have concluded that decision making in industry and government is often of the satisficing variety. Even if this assertion is true, it does not necessarily make profit maximization a bad assumption. Recall our discussion of abstraction and model building in Chapter 1. A map of Los Angeles that omits hundreds of roads is no doubt “wrong” if interpreted as a literal description of the city. Nonetheless, by capturing the most important elements of reality, it may help us understand the city better than a map that is cluttered with too much detail. Similarly, we can learn much about the behavior of business firms by assuming that they try to maximize profits, even though we know that not all of them act this way all of the time.

SOURCE: © The New Yorker Collection 1985 Charles Saxon from cartoonbank.com. All Rights Reserved.

Naturally, many people question whether firms really try to maximize profits to the exclusion of all other goals. But businesspeople are like other human beings: Their motives are varied and complex. Given the choice, many executives may prefer to control the largest firm rather than the most profitable one. Some may be fascinated by technology and therefore spend so much on research and development that it cuts down on profit. Some may want to “do good” and therefore give away some of the stockholders’ money to hospitals and colleges. Different managers within the same firm may not always agree with one another on goals, so that it may not even make sense to speak about “the” goal of the firm. Thus, any attempt to summarize the objectives of management in terms of a single number (profit) is bound to be an oversimplification. In addition, the exacting requirements for maximizing profits are tough to satisfy. In deciding how much to invest, what price to set for a product, or how much to allocate to the advertising budget, the range of available alternatives is enormous. Also, information about each alternative is often expensive and difficult to acquire. As a result, when a firm’s management decides on, say, an $18 million construction budget, it rarely compares the consequences of that decision in any detail with the consequences of all possible alternatives—such as budgets of $17 million or $19 million. Unless all the available possibilities are compared, management cannot be sure that it has chosen the one that brings in the highest possible profit. Often, management’s concern is whether the decision’s results are likely to be acceptable—whether its risks will be acceptably low, whether its profits will be acceptably high—so that the company can live satisfactorily with the outcome. Such analysis cannot be expected to bring in the maximum possible profit. The decision may be good, but some unexplored alternative may be even better. Decision making that seeks only solutions that are acceptable has been called satisficing, to contrast it with optimizing (profit maximization). Some analysts, such as the late Nobel Prize winner

“It’s true that more is not necessarily better, Edward, but it frequently is.”

As in the previous three chapters, marginal analysis helps us to determine what constitutes an optimal decision. Because that method of analysis is so useful, this chapter summarizes and generalizes what we have learned about the methods of marginal analysis, showing also how this analysis applies in many other situations in which optimality is an issue. Marginal analysis leads to some surprising conclusions that show how misleading unaided “common sense” can sometimes be. Here’s an example. Suppose a firm suffers a sharp increase in its rent or some other fixed cost. How should the firm react? Some would argue that the firm should raise the price of its product to cover the higher rent; others would argue that it should cut its price so as to increase its sales enough to pay the increased rent. We will see in this chapter that both of these answers are incorrect! A profitmaximizing firm faced with a rent increase should neither raise nor lower its price if it wants to prevent its net earnings from falling.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 8

PUZZLE:

Output, Price, and Profit: The Importance of Marginal Analysis

CAN A COMPANY MAKE A PROFIT BY SELLING BELOW ITS COSTS?

Price and output decisions can sometimes perplex even the most experienced businesspeople. The following real-life illustration seems to show that it is possible for a firm to make a profit by selling at a price that is apparently below its cost.1 In a recent legal battle between two manufacturers of pocket calculators, Company B accused Company A of selling 10 million sophisticated calculators at a price of $12, which Company A allegedly knew was too low to cover costs. Company B claimed that Company A was cutting its price simply to drive Company B out of business. At first, Company A’s records, as revealed to the court, appeared to confirm Company B’s accusations. The cost of materials, labor, advertising, and other direct costs of the calculators came to $10.30 per calculator. Company A’s accountants also assigned to this product its share of the company’s annual expenditure on overhead—such items as general administration, research, and the like—which amounted to $4.25 per calculator. The $12 price clearly did not cover the $14.55 cost attributed to each calculator. Yet economists representing Company A were able to convince the court that, at the $12 price, manufacturing the calculator was a profitable activity for Company A, so there was no basis on which to conclude that its only purpose was to destroy B. At the end of the chapter, we’ll see how ordinary good sense is not necessarily the best guide in business decisions and how marginal analysis helped solve this problem.

PRICE AND QUANTITY: ONE DECISION, NOT TWO When your company introduces a new line of video games, the marketing department has to decide what price to charge and how many games to produce. These crucial decisions strongly influence the firm’s labor requirements, the consumer response to the product, and, indeed, the company’s future success. This chapter’s main focus is on how to determine these two quantities so as to maximize the firm’s profits. When the firm selects a price and a quantity of output that maximize profits, it seems that it must choose two numbers. In fact, however, the firm can pick only one. Once it has selected the price, the quantity it can sell is up to consumers. Alternatively, the firm may decide how many units it would like to sell, but then the market will determine the price at which this quantity can be sold. The firm’s dilemma explicitly illustrates the powerful role that consumers play in the market. Management gets two numbers by making only one decision because the firm’s demand curve tells it, for any quantity it may decide to market, the highest possible price its product can bring. To illustrate, we return to Chapter 7’s garage-building example. Al’s Building Contractors sells garages to individual homeowners, and Al is trying to figure out how best to make money on his building operation. To do this, he must estimate his firm’s demand curve. The firm’s demand curve is different from the demand curves we encountered in earlier chapters—the demand curve of an individual consumer and the market demand curve (which is the combined demand of all consumers in the market). Now we are dealing with a single firm (Al’s Building Contractors) that is only one among possibly many firms that serve the market. The demand curve of any one supplier depends on the number and activities of the other firms in the market, as each competes for its share of total market demand. The demand curve of a single firm is actually a complicated matter that we will deal with several times in subsequent chapters.2 For now, suffice it to say that Al’s

The following case is disguised to protect the confidentiality of the firms involved. In one case, the relation between market demand and firm demand is very easy. That is the case where the firm has no competitors—it is a monopoly. Since it has the entire market to itself, its demand curve and the market demand curve are one and the same. We deal with monopoly in Chapter 11. Another fairly straightforward case, called perfect competition, will be studied in Chapter 10. 1 2

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

157

158

The Building Blocks of Demand and Supply

Part 2

Price per Garage (thousands $)

35 30 26 19 16

D a

b c d

25 22 20

Profit maximum

e f

g h i

15

j D

10 5 1

0

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

Output, Garages Marketed per Year

F I GURE 1 Demand Curve for Al’s Garages

The total profit of a firm is its net earnings during some period of time. It is equal to the total amount of money the firm gets from sales of its products (the firm’s total revenue) minus the total amount that it spends to make and market those products (total cost).

9

10

demand curve will lie closer to the market demand curve (meaning that Al has a greater share of the market), the better his service, the more effective his advertising, the stronger his reputation for quality, and so on. Suppose Al faces the demand curve for his garages shown as DD in Figure 1. The curve depicts the quantity demanded at each price. For example, the curve shows that at a price of $22,000 per garage (point e), Al’s customers will demand five garages. If Al gets greedy and tries to charge the higher price of $26,000 per garage (point c on the curve), he can sell only three garages. If he wants to sell eight garages, he can find the required number of customers only by offering the garages at the lower price of $16,000 each (point h). In summary:

Each point on the demand curve represents a price–quantity pair. The firm can pick any such pair. It can never pick the price corresponding to one point on the demand curve and the quantity corresponding to another point, however, because such an output cannot be sold at the selected price.

For this reason, we will not discuss price and output decisions separately throughout this chapter, for they are actually two different aspects of the same decision. To analyze this decision, we will make an imperfectly realistic assumption about the behavior of business firms—the assumption that firms strive for the largest possible total profit to the exclusion of any other goal. We will therefore assume throughout this chapter (and for most of the book) that the firm has only one objective: It wants to make its total profit as large as possible. Our analytic strategy will seek to determine what output level (or price) achieves this goal, but you should keep in mind that many of our results depend on this simplifying assumption, so the conclusions will not apply to every case. Our decision to base the analysis on the profit-maximizing assumption gives us sharper insights, but we pay for it with some loss of realism.

TOTAL PROFIT: KEEP YOUR EYE ON THE GOAL Total profit, then, is the firm’s assumed goal. By definition, total profit is the difference between what the company earns in the form of sales revenue and what it pays out in the form of costs: Total profit 5 Total revenue 2 Total cost ( including opportunity cost )

IDEAS FOR BEYOND THE FINAL EXAM

OPPORTUNITY COST AND PROFIT Total profit defined in this way is called economic profit to distinguish it from an accountant’s definition of profit. The two concepts of profit differ because an economist’s total cost counts the opportunity cost of any capital, labor, or other inputs supplied by the firm’s owner. For example, let’s say that Naomi, who owns a small business, earns just enough to pay herself the money that her labor and capital could have earned if they had been sold to others (say, $60,000 per year). Then, as we saw in Chapter 3, economists would say that she is earning zero economic profit. (Naomi is just covering all her costs, including her opportunity costs.) In contrast, most accountants would say her profit is $60,000, referring to the difference between her gross receipts and gross costs.

ECONOMIC PROFIT AND OPTIMAL DECISION MAKING Why do economists use this apparently strange definition of profits, in which they subtract not only the costs that would ordinarily be deducted from total revenue but also the Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 8

159

Output, Price, and Profit: The Importance of Marginal Analysis

opportunity costs? The answer is that doing so tells us directly whether the firm has made an optimal decision, in other words, whether the firm has chosen the price and quantity that maximizes profits. Specifically: 1. If economic profit is positive, then the firm’s decisions are optimal; that is, its price and output yield a profit larger than any alternative prices and outputs. 2. If economic profit is zero, then the firm’s choices are still satisfactory, because its price and output yield as much profit as the best available alternative. 3. If economic profit is negative, then the choice is not optimal; there exists at least one alternative price–output combination that is more profitable. This reasoning explains why we pay so much attention to opportunity cost: because it helps us to determine whether or not a decision is optimal. It works for all decisions, not only those about prices and quantities. But how does it do so? An example will make it clear. Suppose a firm has $100,000 to spend on either packaging or advertising. Suppose further that if the $100,000 is spent on packaging, it will bring in an accounting profit (that is, a profit as ordinarily defined: total revenue minus total ordinary cost, leaving out opportunity cost) of $20,000. If, instead, the (accounting) profit it could obtain from a $100,000 investment in advertising is $X, then by definition, $X is the opportunity cost of the decision to invest in packaging. In other words, $X is the earnings that could have been obtained from the alternative opportunity that the firm gives up by investing in packaging. So, for the possible decision to invest in packaging: Economic profit 5 Accounting profit 2 Opportunity cost 5 $20,000 2 $X 5 The difference between the earnings offered by the two alternative investments

This immediately illustrates our three conclusions above, because: 1. If $X , $20,000, then economic profit . 0, because packaging, which yields $20,000, is the more profitable investment choice. 2. If $X 5 $20,000, then economic profit 5 0, and the two investment options are equally profitable. 3. And if $X . $20,000, then the economic profit of packaging ($20,000 2 $X) is negative, so advertising must be a more profitable investment than packaging. The reason economic profit performs this test is simple: Economic profit of the decision in question 5 its accounting profit 2 its opportunity cost 5 accounting profit of the decision in question 2 accounting profit of the best available alternative. So, the economic profit of the decision in question will be positive only if it is more profitable (in the accountant’s measurement) than the alternative, and so on.

Economic profit equals net earnings, in the accountant’s sense, minus the opportunity costs of capital and of any other inputs supplied by the firm’s owners.

Total, Average, and Marginal Revenue To see how total profit depends on output, we must study how the two components of total profit, total revenue (TR) and total cost (TC), behave when output changes. It should be obvious that both total revenue and total cost depend on the output–price combination the firm selects; we will study these relationships presently. We can calculate total revenue directly from the firm’s demand curve because, by definition, it is the product of price times the quantity that consumers will buy at that price: TR 5 P 3 Q

Table 1 shows how we derive the total revenue schedule from the demand schedule for Al’s garages. The first two columns simply give the relevant quantities and the price of the corresponding quantity, so that they express Figure 1’s demand curve in tabular form. The third column gives, for each quantity, the product of price times quantity. For example, if Al sells seven garages at a price of $18,000 per garage, his annual sales revenue will be 7 garages 3 $18,000 per garage 5 $126,000.

The total revenue of a supplier firm is the total amount of money it receives from the purchasers of its products, without any deduction of costs.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

160

The Building Blocks of Demand and Supply

Part 2

TABLE 1 Demand for Al’s Garages: His Total Revenue Schedule and His Marginal Revenue Schedule

(1)

(2) (3) (4) Price 5 Average Marginal Revenue Total Revenue Garages per Revenue per Added per Garage (in per Year (in Garage (in Year thousands) thousands) thousands) 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

The average revenue (AR) is total revenue (TR) divided by quantity.

— $30 28 26 24 22 20 18 16 14 12

$0 30 56 78 96 110 120 126 128 126 120

$30 26 22 18 14 10 6 2 22 26

Figure 2 displays Al’s total revenue schedule in graphic form as the black TR curve. This graph shows precisely the same information as the demand curve in Figure 1, but in a somewhat different form. For example, point f on the demand curve in Figure 1, which shows a price–quantity combination of P 5 $20,000 per garage and Q 5 6 garages per year, appears as point F in Figure 2 as a total revenue of $120,000 per year ($20,000 per garage 3 6 garages). Similarly, each other point on the TR curve in Figure 2 corresponds to the similarly labeled point in Figure 1. We can speak of the relationship between the demand curve and the TR curve in a slightly different and more useful way than that shown in Figure 1. Because the product price is the revenue per unit that the firm receives, we can view the demand curve as an average revenue (AR) curve. To see why this is so, observe that average revenue and total revenue are, by definition, related to one another by the formula AR 5 TR/Q and, as we have seen, TR 5 P 3 Q. Therefore,3 AR 5 TR/Q 5 P 3 Q/Q 5 P

Total Revenue per Year (thousands $)

Marginal revenue (MR) is the addition to total revenue resulting from the addition of one unit to total output. Geometrically, marginal revenue is the slope of the total revenue curve at the pertinent output quantity. Its formula is MR1 5 TR12TR0, and so on.

As you can see, average revenue and price are just different names for the same thing. The reason should be clear. If a supermarket sells a brand of candy bars at the same price— say, $1—to each and every customer who wants one, then the average revenue that the store derives from each sale of these candy bars must also be $1. Finally, the last column of Table 1 shows the marginal revenue (MR) for each level of output. Marginal revenue provides us with an analytic tool whose use we will explain presently. This concept (analogous to marginal utility and marginal cost) refers to the addition to total revenue that results from raising output by one unit. Thus, in Table 1, we see that when output rises from two to three garages, total revenue goes up from $56,000 to $78,000, so marginal revenue is $78,000 minus $56,000, or $22,000.

140

G

H

F 120

I

E

TR

D

100

J

C 80 B

60 40

A

20 0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

9

10

Output, Garages Sold per Year

F I GURE 2 Total Revenue Curve for Al’s Garages

3

See the appendix to this chapter for a general discussion of the relationship between totals and averages.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

161

Output, Price, and Profit: The Importance of Marginal Analysis

Chapter 8

Total, Average, and Marginal Cost

Maximization of Total Profit We now have all the tools to answer our central question: What combination of output and price will yield the largest possible total profit? To study how total profit depends on output, Table 3 brings together the total revenue and total cost schedules from Tables 1 and 2. The fourth column in Table 3—called, appropriately enough, total profit—is just the difference between total revenue and total cost at each level of output.

Total Cost per Year (thousands $)

180 160 140 120 100 80 60 40 20 0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

9

10

Output, Garages per Year (a) Total Cost 50 Marginal Cost per Added Garage (thousands $)

The revenue side is, of course, only half of the firm’s profit picture. We must turn to the cost side for the other half. As we saw in Chapter 7, average cost (AC) and marginal cost (MC) are obtained directly from total cost (TC) in exactly the same way that average and marginal revenue are calculated from total revenue. Figure 3 plots the numbers in Table 2 and thus shows the total, average, and marginal cost curves for Al’s garage-building operation. As we learned in Chapter 7, the U-shapes of the average cost and marginal cost curves depicted here are considered typical. The shapes mean that, in any given industry, there is one size of firm that is most efficient in producing the output. Smaller enterprises lose any advantages that derive from a large volume of production, and so their average cost (the cost per unit of output) will be greater than that of a firm operating at the most efficient size of output. Similarly, firms that are too large will suffer from difficulties of supervision and coordination, and perhaps from bureaucratic controls, so that their costs per unit of output will also be higher than those of a firm of the most efficient size.

TC

200

MC

45 40 35 30 25 20 15 10 5 0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

9

10

Output, Garages per Year (b) Marginal Cost

Al’s Total, Average, and Marginal Costs

(1)

(2)

Garages per Year

Total Cost per Year (in thousands)

0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

$ 12 40 56 66 74 80 87 96 112 144 190

(3) Marginal Cost per Added Garage (in thousands) $28 16 10 8 6 7 9 16 32 46

(4) Average Cost per Garage (in thousands) — $40 28 22 18.5 16 14.5 13.7 (approx.) 14 16 19

Average Cost per Garage (thousands $)

45

TABLE 2

40 35 30 25

AC

20 15 10 5 0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

9

Output, Garages per Year (c) Average Cost NOTE: Output is in garages per year.

FI GURE 3 Cost Curves for Al’s Garages

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

10

162

Part 2

The Building Blocks of Demand and Supply

TABLE 3 Total Revenues, Costs, and Profit for Al’s Garages

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

Total Total Total Garages Revenue Cost Profit per (TR) (in (TC) (in (TR – TC) (in Year thousands) thousands) thousands) $0 30 56 78 96 110 120 126 128 126 120

$ 12 40 56 66 74 80 87 96 112 144 190

F I GURE 4 Profit Maximization: A Graphical Interpretation

$212 210 0 12 22 30 33 30 16 218 270

$2 10 12 10 8 3 23 214 234 252

Total Revenue, Total Cost per Year (thousands $)

0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Marginal Profit (in thousands)

Because we assume that Al’s objective is to maximize profits, it is simple enough to determine the level of production he will choose. The table indicates that by producing and selling six garages per year, Al’s garage-building operation obtains the highest level of profit it is capable of earning—$33,000 per year (actually, we will see in a moment that it pays Al to produce a little more than this amount). Any higher or lower rate of production would lead to lower profits. For example, profits would drop to $30,000 if output increased to seven garages. If Al were to make the mistake of producing ten garages per season, he would actually suffer a net loss.

Profit Maximization: A Graphical Interpretation We can present the same information on a graph. In Figure 4(a), we bring together into a single diagram the relevant portion of the total revenue curve from Figure 2 and the total cost curve from

200

TC

180 160

Maximum profit

140

TR

M 120 A

100 96 80 74 60

B

$22,000

40 20 0

1

2

3

5

4

6

7

8

9

10

Output, Garages per Year (a) Total Revenue. Total Cost Total Profit per Year (thousands $)

Maximum profit 40 34 20

M E F

C D

0 –20

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

9

10

–40 –60 –80

Output, Garages per Year (b) Total Profit NOTE: Output is in garages per year.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 8

163

Output, Price, and Profit: The Importance of Marginal Analysis

Figure 3. Total profit, which is the difference between total revenue and total cost, appears in the diagram as the vertical distance between the TR and TC curves. For example, when output is four garages, total revenue is $96,000 (point A), total cost is $74,000 (point B), and total profit is the distance between points A and B, or $22,000. In this graphical view of the problem, Al wants to maximize total profit, which is the vertical distance between the TR and TC curves. Figure 4(b) plots these vertical differences derived from Figure 4(a) and so it shows the curve of total profit—that is, TR 2 TC. We see that it reaches its maximum value of about $34,000 (point M) at an output level of 6.5 garages per year—that is, 13 garages every two years. This graph shows that the conclusion we reached by looking at Table 3 was approximately right, but not perfectly accurate. Why? Because the table did not consider the possibility that the labor and material it pays Al to acquire may make it profitable to start on the construction of yet another garage after the first six are completed, with this garage being finished in the next year. We will consider this possibility in more detail in a few paragraphs. The total profit curve in Figure 4(b) is shaped like a hill. Although such a shape is not inevitable, we expect a hill shape to be typical for the following reason: If a firm produces nothing, it certainly earns no profit. At the other extreme, a firm can produce so much output that it swamps the market, forcing price down so low that it loses money. Only at intermediate levels of output—something between zero and the amount that floods the market—can the company earn a positive profit. Consequently, the total profit curve will rise from zero (or negative) levels at a very small output to positive levels at intermediate outputs; finally, it will fall to negative levels when output gets too large.

MARGINAL ANALYSIS AND MAXIMIZATION OF TOTAL PROFIT We see from Figure 4 and Table 3 that many levels of output may yield a positive profit, but the firm is not aiming for just any level of profit. Instead, it wants the largest possible profit. If management knew the exact shape of its profit hill, choosing the optimal level of output would be a simple task indeed. It would merely have to locate the point, such as M in Figure 4(b), that defined the top of its profit hill. However, management rarely, if ever, has so much information, so a different technique for finding the optimum is required. That technique is marginal analysis, which is the same set of tools we used to analyze the firm’s input purchase decisions in Chapter 7 and the consumer ’s buying decisions in Chapters 5 and 6. This time we will use a concept known as marginal profit to solve Al’s problem. Referring back to Table 3, we see that an increase in Al’s output from three to four garages would raise total profit from $12,000 to $22,000; that is, it would generate $10,000 in additional profit, as shown in the last column of Table 3. We call this amount the marginal profit resulting from the addition of the fourth garage. Similarly, marginal profit from the seventh garage would be

Marginal profit is the addition to total profit resulting from one more unit of output.

Total profit from 7 garages 2 Total profit from 6 garages 5 $30,000 2 $33,000 5 2$3,000

The marginal rule for finding the optimal level of output is easy to understand: If the marginal profit from increasing output by one unit is positive, then output should be increased. If the marginal profit from increasing output by one unit is negative, then output should be decreased. Thus, an output level can maximize total profit only if marginal profit is neither positive nor negative—that is, if it equals zero at that output.

For Al’s Building Contractors, the marginal profit from the sixth unit of output (a sixth garage) is $3,000. This means that building six garages is not enough. Because marginal profit is still positive at six garages per year, it pays to produce more than six garages per year. However, marginal profit from the seventh garage is $30,000 2 $33,000, or 2$3,000, so Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Part 2

The Building Blocks of Demand and Supply

the firm should produce less than seven garages because production of the seventh garage would reduce total profit by $3,000. Only at something between six and seven garages, where marginal profit is neither positive nor negative (as is approximately true for 6.5 garages), can total profit be as big as possible, because neither increasing nor reducing output can add to total profit. The marginal profit numbers in Table 3 indicate one way in which marginal analysis helps to improve decisions. If we had looked only at the total profit figures in the fourth column of the table, we might have concluded that six garages is the profitmaximizing output for Al. The marginal profit column (column 5) tells us that this is not so. We see that the marginal profit of a seventh garage is 2$3,000, so Al should, indeed, produce fewer than seven garages per year. But the marginal profit of the sixth garage is 1$3,000, so it pays Al to produce more than six garages. Thus, a production level somewhere between six and seven garages per year, that is, approximately 13 garages every two years, really maximizes profits, as the total profit graph confirms. The profit hill in Figure 4(b) is a graphical representation of the condition stating that to maximize profit, marginal profit should be zero (or as close to zero as possible). Marginal profit is defined as the additional profit that accrues to the firm when output rises by one unit. For example, when output is increased, say, from three units to four units, or the distance CD in Figure 4(b), total profit rises by $10,000 (the distance DE) and marginal profit is therefore DE/CD (see the triangle CDE in the graph). This is precisely the definition of the slope of the total profit curve between points C and E. In general: SOURCE: © David Papazian/Corbis

164

Marginal profit at any output is the slope of the total profit curve at that level of output.

With this geometric interpretation in hand, we can easily understand the logic of the marginal profit rule. At a point such as C in Figure 4(b), where the total profit curve is rising, marginal profit (which equals slope) is positive. Profit cannot be maximal at such a point, because we can increase profits by moving farther to the right. A firm that decided to stick to point C would be wasting the opportunity to increase profits by increasing output, thereby going further up the profit hill. Similarly, the firm cannot be maximizing profits at a point such as F, where the slope of the curve is negative, because there marginal profit (which, again, equals slope) is negative. If it finds itself at a point such as F, the firm can raise its profit by decreasing its output. Only at a point such as M in Figure 4(b), where the total profit curve is neither rising nor falling, can the firm possibly be at the top of the profit hill rather than on one of the sides of the hill. Point M is precisely where the slope of the curve—and hence the marginal profit—is zero. Thus: An output decision cannot be optimal unless the corresponding marginal profit is zero.

It is important to recognize once again that the firm is not interested in marginal profit for its own sake, but rather for what it implies about total profit. Marginal profit is like the needle on the temperature gauge of a car: The needle itself is of no concern to anyone, but failure to watch it can have dire consequences. One common misunderstanding about marginal analysis is the idea that it seems foolish to go to a point where marginal profit is zero. “Isn’t it better to earn a positive marginal profit?” This notion springs from confusion between the quantity one is seeking to maximize (total profit) and the gauge that indicates whether such a maximum has

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

165

Output, Price, and Profit: The Importance of Marginal Analysis

Chapter 8

actually been attained (marginal profit). Of course, it is better to have a positive total profit than a zero total profit. In contrast, a zero value on the marginal profit gauge merely indicates that all is well—that total profit is at its maximum, that we are at the top of the profit hill, where the slope is zero. THE IMPORTANCE OF THINKING AT THE MARGIN Marginal Analysis: You are likely to have noticed a recurrent theme in this chapter, which is a cornerstone of any economic analysis and thus one of our Ideas for Beyond the Final Exam. In any decision about whether to expand an activity, it is always the marginal cost and marginal benefit that are the relevant factors. A calculation based on average data is likely to lead the decision maker to miss all sorts of opportunities, some of them critical. More generally, if one wants to make optimal decisions, marginal analysis should be used in the planning calculations. This is true whether the decision applies to a business firm seeking to maximize total profit or minimize the cost of the output it has selected, to a consumer trying to maximize utility, or to a less developed country striving to maximize per-capita output. It applies as much to decisions on input proportions and advertising as to decisions about output levels and prices.

IDEAS FOR BEYOND THE FINAL EXAM

Marginal Revenue and Marginal Cost: Guides to Optimization An alternative version of the marginal analysis of profit maximization can be derived from the cost and revenue components of profit. For this purpose, refer back to Figure 4, where we used total revenue (TR) and total cost (TC) curves to construct the profit hill. There is another way of finding the profit-maximizing solution. We want to maximize the firm’s profit, which is measured by the vertical distance between the TR and TC curves. This distance is not maximal at an output level such as three units, because there the two curves are growing farther apart. If we move farther to the right, the vertical distance between them (which is total profit) will increase. Similarly, we have not maximized the vertical distance between TR and TC at an output level such as eight units, because there the two curves are coming closer together. We can add to profit by moving farther to the left (reducing output). The conclusion from the graph, then, is that total profit—the vertical distance between TR and TC—is maximized only when the two curves are neither growing farther apart nor coming closer together—that is, when their slopes are equal (in the case of Al’s Building Contractors in Figure 4, at 6.5 garages). Marginal revenue and marginal cost curves, which we learned about earlier TABLE 4 in the chapter, will help us understand this concept better. For precisely the Al’s Marginal Revenue and Marginal Cost same reason that marginal profit is the slope of the total profit curve, marginal revenue is the slope of the total revenue curve—because it represents the in(1) (2) (3) crease in total revenue resulting from the sale of one additional unit. Similarly, Garages Marginal Marginal marginal cost is equal to the slope of the total cost curve. This interpretation of per Revenue (in Cost (in marginal revenue and marginal cost, respectively, as the slopes of the total revYear thousands) thousands) enue and total cost curves permits us to restate the geometric conclusion we 0 — — have just reached in an economically significant way: 1 $30 $28 Profit can be maximized only at an output level at which marginal revenue is (approximately) equal to marginal cost. In symbols: MR 5 MC

The logic of the MR 5 MC rule for profit maximization is straightforward.4 When MR is not equal to MC, profits cannot possibly be maximized because the firm can increase its profits by either raising or reducing its output. For example, if MR 5 $22,000 and MC 5 $10,000 (Table 4), an additional unit of output

2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

26 22 18 14 10 6 2 22 26

4 You may have surmised by now that just as total profit 5 total revenue 2 total cost, it must be true that marginal profit 5 marginal revenue 2 marginal cost. This is, in fact, correct. It also shows that when marginal profit 5 0, we must have MR 5 MC.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

16 10 8 6 7 9 16 32 46

166

Part 2

The Building Blocks of Demand and Supply

F I GURE 5 Profit Maximization: Another Graphical Interpretation

MR and MC per Garage per Year (thousands $)

50

MC

40

30

20 E

10 0 1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

9

10 MR

–10

Total Revenue, Total Cost per Year (thousands $)

Output, Garages per Year (a) Marginal Revenue and Marginal Cost

200

TC

180 160

Maximum profit

140 M

TR

120 A

100 96 80 74 60

B

$22,000

40 20 0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

9

10

Total Profit per Year (thousands $)

Output, Garages per Year (b) Total Revenue. Total Cost

40 34 20

Maximum profit

M E C

F D

0 –20

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

–40 –60 –80

Output, Garages per Year (c) Total Profit

8

9

10

adds $22,000 to revenues but only $10,000 to costs. Hence, the firm can increase its net profit by $12,000 by producing and selling one more unit. Similarly, if MC exceeds MR, say, MR 5 $6,000 and MC 5 $9,000, then the firm loses $3,000 on its marginal unit, so it can add $3,000 to its profit by reducing output by one unit. Only when MR 5 MC (or comes as close as possible to equaling MC) is it impossible for the firm to add to its profit by changing its output level. Table 4 reproduces marginal revenue and marginal cost data for Al’s Building Contractors from Tables 1 and 2. The table shows, as must be true, that the MR 5 MC rule leads us to the same conclusion as Figure 4 and Table 3. If he wants to maximize his profits, Al should produce more than six but fewer than seven garages per year. The marginal revenue of the sixth garage is $10,000 ($120,000 from the sale of six garages less $110,000 from the sale of five garages), whereas the marginal cost is only $7,000 ($87,000 2 $80,000). Therefore, MR > MC and the firm should produce more than the sixth unit. The seventh garage, however, brings in only $6,000 in marginal revenue and its marginal cost is $9,000—clearly a losing proposition. Only at about 6.5 units of output does MR equal MC exactly. Because the graphs of marginal analysis will prove so useful in later chapters, Figure 5(a) shows the MR 5 MC condition for profit maximization graphically. The black curve labeled MR in the figure is the marginal revenue schedule from Table 4. The brick-colored curve labeled MC is the marginal cost schedule. The two curves intersect at point E, where marginal revenue and marginal cost are equal. The optimal output for

NOTE: Output is in garages per year.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 8

Output, Price, and Profit: The Importance of Marginal Analysis

167

Al is 6.5 units.5 Figures 5(b) and 5(c), respectively, reproduce the TR and TC curves from Figure 4(a) and the total profit curve from Figure 4(b). Note how MC and MR intersect at the same output at which the distance of TR above TC is greatest, which is also the output at which the profit hill reaches its peak.

Finding the Optimal Price from Optimal Output At the beginning of this chapter, we set two goals—to determine the profit-maximizing output and to find the profit-maximizing price—and emphasized that once we know either of these, it can automatically tell us the other. So far, we have identified the profit-maximizing output, the output level at which MR 5 MC (6.5 garages per year in our garage-building example). That leaves us with the task of determining the profit-maximizing price. Fortunately, this task requires only one more easy step. As we said earlier, once the firm has selected the output it wants to produce and sell, the demand curve determines the price it must charge to induce consumers to buy that amount of product. Consequently, if we know that the profit-maximizing output is 6.5 garages, the demand curve in Figure 1 tells us what price Al must charge to sell that profit-maximizing output. To sell an average of 6.5 garages per year (that is, 13 garages every two years), he must price each garage at $19,000 (between points f and g). The demand curve tells us that this amount is the only price at which this quantity will be demanded by customers. Once the profit-maximizing output quantity has been determined with the help of the MR 5 MC rule, it is easy to find the profit-maximizing price with the help of the demand curve. Just use that curve to find out at what price the optimal quantity will be demanded.

P OLICY D E B AT E

Profit and the New Market Economies only by the firms themselves but also by some British economists. The debate in the United Kingdom and elsewhere amounts to this: Should severe limits be placed on profits as a matter of fairness and to improve the ethical climate of society, or should such measures be avoided because ceilings on profits undermine the incentives for business success and therefore prevent the market mechanism from delivering the economic abundance of which it is capable?

SOURCE: © The New Yorker Collection 1990 Dana Fradon from cartoonbank.com. All Rights Reserved.

The failure of communism to produce economic abundance has led the nations of Eastern Europe, and even China, to turn to the market mechanism. These countries hope that the market will soon bring them the sort of prosperity achieved by the industrialized countries. The market, as we know, is driven by the profit motive. In a free market, profits are not determined by a government agency, but rather by demand and cost conditions, as described by the demand and cost curves. Many citizens of these new market economies are appalled by the sizes of the profits that the free market affords to successful businesspeople, and they are upset by the greed that these entrepreneurs display. There are pressures to put limits on these profits. The same thing happened in the United Kingdom and elsewhere as firms formerly owned by the government were sold to private individuals and returned to the market. In the United Kingdom, a number of the privatized firms were initially monopolies, and the government chose to protect consumers by putting ceilings on prices but not on profits to provide the firms with appropriate incentives. Yet when some of these firms proved to be quite profitable, the British government agencies reduced the price ceilings so as to cut those profits, a move that was attacked sharply not

“Please stand by, we are switching to a free-market economy”

5 We must note one important qualification. Sometimes marginal revenue and marginal cost curves do not have the nice shapes depicted in Figure 5(a), and they may intersect more than once. In such cases, although it remains true that MR 5 MC at the output level that maximizes profits, there may be other output levels at which MR 5 MC but at which profits are not maximized.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

168

Part 2

The Building Blocks of Demand and Supply

GENERALIZATION: THE LOGIC OF MARGINAL ANALYSIS AND MAXIMIZATION The logic of marginal analysis of profit maximization that we have just studied can be generalized, because essentially the same argument was already used in Chapters 5 and 7 and will recur in a number of chapters later in this book. To avoid having to master the argument each time all over again, it is useful to see how this concept can be applied in problems other than the determination of the firm’s profit-maximizing output. The general issue is this: Decision makers often are faced with the problem of selecting the magnitude of some variable, such as how much to spend on advertising, or how many bananas to buy, or how many school buildings to construct. Each of these acts brings benefits, so the larger the number selected by the decision maker, the larger the total benefits that will be derived. Unfortunately, as larger numbers are selected, the associated costs also grow. The problem is to take the trade-off properly into account and to calculate at what point the net gain—the difference between the total benefit and the total cost—will be greatest. Thus, we have the following general principle: If a decision is to be made about the quantity of some variable, then to maximize Net benefit 5 Total benefit 2 Total cost, the decision maker must select a value of the variable at which Marginal benefit 5 (approximately) Marginal cost

For example, if a community were to determine that the marginal benefit from building an additional school was greater than the cost of an additional school, it would clearly be better off if it built another school. But if the community were planning to build so many schools that the marginal benefit was less than the marginal cost, it would be better off if it switched to a more limited construction program. Only if the marginal benefit and cost are as close as possible to being equal will the community have the optimal number of schools. We will apply this same concept in later chapters. Again and again, when we analyze a quantitative decision that brings together both benefits and costs, we conclude that the optimal decision occurs at the point where the marginal benefit equals the marginal cost. The logic is the same whether we are considering the net gains to a firm, to a consumer, or to society as a whole.

Application: Fixed Cost and the Profit-Maximizing Price We can now use our analytic framework to offer an insight that is often unexpected. Suppose there is a rise in the firm’s fixed cost; for example, imagine that the property taxes on Al’s Building Contractors double. What will happen to the profit-maximizing price and output? Should Al raise his price to cover the increased cost, or should he produce a larger output even if it requires a drop in price? The answer is surprising: Neither! When a firm’s fixed cost increases, its profit-maximizing price and output remain completely unchanged, so long as it pays the firm to stay in business.

In other words, there is nothing that the firm’s management can do to offset the effect of the rise in fixed cost. This is surely a case where common sense is not a reliable guide to the right decision. Why is this so? Recall that, by definition, a fixed cost does not change when output changes. The increase in Al’s fixed costs is the same whether business is slow or booming, whether production is 2 garages or 20. This idea is illustrated in Table 5, which also reproduces Al’s total profits from Table 3. The third column of the table shows that total fixed cost has risen (from zero) to $10,000 per year. As a result, total profit is $10,000 less than it would have been otherwise—no matter what the firm’s output. For example, when output is four units, we see that total profit falls from $22,000 (second column) to $12,000 (last column). Because profit is reduced by the same amount at every output level, whatever output was most profitable before the increase in fixed costs must still be most profitable. In Table 5, we see that $23,000 is the largest entry in the last column, which shows profits after the rise in fixed cost. This approximately highest possible profit is attained, as it was before, when Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

169

Output, Price, and Profit: The Importance of Marginal Analysis

Chapter 8

FIGURE 6

Rise in Fixed Cost: Total Profit Before and After

Fixed Cost Does Not Affect Profit-Maximizing Output

(1) Garages per Year

(2) Total Profit Before (in thousands)

(3) Rise in Fixed Cost (in thousands)

0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

$212 210 0 12 22 30 33 30 16 218 270

$10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10

(4) Total Profit After (in thousands) $222 220 210 2 12 20 23 20 6 228 280

Total Profit per Year (thousands $)

TABLE 5

Profit with zero fixed cost

40

M

Profit with a fixed cost

N 20

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

Output in Garages per Year

output is at six units. The actual profit-maximizing output will remain at 6.5 garages, exactly as before. In other words, the firm’s profit-maximizing price and quantity remain unchanged. This is shown graphically in Figure 6, which displays the firm’s total profit hill before and after the rise in fixed cost (reproducing Al’s initial profit hill from Figure 4). We see that the cost increase simply moves the profit hill straight downward by $10,000, so the highest point on the hill is just lowered from point M to point N. But the top of the hill is shifted neither left nor right. It remains at the 6.5-garage output level.6

PUZZLE RESOLVED:

USING MARGINAL ANALYSIS TO UNRAVEL THE CASE OF THE “UNPROFITABLE” CALCULATOR

We can now put the marginal analysis of profit determination to work to solve the puzzle with which we began this chapter. The example was drawn from reality, and reality never works as neatly as a textbook illustration with a mechanical application of the MR 5 MC rule. However, we will see that the underlying reasoning does shed useful light on real problems. Our “unprofitable” calculator puzzle concerned a firm that produced a number of electronic items, including calculators. The company was apparently losing money on calculator sales because the $12 price was less than the $14.55 average cost that the company’s bookkeepers assigned to the product. This $14.55 figure included $10.30 of (marginal) costs caused directly by the manufacturing and marketing of each additional calculator, plus a $4.25 per-calculator share of the company’s overall general expenses (“overhead”), such as compensation of the company president. When it was accused in a court of law of trying to drive a competitor out of business by deliberately selling below cost, the company turned to marginal analysis to show that the charge was untrue and that the calculators were indeed a profitable line of business. To demonstrate this fact, a witness for the company explained that if selling the calculators really were unprofitable, then the company could increase its earnings by ceasing their production altogether. But, in fact, had the company done so, it would have lowered its profits. To see why, let’s look at the numbers again. If the company gave up the sale of 10 million calculators, its revenues would be reduced by $12 (the price of each calculator) 3 10 million units sold—a (marginal) revenue reduction of $120 million. But how much cost would it save by giving up those sales? The answer is that the cost outlay

6

EXERCISE: Does the added fixed cost change the marginal cost? Explain. What does this imply for optimal output?

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

9

10

170

Part 2

The Building Blocks of Demand and Supply

actually caused by the production of each calculator was only the $10.30 in direct cost. Even if it stopped selling the calculators (which were just one part of its product line), the company would still have to continue to pay for costs like the salary of the company president and general advertising expenditures. In other words, none of the company’s fixed overhead costs would be saved by ending calculator production. Rather, the (marginal) cost saving would be the direct cost of $10.30 per calculator 3 the 10 million calculator output—a total cost saving of just $103 million. The bottom line was that eliminating calculators from the product line would have reduced total profit by $17 million per year—the $120 million in forgone revenue minus the $103 million cost. So, continued production of the calculators was not causing losses; on the contrary, it was contributing $17 million in profits every year, because each unit of output was bringing in $12 in revenue 2 $10.30 in marginal cost 5 $1.70. The court concluded that this reasoning was correct and used this conclusion in its decision. This case illustrates a point that is encountered frequently. The calculator manufacturer was selling its product at a price that appeared not to cover the costs but really did. The appearance stems from the fact that the cost attributable to any one of a company’s products is essentially its marginal cost—the cost the firm must pay to add the item to its product line. But bookkeepers usually don’t think in terms of marginal costs, and in their calculations they often include other types of costs that are not affected by reducing the output of the product or by eliminating its production. The same sort of issue faces airlines that offer discounted fares to students (or to senior citizens, or some other group), when those fares are lower than the average cost (including fuel cost, salaries of personnel, and so on) per passenger. If the discounted fares have the effect of filling up seats that would otherwise have flown empty, and if the fares cover more than their marginal cost (which consists only of the additional cost of selling the tickets and providing the students with a snack), then those fares clearly are adding to the airline’s profits, even though they are below average cost per passenger. Nevertheless, such fare discounts sometimes lead to lawsuits by competitors of the airlines that offer such discounted fares.

CONCLUSION: THE FUNDAMENTAL ROLE OF MARGINAL ANALYSIS

IDEAS FOR BEYOND THE FINAL EXAM

THE IMPORTANCE OF THINKING AT THE MARGIN We saw in Chapter 7 how marginal analysis helps us to understand the firm’s input choices. Similarly, in Chapters 5 and 6, it cast indispensable light on the consumer’s purchase decisions. In this chapter, it enabled us to analyze output and pricing decisions. The logic of marginal analysis applies not only to economic decisions by consumers and firms but also to decisions made by governments, universities, hospitals, and other organizations. In short, this type of analysis applies to any individual or group that must make optimal choices about the use of scarce resources. Thus, one of the most important conclusions that can be drawn from this chapter, and a conclusion brought out vividly by the examples we have just discussed, is the importance of thinking “at the margin”—one of our Ideas for Beyond the Final Exam.

Another real-life example far removed from profit maximization will illustrate how marginal criteria are useful in decision making. For years before women were first admitted to Princeton University (and to several other colleges), administrators cited the cost of the proposed admission of women as a major obstacle. They had decided in advance that any women coming to the university would constitute a net addition to the student body because, for a variety of reasons involving relations with alumni and other groups, it was not feasible to reduce the number of male students. Presumably on the basis of a calculation of average cost, some critics spoke of cost figures as high as $80 million. To economists, it was clear that the relevant figure was actually the marginal cost, or the addition to total cost that would result from the admission of the additional students. The

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 8

Output, Price, and Profit: The Importance of Marginal Analysis

171

women students would, of course, bring additional tuition fees (marginal revenues) to Princeton. If these fees were just sufficient to cover the amount that they would add to costs, the admission of the women would leave the university’s financial picture unaffected. A careful calculation showed that the admission of women would add far less to the university’s financial problems than the average cost figures indicated. One reason was that women’s course preferences at that time were characteristically different from men’s, and hence women frequently selected courses that were undersubscribed in exclusively male institutions. Therefore, the admission of 1,000 women to a formerly allmale institution could be expected to require fewer additional classes than if 1,000 more men had been admitted.7 More important, it was found that a number of classroom buildings were underutilized. The cost of operating these buildings was nearly fixed; their total utilization cost would be changed only slightly by the influx of women. The marginal cost for classroom space was therefore almost zero and certainly well below the average cost (the cost per student). For all of these reasons, it turned out that the relevant marginal cost was much smaller than the figures that had been considered earlier. Indeed, this cost was something like one-third of the earlier estimates. There is little doubt that this careful marginal calculation played a critical role in the admission of women to Princeton at that time and to some other universities that subsequently made use of the calculations in the Princeton analysis. More recent data, incidentally, confirmed that the marginal calculations were amply justified.

THE THEORY AND REALITY: A WORD OF CAUTION We have now completed two chapters describing how business managers can make optimal decisions. Can you go to Wall Street or Main Street and find executives calculating marginal cost and marginal revenue to decide how much to produce? Not very often—although in some important applications they do. Nor can you find consumers in stores using marginal analysis to decide what to buy. Like consumers, successful businesspeople often rely heavily on intuition and “hunches” that cannot be described by any set of rules. In fact, in a 1993 survey of CEOs conducted by Inc. magazine, nearly 20 percent of the respondents admitted to using guesswork to price their products or services. Note that we have not sought to provide a literal description of business behavior but rather a model to help us analyze and predict this behavior. The four chapters that we have just completed constitute the core of microeconomics. We will find ourselves returning again and again to the principles learned in these chapters.

| SUMMARY |

7

1. A firm can choose the quantity of its product that it wants to sell or the price that it wants to charge, but it cannot choose both because price affects the quantity demanded.

3. The demand curve of a firm is determined from the market demand curve by the strength of the competitive efforts of the rival firms in the market.

2. In economic theory, we usually assume that firms seek to maximize profits. This assumption should not be taken literally, but rather interpreted as a useful simplification of reality.

4. Marginal revenue is the additional revenue earned by increasing quantity sold by one unit. Marginal cost is the additional cost incurred by increasing production by one unit.

See Gardner Patterson, “The Education of Women at Princeton,” Princeton Alumni Weekly, 69 (September 24, 1968).

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

172

Part 2

The Building Blocks of Demand and Supply

5. Maximum profit requires the firm to choose the level of output at which marginal revenue is equal to (or most closely approximates) marginal cost.

8. It will generally pay a firm to expand its output if it is selling at a price greater than marginal cost, even if that price happens to be below average cost.

6. Geometrically, the profit-maximizing output level occurs at the highest point on the total profit curve. There the slope of the total profit curve is zero (or as close to zero as possible), meaning that marginal profit is zero.

9. Optimal decisions must be made on the basis of marginal cost and marginal revenue figures, not average cost and average revenue figures. This concept is one of the Ideas for Beyond the Final Exam.

7. A change in fixed cost will not change the profitmaximizing level of output.

| KEY TERMS | average revenue (AR) economic profit 159

160

marginal revenue (MR) optimal decision

160

total profit

156

158

total revenue (TR)

159

marginal profit 163

| TEST YOURSELF | 1. Suppose that the firm’s demand curve indicates that at a price of $10 per unit, customers will demand 2 million units of its product. Suppose that management decides to pick both price and output; the firm produces 3 million units of its product and prices them at $18 each. What will happen? 2. Suppose that a firm’s management would be pleased to increase its share of the market but if it expands its production, the price of its product will fall. Will its profits necessarily fall? Why or why not? 3. Why does it make sense for a firm to seek to maximize total profit rather than to maximize marginal profit? 4. A firm’s marginal revenue is $133 and its marginal cost is $90. What amount of profit does the firm fail to pick up by refusing to increase output by one unit? 5. Calculate average revenue (AR) and average cost (AC) in Table 3. How much profit does the firm earn at the output at which AC 5 AR? Why?

6. A firm’s total cost is $1,000 if it produces one unit, $1,600 if it produces two units, and $2,000 if it produces three units of output. Draw up a table of total, average, and marginal costs for this firm. 7. Draw an average and marginal cost curve for the firm in Test Yourself Question 6 above. Describe the relationship between the two curves. 8. A firm has the demand and total cost schedules given in the following table. If it wants to maximize profits, how much output should it produce? Quantity 1 2 3 4 5

Price $6 5 4 3 2

Total Cost $ 1.00 2.50 6.00 7.00 11.00

| DISCUSSION QUESTION | 1. “It may be rational for the management of a firm not to try to maximize profits.” Discuss the circumstances under which this statement may be true.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 8

Output, Price, and Profit: The Importance of Marginal Analysis

173

| APPENDIX | The Relationships Among Total, Average, and Marginal Data You may have surmised that there is a close connection between the average revenue curve and the marginal revenue curve and that there must be a similar relationship between the average cost curve and the marginal cost curve. After all, we derived our average revenue figures from the total revenues and also calculated our marginal revenue figures from the total revenues at the various possible output levels; a similar relationship applied to costs. In fact: Marginal, average, and total figures are inextricably bound together. From any one of the three sets of figures, the other two can be calculated. The relationships among total, average, and marginal data are exactly the same for any variable—such as revenue, cost, or profit— to which the concepts apply.

To illustrate and emphasize the wide applicability of marginal analysis, we switch our example from profits, revenues, and costs to a noneconomic variable. As we are about to see, the same concepts can be applied to human body weights. We use this example because calculation of weights is more familiar to most people than calculation of profits, revenues, or costs, and it can illustrate several fundamental relationships between average and marginal figures. In Table 6, we begin with an empty room. (The total weight of occupants is equal to zero.) A person weighing 100 pounds enters; total, marginal, and average weights are all, then, 100 pounds. If this person is followed by a person weighing 140 pounds (marginal weight equals 140 pounds), the total weight increases to 240 pounds, average weight rises to 120 pounds (240/2), and so on.8 TABLE 6 Weights of Persons in a Room (in pounds)

Number of Persons in a Room

Marginal Weight

Total Weight

Average Weight

0 1 2 3 4 5 6

100 140 135 125 100 60

0 100 240 375 500 600 660

— 100 120 125 125 120 110

In this illustration, “persons in room” is analogous to units of output, “total weight” is analogous to total revenue or cost, and “marginal weight” is analogous to marginal revenue or cost in the discussions of marginal analysis in the body of the chapter. 8

The rule for converting totals to averages, and vice versa, is Rule 1a. Average weight equals total weight divided by number of persons. Rule 1b. Total weight equals average weight times number of persons.

This rule naturally applies equally well to cost, revenue, profit, or any other variable. We calculate marginal weight from total weight by working with the same subtraction process already used to calculate marginal cost and marginal revenue. Specifically: Rule 2a. The marginal weight of, say, the third person equals the total weight of three people minus the total weight of two people.

For example, when the fourth person enters the room, total weight rises from 375 to 500 pounds, and hence the corresponding marginal weight is 500 2 375 5 125 pounds, as is shown in the second column of Table 6. We can also do the reverse—calculate total from marginal weight—through an addition process. Rule 2b. The total weight of, say, three people equals the (marginal) weight of the first person who enters the room plus the (marginal) weight of the second person, plus the (marginal) weight of the third person.

You can verify Rule 2b by referring to Table 6, which shows that the total weight of three persons, 375 pounds, is indeed equal to 100 1 140 1 135 pounds, the sum of the preceding marginal weights. A similar relation holds for any other total weight figure in the table, a fact that you should verify. In addition to these familiar arithmetic relationships, there are two other useful relationships. Rule 3. With an exception (fixed cost) that was discussed in Chapter 7, the marginal, average, and total figures for the first person must all be equal.

That is, when there is only one person in the room whose weight is X pounds, the average weight will obviously be X, the total weight must be X, and the marginal weight must also be X (because the total must have risen from zero to X pounds). Put another way, when the marginal person is alone, he or she is obviously the average person and also represents the totality of all relevant persons. Our final and very important relationship is Rule 4. If marginal weight is lower than average weight, then average weight must decrease when the number of persons increases. If marginal weight exceeds average weight, average weight must increase when the number of persons increases. If marginal and average weight are

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Part 2

The Building Blocks of Demand and Supply

equal, the average weight must remain constant when the number of persons increases.

These three possibilities are all illustrated in Table 6. Notice, for example, that when the third person enters the room, the average weight increases from 120 to 125 pounds. That increase occurs because this person’s (marginal) weight is 135 pounds, which is above the average and therefore pulls up the average, as Rule 4 requires. Similarly, when the sixth person—who is a 60pound child—enters the room, the average decreases from 120 to 110 pounds because marginal weight, 60 pounds, is below average weight and so pulls the average down. It is essential to avoid a common misunderstanding of this rule. It does not state, for example, that if the average figure is rising, the marginal figure must be rising. When the average rises, the marginal figure may rise, fall, or remain unchanged. The arrival of two persons, both well above the average weight, will push the average up in two successive steps even if the second new arrival is lighter than the first. We see such a case in Table 6, where average weight rises successively from 100 to 120 to 125 pounds, whereas the marginal weight falls from 140 to 135 to 125 pounds.

GRAPHICAL REPRESENTATION OF MARGINAL AND AVERAGE CURVES We have shown how, from a curve of total profit (or total cost or total anything else), we can determine the corresponding marginal figure. In the chapter, we noted repeatedly that the marginal value at any particular point is equal to the slope of the corresponding total curve at that point. But for some purposes, it is convenient to use a graph that records marginal and average values directly rather than deriving them from the curve of totals. We can obtain such a graph by plotting the data in a table of average and marginal figures, such as Table 6. The result looks like the graph shown in Figure 7. In that graph, the number of persons in the room appears on the horizontal axis and the corresponding average and marginal figures appear on the vertical axis. The solid dots represent average weights; the small circles represent

FIGURE 7 The Relationship between Marginal and Average Curves

Marginal and Average Weight (pounds)

174

100

E C

A

D F Marginal weight

50

0

Average weight

B

150

1

2

3

4

5

6

Number of Persons

marginal weights. For example, point A shows that when two people are in the room, their average weight is 120 pounds, as recorded on the third line of Table 6. Similarly, point B on the graph represents information provided in the next column of the table—that is, that the marginal weight of the third person who enters the room is 135 pounds. We have connected these points into a marginal curve and an average curve, represented, respectively, by the solid and the broken curves in the diagram. This is the representation of marginal and average values economists most frequently use. Figure 7 illustrates two of our rules. Rule 3 says that for the first unit, the marginal and average values will be the same; that is precisely why the two curves start out together at point C. The graph also depicts Rule 4 between points C and E: Where the average curve is rising, the marginal curve lies above the average. (Notice that over part of this range, the marginal curve falls even though the average curve is rising; Rule 4 says nothing about the rise or fall of the marginal curve.) We see also that over range EF, where the average curve is falling, the marginal curve is below the average curve, again in accord with Rule 4. Finally, at point E, where the average curve is neither rising nor falling, the marginal curve meets the average curve; the average and marginal weights are equal at that point, so the marginal weights do not pull the average weight either upward or downward.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 8

Output, Price, and Profit: The Importance of Marginal Analysis

175

| TEST YOURSELF | 1. Suppose that the following table is your record of exam grades in your Principles of Eonomics course: Use these data to make up a table of total, average, and marginal grades for the five exams. Exam Date September 30 October 28 November 26 December 13 January 24

Grade 65 75 90 85 95

2. From the data in your exam-grade table in Test Yourself Question 1, illustrate each of the rules mentioned in this appendix. Be sure to point out an instance where the marginal grade falls but the average grade rises.

Comment A slow start A big improvement Happy Thanksgiving! Slipped a little A fast finish!

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Investing in Business: Stocks and Bonds A bargain that is going to become a greater bargain is no bargain. M ARTI N SHU BI K, YAL E U NI VE R S I TY

A

firm does more than select inputs, outputs, and prices—which were the topics of previous chapters. In this chapter, we discuss how real firms finance their activities—notably with stocks and bonds. These days, a very large proportion of the nation’s college graduates invests money in the stock and bond markets. You probably will as well, if you don’t already. For this reason, it is important to understand something about how these markets work, but please do not think that this chapter will turn you into a super speculator who can beat the market consistently. Too many investors have thought that way and ended up losing their life’s savings. Indeed, the main lesson of this chapter is that, for good reason, the future behavior of the stock market is virtually unpredictable. As you look toward the future, the stock market will undoubtedly go up and undoubtedly go down, but the unanswerable question is: When? History repeatedly teaches us that lesson, and as philosopher George Santayana once wrote, “Those who cannot remember the past are condemned to repeat it”—as many stock market investors have done.1

C O N T E N T S PUZZLE 1: WHAT IN THE WORLD HAPPENED TO

What Determines Stock Prices? The Role of Expected Company Earnings

PUZZLE 2: THE STOCK MARKET’S

BUYING STOCKS AND BONDS

THE STOCK MARKET?

UNPREDICTABILITY

1

Selecting a Portfolio: Diversification

CORPORATIONS AND THEIR UNIQUE CHARACTERISTICS

STOCK EXCHANGES AND THEIR FUNCTIONS

Financing Corporate Activity: Stocks and Bonds Plowback, or Retained Earnings

Regulation of the Stock Market Stock Exchanges and Corporate Capital Needs

SPECULATION PUZZLE 2 RESOLVED: UNPREDICTABLE STOCK

PRICES AS “RANDOM WALKS”

PUZZLE 1 REDUX: THE BOOM AND BUST OF THE

U.S. STOCK MARKET

George Santayana, The Life of Reason: Or, The Phases of Human Progress, Vol. I (New York: C. Scribner’s Sons, 1905–1906).

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

178

Part 2

The Building Blocks of Demand and Supply

PUZZLE 1:

WHAT IN THE WORLD HAPPENED TO THE STOCK MARKET?

NASDAQ Stock Market Composite Index, 1990–2007

Mar. 00

5000

4000

3000

2000 Oct. 98

Sep. 01

1000

Ja

nJu 90 lJa 90 nJu 91 lJa 91 nJu 92 lJa 92 nJu 93 lJa 93 nJu 94 lJa 94 nJu 95 lJa 95 nJu 96 lJa 96 nJu 97 lJa 97 nJu 98 lJa 98 nJu 99 lJa 99 nJu 00 lJa 00 nJu 01 lJa 01 nJu 02 lJa 02 nJu 03 lJa 03 nJu 04 lJa 04 nJu 05 lJa 05 nJu 06 lJa 06 nJu 07 l-0 7

0

SOURCE: http://www.freelunch.com.

F I GURE 1

NASDAQ Composite Index (Feb. 5, 1971 = 100)

Sometimes a picture really is worth a thousand words. Figure 1 shows the remarkable behavior of share prices on the NASDAQ stock market (which we will describe later in the chapter) between 1990 and 2007. It looks a bit like the Rocky Mountains, rising spectacularly from the autumn of 1998 to early 2000, and then falling dramatically back down to earth. The numbers on the scale tell you that the index soared from about 1,600 in October 1998 to about 4,800 in March 2000—an astonishing gain of 200 percent in less than a year and a half! But by the fall of 2001, the index was back to about where it had been in October 1998. All in all, it was one of the most spectacular booms and busts in stock market history. What in the world happened? In all honesty, most of the world’s best economists and leading financial experts were left puzzled by this episode. As we will learn in this chapter, the value of a share of stock is supposed to reflect the current and future profits of the company that issues the stock. But that theory of stock prices will not explain why shares of Amazon.com, the online retailer, once sold for about $105 per share and then plunged to around $6 (it was about $131 as this book went to press), or why shares of Priceline.com (which sells airline tickets and books hotel reservations online) once sold for about $165 per share and dropped to around $4 (as against $241 at press time). Alan Greenspan, former chairman of the Federal Reserve, once called the phenomenon that gripped America in the boom years “irrational exuberance”—and it was certainly that. One of the authors of this book called the upside of Figure 1 the “Wile E. Coyote stock market,” after that old nemesis in Road Runner cartoons, who would run off cliffs and yet somehow manage to remain in the air—until he looked down.

Apparently, investors in U.S. technology stocks “looked down” around March 2000. But why then? Why not before? And what made stock prices rise so high in the first place? As we said, the answers to such questions remain shrouded in mystery. Even so, we will be able to throw a little light on the subject by the end of the chapter.

PUZZLE 2:

THE STOCK MARKET’S UNPREDICTABILITY

The stock market is obviously something of an enigma. No other economic activity is reported in such detail in so many newspapers and other media and followed with such concern by so many people. Yet few activities have so successfully eluded prediction of their future. There is no shortage of wellpaid “experts” prepared to forecast the future of the market or the price of a particular stock or the earnings of the company to which the stock price is related. But there are real questions about what these experts deliver.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 9

179

Investing in Business: Stocks and Bonds

For example, a famous study of leading stock market analysts’ predictions of company earnings (on which they based their stock price forecasts) reports: [W]e wrote to 19 major Wall Street firms . . . among the most respected names in the investment business. We requested—and received—past earnings predictions on how these firms felt earnings for specific companies would behave over both a one-year and a five-year period. These estimates . . . were . . . compared with actual results to see how well the analysts forecast shortrun and long-run earnings changes. . . . Bluntly stated, the careful estimates of security analysts (based on industry studies, plant visits, etc.) do very little better than those that would be obtained by simple extrapolation of past trends. . . . For example . . . the analysts’ estimates were compared [with] the assumption that every company in the economy would enjoy a growth in earnings approximating the long-run rate of growth of the national income. It often turned out that . . . this naïve forecasting model . . . would make smaller errors in forecasting long-run earnings growth than . . . [did] the professional forecasts of the analysts. . . . When confronted with the poor record of their five-year growth estimates, the security analysts honestly, if sheepishly, admitted that five years ahead is really too far in advance to make reliable projections. They protested that, although long-term projections are admittedly important, they really ought to be judged on their ability to project earnings changes one year ahead. Believe it or not, it turned out that their one-year forecasts were even worse than their fiveyear projections.2

It has been said that an investor may as well pick stocks by throwing darts at the stock market page—it is far cheaper to buy a set of darts than to obtain the apparently useless advice of a professional analyst. Indeed, there have been at least two experiments, one by a U.S. senator and one by Forbes magazine, in which stocks picked by dart-throwing actually outperformed the mutual funds, the stocks of which are selected by experts. Later in this chapter we will suggest an explanation for this poor performance.

CORPORATIONS AND THEIR UNIQUE CHARACTERISTICS Stocks and bonds are created by corporations and are among the primary tools that these companies use to acquire the funds they need to operate. Corporations play a crucial role in the U.S. economy. Revenues of the top 50 American corporations totaled $4.9 trillion in 2008, or nearly 35 percent of the country’s estimated $14.4 trillion gross domestic product (GDP). Some of these are true industrial giants. Wal-Mart Stores alone generated $378 billion in revenue in 2008, and Exxon Mobil and Chevron took in more than $372 billion and $210 billion, respectively. The combined revenues of just these three firms amounted to considerably more than the GDP of Belgium (and Denmark, Ireland, Norway, Switzerland, and many other countries). But only 20 percent of American firms are incorporated, because most firms are small. Even many corporations are quite small— 40 percent have business receipts of less than $100,000 per year.3 That said, almost all large American firms are corporations. It’s a word you’ve heard used many times. But what, exactly, is a “corporation”? A corporation is a type of firm that is defined by law and to which the law assigns special privileges and special obligations. Three noteworthy features that their legal status entails are the following: • Special limits are placed on the losses that may be suffered by those who invest in these firms. • These firms are subjected to types of taxation from which other firms are exempt. Burton G. Malkiel, A Random Walk Down Wall Street (New York: W. W. Norton; 1990), pp. 140–141. “Fortune 500: The 500 Largest U.S. Corporations,” Fortune magazine, April 5, 2004, p. 289; and Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, OECD in Figures, 2004, http://new.sourceoecd.org. 2 3

A corporation is a firm that has the legal status of a fictional individual. This fictional individual is owned by a number of people, called its stockholders, and is run by a set of elected officers and a board of directors, whose chairperson is often also in a powerful position.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

180

Part 2

The Building Blocks of Demand and Supply

• The corporation is considered to be an entity that is distinct from any of its owners or its management, so that the corporation can outlast the association of any and all of the individuals who are currently connected with the firm.

Limited liability is a legal obligation of a firm’s owners to pay back company debts only with the money they have already invested in the firm.

Let us consider the logic behind these three features. To begin with, although it may seem strange, a corporation is considered an individual in the eyes of the law. Therefore, its earnings, like those of other individuals, are taxed. Thus the legal status leads to what is called “double taxation” of the stockholders. Unlike the earnings of other firms, corporate earnings are taxed twice—once when they are earned by the company and a second time when they go to investors in the form of dividends (and are subject to the personal income tax). This disadvantage is counterbalanced by an important legal advantage, however: Any corporate debt is regarded as that fictitious individual’s obligation, not any one stockholder’s liability. In this way, stockholders benefit from the protection of limited liability—they can lose no more money than they have invested in the firm. In contrast, if you are part or sole owner of a firm that is not a corporation, and it loses money and cannot repay its debts, you can be sued by the people to whom the money is owed, who may be able to force you to pay them out of your own bank account or by selling your vacation home. Limited liability is the main secret of the success of the corporate organizational form, and the reason that some corporations grow so big. Thanks to that provision, individuals throughout the world are willing to invest money in firms whose operations they do not understand and whose management personnel they do not know. Each shareholder receives in return a claim on the firm’s profits and, at least in principle, a portion of the company’s ownership. The corporate form is a boon to investors because their liability for loss is limited to their investments. There is also a major disadvantage to this form of business organization: Corporate income is taxed twice.

Financing Corporate Activity: Stocks and Bonds

A common stock (also called a share) of a corporation is a piece of paper that gives the holder of the stock a share of the ownership of the company. A bond is simply an IOU sold by a corporation that promises to pay the holder of the bond a fixed sum of money at the specified maturity date and some other fixed amount of money (the coupon or interest payment) every year up to the date of maturity.

When a corporation needs money to add to its plant or equipment, or to finance other types of investment, it may reinvest its own earnings (rather than paying them out as dividends to stockholders), or print and sell new stock certificates or new bonds, or take out a loan. Stocks and bonds, in the last analysis, are pieces of paper printed by the firm under a variety of legal safeguards. If it can find buyers, the firm can sell these pieces of paper to the investing public when it wants to obtain more money to invest in its operations. How can a firm obtain money in exchange for such printed paper as a stock or bond certificate? Doesn’t the process seem a bit like counterfeiting? If done improperly, there are indeed grounds for the suspicion. But, carried out appropriately, it is a perfectly reasonable economic process. First, let’s define our terms. Common stock represents partial ownership of a corporation. For example, if a company issues 100,000 shares, then a person who owns 1,000 shares owns 1 percent of the company and is entitled to 1 percent of the company’s dividends, the corporation’s annual payments to stockholders. This shareholder’s vote also normally counts for 1 percent of the total votes in an election of corporate officers or in a referendum on corporate policy. Bonds differ from stocks in several ways. First, the purchaser of a corporation’s stock buys a share of its ownership and some control over its affairs, whereas a bond purchaser simply lends money to the firm and obtains no part of its ownership. Second, whereas stockholders have no idea how much they will receive when they sell their stocks or how much they will receive in dividends each year, bondholders know with a high degree of certainty how much money they will be paid if they hold their bonds to maturity (the date the firm has promised to repay the loan). For instance, a bond with a face value of $1,000 and an $80 coupon (the firm’s annual interest payment to the bondholder) that matures in 2010 will provide $80 per year every year until 2010, and the firm will repay the bondholder’s $1,000 in 2010. Unless the company goes bankrupt,

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 9

181

Investing in Business: Stocks and Bonds

this repayment schedule is guaranteed. Third, bondholders legally have a prior claim on company earnings, which means the stockholders receive no money until the firm has paid its bondholders. For all these reasons, bonds are considered less risky investments than stocks.4 To return to the question we asked earlier, a new issue of stocks and bonds is generally not like counterfeiting. As long as the funds obtained from the sale of the new securities5 are used effectively to increase a firm’s profit-earning capacity, these funds will automatically yield any required repayment and appropriate interest and dividends to purchasers. Occasionally, this payout does not happen. One of the favorite practices of the more notorious nineteenth-century market manipulators was “watering” company stocks—issuing stocks with little or nothing to back them up. The term is originally derived from the practice of some cattle dealers who would force their animals to drink large quantities of water just before bringing them to be weighed for sale.

Stocks and bonds are also called securities.

Similarities Between Stocks and Bonds In reality, the differences between stocks and bonds are not as clear-cut as just described. Two relevant misconceptions are worth noting. First, the ownership represented by a few shares of a company’s stock may be more symbolic than real. A person who holds 0.02 percent of IBM Corporation stock—which, by the way, is a very large investment— exercises no real control over IBM’s operations. In fact, many economists believe that the ownership of large corporations is so diffuse that stockholders or stockholder groups rarely have any effective control over management. In this view, a corporation’s management is a largely independent decision-making body; as long as it keeps enough cash flowing to stockholders to prevent discontent and organized rebellion, management can do anything it wants within the law. Looked at in this way, stockholders, like bondholders, merely provide loans to the company. The only real difference between the two groups, according to this interpretation, is that stockholders’ loans are riskier and therefore entitled to higher payments. Second, bonds actually can be a very risky investment. People who try to sell their bonds before maturity may find that the market price happens to be low; so if they need to raise cash in a hurry, they may incur substantial losses. Also, bondholders may be exposed to losses from inflation. Whether the $1,000 promised to the bondholder at the 2010 maturity date represents substantial (or very little) purchasing power depends on what happens to the general price level in the meantime (that is, how much price inflation occurs). No one can predict the price level this far in advance with any accuracy. Finally, a firm can issue bonds with little backing; that is, the firm may own little valuable property that it can use as a guarantee of repayment to the lender—the bondholder. This is often true of “junk bonds,” and it helps to explain their high risk.

Inflation occurs when prices in an economy rise rapidly. The rate of inflation is calculated by averaging the percentage growth rate of the prices of a selected sample of commodities.

Bond Prices and Interest Rates What makes bond prices go up and down? A straightforward relationship exists between bond prices and current interest rates: Whenever one goes up, the other must go down. The term interest rate refers to the amount that borrowers currently pay to lenders per dollar of the money borrowed—it is the current market price of a loan. For example, suppose that J.C. Penney issued 15-year bonds when interest rates were comparatively low, so the company had to pay only 6 percent to sell the bonds. People who invested $1,000 in those bonds received a contract that promised them $60 per year for 15 years plus the return of their $1,000 at the end of that period. Suppose, however, that interest rates rise, so that new 15-year bonds of similar companies now pay 12 percent. An investor with $1,000 can now buy a bond that offers $120 per year. Obviously, no one will now pay $1,000 for a bond that promises only $60 per year. Consequently, the market price of the old J.C. Penney bonds must fall.

The interest rate is the amount that borrowers currently pay to lenders per dollar of the money borrowed—it is the current market price of a loan.

An important exception involves so-called junk bonds—very risky bonds that became popular in the 1980s. They were used heavily by people trying to purchase enough of a corporation’s stock to acquire control of that firm. 5 Stocks and bonds are also called securities. 4

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

182

Part 2

The Building Blocks of Demand and Supply

This example is not entirely hypothetical. Until a few years ago, bonds issued much earlier—at interest rates of 6 percent or lower—were still in circulation. In the 1980s’ markets, when interest rates were well above 6 percent, such bonds sold for prices far below their original values. When interest rates rise, the prices of previously issued bonds with lower interest earnings must fall. For the same reason, when interest rates fall, the prices of previously issued bonds must rise.

It follows that as interest rates change because of changes in government policy or other reasons, bond prices fluctuate. That is one reason why bonds can be a risky investment.

Corporate Choice Between Stocks and Bonds If a corporation chooses to finance the construction of new factories and equipment through the issue of new stocks or bonds, how does it determine whether bonds or stocks best suit its purposes? Two considerations are of prime importance. Although issuing bonds generally exposes a firm to more risk than issuing stocks, the corporation usually expects to pay more money to stockholders over the long run. In other words, to the firm that issues them, bonds are cheaper but riskier. The decision about which is better for the firm therefore involves a trade-off between the two considerations of expense and risk. Why are bonds risky to a corporation? When it issues $20 million in new bonds at 10 percent, a company commits itself to pay out $2 million every year of the bond’s life, whether business is booming or the firm is losing money. If the firm is unable to meet its obligation to bondholders in some year, bankruptcy may result. Stocks do not burden the company with any such risk, because the firm does not promise to pay stockholders any fixed amount. Stockholders simply receive whatever is left of the company’s net earnings after the firm makes its payments to bondholders. If nothing is left to pay the new stockholders in some years, legally speaking, that is just their bad luck. The higher risk faced by stockholders is the reason they normally obtain higher average payments than bondholders. To the firm that issues them, bonds are riskier than stocks because they commit the firm to make a fixed annual payment, even in years when it is losing money. For the same reason, stocks are riskier than bonds to the buyers of securities. Therefore, stockholders expect to be paid more money than bondholders.

Plowback, or Retained Earnings Plowback (or retained earnings) is the portion of a corporation’s profits that management decides to keep and reinvest in the firm’s operations rather than paying out as dividends to stockholders.

The final major source of funds for corporations, in addition to loans and the issue of stocks and bonds, is plowback, or retained earnings. For example, if a company earns $30 million after taxes and decides to pay only $10 million in dividends to its stockholders and reinvest the remaining $20 million in the firm, that $20 million is called “plowback.” When business is profitable, corporate managers will often prefer plowback to other sources of funding. For one thing, plowback usually involves lower risk. Also, plowback, unlike other sources of funding, does not come under the scrutiny of the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC), the government agency that regulates stocks.6 And, of course, plowback does not depend on the availability of eager customers for new company stocks and bonds. An issue of new securities can be a disappointment if there is little public demand when they are offered, but plowback runs no such risk. Above all, a plowback decision generally does not call attention to the degree of success of management’s operations, as a new stock issue does. When stock is issued, the SEC, potential buyers, and their professional advisers may all scrutinize the company carefully. No management has a perfect record, and the process may reveal things management would prefer to be overlooked. 6 The Securities and Exchange Commission, established in 1934, protects the interests of people who buy securities. It requires firms that issue stock and other securities to provide information about their financial condition, and it regulates the issue and trading of securities.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

What Determines Stock Prices? The Role of Expected Company Earnings

120 105

100 80

76

60 Percent

Another reason for plowback’s attractiveness is that issuing new stocks and bonds is usually an expensive and lengthy process. The SEC requires companies to gather masses of data in a prospectus—a document that describes a company’s financial condition—before any new issue is approved. Figure 2 shows the relative importance of each of the different funding sources to U.S. nonfinancial corporations. It indicates that plowback accounted for more than 100 percent of total corporate financing in 2007, while new bond issues and other forms of debt accounted for another 76 percent. How can this be? As the figure shows, new stock sales amounted to a stunning minus 81 percent of corporate financing, because corporations reduced the number of their stocks in the public’s hands by buying some back.

183

Investing in Business: Stocks and Bonds

SOURCE: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, “Flow of Funds Accounts of the United States, Flows and Outstandings, Third Quarter 2007,” Washington, D.C., December 6, 2007 (data for non-farm, non-financial corporate business).

Chapter 9

40 20 0 Plowback

−20

New bonds and other debt

−40

People invest in stocks because they believe (and −60 hope) that the prices of the stocks they have purchased will rise. But will they? To answer that question, one −80 should understand just what determines the price of a stock—but we do not really know the answer. We do know that, as with other things sold in markets, prices are determined by supply and demand. That merely raises the next question: What explains the behavior of supply and demand? That answer depends on the actions and expectations of the people who have stocks to sell or who wish to buy. There is one apparently logical answer, although later we will see that there are reasons to question that explanation. This answer is that a stock is simply a share of the ownership of the firm that has issued it. The stock will therefore be valuable if the firm earns a good deal of money in the future, and it will rise in price if the firm earns more than investors had expected. The stock will fall in price if the earnings of the firm are poor or disappointing. That is why professional stock analysts who sell their advice to investors devote most of their efforts to studying individual firms and their markets, hoping to gain some insights into each company’s future earnings prospects. Though the stock market has generally been a good investment in the long run, it can be very risky over shorter periods, as we have seen. During the Great Depression that began in 1929, stock prices dropped precipitately and remained low for years. They did not re-attain their 1929 peaks until 1954. More recently, we have just lived through a decade in which stock market gains were zero.

–81

New stocks

FI GURE 2 Sources of New Funds for U.S. Corporations, 2007

BUYING STOCKS AND BONDS Although investors can purchase stocks and bonds through any brokerage firm, not all brokers charge the same fees. Bargain brokerage houses advertise in the newspapers’ financial pages, offering investors very little service—no advice, no research, no other frills—other than merely buying or selling what the customer wants them to, at lower fees than those charged by higher-service brokerage firms. And during the late 1990s, it became possible to buy and sell shares over the Internet at very low cost—and millions of Americans did so. Many investors are not aware of the various ways in which they can purchase (or sell) stocks. Two noteworthy arrangements are (1) a market order purchase, which simply tells the broker to buy a specified quantity of stock at the best price the market currently offers, and (2) a limit order, which is an agreement to buy a given amount of stock when its price falls to

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Part 2

The Building Blocks of Demand and Supply

SOURCE: © The New Yorker Collection, 1957. Richard Decker from http://www.cartoonbank.com. All Rights Reserved.

184

“To hell with a balanced portfolio. I want to sell my Fenwick Chemical and sell it now.” Equities includes individual stocks, stock mutual funds, hybrid mutual funds, exchange-traded funds, and variable annuities. Portfolio diversification means inclusion of a number and variety of stocks, bonds, and other such items in an individual’s portfolio. If the individual owns airline stocks, for example, diversification requires the purchase of a stock or bond in a very different industry, such as breakfast cereal production. A mutual fund, in which individual investors can buy shares, is a private investment firm that holds a portfolio of securities. Investors can choose among a large variety of mutual funds, such as stock funds, bond funds, and so forth. An index fund is a mutual fund that chooses a particular stock price index and then buys the stocks (or most of the stocks) that are included in the index. The value of an investment in an index fund depends on what happens to the prices of all stocks in that index. A stock price index, such as the S&P 500, is an average of the prices of a large set of stocks. These stocks are selected to represent the price movements of the entire stock market, or some specified segment of the market, and the chosen set is rarely changed.

a specified level. If the investor offers to buy at $18, then the broker will purchase shares if and when the market price falls to $18 per share or less. One recent survey estimated that, in 2008, 47 percent of U.S. households (54.5 million) owned equities7 and/or bonds—up from 39 percent of U.S. households in 1989, but down from a peak of about 57 percent of households in 2001. Of these, 60 percent of U.S. households owned both equities and bonds, 36 percent owned only equities, and 4 percent owned only bonds.8

Selecting a Portfolio: Diversification

Perhaps the first rule of safe investing is: Always diversify— never put all your eggs in one basket.9 A person or an organization’s holdings of securities from several different corporations is called a portfolio of investments. A portfolio tends to be far less risky than any of the individual securities it contains because of the benefits of portfolio diversification. Let’s see why. If, for example, Alex divides his holdings among Companies A, B, and C, then his portfolio may perform satisfactorily overall even if Company A goes broke. Moreover, suppose that Company A specializes in producing luxury items, which do well in prosperous periods but very badly during recessions, whereas Company B sells cheap clothing, whose cyclical demand pattern differs greatly from that of Company A. If Alex holds stock in both companies, his overall risk is obviously less than if he owned stock in only one. All other things being equal, a portfolio containing many different types of securities tends to be less risky than a portfolio with fewer types of securities. Increasingly, institutional investors, such as mutual funds, have adopted portfolios composed of broad ranges of stocks typifying those offered by the entire stock market. Mutual funds are now among the largest U.S. investors in securities. They offer their customers portfolios of various groups of domestic stocks, foreign stocks, and bonds. Small investors can easily put their money into these funds, thereby reducing the risks of owning individual stocks and ensuring that the overall market does not significantly outperform their portfolios. Mutual fund transactions can be carried out by telephone or over the Internet, and investors can also easily check on the past performance of the different funds and obtain other pertinent information. Investors purchasing mutual fund shares should check on the fees charged by different funds, because fees vary surprisingly widely from one fund to another—and the difference can have a large effect on the relative earnings of an investment in a fund. One kind of mutual fund, called an index fund, buys the securities used in one of the standard stock price indexes (such as Standard & Poor’s 500—known as the S&P 500—or the broader Wilshire 5000 Index). A stock price index is an average of the prices of a group of stocks—weighted by the size of each company—that are believed to be representative of the overall stock market (or some specialized segment, such as Far Eastern stocks). When you invest in an index fund, the return on your money will therefore reflect the performance of the entire market, rather than any one or a few securities that you or your broker might have selected instead. “A cheap alternative to traditional fund management arose more than 30 years ago, in the form of [index funds that simply buy and hold on to a large representative sample of securities] such as the S&P 500, [rarely incurring the cost of buying or selling]. . . . small investors ought to worry about cost. Figures from John Bogle, founder of the fund giant Vanguard, show that an S&P 500 index-fund returned 12.3% a year between 1980 and 2005, The term equities includes individual stocks, stock mutual funds, hybrid mutual funds, exchange-traded funds, and variable annuities. 8 Investment Company Institute and the Securities Industry and Financial Markets Association, Equity and Bond Ownership in America: 2008, 2008, pp. 5–8, accessed online at http://www.ici.org/pdf/rpt_08_equity_owners.pdf. 9 This was a bitter lesson for employees of Enron, the giant firm that went bankrupt so spectacularly in 2001. Many of its workers invested much of their savings in high-priced Enron stocks and lost virtually everything when the price of Enron stock later plunged. 7

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 9

Investing in Business: Stocks and Bonds

185

“What Is a Share of Google Worth?” (As this book went to press, Google was selling for about $565 a share.)

SOURCE: © AP IMAGES / Ben Margot

It almost goes without saying that Google is one of the world’s leading brands. Its Internet search engine is so ubiquitous that its very name is a verb for looking up information about someone or something. So when its founders decided to “go public” and offer shares of the company for the public to buy, the announcement set off tremendous speculation about what the company would be worth. Google itself predicted a jaw-dropping price range of $108 to $135 for its shares, which would have translated into a company value of $36 billion dollars. That would put Google right up there with the bluest of the “blue chip” stocks—of the thousands of publicly listed companies in the United States, only about 70 companies have a market value that high.* On August 19, 2004, Google made its debut on the NASDAQ stock market. Trading under the ticker symbol GOOG (you can “google it,” if you like), the stock opened at $100, which was almost 18 percent higher than its initial offering price of $85. More than 22 million shares changed hands on that first day of trading, with Google selling a total of 19.6 million shares, thus raising about $1.2 billion for the company. That price implied a market value of $27.2 billion. Not bad for an idea conceived by two Stanford University grad students!

SOURCES: Paul R. La Monica, “Google Jumps 18% in Debut,” CNN Money, August 19, 2004, http://money.cnn.com; Ben Berkowitz, “Is Google Worth $135 a Share?,” MSN Money, July 26, 2004, http://www.msn.com; Ben Elgin, “Commentary: Google This: Investor Beware,” Business Week Online, August 9, 2004, http://www .businessweek.com; “Financial Release: Google Inc. Prices Initial Public Offering of Class A Common Stock,” August 18, 2004, http://www.investor.google.com; and * “2004 Leaders: The Business Week Global 1000,” Business Week, July 26, 2004, http://www.businessweekonline.com.

whereas the average mutual fund investor, because of costs and poor timing, earned just 7.3%. That makes an enormous difference to wealth: $10,000 invested in the index fund grew to $170, 800; a typical mutual-fund investor saw his money grow to just to $48, 200.” (Source: The Economist, March 1, 2008, pp. 15–18.) Institutional money managers increasingly use computer programs to decide on their portfolios and to buy or sell huge portfolios of stocks simultaneously and rapidly. Since 1982, some traders have also allowed their computers to decide when to jump in and make massive sales or purchases. This practice is called program trading. In 2003, program trading accounted for about 40 percent of the total New York Stock Exchange volume and a considerable amount of the volume in other stock exchanges. Program trading was heavily criticized for aggravating price fluctuations and contributing to the stock market crash of October 1987. Restrictions are now in place that curb program trading when stock markets decline sharply.

STOCK EXCHANGES AND THEIR FUNCTIONS The New York Stock Exchange (NYSE)—“The Big Board”—is perhaps the world’s most prestigious stock market. Located on Wall Street in New York City, it is “the establishment” of the securities industry. The NYSE deals with only the best-known and most heavily traded securities—2,447 companies in all, as of the end of 2008. Leading brokerage firms hold 1,366 “seats” on the stock exchange, which enable them to trade directly on the exchange floor. (In the NYSE’s early years, members sat in assigned seats during roll call; the term lost its literal meaning with the advent of continuous trading in 1871.) Seats are traded on the open market. As of 2005, a seat on the exchange went for $3.5 million. In 2008, the NYSE handled almost 36 percent of all stock market transactions, on average, in the United States (measured in volume of shares). A number of regional exchanges—such as the Chicago, Pacific, Philadelphia, Boston, and Cincinnati Stock Exchanges—deal in many of the stocks handled on the NYSE but mainly serve large institutional customers such as Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

186

Part 2

The Building Blocks of Demand and Supply

SOURCE: © PETER MORGAN/REUTERS/LANDOV

banks, insurance companies, and mutual funds. In addition to these regional exchanges, the American Stock Exchange, acquired in 2008 by the NYSE’s parent company, NYSE Euronext, handles about 10 percent of the total stock traded in the United States. The remainder of all stock transactions are carried by NASDAQ (also known as the Nasdaq Stock Market), which draws its name from the National Association of Securities Dealers.10 It is the home of most of the “tech” stocks that soared in the late 1990s, plummeted in 2000–2002, and have now returned to their pre-boom levels. Unlike the NYSE, NASDAQ has no physical trading floor, although it does have an outdoor display at its headquarters in New York City’s Times Square, where a spectacular eight-story LED screen runs a continuous stock ticker, delivers market news, and shows advertisements and logos of NASDAQ member companies. All of its transactions are carried out on a computer network, with NASDAQ handling the stocks of approximately 3,300 companies, including such giants as Intel and Microsoft. In recent years, the established stock markets have faced competition from another source. With the rapid growth of the Internet, people are now buying and selling stocks directly through their home computers. It is estimated that the number of online trading accounts at major U.S. brokerages increased from 1.5 million in 1997 to 19.7 million at the end of 2001, and topped 50 million in 2004.11 According to one estimate, 12 million American households will be trading online by 2011—an increase of 48 percent from 8.1 million households in 2006.12

Regulation of the Stock Market Both the government and the industry itself regulate the U.S. securities markets. At the base of the regulatory pyramid, stock brokerage firms maintain compliance departments to oversee their own operations. At the next level, the NYSE, the American Stock Exchange, NASDAQ, and the regional exchanges are responsible for monitoring their member firms’ business practices, funding adequacy, compliance, and integrity. They also use sophisticated computer surveillance systems to scrutinize trading activity. The Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) is the federal government agency that oversees the market’s self-regulation.

You are standing on the trading floor of the New York Stock Exchange, a crowded and noisy set of rooms cluttered with people, hundreds of computer monitors, and other electronic paraphernalia. It is a high-tech space in a 93-year-old architectural relic of bygone days. Around the floor are 17 stations, or “trading posts,” presided over by specialists, each assigned responsibility for trading a particular set of stocks. Suddenly the floor’s frenetic activity focuses on one specialist’s post. News has just come in that one of the companies whose stock she handles has earned more in the previous quarter than was expected. Brokers crowd around her, calling out orders to buy and sell the company’s stock, as its price rises rapidly in the wake of the good news. Deals are completed verbally, as clerks record the trades and enter them into the computerized tape, making the information instantly available all over the globe.

SOURCE: AP Photo/Gregory Bull

You Are There: An Event on the Trading Floor of the New York Stock Exchange

SOURCE: Murray Teitelbaum, Communications Division, New York Stock Exchange.

The NASD and Nasdaq have been separated legally. The New York Times 2004 Almanac, ed. John W. Wright (New York: Penguin Group, 2003), p. 342, which cites Gómez, Inc., an Internet research firm in Lincoln, Massachusetts; and the Wall Street Journal, “Trading Stocks Online,” http://investing.wsj.com, which cites Forrester Research in Cambridge, Massachusetts. 12 Bill Doyle, US Online Trading Forecast: 2006 to 2011 (Cambridge, Mass.: Forrester Research), February 1, 2007. 10 11

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 9

Investing in Business: Stocks and Bonds

187

One example of these self-imposed rules involves the steps that markets adopted after the October 1987 stock market crash to cushion future price falls. Starting in 1988, with amendments since then, the NYSE and other stock markets adopted a series of rules called circuit breakers, which now halt all trading for one hour, two hours, or the remainder of the trading day when the Dow Jones Industrial Average (a widely followed average price of a sample of stocks) declines below its previous day’s closing value by defined percentage amounts (which are adjusted every quarter). These restrictions on trading vary with the severity of the drop in the Dow and with the time of day when the drop occurs. Circuit breakers were designed to head off panics among market participants and forestall crashes like the ones in October 1929 and October 1987.

Stock Exchanges and Corporate Capital Needs Although corporations often raise needed funds by selling stock, they do not normally do so through the stock exchanges. New stock issues are typically handled by a special type of bank, called an investment bank. In contrast, the stock markets trade almost exclusively in “secondhand securities”—stocks in the hands of individuals and others who bought them earlier and now wish to sell them. Thus, the stock market does not provide funds to corporations needing financing to expand their productive activities. The markets provide money only to persons who already hold previously issued stocks. Nevertheless, stock exchanges perform two critically important functions for corporate financing. First, by providing a secondhand market for stocks, they make individual investment in a company much less risky. Investors know that if they need money, they can always sell their stocks to other investors or to stock market specialists at the current

Corporate Scandals

. . . After a tumultuous few years in which a series of corporate America’s best-known names admitted to wrongdoing of one sort or another—the roll-call includes Enron, WorldCom, Qwest, Adelphia, Rite Aid, Tyco and Xerox—the focus shifted to Wall Street’s banks and fund managers, giving industrial companies some breathing space. They are also relieved that the latest scandals—the billions missing from Italy’s biggest dairy company, Parmalat, and questionable accounting at Adecco, a Swiss-based company that is the world’s biggest temping agency—are unfolding thousands of miles away. . . . Right now, the pack following the demise of one-time corporate titans is enraptured by the trial of Dennis Kozlowksi, former chief executive, and Mark Swartz, former chief financial officer, of Tyco. . . . [S]hareholders were appalled by revelations of excess, including $6,000 spent on a shower curtain and more than $100,000 on a mirror at a posh company apartment where Mr. Kozlowski lived. Prosecutors have alleged that Mr. Kozlowski and Mr. Swartz stole $170 million from the company, illegally gained $430 million from selling stock, and used dubious accounting to hide their actions—allegations the men have denied. . . . So far, of the senior Enron executives, only [Andrew Fastow, former finance chief], has been indicted. The man who set up a series of offshore partnerships that disguised huge liabilities

had pleaded not guilty to charges of fraud, money laundering and conspiracy to inflate Enron’s profits . . . . His wife, also a former Enron employee, was last week offered a deal under which she would plead guilty to a charge of filing a false tax return. . . . “Our financial officer won’t be at February is scheduled work today—he just called in guilty.” to bring two trials, that of Scott Sullivan, former chief financial officer of WorldCom, and that of John Rigas, founder of Adelphia Communications, a cable television company. WorldCom is the holder of the record for the most deceptive accounts, to the tune of an estimated $11 billion over several years. Mr. Sullivan is charged with masterminding the fraud, though he denies this. . . . While the rash of scandals did subside somewhat in 2003, another of the best-known corporate personalities of the late 1990s fell from grace. Dick Grasso resigned as chairman and chief executive of the New York Stock Exchange after a furore erupted over his $140 million pay packet (later revealed to have been $188m in total). . . .

SOURCE: Tribune Media Services, Inc. All Rights Reserved. Reprinted with permission.

Excerpted from the The Economist magazine, the following account provides details of some of the scandals that erupted in the corporate world in the early 2000s.

SOURCE: “A Trying Year,” The Economist, January 13, 2004, http://www.economist.com.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

188

Part 2

The Building Blocks of Demand and Supply

A derivative is a complex financial instrument whose value depends in some way on the price movements of some specified set of investments, such as a group of stocks, bonds, or commodities. For example, a derivative contract may entitle its owner to buy 100 shares of Company X’s stock at a price of $30 in four months, where $30 may be higher or lower than the market price of that stock at the specified date. A credit default swap (CDS) is a financial instrument that functions like an insurance policy that protects a lender. The buyer of a CDS pays the seller for insuring against a thirdparty’s default on a debt that is owed to the former. If the third party defaults on the debt, failing to make the required repayment, the seller of the CDS must pay a lump sum to the buyer of the CDS.

market price. This reduction in risk makes it far easier for corporations to issue new stocks. Second, the stock market determines the current price of the company’s stocks. That, in turn, determines whether it will be difficult or easy for a corporation to raise money by selling new stocks. Some people believe that a company’s stock price is closely tied to its operational efficiency, its effectiveness in meeting consumer demands, and its diligence in going after profitable innovation. According to this view, firms that use funds effectively will usually have comparatively high stock prices, and that will enable the firms to raise more money when they issue new stocks through their investment banks and sell them at the high prices determined by the stock market. In this way, the stock market tends to channel the economy’s funds to the firms that can make best use of the money. Other people voice skepticism about the claim that the price of a company’s stock is closely tied to efficiency. These observers believe that the demand for a stock is disproportionately influenced by short-term developments in the company’s profitability and that the market pays little attention to management decisions affecting the firm’s long-term earnings growth. These critics sometimes suggest that the stock market is similar to a gambling casino in which hunch, rumor, and superstition have a critical influence on prices. (We will learn more about this view later in the chapter.) Whether or not stock prices are an accurate measure of a company’s efficiency, if a company’s stock price is very low in comparison with the value of its plant, equipment, and other assets, or when a company’s earnings seem low compared to its potential level, that company becomes a tempting target for a takeover. Perhaps the firm’s current management is believed not to be very competent, and those who seek to take control of the company believe that they can do better. Alternatively, if the demand for a company’s stocks is believed to be inordinately influenced by short-term developments, such as temporarily low profits, others may believe that it is a bargain in terms of the low current price of

How to Lose Billions: Betting on Derivatives Derivatives are complex financial instruments that “derive” their value from the price movements of an underlying investment, such as a group of stocks, bonds, or commodities. For example, a derivative may entitle its owner to buy 100 shares of Company X’s stock at a price of $30 four months in the future. Below, Professor William Silber of New York University’s Stern School of Business, a widely recognized expert in securities markets, explains the role derivatives played in the most recent financial crisis:

defaulting on their mortgages, returns on these investments, which came from homeowners’ mortgage payments, halted, and the value of these financial products declined rapidly. But when banks tried to redeem their CDS contracts, the insurers, who had not expected these new financial products to fail en masse, did not have enough cash on hand to cover the contracts. Below, Professor Silber describes the dramatic events that followed:

“Businesses buy [derivatives] contracts in an effort to hedge or insure against sudden changes in interest rates or currency values. But they also can be used to speculate in the markets, and sometimes wind up creating bigger problems. Derivatives exacerbated the financial crisis that began in August 2007 by adding to the potential liabilities of major financial institutions who had sold certain types of derivative contracts. Credit Default Swaps (CDSs) are derivatives that, under normal circumstances, allow investors to protect themselves in the event a bond they own goes into default. The seller of the CDS promises that the investor will receive the face value of the bond if the company defaults. The seller receives an up-front fee in exchange.”

“American International Group (AIG) was a major seller of CDSs to a wide variety of financial institutions. As a result of deteriorating credit conditions in September 2009, there was a high probability that AIG would not be able to make all of the payments that were due. It had miscalculated the default risks. Had AIG gone bankrupt, hundreds of other financial institutions that thought they had protection would have been left without any. The prospect of a cascade of bankruptcies forced the U.S. government to lend more than $100 billion to AIG to prevent a further collapse. The lesson is that derivatives can be beneficial if they are used properly but can have unintended consequences unless they are monitored closely.”

In the years leading up to the financial crisis of 2007–2008, U.S. investment banks bought CDSs as insurance to protect against potential losses related to the exotic financial products that they were buying and selling. When many American homeowners began

SOURCES: Professor William Silber, Director, Glucksman Institute for Research in Securities Markets, Stern School of Business, New York University; and Adam Davidson, “How AIG Fell Apart,” September 18, 2008, accessed online at http:// www.thebigmoney.com.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Investing in Business: Stocks and Bonds

189

the stock and its more promising future earnings prospects. A takeover occurs when a group of outside financiers buys a sufficient amount of company stock to gain control of the firm. Often, the new controlling group will simply fire the current management and substitute a new chairman, president, and other top officers.

A takeover is the acquisition by an outside group (the raiders) of a controlling proportion of a company’s stock. When the old management opposes the takeover attempt, it is called a hostile takeover attempt.

Chapter 9

SPECULATION Securities dealings are sometimes viewed with suspicion because they are thought to be an instrument of speculation. When something goes wrong in the stock market—when, say, prices suddenly fall— o bservers often blame speculators. Editorial writers, for example, often use the word speculators as a term of strong disapproval, implying that those who engage in the activity are parasites who produce no benefits for society and often cause considerable harm. (See “How to Lose Billions: Betting on Derivatives,” on the previous page, for a description of a particularly risky speculative instrument, the derivative.) Economists disagree vehemently with this judgment. They argue that speculators perform two vital economic functions:

Individuals who engage in speculation deliberately invest in risky assets, hoping to obtain profits from future changes in the prices of these assets.

• Speculators sell protection from risk to other people, much as a fire insurance policy offers protection from risk to a homeowner. • Speculators help to smooth out price fluctuations by purchasing items when they are abundant (and cheap) and holding them and reselling them when they are scarce (and expensive). In that way, speculators play a vital economic role in helping to alleviate and even prevent shortages. Some examples from outside the securities markets will help clarify the role of speculators. Imagine that a Broadway ticket broker attends a preview of a new musical comedy and suspects it will be a hit. He decides to speculate by buying a large block of tickets for future performances. In that way, he takes over part of the producer’s risk, while the play’s producer reduces her inventory of risky tickets and receives some hard cash. If the show opens and is a flop, the broker will be stuck with the tickets. If the show is a hit, he can sell them at a premium, if the law allows (and he will be denounced as a speculator or a “scalper”). Similarly, speculators enable farmers (or producers of metals and other commodities whose future price is uncertain) to decrease their risk. Let’s say Jasmine and Jim have planted a large crop of wheat but fear its price may fall before harvest time. They can protect themselves by signing a contract with a speculator for future delivery of the crop at an agreed-upon price. If the price then falls, the speculator—not Jasmine and Jim—will suffer the loss. Of course, if the price rises, the speculator will reap the rewards—but that is the nature of risk bearing. The speculator who has agreed to buy the crop at a preset price, regardless of market conditions at the time of the sale, has, in effect, sold an insurance policy to Jasmine and Jim. Surely this is a useful function. The speculators’ second role is perhaps even more important. In effect, they accumulate and store goods in periods of abundance and make goods available in periods of scarcity. Suppose that a speculator has reason to suspect that next year’s crop of a storable commodity will not be nearly as abundant as this year’s. She will buy some of the crop now, when it is cheap, for resale when it becomes scarce and expensive. In the process, she will smooth out the swing in prices by adding her purchases to the total market demand in the low-price period (which tends to bring the price up at that time) and bringing in her supplies during the high-price period (which tends to push this later-period price down).13 Thus, the successful speculator will help to relieve matters during periods of extreme shortage. Speculators have sometimes even helped to relieve famine by releasing supplies they had deliberately hoarded for such an occasion. Of course, speculators are cursed for their high prices when this happens. But those who curse them do not understand that prices would 13

For a diagrammatic analysis of this role of speculation, see Discussion Question 3 at the end of this chapter.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

190

Part 2

The Building Blocks of Demand and Supply

have been even higher if the speculators’ foresight and avid pursuit of profit had not provided for the emergency. On the securities market, famine and severe shortages are not an issue, but the fact remains that successful speculators tend to reduce price fluctuations by increasing demand for stocks when prices are low and contributing to supply when prices are high. Far from aggravating instability and fluctuations, to earn a profit speculators iron out fluctuations by buying when prices are low and selling when prices are high.

PUZZLE 2 RESOLVED:

In one of the puzzles at the beginning of this chapter, we cited evidence indicating that the best professional securities analysts have a forecasting record so miserable that investors may do as well predicting earnings by hunch, superstition, or any purely random process as they would by following professional advice. (See “Giving Up on Stock Gimmicks” on the next page to learn about some crazy ways of “predicting” the stock market’s performance.) Does this mean that analysts are incompetent people who do not know what they are doing? Not at all. Rather, there is fairly strong evidence that they have undertaken a task that is basically impossible. How can this be so? The answer is that to make a good forecast of any variable—be it GDP, population, fuel usage, or stock market prices—there must be something in the past whose behavior is closely related to the future behavior of the variable whose path we wish to predict. If a 10 percent rise in this year’s consumption always produces a 5 percent rise in next year’s GDP, this fact can help us predict future GDP on the basis of current observations. But if we want to forecast the future of a variable whose behavior is completely unrelated to the behavior of any current or past variable, there is no objective evidence that can help us make that forecast. Throwing darts or gazing into a crystal ball are no less effective than analysts’ calculations. A mass of statistical evidence indicates that the behavior of stock prices is largely unpredictable. In other words, the behavior of stock prices is essentially random; the paths they follow approximate what statisticians call random walks. A random walk is like the path followed by a sleepwalker. All we know about his position after his next step is that it will be given by his current position plus whatever random direction his next haphazard step will take. The relevant feature of randomness, for our purposes, is that it is by nature unpredictable, which is just what the word random means. If the evidence that stock prices approximate a random walk stands up to research in the future as it has so far, it is easy enough to understand why stock market predictions are so poor. Analysts are trying to forecast behavior that is basically random; in effect, they are trying to predict the unpredictable. SOURCE: © 1990 Cartoonists & Writers Syndicate/cartoonweb.com

The time path of a variable such as the price of a stock is said to constitute a random walk if its magnitude in one period (say, May 2, 2005) is equal to its value in the preceding period (May 1, 2005) plus a completely random number. That is: Price on May 2, 2005 5 Price on May 1, 2005 1 Random number, where the random number (positive or negative) can be obtained by a roll of dice or some such procedure.

UNPREDICTABLE STOCK PRICES AS “RANDOM WALKS”

“Just a normal day at the nation’s most important financial institution . . .”

Two questions remain. First, does the evidence that stock prices follow a random walk mean that investment in stocks is a pure gamble and never worthwhile? Second, how does one explain the random behavior of stock prices? To answer the first question, it is wrong to conclude that investment in stocks is generally not worthwhile. The statistical evidence is that, over the long run, stock prices as a whole have followed a fairly marked upward trend, perhaps reflecting the long-term growth of the economy. Thus, the random walk does not proceed in just any direction—rather, it represents a set of erratic movements around a basic upward trend in stock prices. Moreover, it is not in the overall level of stock prices that the most pertinent random walk occurs, but in the performance of one company’s stock as compared with another firm’s stock. For this reason, professional advice may be able to predict that investment in the stock market is likely to be a good thing over the long haul. But, if

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 9

Investing in Business: Stocks and Bonds

191

Giving Up on Stock Gimmicks While Super Bowl indicator fans struggled to formulate the “Elway exception,” the St. Louis Rams recaptured the Super Bowl in 2000 forthe NFL originals. Contrarily, the stock market then dropped. . . . A seasonal indicator with a stronger rationale, the January barometer long espoused by investment advisor Yale Hirsch, gave a better performance in 2000. In line with Hirsch’s doctrine that “as January goes, so goes the year,” it foreshadowed a down year for the market when the stock-price averages posted minus signs for the first month. By Hirsch’s reckoning, this rule has seen only three glaring exceptions since 1950. Most years, I readily confess, I find myself checking in January to see how it’s shaping up. But when the time comes to figure out how to put it into use, I’m at a loss. Trading on it seems impractical. Any long-term investor who sits out each January to await a signal misses a lot of gains: Measuring by the Standard & Poor’s 500 Index, 3.3 percent in 1996, 6.1 percent in 1997, 1 percent in 1998 and 4.1 percent in 1999. . . . Maybe you’ve got some favorite indicators of your own. If so, you’re welcome to them. From now on, I never touch the stuff.”

SOURCE: © GABRIEL BOUYS/AFP/Getty Images

“For a New Year’s resolution . . ., I’m giving up stock market forecasting gimmicks. The Super Bowl indicator. The January barometer. Others so numerous I can’t think of them all right now. It won’t be easy to do this cold turkey. The indicators are often ingenious, occasionally quite persuasive, and nearly always fun. They appeal to my yearning for a simple answer to a complicated problem. The first indicator I bid goodbye to, the Super Bowl stock market predictor, is the easiest to forswear. It has suddenly and completely stopped functioning, breaking down like a rusty old car. That’s too bad, because it added some zest to the National Football League championship extravaganza, which more than once has needed it. The idea is this: If a team from the original National Football League before its 1970 merger with the American Football League won the Super Bowl, a good year for the stock market was in store. Conversely, if a team with AFL origins triumphed, tough times lay ahead. An awareness of this pattern would have been especially helpful in the bear-market years 1969, 1970, 1973, 1974, and 1981, all of which began with wins by a team from the wrong side of the tracks. So what if everybody knew there was no possible causal link between football and the stock market? As the years rolled by, though, the novelty of the Super Bowl indicator wore off, especially as analysts picked it apart looking for corollaries. Was the margin of victory important? What about which team scored first? Then along came John Elway to knock the whole thing down with a barrage of his famous bullet passes. The Denver Broncos quarterback led his team, a product of the AFL, to victories in ’98 and ’99, and yet the stock market boomed anyway.

SOURCE: Chet Currier, “Investing: Giving Up on Stock Gimmicks,” from Newsday, January 7, 2001, p. F13. Reprinted by permission of Tribune Media Services.

the random walk evidence is valid, there is no way professionals can tell us which of the available stocks is most likely to increase in price—that is, which combination of stocks is best for the investor to buy. The only appropriate answer to the second question of how to account for the random behavior of stock prices is that no one is sure of the explanation. There are two widely offered hypotheses—each virtually the opposite of the other. The first asserts that stock prices are random because clever professional speculators are able to foresee almost perfectly every influence that is not random. For example, suppose that a change occurs that makes the probable earnings of some company higher than had previously been expected. Then, according to this view, the professionals will instantly become aware of this change and immediately buy enough shares to raise the price of the stock accordingly. Then the only thing for that stock price to do between this year and next is wander randomly, because the professionals cannot predict random movements, and hence they cannot force current stock prices to anticipate them. The second explanation of the random behavior of stock prices is at the opposite extreme from the view that all nonrandom movements are wiped out by super-smart professionals. This is the view that people who buy and sell stocks have learned that they cannot predict future stock prices. As a result, they react to any signal, however irrational and irrelevant it appears. If the president catches cold, stock prices fall. If an astronaut’s venture is successful, prices go up. According to this view, investors are, in the last analysis, trying to predict not the prospects of the economy or of the company whose shares they buy, but the supply and demand behavior of other investors, which

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

192

Part 2

The Building Blocks of Demand and Supply

will ultimately determine the course of stock prices. Because all investors are equally in the dark, their groping around can only result in the randomness that we observe. The classic statement of this view of stock market behavior was provided in 1936 by the English economist John Maynard Keynes, a successful professional speculator himself: Professional investment may be likened to those newspaper competitions in which the competitors have to pick out the six prettiest faces from a hundred photographs, the prize being awarded to the competitor whose choice most nearly corresponds to the average preferences of the competitors as a whole; so that each competitor has to pick not those faces which he himself finds prettiest, but those which he thinks likeliest to catch the fancy of the other competitors, all of whom are looking at the problem from the same point of view. It is not a case of choosing those which, to the best of one’s judgment, are really the prettiest, nor even those which average opinion genuinely thinks the prettiest. We have reached the third degree where we devote our intelligences to anticipating what average opinion expects the average opinion to be. And there are some, I believe, who practice the fourth, fifth and higher degrees.14

14 John Maynard Keynes, The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money (New York: Harcourt Brace; 1936), p. 156.

PUZZLE 1 REDUX:

THE BOOM AND BUST OF THE U.S. STOCK MARKET

This last quotation leads to some insights into the remarkable behavior of the U.S. stock market during the late 1990s and early 2000s—a phenomenon we mentioned at the start of this chapter. (Refer back to Figure 1.) First, many people who buy stocks—both professionals and amateurs—do so for speculative purposes. They may not care (or even know!) what the company does; they care only that its stock price goes up. Second, in a speculative world, where people buy stocks in order to sell them later, a share of stock is basically worth what someone else will pay for it. So even if Smart Susan is convinced that Dotcon.com has poor business prospects, it may still be rational for her to buy the stock at $50 per share if she is convinced that she will be able to sell it to Foolish Frank next year for $100 per share. (This idea has been called the “greater fool” theory of investing: It makes sense to buy a stock at a foolishly high price if you can sell it at an even higher price—to an even greater fool!) Third, once something attains the status of a fad, waves of buying can drive prices up to ridiculous levels, as has happened many times in history. Fourth, America undoubtedly fell in love both with information technology (especially the Internet) and the stock market (especially Internet-related stocks) in the late 1990s. All this set the stage for what is commonly called a financial “bubble.” The metaphor is meant to conjure up images of things like balloons and soap bubbles that blow up and up and up . . . until they burst. Indeed, legions of economists were warning about a stock market bubble in 1998, in 1999, and into 2000. The problem is simply stated: No one ever knows when a bubble will burst. And for stock market speculators, timing is everything. Look back at Figure 1 again. Those who claimed in mid-1999 that technology stocks were overvalued looked pretty silly when stock prices doubled in less than one year. (Of course, they subsequently looked pretty smart when prices collapsed!) Technology enthusiasts ignored them as the stock market partied on. The only thing that is truly predictable about a bubble is that it will burst—eventually. But no one ever knows when. As was also the case more recently when the “housing bubble” burst, triggering the even larger economic crisis of 2007–2008, no one could say definitively that now was the time to sell technology stocks. As the saying goes, the rest is history.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

193

Investing in Business: Stocks and Bonds

Chapter 9

| SUMMARY | 1. Most U.S. manufactured goods are produced by corporations.

raise money because they are able to sell each stock issue at favorable prices.

2. Investors in corporations have greater risk protection than those who put their money into other types of firms because the corporate form gives them limited liability—they cannot be asked to pay more of the company’s debts than they have invested in the firm.

8. Bonds are relatively risky for the firms that issue them, but they are fairly safe for their buyers, because they are a commitment by those firms to pay fixed annual amounts to the bondholders whether or not the companies make money that year. Stocks, which do not promise any fixed payment, are relatively safe for the companies but risky for their owners.

3. Higher taxation of corporate earnings tends to limit the things in which corporations can invest and may lead to inefficiency in resource allocation.

9. A portfolio is a collection of stocks, bonds, and other assets of a single owner. The greater the number and variety of securities and other assets a portfolio contains, the less risky it generally is.

4. A common stock is a share in a company’s ownership. A bond is an IOU for money lent to a company by the bondholder. Many observers argue that a stock purchase really amounts to a loan to the company—a loan that is riskier than a bond purchase.

10. A takeover of a corporation occurs when an outside group buys enough stock to get control of the firm’s decisions. Takeovers are a useful way to get rid of incompetent management or to force management to be more efficient. However, the process is costly and leads to wasteful defensive and offensive activities.

5. If interest rates rise, bond prices will fall. In other words, if some bond amounts to a contract to pay 8 percent and the market interest rate goes up to 10 percent, people will no longer be willing to pay the old price for that bond. 6. Corporations finance their activities mostly by plowback (that is, by retaining part of their earnings and reinvesting the funds in the company). They also obtain funds by selling stocks and bonds and by taking out more traditional loans.

11. Speculation affects stock market prices, but (contrary to widespread belief) it actually tends to reduce the frequency and size of price fluctuations. Speculators are also useful to the economy because they undertake risks that others wish to avoid, thereby, in effect, providing others with insurance against risk.

7. If stock prices correctly reflect the future prospects of different companies, it is easier for promising firms to

12. Statistical evidence indicates that individual stock prices behave randomly (in other words, unpredictably).

| KEY TERMS | bond

180

index fund

common stock corporation

180

179

credit default swap derivative

inflation

188

equities 184

interest rate 188

184

portfolio diversification

181 181

limited liability mutual fund

184

random walk 190 securities

180

speculation

184

181 189

stock price index

plowback (retained earnings) 182

184

takeover 188, 189

| TEST YOURSELF | 1. Suppose that interest rates are 6 percent in the economy and a safe bond promises to pay $3 per year in interest forever. What do you think the price of the bond will be? Why? 2. Suppose that in the economy described in Test Yourself 1, interest rates suddenly fall to 3 percent. What will happen to the price of the bond that pays $3 per year? 3. For whom are stocks riskier than bonds? For whom are bonds riskier than stocks?

4. If the price of a company’s stock constitutes a random walk, next year its price will equal today’s price plus what? 5. Company A sells heaters and Company B sells air conditioners. Which is the safer investment, Company A stock, Company B stock, or a portfolio containing half of each? 6. If you make a lucky prediction about the prices of the stocks of the two companies in Question 5, will you earn more or less if you invest in that company rather than the portfolio?

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

194

Part 2

The Building Blocks of Demand and Supply

| DISCUSSION QUESTIONS | 1. If you hold shares in a corporation and management decides to plow back the company’s earnings some year instead of paying dividends, what are the advantages and disadvantages to you? 2. If you want to buy a stock, when might it pay you to use a market order? When will it pay to use a limit order? 3. Show in diagrams that if a speculator were to buy when price is high and sell when price is low, he would increase price fluctuations. Why would it be in his best interest not to do so? (Hint: Draw two supply-demand diagrams, one for the high-price period and one for the low-price period. How would the speculator’s activities affect these diagrams?) 4. If stock prices really do take a random walk, can you nevertheless think of good reasons for getting professional advice before investing?

5. Hostile takeovers often end up in court when management attempts to block such a maneuver and raiders accuse management of selfishly sacrificing the stockholders’ interests. The courts often look askance at “coercive” offers by raiders—an offer to buy, say, 20 percent of the company’s stock by a certain date from the first stockholders who offer to sell. By contrast, they take a more favorable attitude toward “noncoercive” offers to buy any and all stock supplied at announced prices. Do you think the courts are right to reject “coercive offers” and prevent management from blocking “noncoercive” offers? Why? 6. In program trading, computers decide when to buy or sell stocks on behalf of large, institutional investors. The computers then carry out those transactions with electronic speed. Critics claim that this practice is a major reason why stock prices rose and fell sharply in the 1980s. Is this idea plausible? Why or why not?

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Part

Markets and the Price System

S

o far, we have talked only about firms in general without worrying about the different sorts of markets in which they operate. To understand the different types of competition a firm can face, it is necessary, first, to explain clearly what we mean by the word market. Economists do not reserve this term for only an organized exchange, such as the London stock exchange, operating in a specific location. In its more general and abstract usage, market refers to a set of sellers and buyers whose activities affect the price at which a particular commodity is sold. For example, two separate sales of General Motors stock in different parts of the country can be considered to take place in the same market, whereas sales of bread in one stall of a market square and sales of compact discs in the next stall may, in our sense, occur in totally different markets. Economists distinguish among different kinds of competition in such markets according to how many firms they include, whether the products of the different firms are identical or different, and how easy it is for new firms to enter the markets. Perfect competition is at one extreme (many small firms selling an identical product, with easy entry into the market), and pure monopoly (a single firm dominating the market) is at the other extreme. In between are hybrid forms—called monopolistic competition (many small firms, each selling slightly different products) and oligopoly (a few large rival firms)—that share some of the characteristics of both perfect competition and monopoly. Perfect competition is far from the typical market form in the U.S. economy. Indeed, it is quite rare. Pure monopoly—literally one firm—is also infrequently encountered. Most of the products you buy are no doubt supplied by oligopolies or monopolistic competitors— terms that we will define precisely in Chapter 12.

C H A P T E R S 10 | The Firm and the

Industry under Perfect Competition

11 | Monopoly

12 | Between Competition and Monopoly

13 | Limiting Market Power:

Regulation and Antitrust

195

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

The Firm and the Industry under Perfect Competition Competition . . . brings about the only . . . arrangement of social production which is possible. . . . [Otherwise] what guarantee [do] we have that the necessary quantity and not more of each product will be produced, that we shall not go hungry in regard to corn and meat while we are choked in beet sugar and drowned in potato spirit, that we shall not lack trousers to cover our nakedness while buttons flood us in millions? F R I E D R I C H EN GEL S ( THE FRI END AND COAU THOR OF KARL M A RX)

I

ndustries differ dramatically in the number and typical sizes of their firms. Some, such as commercial fishing, encompass a great many small firms. Others, like automobile manufacturing, are composed of a few industrial giants. This chapter deals with a special type of market structure—called perfect competition—in which firms are numerous and small. As already noted, this market structure is rarely even approximated in reality. Yet, for reasons that will be pointed out, until a few decades ago most economic theory regarding firms and markets focused on the case of perfect competition. We begin this chapter by comparing alternative market forms and defining perfect competition precisely. But first, as usual, we set out our puzzle.

C O N T E N T S PUZZLE: POLLUTION REDUCTION INCENTIVES

THAT ACTUALLY INCREASE POLLUTION

PERFECT COMPETITION DEFINED THE PERFECTLY COMPETITIVE FIRM The Firm’s Demand Curve under Perfect Competition Short-Run Equilibrium for the Perfectly Competitive Firm Short-Run Profit: Graphic Representation

The Case of Short-Term Losses Shutdown and Break-Even Analysis The Perfectly Competitive Firm’s Short-Run Supply Curve

THE PERFECTLY COMPETITIVE INDUSTRY The Perfectly Competitive Industry’s Short-Run Supply Curve Industry Equilibrium in the Short Run Industry and Firm Equilibrium in the Long Run

Zero Economic Profit: The Opportunity Cost of Capital The Long-Run Industry Supply Curve

PERFECT COMPETITION AND ECONOMIC EFFICIENCY PUZZLE RESOLVED: WHICH MORE

EFFECTIVELY CUTS POLLUTION—THE CARROT OR THE STICK?

197

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

198

Part 3

Markets and the Price System

PUZZLE:

POLLUTION REDUCTION INCENTIVES THAT ACTUALLY INCREASE POLLUTION

Many economists and other citizens concerned about the environment believe that society can obtain cleaner air and water cheaply and effectively by requiring polluters to pay for the damages they cause. (See Chapter 17 for more details.) Yet people often view pollution charges as just another tax, and that word can translate into political poison. Some politicians—reasoning that you can move a donkey along just as effectively by offering it a carrot as by poking it with a stick—have proposed paying firms to cut down on their polluting emissions. At least some theoretical and statistical evidence indicates that such a system of bribes (or, to use a more palatable word, subsidies) does work, at least up to a point. Individual polluting firms will, indeed, respond to government payments for decreased emissions by reducing their pollution. But, over the long haul, it turns out that society may well end up with more pollution than before! Subsidy payments to the firms can actually exacerbate pollution problems. How is it possible that subsidies induce each firm to pollute less but in the long run lead to a rise in total pollution? The analysis in this chapter will supplement your own common sense sufficiently to supply the answer.

PERFECT COMPETITION DEFINED Perfect competition occurs in an industry when that industry is made up of many small firms producing homogeneous products, when there is no impediment to the entry or exit of firms, and when full information is available.

You can appreciate just how special perfect competition is by considering this comprehensive definition. A market is said to operate under perfect competition when the following four conditions are satisfied: 1. Numerous small firms and customers. Competitive markets contain so many buyers and sellers that each one constitutes a negligible portion of the whole—so small, in fact, that each player’s decisions have no effect on price. This requirement rules out trade associations or other collusive arrangements in which firms work together to influence price. 2. Homogeneity of product. The product offered by any seller is identical to that supplied by any other seller. (For example, No. 1 red winter wheat is a homogeneous product; different brands of toothpaste are not.) Because products are homogeneous, consumers do not care from which firm they buy, so competition is more powerful. 3. Freedom of entry and exit. New firms desiring to enter the market face no impediments that previous entrants can avoid, so new firms can easily come in and compete with older firms. Similarly, if production and sale of the good proves unprofitable, no barriers prevent firms from leaving the market. 4. Perfect information. Each firm and each customer is well informed about available products and prices. They know whether one supplier is selling at a lower price than another.

These exacting requirements are rarely, if ever, found in practice. One example that comes close to the perfectly competitive standard is a market for common stocks. On any given day, literally millions of buyers and sellers trade Boeing stock. All of the shares are exactly alike, anyone who wishes to sell their Boeing stock can enter the market easily, and most relevant company and industry information is readily available (and virtually free of charge) in the daily newspapers or on the Internet. Many farming and fishing industries also approximate perfect competition, but it is difficult to find many other examples. Our interest in the perfectly competitive model surely does not lie in its ability to describe reality. Why, then, do we spend time studying perfect competition? The answer takes us back to the central theme of this book. Under perfect competition the market mechanism in

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 10

199

The Firm and the Industry under Perfect Competition

many ways performs best. If we want to learn what markets do well, we can put the market’s best foot forward by beginning with perfect competition. As Adam Smith suggested some two centuries ago, perfectly competitive firms use society’s scarce resources with maximum efficiency. Also, as Friedrich Engels suggested in the opening quotation of this chapter, only perfect competition can ensure that the economy turns out just those varieties and relative quantities of goods that match consumer preferences. By studying perfect competition, we can learn some of the things an ideally functioning market system can accomplish. This is the topic of this chapter and Chapter 14. In Chapters 11 and 12, we will consider other market forms and see how they deviate from the perfectly competitive ideal. Later chapters (especially Chapter 15 and all of Parts 4 and 5) will examine many important tasks that the market does not perform well, even under perfect competition. All these chapters combined should provide a balanced assessment of the virtues and vices of the market mechanism.

THE PERFECTLY COMPETITIVE FIRM To discover what happens in a perfectly competitive market, we must deal separately with the behavior of individual firms and the behavior of the industry that is constituted by those firms. One basic difference between the firm and the industry under competition relates to pricing: Under perfect competition, the firm has no choice but to accept the price that has been determined in the market. It is therefore called a “price taker” (rather than a “price maker”).

The idea that no firm in a perfectly competitive market can exert any control over product price follows from our stringent definition of perfect competition. The presence of a vast number of competitors, each offering identical products, forces each firm to meet but not exceed the price charged by the others, because at any higher price all of the firm’s customers would leave it and move their purchases to its rivals. With two important exceptions, analysis of the behavior of the firm under perfect competition is exactly as we described in Chapters 7 and 8. The two exceptions relate to the special shape of the perfectly competitive firm’s demand curve and the freedom of entry and exit, along with their effects on the firm’s profits. We will consider each of these special features of perfect competition in turn, beginning with the demand curve.

Under perfect competition, the firm is a price taker. It has no choice but to accept the price that has been determined in the market.

The Firm’s Demand Curve under Perfect Competition In Chapter 8, we always assumed that the firm faced a downward-sloping demand curve; that is, if a firm wished to sell more (without increasing its advertising or changing its product specifications), it had to reduce its product price. The perfectly competitive firm is an exception to this general principle. A perfectly competitive firm faces a horizontal demand curve. This means that it can sell as much as it wants at the prevailing market price. It can double or triple its sales without reducing the price of its product.

How is this possible? The answer is that the perfectly competitive firm is so insignificant relative to the market as a whole that it has absolutely no influence over price. The farmer who sells his corn through a commodities exchange in Chicago must accept the current quotation that his broker reports to him. Because there are thousands of farmers, the Chicago price per bushel will not budge because farmer Jasmine decides she doesn’t like the price and stores a truckload of corn rather than taking it to the grain elevator. Thus, the demand curve for Jasmine’s corn is as shown in Figure 1(a). As we can see, the price she is paid in Chicago will be $3 per bushel whether she sells one truckload (point A) or two (point B) or three (point C). This is because that $3 price is determined

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

200

Part 3

Markets and the Price System

Price per Bushel in Chicago

D

A

B

C

Industry supply curve E

$3

$3

S

Industry demand curve

Firm’s demand curve S D 0

1

2

3

4

0

100 200 300 400

Truckloads of Corn Sold by Farmer Jasmine per Year

Total Sales in Chicago in Thousands of Truckloads per Year

(a)

(b)

F I GURE 1 Demand Curve for a Firm under Perfect Competition

Short-Run Equilibrium for the Perfectly Competitive Firm

F I GURE 2 Short-Run Equilibrium of the Perfectly Competitive Firm

Revenue and Cost per Bushel

by the intersection of the industry’s supply and demand curves shown in the right-hand portion of the graph, Figure 1(b). Notice that, in the case of perfect competition, the downwardsloping industry demand curve in Figure 1(b) leads to the horizontal demand curve for the individual firm in Figure 1(a). Also notice that the height of the firm’s horizontal demand curve will be the height of the intersection point, E, of the industry supply and demand curves. So the firm’s demand curve will generally not resemble the demand curve for the industry.

We already have sufficient background to study the decisions of a firm operating in a perfectly competitive market. Recall from Chapter 8 that profit maximization requires the firm to pick an output level that makes its marginal cost equal to its marginal revenue: MC 5 MR. The only feature that distinguishes the profit-maximizing equilibrium for the perfectly competitive firm from that of any other type of firm is its horizontal demand curve. We know from Chapter 8 that the firm’s demand curve is also its average revenue curve if it sells its product at the same price to each and every customer, because the average revenue a firm gets from selling a commodity is equal to the price of the commodity. That is, if it sells 100 shirts at a price of $18 each, then obviously, the average revenue it obtains from the sale of each shirt will be the average of $18, 18, 18, etc. 5 $18. So, because the demand curve tells us the price at which the supplier can sell a given quantity, this means it also tells us the average revenue it gets per unit sold when it sells that given quantity. Thus the firm’s demand curve and its average revenue curve are identical, by definition. The same curve does two jobs, but it also does a third job. Because this demand curve is horizontal, the competitive firm’s marginal revenue curve is a horizontal straight line that also coincides with its demand curve; hence, MR 5 Price (P). It is easy to see why this is so. If the price does not depend on how much the firm sells (which is exactly what a horizontal demand curve means), then each additional unit sold brings in an amount of additional revenue (the marginal revenue) exactly equal to the MC AC market price. So marginal revenue always equals price under perfect competition because the firm is a price taker.1 B

$3.00

D = MR = AR

2.25

A

1.50 0

50,000 Bushels of Corn per Year

Under perfect competition the firm’s demand curve, average revenue curve, and marginal revenue curve are all the same.

As in Chapter 8, once we know the shape and position of a firm’s marginal revenue curve, we can use this information and the marginal cost curve to determine its optimal output and profit, as shown in Figure 2. As usual, the profit-maximizing output is that at which MC 5 MR (point

There is another way to prove this. We saw in the appendix to Chapter 8 that if the average revenue curve is horizontal and its height is equal to price, we cannot have either MR , AR or MR . AR, because a marginal revenue lower than average revenue must put the average down, and MR . AR must pull the average up. So with the demand curve horizontal we must have P 5 MR 5 MR. 1

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 10

201

The Firm and the Industry under Perfect Competition

B). This occurs at the point where the MC curve cuts the demand curve (under perfect competition, D 5 MR 5 AR), because, as we have just seen, the firm’s output is too small to affect market price. This particular competitive firm produces 50,000 bushels of corn per year—the output level at which MC and MR both equal the market price, $3. Thus: Because it is a price taker, the equilibrium of a profitmaximizing firm in a perfectly competitive market must occur at an output level at which marginal cost equals price 5 AR 5 MR. This is because a horizontal demand curve makes price and MR equal and, therefore, both must equal marginal cost according to the profit-maximizing principle. In symbols: MC 5 MR 5 P

TABLE 1 Revenues, Costs, and Profits of a Perfectly Competitive Firm

(1)

(2)

(3)

Total Total Marginal Quantity Revenue Revenue 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70

$

0 30 60 90 120 150 180 210

$30 30 30 30 30 30 30

(4)

(5)

(6)

Total Cost

Marginal Cost

Total Profit

$ 32 $ 22 $ 24 56 4 11.5 67.5 22.5 18.5 86 34 26.5 112.5 37.5 56.5 169 11 93 262 252

NOTE: Quantity is in thousands of bushels; dollars are in thousands. This idea is illustrated in Table 1, which gives the firm’s total and marginal revenue, total and marginal cost, and total profit for different output quantities. We see from column (6) that total profit is maximized at an output of about 50,000 bushels where total profit is $37,500. An increase in output from 40,000 to 50,000 bushels incurs a marginal cost ($26,500) that most nearly equals the corresponding marginal revenue ($30,000), confirming that 50,000 bushels is the profit-maximizing output.2

Short-Run Profit: Graphic Representation Our analysis so far tells us how a firm can pick the output that maximizes its profit. It may even be able to earn a substantial profit, but sometimes, even if it succeeds in maximizing profit, the firm may conceivably find itself in trouble because market conditions may make the highest possible profit a negative number. If the demand for its product is weak or its costs are high, even the firm’s most profitable option may lead to a loss. In the short run, the demand curve can either be high or low relative to costs. To determine whether the firm is making a profit or incurring a loss, we must compare total revenue (TR 5 P 3 Q) with total cost (TC 5 AC 3 Q). Because the output (Q) is common to both of these amounts, this equation tells us that the process is equivalent to comparing price (P) with average cost (AC). If P . AC, the firm will earn a profit, and if P , AC, it will suffer a loss. We can, therefore, show the firm’s profit in Figure 2, which includes the firm’s average cost curve. By definition, profit per unit of output is revenue per unit (P) minus cost per unit (AC). We see in Figure 2 that average cost at 50,000 bushels per year is only $2.25 per bushel (point A), whereas average revenue (AR) is $3 per bushel (point B). The firm makes a profit of AR 2 AC 5 $0.75 per bushel, which appears in the graph as the vertical distance between points A and B. Notice that, in addition to showing the profit per unit, Figure 2 can be used to show the firm’s total profit. Total profit is the profit per unit ($0.75 in this example) times the number of units (50,000 per year). Therefore, total profit is represented by the area of the shaded rectangle whose height is the profit per unit ($0.75) and whose width is the number of units sold (50,000).3 In this case, profits are $37,500 per year. In general, total profit at any output is the area of the rectangle whose base equals the level of output and whose height equals AR 2 AC.

2 Marginal cost is not precisely equal to marginal revenue, because to calculate marginal costs and marginal revenues with perfect accuracy, we would have to increase output one bushel at a time instead of proceeding in leaps of 10,000 bushels. Of course, that would require too much space! In any event, our failure to make a more careful calculation in terms of individual bushels explains why we are unable to find the output at which MR and MC are exactly equal. 3

Recall that the formula for the area of a rectangle is Area 5 Height 3 Width.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Revenue and Cost per Bushel

202

Part 3

Markets and the Price System

MC

The MC = P condition gives us the output that maximizes the perfectly competitive firm’s profit. It does not, however, tell us whether the firm is making a profit or incurring a loss. To make this determination, we must compare price (average revenue) with average cost.

AC

A

The Case of Short-Term Losses

$2.25 1.50

0

F I GURE 3 Short-Run Equilibrium of the Perfectly Competitive Firm with a Lower Price

The market is obviously treating the farmer in Figure 2 rather nicely. But what if the corn market were not so generous in its rewards? What if, for example, the market price 30,000 were only $1.50 per bushel instead of $3? Figure 3 shows the Bushels of Corn per Year equilibrium of the firm under these circumstances. The cost curves are the same in this diagram as they were in Figure 2, but the demand curve has shifted down to correspond to the market price of $1.50 per bushel. The firm still maximizes profits by producing the level of output at which marginal cost (MC) is equal to price (P) 2 (MC 5 P 5 MR)—point B in the diagram. But this time “maximizing profits” really means minimizing losses, as shown by the shaded rectangle. At the optimal level of output (30,000 bushels per year), average cost is $2.25 per bushel (point A), which exceeds the $1.50 per bushel price (point B). The firm therefore incurs a loss of $0.75 per bushel times 30,000 bushels, or $22,500 per year. This loss, which is represented by the area of the gold rectangle in Figure 3, is the best the firm can do. If it selected any other output level, its loss would be even greater. B

D = MR = P

Shutdown and Break-Even Analysis

A variable cost is a cost whose total amount changes when the quantity of output of the supplier changes.

Of course, any firm will accept only a limited amount of loss before it stops production. If losses get too big, the firm can simply go out of business. But sometimes it will benefit the firm to continue to operate for a while because of costs that it will still have to pay even if its production ceases. To understand the logic of the choice between shutting down and remaining in operation, at least temporarily to help cover losses, we must return to the distinction between costs that are variable in the short run and those that are not. Recall from Chapter 7 that costs are not variable if the firm cannot escape them in the short run, either because of a contract (say, with a landlord or a union) or because it has already bought the item whose cost cannot now be escaped (for example, a machine bought on credit, with a contract requiring annual payments for X years). If the firm stops producing, then its revenue and its short-run variable costs will fall to zero. But its costs that are not variable will remain. If the firm is losing money, in certain cases it will be better off continuing to operate until its obligations to pay the nonvariable (inescapable) costs expire; but in other cases it will do better by shutting down immediately and producing nothing. That decision obviously depends on whether or not by shutting down immediately, the costs the firm can avoid immediately are greater that the revenue it gives up by having nothing to sell any longer. More explicitly, two rules govern the decision: Rule 1. The firm will make a loss if total revenue (TR) is less than total cost (TC). In that case, it should plan to shut down, either in the short run or in the long run. Rule 2. The firm should continue to operate in the short run if TR exceeds total shortrun variable cost (TVC).

The first rule is self-evident. If the firm’s revenues do not cover its total costs, then it surely will lose money and, sooner or later, it will have to close. The second rule is a bit more subtle. Suppose that TR is less than TC. If our unfortunate firm continues in operation, it will lose the difference between total cost and total revenue: Loss if the firm stays in business 5 TC 2 TR

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 10

203

The Firm and the Industry under Perfect Competition

However, if the firm stops producing, both its revenues and short-run variable costs become zero, but its nonvariable costs must still be paid: Loss if the firm shuts down 5 Nonvariable costs 5 TC 2 TVC

Hence, it is best to keep operating as long as the firm’s loss if it stays in business is less than its loss if it shuts down: TC 2 TR * TC 2 TVC

or TVC * TR, that is, (AVC)Q * PQ, or AVC * P

Case A

Case B

$100 80 60 140 60 40

$100 130 60 190 60 90

MC AC AVC

A

Price

That is, Rule 2. Its logic is simpler than it appears to be: A firm that is losing money should nevertheless stay in business (temporarily) if its revenue more than covers the variable costs that it can escape immediately, because the surplus of TR over TVC provides earnings that help to cover part of the remaining costs—the cost that the firm cannot escape in the short run. Surely, it is better to earn enough to pay off part of those inescapable costs than for the owners of the firm to bear the entire burden themselves and pay the inescapable costs in their entirety. Of course, the firm will not stay in business unless there is some output level at which P 2 AVC, the amount available to help cover inescapable costs, is positive. That is, with the price, P, fixed by industry supply and demand, it will not stay in business unless at the output at which AVC is as small as possible, P . AVC. We can illustrate Rule 2 with the two cases shown in Table 2. Case A deals with a firm that loses money but is better off staying in business in the short run. If it shuts down, it will lose its entire $60,000 worth of shortrun nonvariable cost. If it continues to TABLE 2 operate, its total revenue of $100,000 will The Shutdown Decision exceed its total variable cost (TVC 5 $80,000) by $20,000. That means continuing operation contributes $20,000 toward Total revenue (TR) meeting nonvariable costs and reduces Total variable cost (TVC) losses to $40,000. In Case B, in contrast, it Short-run nonvariable cost pays the firm to shut down because conTotal cost (TC) tinued operation merely adds to its Loss if firm shuts down (5 Short-run nonvariable cost) losses. If the firm operates, it will lose Loss if firm does not shut down $90,000 (the last entry in Table 2); if it NOTE: Figures are in thousands of dollars. shuts down, it will lose only the $60,000 in inescapable costs, which it must pay whether it operates or not. We also can analyze the shutdown decision graphically. In FIGURE 4 Figure 4, the firm will run a loss whether the price is P1, P2, or P3, Shutdown Analysis because none of these prices is high enough to reach the minimum level of average cost (AC). We can show the lowest price that keeps the firm from shutting down immediately by introducing one more short-run cost curve: the average variable cost (AVC) curve that shows how AVC varies, depending on the size of the firm’s output. Why is this curve relevant? Because, as we P3 B have just seen, it pays the firm to remain in operation only P2 if the price exceeds the lowest attainable AVC. An immediate conclusion is P1 The firm will produce nothing unless price lies above the minimum point on the AVC curve.

In Figure 4, price P1 is below the minimum average variable cost. With this price, the firm cannot even cover its variable costs and is better off shutting down (producing zero output).

0 Quantity Supplied

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

P3 P2 P1

204

Part 3

Markets and the Price System

Farming Economics: Ethanol-Driven Price Increases Rock the Food Chain

“Beef prices are up. So are the costs of milk, cereal, eggs, chicken and pork. And corn is getting the blame. President Bush’s call for the nation to cure its addiction to oil stoked a growing demand for ethanol, which is mostly made from corn. Greater demand for corn has inflated prices from a historically stable $2 per bushel to about $4. That means cattle ranchers have to pay more for animal feed that contains corn. Those costs are reflected in cattle prices, which have gone from about $82.50 per 100 pounds a year ago to $91.15 today. The corn price increases flow like gravy down the food chain, to grocery stores and menus. The cost of rounded cubed steak at

local Harris Teeters is up from $4.59 last year to $5.29 this year, according to TheGroceryGame.com, which tracks prices. The Palm restaurant chain recently raised prices as much as $2 for a New York strip. And so on. . . . The heightened demand for corn has decreased the supply of other grains, including soybeans, because farmers are shifting fields to make room for corn. Soybeans are a key ingredient in trans-fat-free cooking oils now in high demand as cities and counties ban fatty oils in restaurants and bakeries. . . . Now Sysco, a Houston food company that is a major supplier of transfat-free oils, says it is seeing pricing pressure on the product.” SOURCE: IndexStock/SuperStock

Because farmers are price takers, they simply have to live with the price that is determined by the market’s supply and demand. Here is an example:

SOURCE: Excerpted from Michael S. Rosenwald, “The Rising Tide of Corn: EthanolDriven Demand Felt Across the Market,” The Washington Post, June 15, 2007, p. D01.

Price P3 is higher. Although the firm still runs a loss if it sets MC 5 P at point A (because AC exceeds P3), it allows the firm to at least cover its short-run variable costs, so it pays to keep operating in the short run. Price P2 is the borderline case. If the price is P2, the firm is indifferent between shutting down and staying in business and producing at a level where MC 5 P (point B). P2 is thus the lowest price at which the firm will produce anything. As we see from the graph, P2 corresponds to the minimum point on the AVC curve.

The Perfectly Competitive Firm’s Short-Run Supply Curve The supply curve of a firm shows the different quantities of output that the firm would be willing to supply at different possible prices during some given period of time.

Without realizing it, we have now derived the supply curve of the perfectly competitive firm in the short run. Why? Recall that a supply curve summarizes in a graph the answers to questions such as, “If the price is so and so, how much output will the firm offer for sale?” We can now see that • In the short run, if the price is high enough for the firm to cover its AVC, then it pays a competitive firm to stay in business and produce the level of output at which MC equals P. Thus, for any price above point B, the lowest point on the AVC curve, in Figure 4, we can read the corresponding quantity supplied from the firm’s MC curve. We can now conclude that The short-run supply curve of the perfectly competitive firm that is not going out of business is the corresponding portion of its marginal cost curve where P 5 AR 5 MR 5 MC. P lies above the lowest point on the average variable cost curve—that is, above the minimum level of AVC. (But it should be remembered that if the market price is below the firm’s AVC at all output levels, as we have just seen, it will pay the firm to go out of business as quickly as possible, dropping its quantity supplied to zero.)

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

205

The Firm and the Industry under Perfect Competition

Chapter 10

THE PERFECTLY COMPETITIVE INDUSTRY Now that we have completed the analysis of the perfectly competitive firm’s supply decision, we turn our attention next to the perfectly competitive industry.

The Perfectly Competitive Industry’s Short-Run Supply Curve Once again, we need to distinguish between the short run and the long run, but the distinction is different here. The short run for the industry is defined as a period of time too brief for new firms to enter the industry or for old firms to leave, so the number of firms is fixed. By contrast, the long run for the industry is a period of time long enough for any firm to enter or leave as it desires. In addition, in the long run each firm in the industry can adjust its output to its own long-run costs.4 We begin our analysis of industry equilibrium in the short run. With the number of firms fixed, it is a simple matter to derive the supply curve of the perfectly competitive industry from those of the individual firms. At any given price, we simply add up the quantities supplied by each of the firms to arrive at the industry-wide quantity supplied. For example, if each of 1,000 identical firms in the corn industry supplies 45,000 bushels when the price is $2.25 per bushel, then the quantity supplied by the industry at a $2.25 price will be 45,000 bushels per firm 3 1,000 firms 5 45 million bushels. This process of deriving the market supply curve from the individual supply curves of firms is analogous to the way we derived the market demand curve from the individual consumers’ demand curves in Chapter 6. Graphically, what we are doing is summing the individual supply curves horizontally, as illustrated in Figure 5. At a price of $2.25, each of the 1,000 identical firms in the industry supplies 45,000 bushels—point c in Figure 5(a)—so the industry supplies 45 million bushels—point C in Figure 5(b). At a price of $3, each firm supplies 50,000 bushels—point e in Figure 5(a)—and so the industry supplies 50 million bushels—point E in Figure 5(b). We can carry out similar calculations for any other price. By adding up the quantities supplied by each firm at each possible price, we arrive at the industry supply Firm curve SS in Figure 5(b).

This adding-up process indicates, incidentally, that the supply curve of the industry will shift to the right whenever a new firm enters the industry.

FI GURE 5 Derivation of the Industry Supply Curve from the Supply Curves of the Individual Firms

Industry

e

$3.00 c

2.25 s

S Price per Bushel

s Price per Bushel

The supply curve of the competitive industry in the short run is derived by summing the shortrun supply curves of all the firms in the industry horizontally.

The supply curve of an industry shows the different quantities of output that the industry would supply at different possible prices during some given period of time.

E

$3.00 C

2.25 S

45 50 Quantity Supplied in Thousands of Bushels (a)

45 50 Quantity Supplied in Millions of Bushels (b)

Industry Equilibrium in the Short Run Now that we have derived the industry supply curve, we need only add a market demand curve to determine the price and quantity that will emerge in equilibrium. We do this for our illustrative corn industry in Figure 6, where the blue industry supply

The relationship between short-run and long-run cost curves for the firm was discussed in Chapter 7, pages 141–143. 4

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

206

Part 3

Markets and the Price System

curve, carried over from Figure 5(b), is SS and the demand curve is DD. The only equilibrium combination of price and quantity is a price of $3 and a quantity of 50 million bushels, at which the supply curve, SS, and the demand curve, DD, intersect (point E). At any lower price, such as E $2.25, quantity demanded (72 million bushels, as shown by point A on the demand curve) will be higher than the A C 45-million-bushel quantity supplied (point C). Thus, the price will be bid up toward the $3 equilibrium. The oppoD site will happen at a price such as $3.75, which is above equilibrium. Note that for the perfectly competitive industry, unlike 45 50 72 the perfectly competitive firm, the demand curve normally Quantity of Corn in slopes downward. Why? Each firm by itself is so small that Millions of Bushels if it alone were to double its output, the effect would hardly be noticeable. But if every firm in the industry were to expand its output, that would make a substantial difference. Customers can be induced to buy the additional quantities arriving at the market only if the price of the good falls. Point E is the equilibrium point for the perfectly competitive industry, because only at a price of $3 are sellers willing to offer exactly the amount that consumers want to purchase (in this case, 50 million bushels). Should we expect price actually to reach, or at least to approximate, this equilibrium level? The answer is yes. To see why, we must consider what happens when price is not at its equilibrium level. Suppose that the price is lower—say, $2.25. This low price will stimulate customers to buy more; it will also lead firms to produce less than they would at a price of $3. Our diagram confirms that at a price of $2.25, quantity supplied (45 million bushels) is lower than quantity demanded (72 million bushels). Thus, the availability of unsatisfied buyers will probably lead sellers to raise their prices, which will force the price upward in the direction of its equilibrium value, $3. Similarly, if we begin with a price higher than the equilibrium price, we may readily verify that quantity supplied will exceed quantity demanded. Under these circumstances, frustrated sellers are likely to reduce their prices, so price will be forced downward. In the circumstances depicted in Figure 6, in effect a magnet at the equilibrium price of $3 will pull the actual price in its direction, if for some reason the actual price starts out at some other level. In practice, prices do move toward equilibrium levels over a sufficiently long period of time in most perfectly competitive markets. Matters eventually appear to work out, as depicted in Figure 6. Of course, numerous transitory influences can jolt any real-world market away from its equilibrium point—a workers’ strike that cuts production, a sudden change in consumer tastes, and so on. Yet, as we have just seen, powerful forces push prices back toward equilibrium— toward the level at which the supply and demand curves intersect. These forces are fundamentally important for economic analysis. If no such forces existed, prices in the real world would bear little resemblance to equilibrium prices, and there would be little reason to study supply-demand analysis. Fortunately, the required equilibrating forces do step in, as appropriate, to bring markets back toward equilibrium. S

Price per Bushel

D $3.75 3.00 2.25 S 0

F I GURE 6 Supply-Demand Equilibrium of a Perfectly Competitive Industry

Industry and Firm Equilibrium in the Long Run The equilibrium of a perfectly competitive industry in the long run may differ from the short-run equilibrium that we have just studied, for two reasons. First, the number of firms in the industry (1,000 in our example) is not fixed in the long run. Second, as we saw in Chapter 7 (page 129), in the long run firms can vary their plant size and change other commitments that could not be altered in the short run. Hence, the firm’s (and the industry’s)

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 10

The Firm and the Industry under Perfect Competition

207

Price per Bushel

long-run cost curves are not the same as the short-run cost curves. These differences can be very important, as we will see. What will lure new firms into the industry or encourage old ones to leave? The answer is profits—economic profits; that is, any part of the firm’s earnings that exceeds the average earnings of other firms in the economy and thus exceeds the firm’s costs, including its opportunity costs. Remember that when a firm selects its optimal level of output by setting MC 5 P, it may wind up with either a profit, as in Figure 2, or a loss, as in Figure 3. Such profits or losses must be temporary for perfectly competitive firms because new firms are free to enter the industry if profits that are greater than the average obtained elsewhere are available in our industry. For the same reason, old firms will leave if they cannot cover their costs in the long run. Suppose that firms in the industry earn very high profits, in excess of the normal rates of return currently available. Then new companies will find it attractive to enter the business, and expanded production will force the market price to fall from its initial level. Why? Recall that the industry supply curve is the horizontal sum of the supply curves of individual firms. Under perfect competition, new firms can enter the industry on the same terms as existing firms. Thus, new entrants will have the same individual supply curves as the old firms. If the market price did not fall, the entry of new firms would lead to an increased number of firms, with no change in output per firm. Consequently, the total quantity supplied to the market would be higher, and it would exceed quantity demanded—which, of course, would also drive prices down. Thus, the entry of new firms must push the price down. FI GURE 7 Figure 7 shows how the entry process works. In this diagram, the demand curve DD and A Shift in the Industry Supply Curve Caused by the original (short-run) supply curve S0S0 are carried over from Figure 6. The entry of new the Entry of New Firms firms seeking high profits shifts the industry’s short-run supply curve outward to the right, to S1S1. The new market equilibrium at point A (rather than at point E) indi(1,000 firms) cates that price is $2.25 per bushel and that 72 million (1,600 firms) S0 bushels are produced and consumed. The entry of new S1 D firms reduces price and raises total output. If the price had not fallen, the quantity supplied after the new firms’ entry would have been 80 milE F $3.00 lion bushels—point F. Why must the price fall in this A case? Because the demand curve for the industry 2.25 slopes downward, consumers will purchase the D increased output only at a reduced price. S1 S0 To see the point at which entry stops being attracted by high profits, we must consider how entry 72 80 50 by new firms affects existing firms’ behavior. At first Quantity of Corn in glance, this notion may seem to contradict the idea Millions of Bushels of perfect competition; perfectly competitive firms are not supposed to be affected by what competitors do, because no individual firm can influence the industry. Indeed, these corn farmers don’t care about the entry of new firms. But they do care very much about the market price of corn and, as we have just seen, the entry of new firms into the corn-farming industry lowers the price of corn. In Figure 8, we juxtapose the diagram of perfectly competitive firm equilibrium (Figure 2) with the perfectly competitive industry equilibrium diagram (Figure 7). Before the new firms’ entry, the market price was $3, point E in Figure 8(b), and each of the 1,000 firms produced 50,000 bushels—the point where marginal cost and price were equal, point e in Figure 8(a). Each firm faced the horizontal demand curve D0 in Figure 8(a). Firms within the industry enjoyed profits because average costs (AC) at 50,000 bushels per firm were less than price. Now suppose that 600 new firms are attracted by these high profits and enter the industry. Each faces the cost structure indicated by the AC and MC curves in Figure 8(a).

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

208

Part 3

Markets and the Price System

Firm

Industry MC

(1,000 firms) S0

e

$3.00

D0

a

2.25

Price per Bushel

Price per Bushel

AC

D1

D (1,600 firms) S1

E $3.00

A 2.25

b

S0

D

S1

40 45 50

50

Quantity of Corn in Thousands of Bushels (a)

72

Quantity of Corn in Millions of Bushels (b)

F I GURE 8 The Perfectly Competitive Firm and the Perfectly Competitive Industry

F I GURE 9 Long-Run Equilibrium of the Perfectly Competitive Firm and Industry

As a result of the new entrants’ production, the industry supply curve in Figure 8(b) shifts to the right, and price falls to $2.25 per bushel. Because the height of the firm’s horizontal demand curve is, as we have seen, equal to the industry price, the firm’s demand curve must now move down to the brick-colored line D1 corresponding to the reduced market price. Firms in the industry react to this demand shift and its associated lower price. As we see in Figure 8(a), each firm reduces its output to 45,000 bushels (point a). But now there are 1,600 firms, so total industry output is 45,000 bushels 3 1,600 firms 5 72 million bushels, point A in Figure 8(b). At point a in Figure 8(a), some profits remain available because the $2.25 price still exceeds average cost (point b is below point a). Thus, the entry process is not yet complete. New firms will stop appearing only when all profits have been competed away. Figures 9(a) and 9(b) show the perfectly competitive firm and the perfectly competitive industry in long-run equilibrium. Only when entry shifts the industry supply curve so far to the right—S2S2 in Figure 9(b)—that each individual firm faces a demand curve that has fallen

Firm

Industry

AC

m D2

$1.87

Price per Bushel

Price per Bushel

MC D (2,075 firms) S2 M $1.87 S2

83

40 Quantity of Corn in Thousands of Bushels (a)

D

Quantity of Corn in Millions of Bushels (b)

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 10

209

The Firm and the Industry under Perfect Competition

to the level of minimum average cost—point m in Figure 9(a)—will all profits be eradicated and entry cease.5 At the equilibrium point, m, in Figure 9(a), each firm picks its own output level to maximize its profit. As a result, for each firm P 5 MC. But free entry also forces AC to equal P in the long run—point M in Figure 9(b)—because if P were not equal to AC, firms would either earn profits or suffer losses. That would mean, in turn, that firms would find it profitable to enter or leave the industry, which is not compatible with industry equilibrium. Thus: When a perfectly competitive industry is in long-run equilibrium, firms maximize profits so that P 5 MC, and entry forces the price down until it is tangent to the firm’s long-run average cost curve (P 5 AC). As a result, in long-run perfectly competitive equilibrium it is always true that for each firm P 5 MC 5 AC

Thus, even though every firm earns zero profit, profits are at the maximum that is sustainable.6

Zero Economic Profit: The Opportunity Cost of Capital Why would there be any firms in the industry at all if, in the long run, they do not make a profit? The answer is that the zero profit concept used in economics does not mean the same thing that it does in ordinary, everyday usage. We have already encountered this and discussed its relevance in Chapter 8 (pages 159–160). Here we will explain this important point in a slightly different way. We have noted that when economists measure average cost, they include the cost of all of the firm’s inputs, including the opportunity cost of the capital (the funds) or any other inputs, such as labor, provided by the firm’s owners. Because the firm may not make explicit payments to some of the people who provide it with capital, this element of cost may not be picked up by the firm’s accountants. So what economists call zero economic profit will correspond to a positive amount of profit as measured by conventional accounting techniques. For example, if investors can earn 15 percent by lending their funds elsewhere, then the firm must earn a 15 percent rate of return to cover its opportunity cost of capital. The chance for investors to earn 15 percent on their money by putting it into the firm is what attracts them to do so. True, the 15 percent return is no more than the investors can earn by putting their money elsewhere, but that does not make their 15 percent receipt unattractive. HOW MUCH DOES IT REALLY COST? Opportunity Cost: Because economists consider the 15 percent opportunity cost in this example to be the cost of the firm’s capital, they include it in the AC curve. If the firm cannot earn at least 15 percent on its capital, funds will not be made available to it, because investors can earn greater returns elsewhere. To break even—to earn zero economic profit—a firm must earn enough to cover not only the cost of labor, fuel, and raw materials but also the cost of its funds, including the opportunity cost of any funds supplied by the owners of the firm.

Economic profit equals net earnings, in the accountant’s sense, minus the opportunity costs of capital and of any other inputs supplied by the firm’s owners.

IDEAS FOR BEYOND THE FINAL EXAM

An example will illustrate how economic profit and conventional accounting profit differ. Suppose that U.S. government bonds pay 8 percent interest, and the owner of a small shop earns 6 percent on her business investment. This shopkeeper might see this as a

5 If the original short-run equilibrium had involved losses instead of profits, firms would have exited from the industry, shifting the industry supply curve inward, until all losses were eradicated, and we would end up in a position exactly like Figure 9. EXERCISE: To test your understanding, draw the version of Figure 8 that corresponds to this case. 6 EXERCISE: Show what happens to the equilibrium of the firm and of the industry in Figure 9 if a rise in consumer income leads to an outward shift in the industry demand curve.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

210

Part 3

Markets and the Price System

6 percent profit, but an economist would see a 2 percent loss on every dollar she has invested in her business. By keeping her money tied up in her firm, the shop owner gives up the chance to buy government bonds and receive an 8 percent return. She is earning minus 2 percent in economic profit. With this explanation of economic profit, we can understand the logic behind the zero-profit condition for the long-run industry equilibrium. Zero profit in the economic sense simply means that firms are earning a return, but that return is just the same as the normal, economy-wide rate of profit in the accounting sense. This result is guaranteed, in the long run, under perfect competition, by freedom of entry and exit.

The Long-Run Industry Supply Curve

FIGURE 10

Price, Average Cost per Bushel

Short-Run Industry Supply and Long-Run Industry Average Cost

$2.62 S 1.50

0

We have now seen basically what lies behind the supply-demand analysis that we first introduced in Chapter 4. Only one thing remains to be explained. Figures 5 through 8 depicted short-run industry supply curves and short-run equilibrium. However, because Figure 9 describes long-run perfectly competitive equilibrium, its industry supply curve must also pertain to the long run. How does the long-run industry supply curve relate to the short-run supply curve? The answer is implicit in what we have just discussed. The long-run industry supply curve evolves from the short-run supply curve via two simultaneous processes. First, new firms enter or some existing ones exit, which shifts the short-run industry supply curve toward its long-run position. Second, and concurrently, as in the long run each firm in the industry is freed from its fixed commitments, the cost curves pertinent to its decisions become its long-run cost curves rather than its short-run cost curves. For example, consider a company that was stuck in the short run with a plant designed to serve 20,000 customers, even though it is now fortunate enough to have 25,000 customers. When it is time to replace the old plant, management will want to build a new plant that can serve the larger number of customers more conveniently, efficiently, and more cheaply. The reduced cost that results from the larger plant is the pertinent cost to both the firm and the industry in the long run. Finally, let us note that the long-run supply curve of the perfectly competitive industry (S2S2 in Figure 9) must be identical to the industry’s long-run average cost curve. This is because in the long run, as we have seen, economic profit must be zero. The price the industry charges cannot exceed the long-run average cost (LRAC) of supplying that quantity because any excess of price over LRAC would constitute a profit opportunity for others that would have attracted new firms and driven price down to average cost. Similarly, price cannot be below LRAC because firms would then have refused to continue to supply that output at this price and output would have fallen, driving price up until it equaled average cost. Therefore, for each possible long-run quantity supplied, the price must equal the industry’s long-run average cost. Thus, this long-run industry supply curve is also the industry’s average S cost curve, and that is the cost curve relevant for determination of long-run equilibrium price and LRAC B quantity in a standard supply-demand diagram. These ideas are illustrated in Figure 10, in which the short-run industry supply curve, SS, lies above and to the left of the long-run average cost curve, A LRAC. Consider any industry output—say, 70 million bushels of corn per year. At that output, the long-run average cost is $1.50 per bushel (point A). But if the 70 price charged by farmers were given by the short-run supply curve for that output—that is, $2.62 per bushel Output in (point B)—then the firms would earn $1.12 in ecoMillions of Bushels of Corn nomic profit on each and every bushel they sold.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 10

The Firm and the Industry under Perfect Competition

211

P OLICY D E B AT E

Should Government Regulators Use Perfect Competition as a Guide? competition is an undesirable and, indeed, impossible goal for such regulated industries. For example, if those industries are characterized by economies of scale, then breaking them into small firms will raise their costs and consumers will have to pay more, not less. Moreover, as we saw in Chapter 7, where there are economies of scale, the average cost curve must go downhill—the larger the firm’s output, the lower its average cost. So marginal cost must be below average cost (see the appendix to Chapter 8 for a review), and a price equal to marginal cost must also be below average cost—and therefore incur a loss rather than earn any profit. Thus, where there are economies of scale, if the firm is forced to charge a price equal to marginal cost it will be forced to go bankrupt! Even so, many regulators, economists, and others believe that perfect competition is so desirable a state of affairs that regulated firms should be required to come as close to it as possible in their behavior. SOURCE: © Hisham Ibrahim/Corbis

As we have seen here and will discuss further in Chapter 14, perfect competition displays the market mechanism at its best, at least in several important respects. It prevents firms from earning excess profits, forces firms to produce the output quantity at which AC is as low as possible, and has other virtues as well. As we will see in Chapters 11 and 12, markets where monopoly or oligopoly prevail are very different from perfect competition. In monopolistic or oligopolistic markets, a few large firms may charge high prices that yield large profits, and they may produce output quantities that do not match consumer preferences. Consequently (see Chapter 13), such industries are often regulated by government agencies. But just what should regulation force monopoly or oligopoly firms to do? Should it force them to behave like perfectly competitive firms? Should it force their prices to equal marginal costs? Should it try to break them up into thousands of tiny enterprises? No one believes that government regulation should go quite that far. Indeed, some economists and others argue that perfect

Such economic profits would induce other firms to enter the industry, which would force prices downward as the industry supply curve shifted outward. So long as this shift did not take SS all the way down to LRAC, some economic profits would remain, and so entry would continue. Thus, SS must continue to fall until it reaches the position of the long-run average cost curve. Then and only then will entry of new firms cease and longrun equilibrium be attained. The long-run supply curve of the perfectly competitive industry is also the industry’s long-run average cost curve. The industry is driven to that supply curve by the entry or exit of firms and by the adjustment of firms already in the industry.

We will see presently that the identity of the industry’s long-run supply curve and its LRAC curve provide us with some important insights.

PERFECT COMPETITION AND ECONOMIC EFFICIENCY Economists have long admired perfect competition as a thing of beauty, like one of King Tutankhamen’s funerary masks. (And it’s just as rare!) Adam Smith’s invisible hand produces results that are considered efficient in a variety of senses that we will examine carefully in Chapter 14. But one aspect of the great efficiency of perfect competition follows immediately from the analysis we have just completed. We saw earlier that when the firm is in long-run equilibrium, it must have P 5 MC 5 AC, as indicated by Figure 9(a), but we know that MC does not equal AC at any point on the AC curve that is moving either downhill or uphill (see the appendix to Chapter 8 if you need to be reminded why this is so). This implies that the long-run competitive equilibrium of the firm will occur at the lowest point (the horizontal point)

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

212

Part 3

Markets and the Price System

on its long-run AC curve, which is also where that curve is tangent to the firm’s horizontal demand curve. In long-run perfectly competitive equilibrium, every firm produces at the minimum point on its average cost curve. Thus, the outputs of perfectly competitive industries are produced at the lowest possible cost to society.

An example will show why it is most efficient if each firm in a perfectly competitive industry produces at the point where AC is as small as possible. Suppose the industry is producing 12 million bushels of corn. This amount can be produced by 120 farms each producing 100,000 bushels, or by 100 farms each producing 120,000 bushels, or by 200 farms each producing 60,000 bushels. Of course, the job can also be done instead by other numbers of farms, but for simplicity let us consider only these three possibilities. Suppose that the AC figures for the firm are as TABLE 3 shown in Table 3. Suppose, moreover, that an outAverage Cost for the Firm and Total Cost for the Industry put of 100,000 bushels corresponds to the lowest (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) point on the firm’s AC curve, equal to 70 cents per bushel. Which is the cheapest way for the industry Firm’s Total Firm’s Average Number of Industry Industry to produce its 12-million-bushel output? In other Output Cost Firms Output Cost words, what is the cost-minimizing number of firms for the job? Looking at column (5) of Table 3, we 60,000 $0.90 200 12,000,000 $10,800,000 100,000 0.70 120 12,000,000 8,400,000 see that the industry’s total cost of producing the 120,000 0.80 100 12,000,000 9,600,000 12-million-bushel output is as low as possible if 120 firms each produce the cost-minimizing output of NOTE: Output is in bushels. 100,000 bushels. Why is this so? The answer is not difficult to see. For any given industry output Q, because Q is constant in the calculation, total industry cost (5 AC 3 Q) will be as small as possible if and only if AC (for each firm) is as small as possible—that is, if the number of firms doing the job is such that each is producing the output at which AC is as low as possible. That this kind of cost efficiency characterizes perfect competition in the long run can be seen in Figures 8 and 9. Before full long-run equilibrium is reached (Figure 8), firms may not be producing in the least costly way. For example, the 50 million bushels being produced by 1,000 firms at points e and E in Figures 8(a) and 8(b) could be produced more cheaply by more firms, each producing a smaller volume, because the point of minimum average cost lies to the left of point e in Figure 8(a). This problem is rectified in the long run by the entry of new firms seeking profit. We see in Figure 9 that after the entry process is complete, every firm is producing at its most efficient (lowest AC) level—40,000 bushels. As Adam Smith might have put it, even though each farmer cares only about his or her own profits, the corn-farming industry as a whole is guided by an invisible hand to produce the amount of corn that society wants at the lowest possible cost.

PUZZLE RESOLVED:

WHICH MORE EFFECTIVELY CUTS POLLUTION— THE CARROT OR THE STICK?

We end by returning to the puzzle with which the chapter began, because we now have all the tools needed to solve it, particularly the observation that the perfectly competitive industry’s long-run supply curve is also its LRAC curve. Remember that we asked: Should polluters be taxed on their emissions, or should they, instead, be offered subsidies to cut emissions? A subsidy—that is, a government payment to the firms that comply—would indeed induce firms to cut their emissions. Nevertheless, the paradoxical result is likely to be an increase in total pollution. Let us see now why this is so. In Figure 11, we have drawn the industry long-run average cost curve (LRAC), XX. We now know that this must also be the industry’s long-run supply curve, because if

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

The Firm and the Industry under Perfect Competition

Chapter 10

FIGURE 11 Taxes versus Subsidies as Incentives to Cut Pollution

T D Price, Average Cost

X B E

S A

T D

X S

0

Qb

Qe

Qa

Output

SOURCE: © The New Yorker Collection 1970 James Stevenson From Cartoonbank.com. All Rights Reserved.

the supply curve lies above (to the left of) LRAC, then economic profits will be earned and entry will drive the supply curve to the right. The opposite would occur if the supply were below and to the right of LRAC. Now, a tax on business firms clearly raises the long-run average costs of the industry. Suppose that it shifts the industry’s LRAC, and thus the long-run supply curve, upward from XX to TT in the graph. This change will move the equilibrium point from E to B and reduce the industry’s polluting output from Qe to Qb. Similarly, a subsidy reduces average cost, so it shifts the LRAC and the long-run supply curve downward and to the right (from XX to SS). This change moves the equilibrium point from E to A and raises the industry’s polluting output to Qa. “So that’s where it goes! Well, I’d like to thank Our paradoxical result follows from the you fellows for bringing this to my attention.” presumption that the more output a polluting industry produces, the more pollution it will emit. Under the tax on emissions, equilibrium moves from E to B, so the polluting output falls from Qe to Qb. Thus, emissions will fall—just as common sense leads us to expect. But, with the subsidy, industry output will rise from Qe to Qa. Thus, contrary to intuition and despite the fact that each firm emits less, the industry must pollute more! What explains this strange result? The answer is the entry of new firms or the exit of old firms. A subsidy will initially bring economic profits to the polluters, which will in turn attract even more polluters into the industry. In essence, a subsidy encourages more polluters to open up for business. But our graph takes us one step beyond this simple observation. It is true that we end up with more polluting firms, but each will be polluting less than before. Thus, we have one influence leading to more pollution and another influence leading to less pollution. Which of these forces will win out? The graph tells us that if a rise in the polluting good’s output always increases pollution, then, in a perfectly competitive industry, subsidies must lead to increased pollution on balance. The corresponding explanation, entailing the exit of firms that are forced to pay a tax penalty for their emissions, applies to the use of taxes to discourage pollution.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

213

214

Part 3

Markets and the Price System

| SUMMARY | 1. Markets are classified into several types depending on the number of firms in the industry, the degree of similarity of their products, and the possibility of impediments to entry. 2. The four main market structures discussed by economists are monopoly (single-firm production), oligopoly (production by a few firms), monopolistic competition (production by many firms with somewhat different products), and perfect competition (production by many firms with identical products, free entry and exit, and full information). 3. Few, if any, industries satisfy the conditions of perfect competition exactly, although some come close. Perfect competition is studied because it is easy to analyze and because it represents a case in which the market mechanism works well, so that it is useful as a yardstick to measure the performance of other market forms. 4. The demand curve of the perfectly competitive firm is horizontal because its output is such a small share of the industry’s production that it cannot affect price. With a horizontal demand curve, price, average revenue, and marginal revenue are all equal. 5. The short-run equilibrium of the perfectly competitive firm is at the level of output that maximizes profits— that is, where MR 5 MC 5 price. This equilibrium may involve either a profit or a loss.

6. The short-run supply curve of the perfectly competitive firm is given by the firm’s marginal cost curve. 7. The industry’s short-run supply curve under perfect competition is the horizontal sum of the supply curves of all of its firms. 8. In the long-run equilibrium of the perfectly competitive industry, freedom of entry forces each firm to earn zero economic profit, or no more than the firm’s capital could earn elsewhere (the opportunity cost of the capital). 9. Industry equilibrium under perfect competition is at the point where the industry supply and demand curves intersect. 10. In long-run equilibrium under perfect competition, the firm chooses output such that average cost, marginal cost, and price are all equal. Output is at the point of minimum average cost. The firm’s demand curve is tangent to its average cost curve at its minimum point. 11. The competitive industry’s long-run supply curve coincides with its long-run average cost curve. 12. Both a tax on the emission of pollutants and a subsidy payment for reductions in those emissions induce firms to cut emissions. However, under perfect competition, a subsidy leads to the entry of more polluting firms and the likelihood of a net increase in total emissions by the industry.

| KEY TERMS | economic profit 209

price taker

perfect competition

supply curve of a firm

198

199

supply curve of an industry 204

variable cost

205

202

| TEST YOURSELF | 1. Under what circumstances might you expect the demand curve of the firm to be a. Vertical?

4. If the firm’s lowest average cost is $52 and the corresponding average variable cost is $26, what does it pay a perfectly competitive firm to do if

b. Horizontal?

a. The market price is $51?

c. Negatively sloping?

b. The price is $36?

d. Positively sloping? 2. Explain why P 5 MC in the short-run equilibrium of the perfectly competitive firm, whereas in long-run equilibrium P 5 MC 5 AC.

c. The price is $12? 5. If the market price in a competitive industry were above its equilibrium level, what would you expect to happen?

3. Explain why it is not sensible to close a business firm if it earns zero economic profits.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 10

The Firm and the Industry under Perfect Competition

215

| DISCUSSION QUESTIONS | 1. Explain why a perfectly competitive firm does not expand its sales without limit if its horizontal demand curve indicates that it can sell as much as it desires at the current market price. 2. Explain why a demand curve is also a curve of average revenue. Recalling that when an average revenue curve is neither rising nor falling, marginal revenue must equal average revenue, explain why it is always true that P 5 MR 5 AR for the perfectly competitive firm. 3. Regarding the four attributes of perfect competition (many small firms, freedom of entry, standardized product, and perfect information): a. Which is primarily responsible for the fact that the demand curve of a perfectly competitive firm is horizontal?

b. Which is primarily responsible for the firm’s zero economic profits in long-run equilibrium? 4. We indicated in this chapter that the MC curve cuts the AVC (average variable cost) curve at the minimum point of the latter. Explain why this must be so. (Hint: Because marginal costs are, by definition, entirely composed of variable costs, the MC curve can be considered the curve of marginal variable costs. Apply the general relationships between marginals and averages explained in the appendix to Chapter 8.) 5. (More difficult) In this chapter we stated that the firm’s MC curve goes through the lowest point of its AC curve and also through the lowest point of its AVC curve. Because the AVC curve lies below the AC curve, how can both of these statements be true? Why are they true? (Hint: See Figure 4.)

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Monopoly The price of monopoly is upon every occasion the highest which can be got. ADAM S M I TH 1

I

n Chapter 10, we described an idealized market system in which all industries are perfectly competitive, and in Chapters 14 and 16 we will describe the virtues of that system. In this chapter, we turn to one of the blemishes—the possibility that some industries may be monopolized—and to the consequences of such a flaw in the market system. We will indeed find that monopolized markets do not match the ideal performance of perfectly competitive markets. Under monopoly, the market mechanism no longer allocates society’s resources efficiently. This suggests that government actions to constrain monopoly may sometimes be able to improve the workings of the market—a possibility that we will study in detail in Chapter 13. But, first, as usual, we start with a real-life puzzle.

C O N T E N T S PUZZLE: WHAT HAPPENED TO AT&T’S “NATURAL MONOPOLY” IN TELEPHONE SERVICE?

MONOPOLY DEFINED Sources of Monopoly: Barriers to Entry and Cost Advantages Natural Monopoly

THE MONOPOLIST’S SUPPLY DECISION Determining the Profit-Maximizing Output

1

Comparing Monopoly and Perfect Competition Monopoly Is Likely to Shift Demand Monopoly Is Likely to Shift Cost Curves

PRICE DISCRIMINATION UNDER MONOPOLY

CAN ANYTHING GOOD BE SAID ABOUT MONOPOLY?

PUZZLE RESOLVED: COMPETITION IN TELEPHONE

Is Price Discrimination Always Undesirable?

SERVICE

Monopoly May Aid Innovation Natural Monopoly: Where Single-Firm Production Is Cheapest

But Adam Smith’s statement is incorrect! See Discussion Question 4 at the end of the chapter.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Part 3

Markets and the Price System

PUZZLE:

WHAT HAPPENED TO AT&T’S “NATURAL MONOPOLY” IN TELEPHONE SERVICE?

We are all keenly aware of the strong competition in the market for telephone service. How can we miss it? A plethora of firms (old and new) offering telephone service of one kind or another besiege us with television commercials, pop-up ads on the Internet, and mountains of junk mail. The days of “Ma Bell,” the affectionate nickname for AT&T’s ubiquitous Bell Telephone System—which used to be virtually the only provider of telephone service—are long gone and now seem as quaint and old-fashioned as the horse and buggy. What was it that allowed competition in this industry, which had always been considered by some as a classic example of a “natural monopoly” against which no competitor could be expected to survive (see a fuller definition below)? In this chapter you will learn about the causes and consequences of monopoly and, in the process, obtain insights about the answers to this question.

SOURCE: © AP Images/DG

218

MONOPOLY DEFINED A pure monopoly is an industry in which there is only one supplier of a product for which there are no close substitutes and in which it is very difficult or impossible for another firm to coexist.

The definition of pure monopoly has rather stringent requirements. First, only one firm can be present in the industry—the monopolist must be “the only game in town.” Second, no close substitutes for the monopolist’s product may exist. Thus, even a city’s sole provider of natural gas is not considered a pure monopoly because other firms offer close substitutes such as heating oil and electricity. Third, there must be a reason why entry and survival of potential competitors is extremely unlikely. Otherwise, monopolistic behavior and its excessive economic profits could not persist. These rigid requirements make pure monopoly a rarity in the real world. The telephone company and the post office used to be examples of one-firm industries that faced little or no effective competition, at least in some of their activities, but most firms face at least a degree of competition from substitute products. If only one railroad serves a particular town, it still must compete with bus lines, trucking companies, and airlines. Similarly, the producer of a particular brand of beer may be the only supplier of that specific product, but the firm is not a pure monopolist by our definition. Because many other beers are close substitutes for its product, the firm will lose much of its business if it tries to raise its price far above the prices of other brands. There is another reason why the unrestrained pure monopoly of economic theory is rarely found in practice. We will learn in this chapter that pure monopoly can have a number of undesirable features. The government has often intervened in markets where a pure monopoly might otherwise prevail, in order to prevent monopolization or to limit the discretion of a monopolist to set its price (for more on types of government intervention to constrain the power of monopolies, see Chapter 13).

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 11

219

Monopoly

If we do not study pure monopoly for its descriptive realism, why do we study it? Because, like perfect competition, pure monopoly is a market form that is easier to analyze than the more common market structures that we will consider in the next chapter. Thus, pure monopoly is a stepping-stone toward more realistic models. More important, we will understand the possible evils of monopoly (and some of its possible benefits) most clearly if we examine monopoly in its purest form.

Sources of Monopoly: Barriers to Entry and Cost Advantages The key requirement for preservation of a monopoly is exclusion of potential rivals from the market. One way to achieve this result is by means of some specific impediment that prevents the establishment of a new firm in the industry. Economists call such impediments barriers to entry. Here are some examples.

1. Legal Restrictions The U.S. Postal Service has a monopoly position for some of its services because Congress has given it one. Private companies that may want to compete with the postal service directly in those services are prohibited from doing so by law. Local monopolies of various kinds are sometimes established either because government grants some special privilege to a single firm (for example, the right to operate a food concession in a municipal stadium) or prevents other firms from entering the industry (for instance, by licensing only a single cable television supplier).

Barriers to entry are attributes of a market that make it more difficult or expensive for a new firm to open for business than it was for the firms already present in that market.

2. Patents Some firms benefit from a special, but important, class of legal impediments to entry called patents. To encourage inventiveness, the government gives exclusive production rights for a period of time to the inventors of certain products. As long as a patent is in effect, the firm has a protected position and holds a monopoly. For example, Xerox Corporation for many years had (but no longer has) a monopoly in plain-paper copying. Most pharmaceutical companies also obtain monopolies on the medicines they discover. The drugmaker Pfizer, for instance, had a patent on Zoloft, which is a best-selling antidepressant medication. This patent expired at the end of 2005, which opened the door to competition from generic makers of the drug that has intensified, contributing to a decrease in the company’s earnings.2

A patent is a privilege granted to an inventor, whether an individual or a firm, that for a specified period of time prohibits anyone else from producing or using that invention without the permission of the holder of the patent.

3. Control of a Scarce Resource or Input If a certain commodity can be produced only by using a rare input, a company that gains control of the source of that input can establish a monopoly position for itself. Real examples are not easy to find, but the South African diamond syndicate used to come close.

4. Deliberately Erected Entry Barriers A firm may deliberately attempt to make entry into the industry difficult for others. One way is to start costly lawsuits against new rivals, sometimes on trumped-up charges. Another is to spend exorbitant amounts on advertising, thus forcing any potential entrant to match that expenditure.

5. Large Sunk Costs Entry into an industry will, obviously, be very risky if it requires a large investment, especially if that investment is sunk—meaning that it cannot be recouped for a considerable period of time. For example, production in an industry may require the firm to construct a large, expensive building of a very special type, and that expenditure will only be covered fully out of returns from company sales far in the future. Thus, the need for a large sunk investment discourages entry into an industry. Many analysts therefore consider sunk costs to be the most important type of “naturally imposed” barrier to entry. For example, the high sunk costs involved in jet airplane production helped Boeing Corporation enjoy a monopoly at the top end of the long-range, wide-body

2 Tim Annett, “The Afternoon Report: Patents & Profits,” The Wall Street Journal (Eastern edition), Online edition, April 20, 2007.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

220

Part 3

Markets and the Price System

jet airliner market for many years after the launch of the 747 jumbo jet. The rival aircraft manufacturer Airbus, which with European governments’ sponsorship has been able to afford the high investments, has since encroached on Boeing’s territory. Such barriers can keep rivals out and ensure that an industry is monopolized. However, monopoly can also occur in the absence of barriers to entry if a single firm has substantial cost advantages over potential rivals. Two examples of attributes of production that create such advantages are technical superiority and economies of scale.

6. Technical Superiority A firm whose technological expertise vastly exceeds that of any potential competitor can, for a period of time, maintain a monopoly position. For example, IBM Corporation for many years had little competition in the computer business mainly because of its technological virtuosity. Of course, competitors eventually caught up. More recently, Microsoft Corporation has established a commanding position in the software business, especially for operating systems, through a combination of inventiveness and marketing wizardry.

7. Economies of Scale If mere size gives a large firm a cost advantage over a smaller rival, it is likely to be impossible for anyone to compete with the largest firm in the industry.

Natural Monopoly

Average Cost

This last type of cost advantage is important enough to merit special attention. In some industries, economies of large-scale production or economies of scope (cost reductions from simultaneous production of a large number of related items, such as car motors and bodies, truck parts, and so on) are so extreme that the industry’s output can be produced at far lower cost by a single large firm than by a number of smaller firms. In such cases, A natural monopoly we say there is a natural monopoly. Once a firm becomes large enough relative to the size is an industry in which of the market for its product, its natural cost advantage may well drive the competition advantages of large-scale out of business whether or not anyone in the relatively large firm has evil intentions. production make it possible A monopoly need not be a large firm if the market is small enough. What matters is the for a single firm to produce size of a single firm relative to the total market demand for the product. Thus, a small bank in a the entire output of the rural town or a gasoline station at a less traveled intersection may both be natural monopmarket at lower average olies, even though they are very small firms. cost than a number of firms each producing a smaller Figure 1 shows the sort of average cost (AC) curve that leads to natural monopoly. It quantity. has a negative slope throughout, meaning that the more a firm in this industry produces, the lower its average cost will be. Suppose that any firm producing video games has this AC curve and that, initially, there are two firms in the industry. Suppose also that the larger firm is producing 2 million games at an average cost of $2.50 (point A), and the smaller firm is producing 1 million games that are no better than its rival’s at an average cost of $3.00 (point B). Clearly, the larger firm can drive the smaller firm out of business F I GURE 1 if it offers its output for sale at a price below $3.00 (so the smaller firm can match the Natural Monopoly price only by running a loss) but above $2.50 (so it can still make a profit). Hence, a monopoly may arise “naturally,” even in the absence of barriers to entry. Once the monopoly is established (producing, say, 2.5 milB lion video games–point C), its output is apt to grow even $3.00 larger, so that its AC will fall even further. The economies of A 2.50 scale act as a very effective deterrent to entry because no new C entrant can hope to match the low average cost ($2.00) of the 2.00 existing monopoly firm. Of course, the public interest may AC be well served if the natural monopolist uses its low cost to keep its prices low. The danger, however, is that the firm 1 2 2.5 may raise its price once rivals have left the industry. Many public utilities operate as regulated monopoly supQuantity Supplied pliers for exactly this reason. It is believed that the technology of producing or distributing their output enables them NOTE: Average cost is in dollars per unit; quantity is in millions.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 11

Monopoly

to achieve substantial cost reductions by producing large quantities. It is therefore often considered preferable to permit these firms to achieve lower costs by having the entire market to themselves and then to subject them and their prices to regulatory supervision, rather than to break them up into a number of competing firms. We will examine the issues connected with regulation of natural monopolies in detail in Chapter 13. To summarize this discussion: There are two basic reasons why a monopoly may exist: barriers to entry, such as legal restrictions and patents, and cost advantages of superior technology or large-scale operation that lead to natural monopoly. It is generally considered undesirable to break up a large firm whose costs are low because of scale economies. But barriers to entry are usually considered to be against the public interest except where they are believed to offer offsetting advantages, as in the case of patents, which are designed to encourage invention.

The rest of this chapter analyzes how a monopoly can be expected to behave if its freedom of action is not limited by the government.

THE MONOPOLIST’S SUPPLY DECISION A monopoly firm does not have a “supply curve,” as we usually define the term. Unlike a firm operating under perfect competition, a monopoly is not at the mercy of the market; the firm does not have to accept the market’s price as beyond its control and adjust its output level to that externally fixed price, as the supply curve assumes. Instead, it has the power to set the price, or rather to select the price-quantity combination on the demand curve that suits its interests best. Put differently, a monopolist is not a price taker that must simply adapt to whatever price the forces of supply and demand decree. Rather, a monopolist is a price maker that can, if so inclined, raise the product price. Thus, the standard supply-demand analysis described in Chapter 4 does not apply to the determination of price or output in a monopolized industry. But it remains true that, for whatever price the monopolist selects, the demand curve for the product indicates how much consumers will buy. The demand curve of a monopoly, unlike that of a perfectly competitive firm, is normally downward-sloping, not horizontal. This means that a price rise will not cause the monopoly to lose all of its customers, but any increase will cost it some business. The higher the price, the less the monopolist can expect to sell. The market cannot impose a price on a monopolist as it imposes a price on the pricetaking perfectly competitive firm. But the monopolist cannot select both price and the quantity it sells. In accord with the demand curve, the higher the price it sets, the less it can sell.

In deciding what price best serves the firm’s interests, the monopolist must consider whether profits can be increased by raising or lowering the product’s price. Because of the downward-sloping demand curve, the sky is not the limit in pricing by a monopolist. Some price increases are not profitable because they lead to disproportionately large reductions in sales of the products. In our analysis, we will assume that the monopolist wants to maximize profits. That does not mean that a monopoly is guaranteed a positive profit. If the demand for its product is low, or if the firm is inefficient, even a monopoly may lose money and eventually be forced out of business. However, if a monopoly firm does earn a positive profit, it may be able to continue doing so in the long run because there will be no entry that competes the profits away. We can use the methods of Chapter 8 to determine which price the profit-maximizing monopolist will prefer. To maximize profits, the monopolist must compare marginal revenue (the addition to total revenue resulting from a one-unit rise in output) with marginal

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

221

222

Part 3

Markets and the Price System

Is the Software Industry a Natural Monopoly?

One factor is diminishing costs: while the first copy of a software program costs millions to produce, the cost to produce subsequent copies is negligible. The second factor is the network effect in which the value of software increases by the number of people using it and developers creating applications for it. The third factor is the lock-in effect, in which the cost of switching to another system (installation, training, application compatibility) persuades users to stick with current systems. . . . These forces create natural barriers to entry for newcomers, and Microsoft’s operating-system dominance is a prime example.

SOURCE: AP Photo/Aynsley Floyd

Some leading economists believe the software industry is prone to monopoly. Three influences may incline the industry in this direction, as an article in InfoWorld describes:

SOURCE: Lynda Radosevich, “Top of the News: How the Software Industry Creates Monopolies,” Infoworld 20 (May 25, 1998).

cost (the addition to total cost resulting from that additional unit). Figure 2 shows a marginal cost (MC) curve and a marginal revenue (MR) curve for a typical monopolist. Recall that the firm’s demand curve (DD) is also its average revenue (AR) curve. That is because if a firm sells Q units of output, selling every unit of output at the price P, then the average revenue brought in by a unit of output must be the price, P, because the average of a bunch of equal numbers must be that same number. Since the demand curve gives the price at which any particular quantity can be sold, it also automatically indicates the AR (5 price) yielded by that quantity. Notice that the marginal revenue curve is always below the demand curve, meaning that MR is always less than price (P). We have already seen that this must be true in the appendix to Chapter 8, where it was demonstrated that if the AR curve slopes downward, the MR curve must lie below the AR curve, because it is this MR , AR that pulls the average down. This important fact is also easy to explain here in common-sense terms. The monopoly firm charges the same price to all of its customers. If the firm wants to increase sales by one unit, it must decrease the price somewhat to all of its customers.

F I GURE 2 Profit-Maximizing Equilibrium for a Monopolist

MC

Price per Unit

D P

AC

$9 M 7 MC 4 AC

C

D (AR) MR

0

150 Quantity

NOTE: Price is in dollars per unit.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 11

Monopoly

223

When it cuts the price to attract new sales, all previous customers also benefit. Thus, the additional revenue that the monopolist takes in when sales increase by one unit (marginal revenue) is the price that the firm collects from the new customers minus the revenue that it loses by cutting the price paid by all of its old customers. This means that MR is necessarily less than P 5 AR; graphically, it implies that the MR curve is below the demand curve, as in Figure 2.

Determining the Profit-Maximizing Output Like any other firm, the monopoly maximizes its profits by setting marginal revenue (MR) equal to marginal cost (MC). It selects point M in Figure 2, where output is 150 units. But point M does not tell us the monopoly price because, as we have just seen, price exceeds MR for a monopolist. To learn what price the monopolist charges, we must use the demand curve to find the price at which consumers are willing to purchase the profit-maximizing output of 150 units. The answer, as we know, is given by the height of the demand curve at that output—it is given by point P directly above M. The monopoly price is $9 per unit. Not surprisingly, it exceeds both MR and MC (which are equal at $7). The monopolist depicted in Figure 2 is earning a tidy profit. This profit is shown in the graph by the shaded rectangle whose height is the difference between price (point P) and average cost (point C) and whose width is the quantity produced (150 units). In the example, profits are $5 per unit, or $750. To study the decisions of a profit-maximizing monopolist: 1. Find the output at which MR equals MC to select the profit-maximizing output level. 2. Find the height of the demand curve at that level of output to determine the corresponding price. 3. Compare the height of the demand curve with the height of the AC curve at that output to see whether the net result is an economic profit or a loss.

We also can show a monopolist’s profit-maximization calculation numerically. In Table 1, the first two columns show the quantity and price figures that constitute this monopolist’s demand curve. Column (3) shows total revenue (TR) for each output, which is the product of price times quantity. Thus, for 3 units of output, we have TR 5 $92 3 3 5 $276. Column (4) shows marginal revenue (MR). For example, when output rises from 3 to 4 units, TR increases from $276 to $320, so MR is $320 2 $276 5 $44. Column (5) gives the monopolist’s total cost for each level of output. Column (6) derives marginal cost (MC) from total cost (TC) in the usual way. Finally, by subtracting TC from TR for each level of output, we obtain total profit in column (7). The table brings out a number of important points. We note first in columns (2) and (3) that a cut in price may inTABLE 1 crease or decrease total revenue. When output rises from 1 A Profit-Maximizing Monopolist’s Price-Output Decision to 2 units, P falls from $140 to $107 and TR rises from $140 to $214. However, when (between 5 and 6 units of output) Revenue Cost Total Profit P falls from $66 to $50, TR falls from $330 to $300. Next we (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) observe, by comparing columns (2) and (4), that after the Q P TR 5 P 3 Q MR TC MC TR 2 TC first unit, price always exceeds marginal revenue (because the marginal revenue curve must lie below the downward0 — $ 0 $ 10 $210 $140 $60 sloping demand [AR] curve). Finally, from columns (4) 1 $140 140 70 70 74 50 and (6) we see that MC 5 MR 5 $44 when Q is between 2 107 214 120 94 62 46 3 and 4 units, indicating that this is the level of output that 3 92 276 166 110 44 44 maximizes the monopolist’s total profit. This is confirmed 4 80 320 210 110 10 43 in column (7) of the table, which shows that at this output 5 66 330 253 77 profit reaches its highest level, $110, for any of the output 230 45 6 50 300 298 2 quantities considered in the table.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

224

Part 3

Markets and the Price System

Comparing Monopoly and Perfect Competition This completes our analysis of the monopolist’s price—output decision. At this point, it is natural to wonder whether there is anything distinctive about the monopoly equilibrium. To find out, we need a standard of comparison. Perfect competition provides this standard because, as we will learn in Chapter 14, it is a theoretical benchmark of ideal performance against which other market structures can be judged. By comparing the results of monopoly with those of perfect competition, we will see why economists since Adam Smith have condemned monopoly as inefficient.

1. A Monopolist’s Profit Persists The first difference between competition and

Monopoly profits are any excess of the profits earned persistently by a monopoly firm over and above those that would be earned if the industry were perfectly competitive.

monopoly is a direct consequence of barriers to entry in monopoly. Profits such as those shown in Figure 2 would be competed away by free entry in a perfectly competitive market, because a positive profit would attract new competitors into the business. A competitive firm must earn zero economic profit in the long run; that is, it can earn only enough to cover its costs, including the opportunity cost of the owner’s capital and labor. But higher profit can persist under monopoly—if the monopoly is protected from the arrival of new competitors by barriers to entry. This can, then, allow monopolists to grow wealthy at the expense of their consumers. But because people find such accumulations of wealth objectionable, monopoly is widely condemned. As a result, monopolies are generally regulated by government, which often limits the profits they can earn.

2. Monopoly Restricts Output to Raise Short-Run Price Excess monopoly profit can be a problem, but economists believe that the second difference between competition and monopoly is even more worrisome: Compared with the perfectly competitive ideal, the monopolist restricts output and charges a higher price.

To see that this is so, let us conduct the following thought experiment. Imagine that a court order breaks up the monopoly firm depicted in Figure 2 (and reproduced as Figure 3) into a large number of perfectly competitive firms. Suppose further that the industry demand curve is unchanged by this event and that the MC curve in Figure 3 is also the (horizontal) sum of the MC curves of all the newly created competitive firms. These may be unrealistic assumptions, as we will soon explain; however, they make it easy to compare the output-price combinations that would emerge in the short run under monopoly and perfect competition. Before making our comparison, we must note that under monopoly, the firm and the industry are exactly the same entity, but under perfect competition, any one firm is just F I GURE 3 MC D Price per Unit

Comparison of a Monopoly and a Perfectly Competitive Industry

AC

P $9 B

M 7 MC

D (AR)

C AC MR 150

300

Quantity (millions) NOTE: Price is in dollars per unit.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 11

Monopoly

a small portion of the industry. So when we measure the performance of monopoly against that of perfect competition, we should compare the monopoly with the entire competitive industry, not with an individual competitive firm. In Figure 3, the monopolist’s output is point M at which MC 5 MR. The long-run competitive output (point B) is greater than the monopoly’s because it must be sufficiently large to yield zero economic profit (P 5 AR 5 AC). It is self-evident and not very interesting to observe that the output of the monopolist is virtually certain to be larger than that of a tiny competitive firm. The interesting issue is how much of the entire industry’s product gets into the hands of consumers under the two market forms—that is, how much output is produced by a monopoly as compared with the quantity provided by a similar competitive industry.

3. Monopoly Restricts Output to Raise Long-Run Price As we have seen, monopoly output is determined by the profit-maximization requirement that MC 5 MR (point M). Moreover, in Chapter 10, we learned that long-run perfectly competitive equilibrium occurs at point B in Figure 3, where price (5AR) and average cost are equal and economic profit is zero. By comparing point B with the monopolist’s equilibrium (point M), we see that the monopolist produces fewer units of output than would a competitive industry with the same demand and cost conditions. Because the demand curve slopes downward, producing less output means that the industry gets away with a higher price. The monopolist’s price, indicated by point P on the demand curve and directly above M, exceeds the price that would result from perfect competition at point B. This is the essence of the truth behind the popular view that unregulated monopolists “gouge the public.” The monopolist deliberately cuts back the amount of output produced in order to make the product scarcer and thereby force its price upward. We should note that matters will always turn out that way if the average cost curve has a positive slope between the monopoly output level and the competitive output level. That is because we know, in this case, that the MC curve must lie above the AC curve (to review why, see pages 173–174 of Chapter 8). We also have just seen that the MR curve must lie below the demand (AR) curve. It is clear, then, that the point where the MR curve meets the MC curve (the monopoly output) must always lie to the left of the output at which AC and AR meet (the competitive industry output). Consequently, monopoly output will always be the smaller of the two when the curves of the competitive and monopoly industries are identical. With monopoly output lower, its price will always be higher. 4. Monopoly Leads to Inefficient Resource Allocation We conclude, then, that a monopoly will charge a higher price and produce a smaller output than will a competitive industry with the same demand and cost conditions. Why do economists find this situation so objectionable? Because, as we will learn in Chapter 14, a competitive industry devotes “just the right amount” of society’s scarce resources to the production of its particular commodity. Therefore, if a monopolist produces less than a competitive industry, it must be producing too little. To summarize this discussion of the consequences of monopoly: Because it is protected from entry, a monopoly firm may earn positive economic profits; that is, profits in excess of the opportunity cost of capital. At the same time, monopoly breeds inefficiency in resource allocation by producing too little output and charging too high a price. For these reasons, some of the virtues of the free market evaporate if an industry becomes monopolized.

Monopoly Is Likely to Shift Demand This analysis need not always apply. For one thing, it has assumed that the market demand curve is the same whether the industry is competitive or monopolized. But is

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

225

226

Part 3

Markets and the Price System

SOURCE: © Sidney Harris, www.sciencecartoonsplus.com

this usually so? The demand curve will be the same if the monopoly firm does nothing to expand its market, but that is hardly plausible. Under perfect competition, purchasers consider the products of all suppliers in an industry to be identical, so no single supplier has any reason to advertise. Advertising expenditure by firm X will bring most of its benefits to the other firms in the industry, because the ads, if they work, will induce customers to buy more of the identical product from among any of its many sellers. But if a monopoly takes over from a perfectly competitive industry, it may very well pay to advertise. If management believes that the creative touch of the advertising agency can make consumers rush to the market to purchase the product whose virtues have been extolled on television, then the firm will allocate a substantial sum of money to accomplish this feat. Take the Eastman Kodak Company, for example. Kodak enjoyed a near monopoly on U.S. film sales from the turn of the century until the 1980s, but that did not stop the company from spending a good deal on advertising. This type of expenditure should shift the demand curve outward. The monopoly’s demand curve and that of the competitive industry will then no longer be the same. The higher demand curve for the monopoly’s product may induce it to expand production and therefore reduce the difference between the competitive and the monopolistic output levels indicated in Figure 3. But it may also make it possible for the monopoly to charge even higher prices, so the increased output may not constitute a net gain for consumers.

Monopoly Is Likely to Shift Cost Curves The advent of a monopoly also may shift the average and marginal cost curves. One reason for higher costs is the advertising we have just been discussing. Another reason is the sheer size of the monopolist’s organization, which may lead to bureaucratic inefficiencies, coordination problems, and the like. At the same time, a monopolist may be able to eliminate certain types of duplication that are unavoidable for a number of small, independent firms: One purchasing agent may do the input-buying job where many buyers were needed before; a few large machines may replace many small items of equipment in the hands of the competitive firms. In addition, the large scale of the monopoly firm’s input purchases may permit it to take advantage of quantity discounts by its input suppliers that are not available to small competitive firms. If the consolidation achieved by a monopoly does shift the marginal cost curve downward, monopoly output will tend to move up closer to the competitive level. The monopoly price will then tend to move down closer to the competitive price.

CAN ANYTHING GOOD BE SAID ABOUT MONOPOLY? We conclude that our graphic comparison of monopoly and perfect competition is very artificial. It assumes that all other things will remain the same, even though that is unlikely to happen in reality. For that reason and others, there are certain cases in which monopoly may not be as damaging to the public interest as the previous discussion suggests. Let us consider some specific ways in which monopoly can offset some of its undesirable consequences.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 11

227

Monopoly

Monopoly May Aid Innovation Some economists have emphasized that it is misleading to compare the cost curves of a monopoly and a competitive industry at a single point in time. Because it is protected from rivals and therefore sure to capture the benefits from any cost-saving methods and new products it can invent, a monopoly has particularly strong motivation to invest in research, these economists argue. If this research bears fruit, the monopolist’s costs will be lower than those of a competitive industry in the long run, even if they are higher in the short run. Monopoly, according to this view, may be the handmaiden of innovation. Although the argument is an old one, it remains controversial. The statistical evidence is decidedly mixed.

Natural Monopoly: Where Single-Firm Production Is Cheapest Second, we must remember that the monopoly depicted in Figure 2 is not a natural monopoly, because its average costs increase rather than decrease when its output expands. However, some of the monopolies you find in the real world are “natural” ones. Where a monopoly is natural, costs of production would, by definition, be higher— possibly much higher—if the single large firm were broken up into many smaller firms. (Refer back to Figure 1.) In such cases, it may serve society’s interests to allow the monopoly to continue because consumers benefit from the economies of large-scale production. But then it may be appropriate to regulate the monopoly by placing legal limitations on its ability to set its prices.

PRICE DISCRIMINATION UNDER MONOPOLY So far we have assumed that a monopoly charges the same price to all of its customers, but that is not always true. In reality, monopoly firms can sell the same product to different customers at different prices, even if that price difference is unrelated to any special costs that affect some customers but not others. Such a practice is called price discrimination. Pricing is also said to be discriminatory if it costs more to supply a good to Customer A than to Customer B, but A and B are nonetheless charged the same price. We are all familiar with cases of price discrimination. For example, suppose that Erik and Emily both mail letters from Lewisburg, Pennsylvania, but his goes to New York while hers goes to Hawaii. Both pay the same 44¢ postage even though Hawaii is much farther away from Lewisburg than New York. Bargain airline fares are another example. Passenger C, who obtained a student discount, may find herself seated next to Passenger D, who has paid 25 percent more for the same flight and the same tastefree food. The airline example shows that price discrimination occurs in industries that are not monopolies. Still, it is easier for a monopolist to charge discriminatory prices than it is for a firm that is affected by competition, because price discrimination means that sales to some customers are more profitable than sales to others. Such discrepancies in profitability tempt rivals, including new entrants into the industry, to charge the more profitable consumers somewhat lower prices in order to lure them away from the firm that is “overcharging” them. Price discriminators sneeringly call this type of targeted entry cream skimming, meaning that entrants go after the best-paying customers, leaving the low payers (the “skimmed milk”) to the discriminator. Whether desirable or not, such entry certainly makes it more difficult to charge higher prices to the more profitable customers. Why do firms sometimes engage in price discrimination? You may already suspect the answer: to increase their profits. To see why, let us consider a simple example. Imagine a town with 100 rich families and 1,000 poor ones. The poor families are each willing to buy

Price discrimination is the sale of a given product at different prices to different customers of the firm when there are no differences in the costs of supplying these customers. Prices are also discriminatory if it costs more to supply one customer than another but they are charged the same price.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

228

Part 3

Markets and the Price System

one video game but cannot afford to pay more than $25. The rich, however, are prepared to buy one per family as long as the price is no higher than $75. If it cannot price-discriminate, the best the firm can do is to set the price at $25 for everyone, yielding a total revenue of $25 3 1,100 5 $27,500. If it charged more, say, $75, it would sell only to the rich and earn just $7,500. If the added cost of producing the 1,000 games for the poorer families is less than the $20,000 in added revenues from the larger sales to the additional poor customers who are led to purchase the games by the lower price ($27,500 2 $7,500 5 $20,000), then the $25 price must be more profitable than the $75 price. But what if the game maker can charge different prices to the rich and to the poor—and can prevent the poor from reselling their low-priced merchandise to the rich at a markup? Then the revenue obtainable by the firm from the same 1,100 video game output becomes $25 3 1,000 5 $25,000 from selling to the poor plus $75 3 100 5 $7,500 from selling to the rich, for a total of $32,500. This is clearly a better deal for the firm than the $27,500 revenue obtainable without price discrimination. Profits are $5,000 higher. In general: When a firm charges discriminatory prices, profits are normally higher than when the firm charges nondiscriminatory (uniform) prices because the firm then divides customers into separate groups and charges each group the price that maximizes its profits from those customers.

We have constructed our simple example to make the two profit-maximizing prices obvious. In practice, that is not so; the monopolist knows that if it sets a price too high, quantity demanded and hence profits will be too low. The discriminating monopolist’s problem is determining the different profit-maximizing prices to charge to different customer groups. The solution to this problem is given by another rule of marginal analysis. For simplicity, suppose that the seller proposes charging two different prices to two customer groups, A and B. Profit maximization requires that the price to Group A and the price to Group B are such that they yield the same marginal revenue, so that the MR from each customer group is equal to the MC of the product; that is, The marginal revenue from a sale to a Group A customer must be the same as that from a sale to a Group B customer: MRa 5 MRb

The reasoning is straightforward. Basically it amounts to this: Suppose you have been selling widgets to two customers and have two widgets left over. When would you be willing to sell one of this remainder to each customer, rather than selling both to only one of the customers? The obvious answer is that you will sell one to each if neither offers you a higher payment (MR) than the other. Thus, suppose that the sale of an additional video game to a Group A customer who lives in Richtown brings in MR a 5 $28 in revenue, whereas the corresponding sale to a Group B customer in Poorborough adds only MRb 5 $12. Such an arrangement cannot possibly be a profitmaximizing solution. By switching one unit of its shipments from Poorborough, with its B customers, and sending that unit instead to Richtown’s A customers, the firm gives up $12 in revenue to gain $28—a net gain of $16 from the same total quantity of sales. Because a similar argument holds for any other pair of marginal revenues that are unequal, profit maximizing clearly requires that the marginal revenue from each group of customers be equal. The equal-marginal-revenue rule enables us to determine the profit-maximizing prices and sales volumes for two such groups of customers diagrammatically. The two panels of Figure 4 show the demand curves and corresponding marginal revenue curves for customer groups A and B. Suppose that the firm is selling the quantity Qa to Group A customers at price Pa. How much must the firm then sell to Group B customers, and at what price, to maximize profits? Our rule gives the answer. The marginal revenue from selling to Group A is equal to H—as we see from point J directly above Qa on the MR curve

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

229

Monopoly

Chapter 11

Customer Group A

Customer Group B

Da Db Pb

Price

Price

Pa

H

0

W

J

Qa

MRa Quantity (a)

Da

0

Qb

H

MRb

Db

Quantity (b)

FI GURE 4 in Panel (a). The rule tells us that the firm must charge a price to Group B customers that induces them to buy the quantity that yields the same marginal revenue, H. We find this quantity by drawing a horizontal line HH through point J from Figure 4(a) to Figure 4(b). The marginal revenues of the two customer groups will clearly be equal where HH cuts the Group B marginal revenue curve—at point W. The profit-maximizing sales volume to Group B will be Qb, directly below point W. And at sales volume Qb, the market B price is clearly given by the corresponding point on the market B demand curve, price Pb directly above Qb.

Prices and Quantities under Price Discrimination

Given price and output in one of two markets (Figure 4a), to determine the profitmaximizing output and price in the other market (Figure 4b) under price discrimination, do the following: 1. Draw the demand and marginal revenue curves for the different customer groups (Group A and Group B) side by side. 2. For the first market (Group A, Figure 4a), draw a horizontal line through point J corresponding to the marginal revenue—quantity combination, which will set the price and quantity for Customer Group A at (Pa, Qa). 3. Knowing the marginal revenue H and output (Qa), point J, for the first market, find the profit-maximizing sales quantity for the second market where the horizontal line cuts the MR curve for the second group of customers, so that the MR levels are the same for both customer groups. 4. Knowing the marginal revenue H and point-maximizing sales quantity Qb for the second market, determine the second customer group’s profit-maximizing price Pb, point W, by locating the point on the demand curve corresponding to the profitmaximizing quantity.

That is not quite the end of the story: We have not yet said anything about costs, and we know that profit maximization must take account of costs as well as revenues. We can deal with the cost issue quite easily, at least if the marginal cost of a video game is the same whether supplied to an A customer or a B customer. Even under price discrimination, we still have the fundamental MR 5 MC rule for profit maximization in each market

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

230

Part 3

Markets and the Price System

segment (see page 165 in Chapter 8). The extended profit-maximization rule under price discrimination then must be: MRa 5 MRb 5 MC

Is Price Discrimination Always Undesirable? Although the word discrimination is generally used to refer to reprehensible practices, price discrimination may not always be bad. Most people feel strongly that it is appropriate for the post office to charge the same price for all first-class letters going between two points in the United States, regardless of the differences in delivery costs. Similarly, most people approve of discounts on theater tickets sold to students or to senior citizens, even though those prices are obviously discriminatory. The same is widely agreed about lower doctor’s fees for needy patients. Other reasons, in addition to some standard of fairness or justice, may provide a defense for price discrimination in certain cases. One such case arises when it is impossible without price discrimination for a private firm to supply a product that customers want. For an illustration, go back to our numerical example of video-game price discrimination. Suppose that the total cost of producing 100 video games is $8,000, and the total cost of producing 1,100 video games is $30,000. Then our firm cannot cover its costs with a uniform, nondiscriminatory price. If it charged $75 to the 100 rich customers willing to pay that much, its $7,500 total revenue would fall short of its $8,000 total cost. Similarly, charging the uniform price of $25 to all 1,100 customers would yield total revenue of only $27,500, which is less than the $30,000 total cost. Thus, any uniform price would drive the firm out of business, depriving customers of the consumers’ surplus from purchasing the product. With discriminatory prices, we saw that the firm would earn $32,500, enabling the firm to cover the $30,000 cost of supplying the requirements of both sets of customers. It is even possible that price discrimination can make a product cheaper than it would otherwise be for all customers—even those who pay the higher discriminatory prices. As you may imagine, this can be true only if the production of the commodity involves significant economies of scale. For example, suppose that price discrimination permits the firm to offer lower prices to certain customers, thereby attracting some business that it would not otherwise have. The firm’s output will therefore increase. Scale economies can then reduce the firm’s marginal costs. If marginal cost falls enough, even the high-priced customer group may end up paying less than it would in the absence of price discrimination. The conclusion from this discussion is not that price discrimination is always a good thing, but rather that it is sometimes desirable. In particular, we must recognize that a firm may be unable to cover its costs without price discrimination—a situation that some observers consider to be relatively common.

PUZZLE RESOLVED:

COMPETITION IN TELEPHONE SERVICE

We conclude our discussion of monopoly by returning to the puzzle that began this chapter: Why are phone services around the country threatened by competition in an industry that was once considered the very definition of a natural monopoly? The answer has many parts, notably changes in the government’s rules and new rulings by the courts, but the main development that made competition in the industry possible is the huge change in telephone service technology.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Monopoly

Until recently, the market for local telephone service was considered a natural monopoly. The primary reason was the need for very expensive transmission facilities, primarily the wires that had to enter every subscriber’s home. Local and state governments even disallowed competition in these markets because they believed that it would lead to wasteful duplication of such costly equipment and that this expensive duplication would lead to higher prices. Instead, local utility commissions regulated these monopolies to ensure adequate service and reasonable prices. Because long-distance calls also had to reach the home and office via those costly wires, the firm that owned them would have been in a position to control the industry and perhaps even to turn it into a monopoly once again, if government rules had not prevented it. Recent changes in communications technology have since made this market riper for competition. Computers and satellite technology have reduced the investment costs of providing phone service. Wherever you live, competition has become a reality, with cell phones that need no wires to connect to households. In addition, voice message transmission via the Internet often is far less costly and easily supplied by rival providers. Local landline phone companies still have some nearmonopoly power in their own geographic territories, but that power seems likely to erode before long.

231

SOURCE: © AP Images/PRNewsFoto/Verizon Wireless

Chapter 11

| SUMMARY | 1. A pure monopoly is a one-firm industry producing a product for which there are no close substitutes. 2. Monopoly can persist only if there are important cost advantages to single-firm operation or barriers to free entry. These barriers may consist of legal impediments (patents, licensing), the special risks faced by a potential entrant resulting from the need to incur large sunk investments, or the result of “dirty tricks” designed to make things tough for an entrant. 3. One important case of cost advantages is natural monopoly—instances in which only one firm can survive because of significant economies of large-scale production.

competitive supply curve has a positive slope, then monopoly output will be lower and price will be higher than they will be in the competitive industry. 6. Economists consider the fact that monopoly output tends to be below the competitive level to constitute an (undesirable) inefficiency. 7. Advertising may enable a monopoly to shift its demand curve above that of a comparable competitive industry. Through economies such as large-scale input purchases, a monopoly may be able to shift its cost curves below those of a competitive industry.

4. A monopoly has no supply curve. It maximizes its profit by producing an output at which its marginal revenue equals its marginal cost. Its price is given by the point on its demand curve corresponding to that output.

8. A monopoly may be able to increase its profits by engaging in price discrimination—charging higher prices for the same goods to customers who are less resistant to price increases, or failing to charge higher prices to customers whom it costs more to serve.

5. In a monopolistic industry, if demand and cost curves are the same as those of a competitive industry, and if the demand curve has a negative slope and the

9. The profit-maximizing discriminatory prices, and corresponding sales volumes, for a firm with several different customer groups can be determined with the

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

232

Part 3

Markets and the Price System

help of an extended rule for profit maximization: that the marginal revenues from sales to each customer group must be equal to one another and to the firm’s marginal cost.

Some firms cannot survive without it, and price discrimination may even reduce prices to all customers if there are substantial economies of scale.

10. Price discrimination can sometimes be damaging to the public interest, but at other times it can be beneficial.

| KEY TERMS | barriers to entry

219

natural monopoly

monopoly profits 224

patents

220

price discrimination

219

pure monopoly

227

218

| TEST YOURSELF | 1. Which of the following industries are pure monopolies? a. The only supplier of heating fuel in an isolated town b. The only supplier of IBM notebook computers in town c. The only supplier of digital cameras Explain your answers. 2. The following are the demand and total cost schedules for Company Town Water, a local monopoly: Output in Gallons 50,000 100,000 150,000 200,000 250,000 300,000

Price per Gallon $0.28 0.26 0.22 0.20 0.16 0.12

Total Cost $ 6,000 15,000 22,000 32,000 46,000 64,000

How much output will Company Town Water produce, and what price will it charge? Will it earn a profit? How much? (Hint: First compute the firm’s MR and MC schedules.) 3. Show from the table in Test Yourself Question 2 that for the water company, marginal revenue (per 50,000-gallon unit) is always less than price. 4. A monopoly sells Frisbees to two customer groups. Group A has a downward-sloping straight-line demand curve, whereas the demand curve for Group B is infinitely elastic. Draw the graph determining the profit-maximizing discriminatory prices and sales to the two groups. What will be the price of Frisbees to Group B? Why? How is the price to Group A determined?

| DISCUSSION QUESTIONS | 1. Suppose that a monopoly industry produces less output than a similar competitive industry. Discuss why this may be considered socially undesirable. Is this because it is always socially beneficial to produce more of some product? 2. If competitive firms earn zero economic profits, explain why anyone would invest money in them. (Hint: What is the role of the opportunity cost of capital in economic profit?) 3. Suppose that a tax of $28 is levied on each item sold by a monopolist, and as a result, it decides to raise its price by exactly $28. Why might this decision be against its own best interests?

4. Use Figure 2 to show that Adam Smith was wrong when he claimed that a monopoly would always charge “the highest price which can be got.” 5. General Motors declared bankruptcy in 2009. If it goes out of business altogether, why might that not reduce the competition facing rival automaker Ford? (Hint: At what price would the assets of the bankrupt companies be offered for sale?) 6. What does your answer to the previous question tell you about the ease or difficulty of entry into the automobile industry?

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 11

7. A firm cannot break even by charging uniform (nondiscriminatory) prices, but with price discrimination it can earn a small profit. Explain why in this case consumers must be better off if the firm is permitted to charge discriminatory prices.

Monopoly

233

8. It can be proved that, other things being equal, under price discrimination the price charged to some customer group will be higher the less elastic the demand curve of that group is. Why is that result plausible?

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Between Competition and Monopoly . . . neither fish nor fowl. JOHN HEY WO OD (C. 1565)

M

ost productive activity in the United States, as in any advanced industrial society, falls somewhere between the two extreme market forms we have considered so far. So if we want to understand the workings of the market mechanism in a real, modern economy, we must look at hybrid market structures that fall somewhere between perfect competition and pure monopoly. There are two such market forms— monopolistic competition and oligopoly—that are analyzed extensively by economists and are extremely important in practice. Monopolistic competition is a market structure characterized by many small firms selling somewhat different products. Here, each firm’s output is so small relative to the total output of closely related and, hence, rival products that the firm does not expect its competitors to respond to or even to notice any changes in its own behavior. Monopolistic competition, or something close to it, is widespread in retailing: shoe stores, restaurants, and gasoline stations are good examples. Most firms in our economy can be classified as monopolistic competitors, because even though they are small, such enterprises are abundant. We begin the chapter by using the theory of the firm described in Chapter 8 to analyze a monopolistically competitive firm’s price–output decisions, then we consider the role of entry and exit, as we did in Chapter 10. Finally we turn to oligopoly, a market structure in which a few large firms dominate the market. The steel, automobile, and airplane manufacturing industries are good examples of oligopolies, despite the increasing number of strong foreign competitors. Probably the largest share of U.S. economic output comes from oligopolists. Although they are fewer in number than monopolistic competitors, many oligopoly firms are extremely large, with annual sales exceeding the total outputs of most countries in the world and even of some of the smaller industrial European countries.

C O N T E N T S THREE PUZZLING OBSERVATIONS

The Excess Capacity Theorem and Resource Allocation

PUZZLE 1: WHY ARE THERE SO MANY RETAILERS?

1ST PUZZLE RESOLVED: EXPLAINING THE ABUNDANCE OF RETAILERS

PUZZLE 2: WHY DO OLIGOPOLISTS ADVERTISE MORE THAN “MORE COMPETITIVE” FIRMS?

OLIGOPOLY

PUZZLE 3: WHY DO OLIGOPOLISTS SEEM TO CHANGE THEIR PRICES So INFREQUENTLY?

MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION Characteristics of Monopolistic Competition Price and Output Determination under Monopolistic Competition

2ND PUZZLE RESOLVED: WHY OLIGOPOLISTS ADVERTISE BUT PERFECTLY COMPETITIVE FIRMS GENERALLY DO NOT Why Oligopolistic Behavior Is So Difficult to Analyze A Shopping List Sales Maximization: An Oligopoly Model with Interdependence Ignored

3RD PUZZLE RESOLVED: THE KINKED DEMAND CURVE MODEL The Game Theory Approach Games with Dominant Strategies Games without Dominant Strategies Other Strategies: The Nash Equilibrium Zero-Sum Games Repeated Games

MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION, OLIGOPOLY, AND PUBLIC WELFARE A GLANCE BACKWARD: COMPARING THE FOUR MARKET FORMS

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

236

Part 3

Markets and the Price System

One critical feature distinguishing an oligopolist from either a monopolist or a perfect competitor is that oligopolists care very much about what other individual firms in the industry do. The resulting interdependence of decisions, as we will see, makes oligopoly very difficult to analyze and results in a wide range of behavior patterns. Consequently, economic theory uses not just one but many models of oligopoly (some of which we will review in this chapter), and it is often hard to know which model to apply in any particular situation.

PUZZLE:

THREE PUZZLING OBSERVATIONS We need to study the hybrid market structures considered in this chapter because many economic phenomena cannot be explained in terms of perfect competition or pure monopoly. Here are three examples:

PUZZLE 1: WHY ARE THERE SO MANY RETAILERS? You have undoubtedly seen road intersections with gasoline stations on every corner. Often, two or three of them have no customers at the pumps. There seems to be more gas stations than the number of cars warrants, with a corresponding waste of labor, time, equipment, and other resources. Why—and how—do they all stay in business?

PUZZLE 2: WHY DO OLIGOPOLISTS ADVERTISE MORE THAN “MORE COMPETITIVE” FIRMS? Many big companies use advertising as a principal weapon in their battle for customers, and advertising budgets can constitute very large shares of their expenditures. Such firms spend literally billons of dollars per year on advertising, seeking to leap ahead of their rivals. For instance, Procter & Gamble, the largest U.S. advertiser, reportedly spent $2.8 billion on advertising (about 23 percent of its 2008 net earnings).1 Yet critics often accuse oligopolistic industries containing only a few giant firms of being “uncompetitive.” Farming, in contrast, is considered as close to perfect competition as any industry in our economy, but few, if any, individual farmers spend anything at all on advertising.2 Why do these allegedly “uncompetitive” oligopolists make such heavy use of combative advertising, whereas very competitive farmers do not?

PUZZLE 3: WHY DO OLIGOPOLISTS SEEM TO CHANGE THEIR PRICES SO INFREQUENTLY? Many prices in the economy change from minute to minute. The very latest prices of commodities such as soybeans, pork bellies, and copper are available online 24 hours a day, seven days a week. If you want to buy one of these commodities at 11:45 A.M. today, you cannot use yesterday’s price—or even the price from 11:44 A.M. today—because it has probably changed already. Yet prices of products such as cars and refrigerators generally change only a few times a year at most, even during fairly rapid inflation. Firms that sell cars and refrigerators know that product and input market conditions change all the time. Why don’t they adjust their prices more often? This chapter will offer answers to each of these questions.

MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION For years, economic theory told us little about market forms in between the two extreme cases of pure monopoly and perfect competition. Then, during the 1930s, Edward Chamberlin of Harvard University and Joan Robinson of Cambridge University (working

Source: The Nielsen Company, “U.S. Ad Spending Fell 2.6% in 2008, Nielsen Reports,” press release, March 13, 2009, accessed online: http://en-us.nielsen.com/main/news/news_releases; and The Procter & Gamble Company, 2008 Annual Report, accessed online: http://www.pg.com/annualreport2008.

1

2

Farmers’ associations, such as Sunkist and various dairy groups, do spend money on advertising.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 12

237

Between Competition and Monopoly

separately) partially filled this gap and helped to make economic theory more realistic. The market structure they analyzed is called monopolistic competition.

Characteristics of Monopolistic Competition A market is said to operate under conditions of monopolistic competition if it satisfies four requirements, three of which are the same as those for perfect competition:

Monopolistic competition refers to a market in which products are heterogeneous but which is otherwise the same as a market that is perfectly competitive.

• Numerous participants—that is, many buyers and sellers, all of whom are small • Freedom of exit and entry • Perfect information • Heterogeneous products—as far as the buyer is concerned, each seller’s product differs

at least somewhat from every other seller’s product

Notice that monopolistic competition differs from perfect competition in only the last respect. Perfect competition assumes that the products of different firms in an industry are identical, but under monopolistic competition products differ from seller to seller—in terms of quality, packaging, supplementary services offered (such as windshield washing at a gas station), or merely consumers’ perceptions. The attributes that differentiate products need not be “real” in any objective or directly measurable sense. For example, differences in packaging or in associated services can and do distinguish otherwise identical products. However, although two products may perform quite differently in quality tests, if consumers know nothing about this difference, it is irrelevant. In contrast to a perfect competitor, a monopolistic competitor’s demand curve is negatively sloped. Because each seller’s product is different, each caters to a set of customers who vary in their loyalty to the particular product. If the firm raises its price somewhat, it will drive some of its customers to competitors’ offerings, but customers who strongly favor the firm’s product will not switch. If one monopolistic competitor lowers its price, it may expect to attract some trade from rivals. However, because different products are imperfect substitutes, it will not lure away all of the rivals’ business. For example, if Harriet’s Hot Dog House reduces its price slightly, it will attract those customers of Sam’s Sausage Shop who were nearly indifferent between the two. If Harriet were to cut her prices further, she would gain some customers who have a slightly greater preference for Sam’s product. But even a big cut in Harriet’s price will not bring her the hard-core sausage lovers who hate hot dogs. Therefore, monopolistic competitors face a demand curve that is negatively sloped, like that of a monopolist, rather than horizontal, like that of a perfect competitor who will lose all of his business if he insists on a higher price than that charged by a rival. Because consumers see each product as distinct from all others, a monopolistically competitive firm appears to have something akin to a small monopoly. Can we therefore expect it to earn more than zero economic profit? Like perfect competitors, perhaps monopolistic competitors will obtain economic profits in the short run. In the long run, however, high economic profits will attract new entrants into a monopolistically competitive market—not with products identical to an existing firm’s, but with products sufficiently similar to absorb the excess economic profits. If McDonald’s is thriving at a particular location, it can confidently expect Burger King or some other fast-food outlet to open a franchise nearby shortly. When one seller adopts a new, attractive package, rivals will soon follow suit with slightly different designs and colors of their own. In this way, freedom of entry ensures that the monopolistically competitive firm earns no higher return on its capital in the long run than that capital could earn elsewhere. In other words, the firm earns no excess economic profits. Just as under perfect competition, competition will drive price down to equal average cost, including the opportunity cost of capital. In this sense, although its product differs somewhat from everyone else’s, the firm under monopolistic competition has no more monopoly power than does one operating under perfect competition.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

238

Part 3

Markets and the Price System

F I GURE 1 Short-Run Equilibrium of the Firm under Monopolistic Competition

Let us now examine the process that ensures that competition will drive economic profits down to zero in the long run, even under monopolistic competition, and see what prices and outputs that process fosters.

Price and Output Determination under Monopolistic Competition MC

Price per Gallon

$3.40

$3.00 $2.80 $2.50

F I GURE 2

Price per Gallon

Long-Run Equilibrium of the Firm under Monopolistic Competition

$2.85 $2.70

The short-run equilibrium of the firm under monopolistic competition differs little from the equilibrium seen under monopoly. Because the AC firm faces a downward-sloping demand curve (labeled D in Figure 1), its marginal revenue (MR) curve will lie below its demand curve. P Like any firm, a monopolistic competitor maximizes profits by producing the output at which marginal revenue equals marginal cost (MC). In C Figure 1, the profit-maximizing output for a hyE pothetical gas station is 12,000 gallons per week, D and it sells this output at a price of $3.00 per gallon (point P on the demand curve). The firm makes 20 cents per gallon in profits, as depicted by the vertical distance from C to P. MR This analysis, you will note, looks much like 12,000 Figure 2 in Chapter 11 for a monopoly. The main difference is that monopolistic competitors are Gallons of Gasoline per Week likely to face a much flatter demand curve than pure monopolists do, because many products serve as close substitutes for the monopolistic competitor’s product. If our gas station raises its price to $3.40 per gallon, most of its customers will go across the street. If it lowers its price to $2.50 per gallon, it will have long lines at its pumps. The gas station depicted in Figure 1 is enjoying economic profits. Because average cost at 12,000 gallons per week is only $2.80 per gallon (point C), the station makes a profit of 20 cents per gallon on gasoline sales, or $1,200 per week in total, shown by the shaded rectangle. Under monopoly, such profits can persist. Under monopolistic competition, they cannot—because economic profits will entice MC new firms to enter the market. Although the new gas stations will not offer the identical AC product, they will offer products that are close enough to take away some business from our firm. (For example, they may sell Conoco or Shell gasoline instead of Exxon gasoline.) P When more firms enter the market, each firm’s M demand curve will shift downward (to the left). But how far will it shift? The answer is basically the same as it was under perfect competition: Market entry will cease only when the most that the firm can earn is zero economic profit—exactly E the same return the firm can earn elsewhere. D Figure 2 depicts the same monopolistically competitive firm as in Figure 1 after the adMR justment to the long-run equilibrium is com10,000 15,000 plete. The demand curve—and also the MR curve—has been pushed down so far by the Gallons of Gasoline per Week entry of new rivals that when the firm equates

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 12

Between Competition and Monopoly

MC and MR in an attempt to maximize profits (point E), it simultaneously equates price (P) and average cost (AC) so that economic profits are zero (point P). As compared to the short-run equilibrium depicted in Figure 1, price in long-run equilibrium is lower ($2.85 cents per gallon versus $3.00), more firms participate in the industry, and each firm produces a smaller output (10,000 gallons versus 12,000 gallons) at a higher average cost per gallon ($2.85 versus $2.80).3 In general: Long-run equilibrium under monopolistic competition requires that the firm’s output be at a level where its demand curve and its average cost curve meet, and there the two curves must be tangent, not crossing.

Why? Because if the demand curve were above the average cost curve or the two curves intersected, firms could produce output quantities at which price would exceed average cost, which means that participants would be earning economic profits, and that would draw an influx of new close-substitute products that would push down the demand curve. Similarly, if the average cost curve were above the demand curve at every point, the firm would incur an economic loss—it would be unable to obtain returns equal to those that its capital can get elsewhere, and firms would leave the industry. This analysis of entry is quite similar to the perfectly competitive case. Moreover, the notion that firms under monopolistic competition earn exactly zero economic profits seems to correspond fairly well to what we see in the real world. Gas station operators, whose markets fit the characteristics of monopolistic competition, do not earn notably higher profits than do small farmers, who operate under conditions closer to perfect competition.

The Excess Capacity Theorem and Resource Allocation One economically significant difference arises between perfect and monopolistic competition. Look at Figure 2 again. The tangency point between the average cost and demand curves, point P, occurs along the negatively sloping portion of the average cost curve, because P is the only point where the AC curve has the same (negative) slope as the demand curve. If the AC curve is U-shaped, the tangency point must therefore lie above and to the left of the minimum point on the average cost curve, point M. In other words, under monopolistic competition, the demand curve hits the average cost curve in a region where average costs are still declining. Average costs have yet to reach their lowest point. By contrast, the perfectly competitive firm’s demand curve is horizontal, so tangency must take place at the minimum point on the average cost curve. You can easily confirm this by referring back to Figure 9(a) in Chapter 10. This difference leads to the following important conclusion: Under monopolistic competition in the long run, the firm will tend to produce an output lower than that which minimizes its unit costs, and hence unit costs of the monopolistic competitor will be higher than necessary. Because the level of output that corresponds to minimum average cost is naturally considered to be the firm’s optimal capacity, this result has been called the excess capacity theorem of monopolistic competition. Thus, monopolistic competition tends to lead firms to have unused or wasted capacity.

It follows that if every firm under monopolistic competition were to expand its output, cost per unit of output would be reduced. However, we must be careful about jumping to policy conclusions from that observation. It does not follow that every monopolistically competitive firm should produce more. After all, such an overall increase in industry output means that a smaller portion of the economy’s resources will be available for other uses;

EXERCISE: Show that if the demand curve fell still further, the firm would incur a loss. What would then happen in the long run?

3

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

239

Part 3

Markets and the Price System

from the information at hand, we have no way of knowing whether that choice leaves us better or worse off in terms of social benefits. Even so, the situation depicted in Figure 2 probably represents a substantial inefficiency. Although it is not clear that society would gain if every firm were to achieve lower costs by expanding its production, society can save resources if firms combine into a smaller number of larger companies that produce the same total output. For example, suppose that in the situation shown in Figure 2, 15 monopolistically competitive firms each sell 10,000 gallons of gasoline per week. The total cost of this output, according to the figures given in the diagram, would be:

Number of firms 3 Output per firm 3 Cost per unit 5 15 3 10,000 3 $2.85 5 $427,500 If, instead, the number of stations were cut to 10 and each sold 15,000 gallons, total production would be unchanged. But total costs would fall to 10 3 15,000 3 $2.70 5 $405,000, a net saving of $22,500 without any cut in total output. This result does not depend on the particular numbers that we used in our illustration. It follows directly from the observation that lowering the cost per unit must always reduce the total cost of producing any given industry output. That is, producing a given output, Q, always must have a lower total cost when average cost is lower: Specifically, if AC1,AC2, it must obviously always be true that TC1 5 Q 3 AC1 , Q 3 AC2 5 TC2. Society must gain in the sense of getting the same total output, Q, as before but at a lower total cost. After all, which do you prefer—a dozen cans of soda for $0.70 each or the same dozen cans for $0.55 each?

1ST PUZZLE RESOLVED:

EXPLAINING THE ABUNDANCE OF RETAILERS

The excess capacity theorem explains one of the puzzles mentioned at the beginning of this chapter. The highway intersection with four gas stations, where two could serve the available customers with little increase in customer delays and at lower costs, is a real-world example of excess capacity. The excess capacity theorem seems to imply that too many sellers participate in monopolistically competitive markets and that society would benefit from a reduction in their numbers. However, such a conclusion may be a bit hasty. Even if a smaller number of larger firms can reduce costs, society may not benefit from the change because it will leave consumers with a smaller range of choice. Because all products differ at least slightly under monopolistic competition, a reduction in the number of firms means that the number of different products falls as well. We achieve greater efficiency at the cost of greater standardization. In some cases, consumers may agree that this trade-off represents a net gain, particularly if the variety of products available was initially so great that it only confused them. But for some products, most consumers would probably agree that the diversity of choice is worth the extra cost involved. After all, we would probably save money on clothing if every student were required to wear a uniform. But because the uniform is likely to be too hot for some students, too cool for other students, and aesthetically displeasing to almost “Why have we come? Because only Earth offers the rock-bottom everyone else, would the cost saving really be a prices and wide selection of men’s, women’s, and children’s clothing net benefit? SOURCE: © The New Yorker Collection, 1997, Michael Maslin from Cartoonbank.com. All Rights Reserved.

240

in the styles and sizes we’re looking for.”

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Between Competition and Monopoly

241

An oligopoly is a market dominated by a few sellers, at least several of which are large enough relative to the total market that they may be able to influence the market price. In highly developed economies, it is not monopoly, but oligopoly, that is virtually synonymous with “big business.” Any oligopolistic industry includes a group of giant firms, each of which keeps a watchful eye on the actions of the others. Under oligopoly, rivalry among firms takes its most direct and active form. Here one encounters such actions and reactions as frequent new-product introductions, free samples, and aggressive—if not downright nasty—advertising campaigns. A firm’s price decision may elicit cries of pain from its rivals, and firms are often engaged in a continuing battle in which they plan strategies day by day and each major decision induces direct responses by rival firms. Notice that the definition of oligopoly does not mention the degree of product differentiation. Some oligopolies sell products that are essentially identical (such as steel plate from different steel manufacturers), whereas others sell products that are quite different in consumers’ eyes (for example, Chevrolets, Fords, and Hondas). Some oligopolistic industries also contain a considerable number of smaller firms (example: soft drink manufacturers), but they are nevertheless considered oligopolies because a few large firms carry out the bulk of the industry’s business and smaller participants must follow their larger rivals’ lead to survive at the margins of the industry. Oligopolistic firms often seek to create unique products—unique, at least, in consumers’ perceptions. To the extent that an oligopolistic firm can create a unique product in terms of features, location, or appeal, it protects itself from the pressures of competition that will force down its prices and eat into its sales. Managers of large, oligopolistic firms who have occasion to study economics are somewhat taken aback by the notion of perfect competition, because it is devoid of all harsh competitive activity as they know it. Recall that under perfect competition firm managers make no price decisions—they simply accept the price dictated by market forces and adjust their output accordingly. As we observed at the beginning of the chapter, a perfectly competitive firm does not advertise; it adopts no sales gimmicks; it does not even know most of its competitors. But because oligopolists have some degree of influence on market forces, they do not enjoy the luxury of such anonymity. They worry about prices, spend fortunes on advertising (see “The Mad Scramble to Differentiate the Product” on the next page), and try to understand or even predict their rivals’ behavior patterns.

An oligopoly is a market dominated by a few sellers, at least several of which are large enough relative to the total market to be able to influence the market price.

Chapter 12

OLIGOPOLY

2ND PUZZLE RESOLVED:

WHY OLIGOPOLISTS ADVERTISE BUT PERFECTLY COMPETITIVE FIRMS GENERALLY DO NOT

The two reasons for such divergent behavior should be clear, and they explain the puzzling fact that oligopolists advertise far more than the supposedly far more competitive firms in perfectly competitive markets. First, a perfectly competitive firm can sell all it wants at the current market price, so why should it waste money on advertising? By contrast, Ford Motor Company and Toyota cannot sell all the cars they want at the current price. Because they face negatively sloped (and thus less than perfectly elastic) demand curves, if they want to sell more, they must either reduce prices (to move along the demand curve toward greater quantities) or advertise more (to shift their demand curves outward). Second, because the public believes that the products supplied by firms in a perfectly competitive industry are identical, if Firm A advertises its product, the advertisement is just as likely to bring customers to Firm B as to itself. Under oligopoly, however, consumer products are often not identical. Volkswagen advertises to convince consumers that its automobiles are better than Ford’s or Toyota’s. If the advertising campaign succeeds, Ford and Toyota will be hurt and probably will respond with more advertising of their own. Thus, the firms in an oligopoly with differentiated products must compete via advertising, whereas perfectly competitive firms gain little or nothing by doing so.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

242

Part 3

Markets and the Price System

Competition is fierce in the world of business, and companies will go very far indeed to outdo their rivals. In the summer of 2000, Pizza Hut’s advertising campaign was literally out of this world: The firm helped to bankroll Russia’s space agency by putting a 10-meter-high, $1.25-million ad on a Proton booster rocket. More recent advertising stunts include Snapple’s 2005 attempt to erect a 25-foot-tall popsicle in Times Square (it melted in the June heat), a glass elevator decorated to look like a giant Oreo cookie dunking into a glass of milk, and deodorant-maker Right Guard’s 2008 “pitvertising” campaign: London subway riders with miniature TV screens playing Right Guard commercials sewn into the armpits of their shirts. SOURCES: “Marketing: Guerrillas in Our Midst,” The Economist, October 14, 2000, p. 80; Gina Gayle, “Giant Popsicle Melts, Floods New York Park,” Associated Press, June 22, 2005; and Stephanie Clifford, “Summer Silliness Brings a Pizza Field and a Giant Oreo,” The New York Times, August 1, 2008.

SOURCE: Courtesy of Pizza Hut

The Mad Scramble to Differentiate the Product

Why Oligopolistic Behavior Is So Difficult to Analyze Firms in an oligopolistic industry—in particular, the largest of those firms—have some latitude in choosing their product prices and outputs. Furthermore, to survive and thrive in an oligopolistic environment, firms must take direct account of their rivals’ responses. Both of these features complicate the analysis of the oligopolistic firm’s behavior and prevent us from drawing unambiguous conclusions about resource allocation under oligopoly. Oligopoly is much more difficult to analyze than other forms of economic organization, because oligopolistic decisions are, by their very nature, interdependent. Oligopolists recognize that the outcomes of their decisions depend on their rivals’ responses. For example, Volkswagen managers know that their actions will probably lead to reactions by Ford, which in turn may require a readjustment of Volkswagen’s plans, thereby modifying Ford’s response, and so on. Where such a sequence of moves and countermoves may lead is difficult enough to ascertain, but the fact that Volkswagen executives recognize this possibility in advance, and may try to second-guess or predict Ford’s reactions as they initially decide on a marketing tactic, makes even that first step difficult to analyze and almost impossible to predict. Truly, almost anything can and sometimes does happen under oligopoly. The early railroad kings went so far as to employ gangs of hoodlums who fought pitched battles to try to squelch rival lines’ operations. At the other extreme, oligopolistic firms have employed overt or covert forms of collusion to avoid rivalry altogether—to transform an oligopolistic industry, at least temporarily, into a monopolistic one. In other instances, oligopolistic firms seem to have arranged to live and let live, via price leadership (discussed later) or geographic allocations, dividing up customers by agreement among the firms.

A Shopping List Because oligopolies in the real world are so diverse, oligopoly models in the theoretical world should also come in various shapes and sizes. An introductory course cannot hope to explain all of the many oligopoly models. This section offers a quick review of some oligopolistic behavior models. In the remainder of the chapter, we turn our attention to a

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 12

243

Between Competition and Monopoly

particularly interesting set of models that use methods such as game theory to analyze oligopolistic firm behavior.

1. Ignoring Interdependence One simple approach to the problem of oligopolistic interdependence is to assume that the oligopolists themselves ignore it—that they behave as if their actions will not elicit reactions from their rivals. Perhaps an oligopolist, finding the “If they think that we think that they think . . . ” chain of reasoning too complex, will decide to ignore rivals’ behavior. The firm may then just seek to maximize profits, assuming that its decisions will not affect its rivals’ strategies. In this case, economists can analyze oligopoly in the same way they look at monopoly, which we described in Chapter 11. Probably no oligopolist totally ignores all of its major rivals’ decisions, but many of them seem to do so as they make their more routine decisions, which are nevertheless often quite important.

2. Strategic Interaction Although some oligopolists may ignore interdependence some of the time, models based on such behavior probably do not offer a general explanation for most oligopoly behavior most of the time. The reason is simple: Because they operate in the same market, the price and output decisions of soapsuds makers Brand X and Brand Y really are interdependent. Suppose, for example, that Brand X, Inc., managers decide to cut their soapsuds’ price from $1.12 to $1.05, on the assumption that rival Brand Y, Inc., will ignore this move and continue to charge $1.12 per box. Brand X decides to manufacture 5 million boxes per year and to spend $1 million per year on advertising. It may find itself surprised when Brand Y cuts its price to $1.00 per box, raises production to 8 million boxes per year, and sponsors the Super Bowl! In such a case, Brand X’s profits will suffer, and the company will wish it had not cut its price in the first place. Most important for our purposes, Brand X managers will learn not to ignore interdependence in the future. For many oligopolies, then, competition may resemble military operations involving tactics, strategies, moves, and countermoves. Thus, we must consider models that deal explicitly with oligopolistic interdependence. 3. Cartels The opposite of ignoring interdependence occurs when all firms in an oligopoly try to do something about their interdependence and agree to set price and output, acting as a monopolist would. In a cartel, firms collude directly to coordinate their actions to transform the industry into a giant monopoly. A notable cartel is the Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC), which first began making joint decisions on oil production in the 1970s. For a while, OPEC was one of the most spectacularly successful cartels in history. By restricting output, its member nations managed to quadruple the price of oil between 1973 and 1974. Unlike most cartels, which come apart because of internal bickering or other reasons, OPEC held together through two worldwide recessions and a variety of unsettling political events. It struck again with huge price increases between 1979 and 1980. In the mid-1980s, its members began to act in ways that did not promote the interest of the entire industry and oil prices tumbled, but prices have since risen spectacularly and OPEC continues to dominate the world oil market. (See “OPEC Says Market Woes Cloud Output View” on the next page for more recent news of OPEC and oil prices.) OPEC’s early success is hardly the norm. Cartels are difficult to organize and even more difficult to enforce. Firms struggle to agree on such things as the amount by which each will reduce its output in order to help push up the price. For a cartel to survive, each member must agree to produce no more output than that assigned to it by the group. Yet once the cartel drives up the price and increases profitability, each member faces the temptation to offer secret discounts that lure some of the now very profitable business away from other members. When this happens, or even when members begin to suspect one another of doing so, the collusive agreement often begins to come apart. Each member

A cartel is a group of sellers of a product who have joined together to control its production, sales, and price in the hope of obtaining the advantages of monopoly.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

244

Part 3

Markets and the Price System

begins suspecting the others and is tempted to cut its price first, before the others beat it to the punch. For this reason, cartels usually adopt elaborate policing arrangements. In effect, they spy on each member firm to ensure that it does not sell more than it is supposed to or shave the price below that chosen by the cartel. This means that cartels are unlikely to succeed or to last very long if the firms sell many, varied products whose prices are difficult to compare and whose outputs are difficult to monitor. In addition, if firms frequently negotiate prices on a customer-by-customer basis and often offer special discounts to favored buyers, a cartel may be almost impossible to arrange. Many economists consider cartels to be the worst form of market organization, in terms of efficiency and consumer welfare. A successful cartel may end up charging the monopoly price and obtaining monopoly profits. But because the firms do not actually combine operations, cartels offer the public no offsetting benefits in the form of economies of large-scale production. For these and other reasons, open collusion on prices and outputs among firms is illegal in the United States, as we will see in Chapter 13. Outright cartel arrangements rarely occur within the United States, although they are common in some other countries. Only one major exception occurs in the United States: Government regulations have sometimes forced industries such as railroads and gas pipeline transportation to behave as cartels. Regulations prohibited these firms from undercutting the prices set by the regulatory agencies—an exception that we will discuss in Chapter 13.

4. Price Leadership and Tacit Collusion Overt collusion—in which firms actually meet or communicate directly in some other way to decide on prices and outputs—is quite rare, presumably because it is illegal and can result in large fines or other penalties. But some observers think that tacit collusion—where firms, without meeting together, try to do unto their competitors as they hope their competitors will do unto them—occurs quite commonly among oligopolists in our economy. Oligopolists who do not want to rock a very profitable boat may seek to find some indirect way of communicating with

DUBAI, United Arab Emirates—Damping expectations that it will pump more crude to ease high prices, the Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries said uncertainties over world economic growth were clouding the outlook for oil demand. The 12-member group, which pumps about 40% of the world’s oil, said in its monthly market report that a “more bearish economic trend,” partly triggered by the U.S. problems with subprime lending, may hurt demand growth in the second half. At this time, though, OPEC expects demand for its crude to rise to 31.14 million barrels a day in the third quarter, and to 31.32 million barrels a day in the fourth quarter, from 30.30 million barrels a day in the second quarter. OPEC expects daily demand for its crude to average under 30.8 million barrels next year, 239,000 barrels a day lower than the 31 million barrels a day forecast for this year. OPEC also said crude inventories are comfortable in the U.S. and for industrialized nations. . . . The International Energy Agency, which monitors oil markets on behalf of industrialized nations, has warned of rising prices if economic growth and oil demand continue to rise and if OPEC doesn’t raise crude production.

SOURCE: © Bettmann/CORBIS

OPEC Says Market Woes Cloud Output View

SOURCE: Excerpted from Oliver Klaus and Ayesha Daya, “OPEC Says Market Woes Cloud Output View,” The Wall Street Journal, August 15, 2007, p. A4. Reprinted by permission of The Wall Street Journal. Copyright © 2007 Dow Jones & Company, Inc. All Rights Reserved Worldwide.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

245

Between Competition and Monopoly

Chapter 12

P OLICY D E B AT E Antitrust laws unequivocally prohibit price fixing—collusion among competitors in which they agree on their pricing policies (see Chapter 13). Suppose that the firms in an industry, recognizing their interdependence, simply decide to go along with each other’s decisions? Is this collusion by long distance? Should it be declared illegal? Should the government require such a firm to “make believe” that it does not know how competitors will respond to its price moves? Must firms act as if they were not interdependent? If such requirements make no sense, what should the government require of oligopolistic firms? The airline industry constantly illustrates this issue and its complexities. In 1992, American Airlines decided that the vast number of different airline fares and discounts hurt all airlines and that the industry needed a simplified fare structure. American offered a new, simplified pricing plan called “value pricing,” in the hope that other airlines would copy that structure widely. A few weeks later, Northwest Airlines introduced a special vacation travel deal that undercut American’s pricing. This led to a price war, and American had to withdraw its plan, losing considerable money in the process. In this case, American’s rivals did not go along with a price leader’s decision. In a more recent set of events, matters worked out differently. The airlines, which have lost money for years, have been seeking ways to cut costs by reducing wages, firing employees, and so on. As oil prices rose in early 2008, these cost-cutting efforts proved insufficient, and airlines began imposing new surcharges and fees on their customers. In May of 2008, American Airlines was the first major carrier to announce that it would charge passengers for the first checked bag. This

SOURCE: © Peter Christopher/Masterfile

Acting on Recognized Interdependence versus “Tacit Collusion”

move was risky—if other airlines did not adopt similar surcharges, American could lose much of its business to competitors. But even before American’s surcharge became effective, two other major airlines followed suit by announcing that they would adopt the same $15 fee for the first checked bag. By the end of 2008, seven major airlines in the United States had enacted similar fees. As of this writing, two of these airlines, Delta and AirTran, have been sued for this parallel conduct. That complaint alleges that Delta and AirTran colluded by explicitly coordinating the introduction of their new luggage fees. Presumably there is no evidence that the other airlines consulted one another before adopting identical surcharges.

one another, signaling their intentions and managing the market accordingly. Each tacitly colluding firm hopes that if it does not make things too difficult for its competitors, its rivals will return the favor. For example, three major makers of infant formula—Abbott Laboratories, Bristol-Myers Squibb, and American Home Products—were accused of conspiring against competitors by keeping their wholesale prices only a few cents apart. The formula makers denied any wrongdoing. (See “Acting on Recognized Interdependence versus ‘Tacit Collusion’” above for another example.) One common form of tacit collusion is price leadership, an arrangement in which one firm in the industry, in effect, makes pricing decisions for the entire group. Other firms are expected to adopt the prices set by the price leader, even though no explicit agreement exists—only tacit consent. Often, the price leader will be the largest firm in the industry. But in some price-leadership arrangements, the leadership role may rotate from one firm to another. For example, analysts suggested that for many years the steel industry conformed to the price-leadership model, with U.S. Steel and Bethlehem Steel assuming the leadership role at different times. Price leadership does overcome some problems for the firms that result from oligopolistic interdependence, although it does not provide the only possible way of doing so. If Brand X, Inc. acts as price leader for the soapsuds industry, it can predict how Brand Y, Inc. will react to any price increases that it announces: Brand Y will match the increases. Similarly, Brand Z, Inc. executives will be able to predict Brand Y’s behavior as long as the price-leadership arrangement holds up. One problem besetting price leadership is that, although the oligopolists as an industry may benefit by avoiding a damaging price war, the firms may not benefit equally. The

Under price leadership, one firm sets the price for the industry and the others follow. In a price war, each competing firm is determined to sell at a price that is lower than the prices of its rivals, often regardless of whether that price covers the pertinent cost. Typically, in such a price war, Firm A cuts its price below Firm B’s price; B retaliates by undercutting A; and so on and on until some of the competitor firms surrender and let themselves be undersold.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

246

Part 3

Markets and the Price System

price-leading firm may be able to enhance its own profits more easily than any of the other firms in the group can. But if the price leader does not consider its rivals’ welfare as it makes price decisions, it may find itself dethroned! Like cartels, such arrangements can easily break down.

Sales Maximization: An Oligopoly Model with Interdependence Ignored A firm’s objective is said to be sales maximization if it seeks to adopt prices and output quantities that make its total revenue (the money value of its sales), rather than its profits, as large as possible.

Early in our analysis of the firm we discussed the profit-maximization hypothesis, and we noted that firms have other possible objectives. Among these alternative goals, one has attracted much attention: sales maximization. Modern industrial firms are managed by people who are not the owners of the companies. Paid executives manage the firms, working for the company on a full-time basis. These managers may begin to believe that whatever is good for them as individuals must be good for the company. The owners may be a large and diverse group of stockholders, most of whom own only a tiny fraction of the outstanding stock. They may take little interest in the company’s day-to-day operations and may feel no real sense of ownership. In such a situation, managers’ goals may influence company decisions more strongly than the owners’ goal of profit maximization. Some statistical evidence, for example, suggests that management’s compensation often relates more directly to company size, as measured by sales volume, than to profit. The president of a large firm generally fetches a much higher salary—and bigger incentive rewards— than the president of a tiny company. Therefore, firm managers may select price—output combinations that maximize sales rather than profits. But does sales maximization lead to different outcomes than profit maximization? We shall see shortly that the answer is yes. The graph in Figure 3 should be familiar by now. It shows the marginal cost (MC) and average cost (AC) curves for a soapsuds firm—in this case Brand X, Inc.—along with its demand and marginal revenue (MR) curves. We have used such diagrams before and thus know that if the company wants to maximize profits, it will select point A, where MC 5 MR. Brand X will produce 2.5 million boxes of soapsuds per year and sell them at $1 each (point E on the demand curve above A). Because average cost at this level of output is only 80 cents per box, X earns 20 cents economic profit per unit. Total profits are therefore $0.20 3 2,500,000 5 $500,000 per year. This is the highest attainable profit level for Brand X. What if Brand X chooses to maximize total sales revenue instead? In this case, it will want to keep producing until MR falls to zero; that is, it will select point B. Why? By definition, MR is the additional revenue obtained by raising output by one unit. If the firm wishes to maximize total revenue, then whenever MR is positive, it will want to increase output further, and anytime that MR becomes negative, X’s management will want to decrease output. Only when MR = 0 can management possibly have maximized total sales revenue.4 Thus, if Brand X is a sales maximizer, it will produce 3.75 million boxes of soapsuds per year (point B), and charge 75 cents per box (point F). Because average costs at this level of production are only 69 cents per box, profit per unit is 6 cents and, with 3.75 million units sold, total profit is $225,000. Naturally, this profit is substantially less than the $500,000 profit the firm can achieve if it reduces output to the profit-maximizing level. But that is not the goal of Brand X’s management. The firm’s sales revenue at point B is 75 cents per unit times 3.75 million units, or $2,812,500, whereas at point A it was only $2,500,000 (2.5 million units at $1.00 each). We conclude that If a firm is maximizing sales revenue, it will produce more output and charge a lower price than it would if it were maximizing profits.

The logic here is exactly the same as the logic that led to the conclusion that a firm maximized profits by setting marginal profit equal to zero. If you need to review, consult Chapter 8, especially pages 163–165. 4

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

247

Between Competition and Monopoly

Chapter 12

FI GURE 3 MC

AC

E

$1.00 Price per Box

Sales-Maximization Equilibrium

.80 .75 .69

F

A

D

2.5

B 3.75

MR Millions of Boxes per Year

Figure 3 clearly shows that this result holds for Brand X, but does it always hold? The answer is yes. Look again at Figure 3, but ignore the numbers on the axes. At point A, where MR = MC, marginal revenue must be positive because it equals marginal cost (which, we may assume, is always positive—output can normally not be increased at zero additional cost). At point B, MR is equal to zero. Because the marginal revenue curve slopes negatively, the point where it reaches zero (point B) must necessarily correspond to a higher output level than does the point where it cuts the marginal cost curve (point A). Thus, sales-maximizing firms always produce more than profit-maximizing firms and, to sell this greater volume of output, they must charge lower prices.5

3RD PUZZLE RESOLVED:

THE KINKED DEMAND CURVE MODEL

6

Another oligopoly analysis model was designed to explain the alleged “stickiness” in oligopolistic pricing, meaning that prices in oligopolistic markets change far less frequently than do competitive market prices—one of the puzzling phenomena with which we began this chapter. The prices of corn, soybeans, pork bellies, and silver—all commodities that trade in markets with large numbers of buyers and sellers—change second by second. But

EXERCISE: In the graph, how much below maximum profit is total profit under sales maximization? Variants of this model were constructed by Hall and Hitch in England and by Sweezy in the United States. See R. L. Hall and C. J. Hitch, “Price Theory and Business Behavior,” Oxford Economic Papers 2 (May 1939), pp. 12–45; and P. M. Sweezy, “Demand under Conditions of Oligopoly,” Journal of Political Economy 47 (August 1939), pp. 568–573. 5 6

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

248

Part 3

Markets and the Price System

products supplied by oligopolists, such as cars, televisions, and refrigerators, usually change prices only every few months or even more rarely. These products seem to resist frequent price changes, even in inflationary periods. One reason for such “sticky” prices may be that when an oligopolist cuts its product’s price, it can never predict how rival companies will react. One extreme possibility is that Firm Y will ignore Firm X’s price cut; that is, Firm Y’s price will not change. Alternatively, Firm Y may reduce its price, precisely matching that of Firm X. Accordingly, the model of oligopolistic behavior we discuss next uses two different demand curves. One curve represents the quantities a given oligopolistic firm can sell at different prices if competitors match its price moves, and the other demand curve represents what will happen if competitors stubbornly stick to their initial price levels. Point A in Figure 4 represents our firm’s initial price and output: 1,000 units at $8 each. Two demand curves, DD and dd, pass through point A. DD represents our company’s demand if competitors keep their prices fixed, and dd indicates what happens when competitors match our firm’s price changes. Of the two, the DD curve is the more elastic (flatter with demand, more responsive to price changes), and a moment’s thought indicates why this should be so. If our firm cuts its price from its initial level of $8 to, say, $7, and if competitors do not match this cut, we would expect our firm to get a large number of new customers—perhaps its quantity demanded will jump to 1,400 units. However, if its competitors respond by also reducing their prices, its quantity demanded will rise by less—perhaps only to 1,100 units (more inelastic demand curve dd). Similarly, when it raises its price, our firm may expect a larger customer flight to its rivals if those rivals fail to match its price increase, and this is indicated by the relative flatness (elasticity) of the curve DD in Figure 4, as compared to dd, the firm’s demand curve when rivals do match our firm’s price changes. How does this relate to sticky oligopolistic prices? The economists who designed this model hypothesized that a typical oligopolistic firm has good reason to fear the worst. If Firm X lowers its prices its rivals will be forced to do the same, because otherwise X’s price cut will steal away many of its competitors’ customers. The inelastic demand curve, dd (that applies when competitors copy X’s price cut), will therefore be the relevant curve if Firm X decides on a price reduction (points below and to the right of point A). If, on the contrary, Firm X chooses to increase its price, management fears that its rivals will respond quite differently than they would to a price cut. The price-raising

F I GURE 4 The Kinked Demand Curve

Price

d

D $8 7

A D (Competitors’ prices are fixed)

(Competitors d respond to price changes)

0

1,000

1,100

1,400

Quantity per Year

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

249

Between Competition and Monopoly

Chapter 12

Firm X will fear that its rivals will continue to sit at their old price levels, calmly collecting customers as they flee from X’s higher prices. Thus, this time, for price increases, the relevant demand curve (above A) will be DD, not dd. In sum, our firm will figure that it will face a segment of the elastic demand curve DD if it raises its price and a segment of the inelastic demand curve dd if it decreases its price. Its true demand curve will then be given by the heavy brick-colored line, DAd. For obvious reasons, it is called a kinked demand curve. The kinked demand curve represents a “heads you lose, tails you lose” proposition in terms of any potential price changes. If a firm raises its price, it will lose many customers (because in that case rivals will [may] not follow, so X’s demand is elastic); if it lowers its price, the sales increase will be comparatively small (because then rivals can be expected to have to match the cut, so X’s demand is inelastic). In these circumstances, neither a price cut nor a price rise seems beneficial, and management will vary its price only under extreme provocation—that is, only if its costs change enormously. Figure 5 illustrates this conclusion graphically. The two demand curves, DD and dd, are carried over precisely from Figure 4. The dashed line labeled MR is the marginal revenue curve associated with DD, whereas the solid line labeled mr is the marginal revenue curve associated with dd. The marginal revenue curve relevant to the firm’s decision making is MR for any output level below 1,000 units, but mr for any output level above 1,000 units. Therefore, the composite marginal revenue curve facing the firm is shown by the gold-highlighted line DBCmr with two slopes. The marginal cost curve drawn in the diagram cuts this composite marginal revenue curve at point E, which indicates the profit-maximizing combination of output and price for this oligopolist. Specifically, the quantity supplied at point E is 1,000 units, and the price is $8, which we read from the brick-colored demand curve DAd. The unique aspect of this diagram is that the kinked demand curve leads to a marginal revenue curve that takes a sharp plunge between points B and C. Consequently, even if the MC curve shifts moderately upward or downward, it will still intersect the marginal revenue curve somewhere between B and C and thus will not lead the firm to change its output decision. Therefore, the firm’s price will remain unchanged. (Try this for yourself in Figure 5.) Oligopoly prices are “sticky,” then, in the sense that they do not respond to minor cost changes. Only cost changes large enough to push the MC curve out of the BC range will lead to price changes.

A kinked demand curve is a demand curve that changes its slope abruptly at some level of output.

A price is called sticky if it does not change often, even when there is a moderate change in cost.

FI GURE 5 d

The Kinked Demand Curve and Sticky Prices

MC

Price

D A $8 B

D

E MR

d

C 1,000

mr Quantity Supplied per Year

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

250

Part 3

Markets and the Price System

If this is, in fact, the way oligopolists view their competitors’ behavior, we can easily see why they may be reluctant to make frequent price changes. We can also understand why price leadership may arise. The price-leader firm can raise prices at will, confident that the firm will not be left out on a limb (a kink?) by other firms’ unwillingness to follow.

The Game Theory Approach In 1944, the mathematician John von Neumann (1903–1957) and the economist Oskar Morgenstern (1902–1977) contributed a new approach to oligopoly analysis called game theory. Game theory is now economists’ most widely used analysis of oligopoly behavior. The theory deals with the issue of interdependence directly, taking for granted that the managers of business firms make decisions on the assumption that rival managers are also strategic decision makers. In this model, each oligopolist acts as a competing player in a strategic game. A payoff matrix shows Game theory uses two fundamental concepts: strategy and the payoff matrix. A strathow much each of two egy represents a participant’s operational plan. In its simplest form, it may refer to just competitors (players) can one possible decision, such as “Add to my product line a new car model that features a expect to earn, depending DVD player for backseat passengers,” or “Cut the price of my car to $19,500.” The payon the strategic choices off matrix will be explained presently. For simplicity’s sake, we will follow the frequent each of them makes. practice in discussions of game theory and focus on an oligopoly with just two firms—a duopoly. An example will help to explain the analysis. Imagine that the market for telecommunications on a low-income Caribbean island is about to be entered by two cell phone service providers. Say that patent restrictions and other impediments mean that the two companies each have a choice between only one of two cell phones: (1) an expensive, high-tech phone that would have to be sold at a price that gives the seller a low profit TAB LE 1 margin or (2) a cheaper, low-tech phone with a high profit margin. Furthermore, under Firm A’s Payoff Matrix this island government’s rules, each firm is required to offer the same phone and price for in a Game with a Domtwo years. Table 1 illustrates the resulting payoff matrix for one of the two inant Strategy players in this game, Firm A. Firm This matrix shows how the profits that Firm A can expect to earn B depend on the strategy that its sole rival, Firm B, adopts. The choice open Strategy to each firm is to select one of the two available strategies—either the Low-tech High-tech “low-tech, high-markup” cell phone or the “high-tech, low-markup” cell phone—without knowing the strategy that the other will choose. The $10m $–2m Low-tech matrix is read like a mileage chart. It shows, for example, that if Firm A Firm A chooses the high-tech option (second row of the matrix) and Firm B selects Strategy the low-tech option (left-hand column), then A will earn $12 million (lower left-hand square). It also shows the profit payoff to Firm A when it or its $12m $3m High-tech rival makes different choices between the two strategies that each firm has available.

Games with Dominant Strategies A dominant strategy for one of the competitors in a game is a strategy that will yield a higher payoff than any of the other strategies that are possible, no matter what choice of strategy is made by competitors.

How does game theory analyze Firm A’s optimal strategic choice? There are a number of related methods. The most direct way is to search for what is called a dominant strategy, though, as we will see, it is possible that no such strategy may be available to one or both of the firms. A dominant strategy is defined as one that gives the bigger payoff to the firm that selects it, no matter which of the two strategies the competitor happens to choose. As we just said, not all games have such a dominant strategy, but the one illustrated in Table 1 does. Let us see how we know this. Consider Firm A’s decision. Either company can select either the high-tech or the lowtech strategy. Whichever choice B makes, there are two possible profit outcomes for A

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 12

251

Between Competition and Monopoly

depending on which strategy it selects. For example, if B selects low-tech, A will either earn $10 million or $12 million, depending on its strategy choice (see the left-hand column of Table 1). So the high-tech strategy, with its $12 million payoff, is clearly A’s better decision if B selects low-tech. But what if B turns out to pick high-tech, instead? In that case, we see from the right-hand column of the matrix that if A offers the low-tech product, it will lose $2 million, whereas with that same choice by firm B, A could earn $3 million in profit by choosing high-tech (the lower right-hand entry). So high-tech is again the better choice for A. Clearly, the high-tech option is a dominant strategy for firm A, because it will give A a higher profit than the low-tech choice no matter which option firm B selects. Now let us expand the payoff matrix to show simultaneously the earnings of both firms—not, as before, only those of Firm A. In Table 2, this combined payoff matrix reports the profits that each firm can expect to Low-tech earn, given its own pricing choice and that of its rival. For example, the upper-left square indicates that if both firms decide to offer the low-tech, Firm A high-markup model, both A and B will earn $10 million. We also see that if Strategy one firm brings in the high-tech model, whereas the other does not, the High-tech high-tech supplier will actually raise its profit to $12 million (presumably by capturing more sales) and drive its rival to a $2 million loss. However, if both firms offer the high-tech model, each will be left with a modest $3 million profit. EXERCISE: Use the same reasoning as above to show that high-tech is also the dominant strategy for Firm B. Because both firms have a dominant strategy in this example, and it is the same for both, they can both be expected to select it. Each will therefore end up offering the hightech cell phone, and each will earn $3 million per year. This example has important implications for policy, because it shows just how competition can force business firms to behave in the way that most benefits consumers, even though it is not the most profitable for the firms. In this example, both firms would have profited most by offering the lower-quality, higher-markup equipment. If they had both chosen the low-tech strategy, they would each have earned $10 million, but at the consumers’ expense. However, the presence of a competitor, with its unknown choice, forces each firm to protect itself by choosing the dominant strategy, offering the better (hightech) product, even though they end up each earning only $3 million. Of course, if the market had been served by a profit-maximizing monopolist, the lone firm would have selected the more profitable low-tech option, and the public would have been denied the better-quality product.

TABLE 2 The Two-Firm Payoff Matrix in a Game with Dominant Strategies Firm B Strategy Low-tech

High-tech

A gets $10m A gets $–2m B gets $10m B gets $12m

A gets $12m A gets $3m B gets $–2m B gets $3m

The Moral of the Story: A market that is a duopoly, that is, a two-firm oligopoly, may serve the public interest better than a monopoly because of the competition between the two duopolists.

Notice that each firm’s fear of what its rival will do virtually forces it to offer the high-tech product and to forgo the higher ($10 million) profit that it could earn if it could trust the other to stick to a lower-quality product. This example illustrates why many observers conclude that, particularly where the number of firms is small, companies should not be permitted to confer or exchange information on prices or product quality. If the two rivals were allowed to collude and act like a monopolist, consumers would be damaged in two ways: They would have to pay more in order to provide the resulting additional profits and, besides, as usually is expected to happen under a monopoly, consumers would get smaller quantities of the products, which may be of lower quality. Games whose payoff matrices have dominant strategies like that in Table 2 have many other interesting applications. They illustrate how people can get trapped into making both themselves and their rivals worse off. For example, a matrix with the same pattern of payoffs applies to people driving polluting cars in the absence of laws requiring emission

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

252

Part 3

Markets and the Price System

controls. Each driver runs a polluting auto because she does not trust other drivers to install emission controls voluntarily. So if she alone goes to the expense of equipping her car with pollution controls, most of the pollution—that from all other cars—will remain in the air. She will have paid for the equipment but have gotten little or no cleaner air benefit. So they all end up with a low payoff (breathing polluted air), even though by getting together and all agreeing to do what is needed to cut emissions, they could all end up with a higher payoff in terms of better health, etc.7 Still another interpretation explains why the game in Table 2 is known as the prisoners’ dilemma. Instead of a two-firm industry, the prisoners’ dilemma involves two burglary suspects who are captured by the police and interrogated in separate rooms. Each suspect has two strategy options: to deny the charge or to confess. If both deny it, both go free, because the police have no other evidence. But if one confesses and the other does not, the silent prisoner can expect the key to his cell to be thrown away while the talker gets off with a light sentence. The dominant solution for each prisoner, then, is to confess and receive the light sentence that results from this choice. The prisoners’ dilemma story confirms the important economic point we made earlier. The reason the two prisoners are both driven to confess, and to bring themselves to justice, is that they are not allowed to communicate and so they do not trust one another. Otherwise, they would collude and promise each other not to confess. The same thing applies to a duopoly. The public interest requires that the duopolists be banned from colluding. If they were permitted to get together and agree on a high price and low-cost, low-quality products, they would earn monopoly profits and the public would suffer the consequences. The Moral of the Story: It is damaging to the public interest to permit rival firms to collude and to make joint decisions on what prices to charge for their similar products and what quality of product to supply.

The maximin criterion requires a player to select the strategy that yields the maximum payoff on the assumption that the opponent will do as much damage as it can.

Games without Dominant Strategies

We have already observed that games need not offer dominant strategies. An example is easy to provide. For simplicity, Table 3 again shows only the payoffs for Firm A, but this time the hypothetical payoff numbers are different from those in Table 1. With these new numbers, neither a low-tech nor a high-tech choice is a dominant strategy for A. Suppose A chooses to go with the low-tech product. Then, if B also happens to select low-tech, A will find itself better off (at a $10 million payoff) than if it had chosen a TAB LE 3 high-tech product (profit 5 $3 million). But if B goes the other way and offers the hightech product, A’s payoff will be worse ($7 million) with a low-tech prodFirm A’s Payoff Matrix in a Game without a uct than with one that is high-tech ($8 million payoff). Which of the two Dominant Strategy options is better for A depends on B’s unforeseeable strategy choice. NeiFirm ther choice by A offers it foolproof protection, so neither of A’s possible B strategies is dominant. Strategy The decision for A in Table 3 is now much harder than it was before. How Low-tech High-tech can it go about selecting a strategy? One solution proposed in game theory is called the maximin criterion. In this strategy, we may envision the man$10m $7m Low-tech agement of Firm A reasoning as follows: “If I choose a low-tech strategy, the worst that can happen to me is that my competitor will select the high-tech Firm A counterstrategy, which will make my return $7 million (the brick-colored Strategy number in the first row of the payoff matrix). Similarly, if I select a high-tech $3m $8m High-tech strategy, the worst possible outcome for me is a $3 million profit” (the brickcolored minimum payoff in the second row of the matrix). How can the

7

EXERCISE: Make up a payoff matrix that tells this story.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 12

253

Between Competition and Monopoly

managers of Firm A best protect their company from trouble in these circumstances? Game theory suggests that it may be rational to select a strategy based on comparison of the two minimum payoffs offered by the two different strategies. If the firm’s managers want to cut down the risk, they should pick what can be interpreted as an insurance-policy approach. They should select the strategy that will guarantee them the highest of these undesirable minimum payoffs. In other words, expecting the worst outcome for any strategy choice it makes, Firm A should pick the strategy that promises the best of those bad outcomes. In this case, the maximin strategy for Firm A is to offer the low-tech product, whose worst possible outcome is $7 million, whereas the worst outcome if it selects the high-tech product is a profit of only $3 million.

Other Strategies: The Nash Equilibrium We can interpret the maximin strategy as a pessimist’s way to deal with uncertainty. A player who adopts this strategy assumes that the worst will always happen: No matter what move she makes, her opponent will adopt the countermove that does her the most damage. The maximin strategy neglects the possibility that opponents will not have enough information to find out the most damaging countermove. It also ignores the possibility of finding common ground, as when two competitors collude to extract monopoly profit from consumers. Other strategies are less pessimistic, yet still rational. One of the most analytically useful strategies leads to what is called a Nash equilibrium. The mathematician John Nash devised this strategy, for which he won the Nobel Prize in economics in 1994 (after a long period of schizophrenia).8 The basic idea is simple. In a two-player game, suppose that each firm is trying to decide whether to adopt a blue or a red package for its product. Assume that each firm earns a higher profit if it selects a package color that differs from the other’s. Then, if Firm X happens to select a red package, it will obviously be most profitable for Y to select a blue package. Moreover, it will pay each firm to stick with that choice, because blue is Y’s most profitable response to X’s choice of red, and vice versa. In general, a Nash equilibrium describes a situation in which both players adopt moves such that each player’s move is the most profitable response to the other player’s move. Often, no such mutually accommodating solution is possible, but where it is possible, if both players realize this fact and act accordingly, they may both be able to benefit. For example, note how much worse off both firms would be in the preceding example if Firm Y were determined to damage Firm X, at whatever the cost to itself, and adopted a red package, just like X’s.

A Nash equilibrium results when each player adopts the strategy that gives the highest possible payoff if the rival sticks to the strategy it has chosen.

A zero-sum game is one in which exactly the amount one competitor gains must be lost by other competitors.

Zero-Sum Games

TABLE 4

There is a special but significant situation involving a simple form of payoff matrix that has even been taken up in popular parlance. It is called a zero-sum game. The idea is a simple one and is a useful way to think about many issues. A zero-sum game is one in which whatever one player gains, the other must lose. Thus, when one adds up all the gains and losses, the sum is always zero. If I pick your pocket and find $80 in cash, you are $80 poorer and I am $80 richer, so that the sum of the positive gains and negative losses is clearly zero. But if the money was in a wallet with your driver’s license and credit cards, and I take the money out and then throw the wallet into a river, it is evidently not zero-sum. You have lost not only the money but also the time and cost of replacing the license and credit cards, whereas I have gained only the money. The payoff matrix of a zero-sum game has a very simple structure. Table 4 provides an example:

Zero-Sum Payoff Matrix

8

Firm B Strategy Strategy 1

Strategy 2

Strategy 1 A gets $10m A gets $–2m B gets 0 B gets $12m Firm A Strategy Strategy 2

A gets $4m A gets $7m B gets $6m B gets $3m

As described in the 2001 movie A Beautiful Mind, which was based on the book by Sylvia Nasar.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

254

Part 3

Markets and the Price System

The special feature of this matrix is that the payoffs of the two firms add up to $10 million in each and every payoff square. For example, in the lower left-hand square of Table 4, Firm A’s payoff is $4 million and Firm B’s payoff is $6 million, for a total of $10 million. You can verify that the sum of the two payoffs is $10 million in each of the other three cells, as well. So if A gains by a strategy change, this must occur, to the penny, at B’s expense. If A gains $734, B must lose exactly $734. The following example will bring out the importance of understanding the zero-sum case as a way to avoid fallacious analysis. It was once thought that international trade was a zero-sum game, because it was believed that each trading nation’s objective was to get as much gold as possible from other countries in payment for their purchases. If Brazil ships coffee to France, and the French shippers pay 10,000 ounces of gold for the shipment, then on this view of the matter, Brazil has gained and France has lost exactly the same amount—making it a zero-sum transaction. But a little thought tells us that this view is naïve, because it leaves the coffee shipment itself out of the calculation. Trade is not just about money but also about the goods and services that are traded. If France is too cold to grow good coffee, and Brazil is too hot to produce good wine, and the populations of both countries prefer coffee in the morning and wine in the evening, then it is clear that both will be better off as the result of an exchange of wine for coffee. The game of international trade is far from zero-sum. This is something that must be kept in mind when we consider contentious trade-related issues such as globalization and outsourcing, which will be discussed in Chapter 34.

Repeated Games

A repeated game is one that is played a number of times.

The scenarios described so far involve one-time transactions, as when a tourist passes through a city and makes a purchase at a store that he will never visit again. Most business transactions are different. A firm usually sells its products day after day, often to repeat buyers. It must continuously review its pricing decisions, knowing that its rivals are likely to gain information from any repeated behavioral patterns and adapt their response. The important concept of repeated games also offers significant additional insights about the competitive process under oligopoly. Repeated games give all of the players the opportunity to learn something about each other’s behavior patterns and, perhaps, to arrive at mutually beneficial arrangements. By adopting a fairly clear pricing behavior pattern, each firm can attain a reputation that elicits desired responses from competitors. We return to the example of the product introduction war between Firm A and Firm B to show how this approach works. When we studied the payoff matrix for that game, we assumed that in a single play in which neither player knew anything about the other’s behavior pattern, each player was likely to feel forced to adopt its dominant strategy. In other words, each firm offered the low-profit, high-tech product for fear that if it adopted the potentially more profitable low-tech product, its rival would adopt a high-tech product and take customers away. In that way, both firms would end up with low profits. When games are repeated, the players may be able to escape such a trap. For example, Firm A can cultivate a reputation for selecting a strategy called “tit for tat.” Each time Firm B chooses a high-tech product, Firm A responds by also introducing a high-tech product next time, with its limited profit. Firm A also follows a similar repeating strategy if B’s product choice is low-tech. After a few repetitions, B will learn that A always matches its decisions. B will then see that it is better off sticking to a more profitable low-tech product. Firm A, too, benefits from its tit-for-tat approach, which will lead both, eventually, to stick permanently to the more profitable low-tech products. In practice, this amounts to tacit collusion. The two competing firms never actually get together to reach a joint decision on product price and quality, behavior that is illegal. But

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

255

Between Competition and Monopoly

Chapter 12

they watch one another’s behavior in their repeated game, and each eventually learns to adapt itself and go along with the other’s behavior—which may be anticompetitive and damaging to consumer interests but offers monopoly profits to the tacit colluders. The courts do not have a clear response to this behavior, because it is difficult to argue that firms should not consider all publicly and legitimately available information about its rivals, or that firms should not take this observed rival behavior into consideration when they make their own decisions.

Threats and Credibility A player can also use threats to induce rivals to change their behavior. The trouble is that, if carried out, the threat may well damage both parties. For example, a retailer can threaten to double its output and drive prices down near zero if a rival imitates its product. However, the rival is unlikely to believe the threat, because such a low price harms the threatener as much as the threatened. Such a threat is simply not credible, with one exception. The possibility can become a credible threat if the threatener takes steps that commit it to carry out the action. For example, if Firm A signed an irrevocable contract committing it to double its output if Firm B copied A’s product, then the threat would become credible, and B would be forced to believe it. But A can make other commitments that make its threat credible. For example, it can build a large plant with plenty of excess capacity. The factory may be very expensive to build, but once built, that cost is irrevocable. If there is only a small additional cost of raw material and labor needed to turn out the product, once the cost of the plant has already been paid, then it may not harm A to expand its output of the product, even at a competitor’s very low price (if that price exceeds the marginal [variable] cost of the item). So, having built the large factory, the threat to expand output in response to entry becomes credible. This last possibility leads directly to an important application of game theory: how firms inside an industry (“the old firms”) can decide strategically on ways to prevent new firms from entering into the industry. To create a credible threat to potential entrants, we see that the old firm may well consider building a bigger factory than it would otherwise want. Some hypothetical numbers and a typical game theory graph will make the story clear. The old firm faces two options: to build a small factory or a big one. Potential entrant firms also face two options: open for business (that is, enter the industry) or do not enter. Figure 6 shows the four resulting possible decision combinations and the corresponding profits or losses that the two firms may expect in each case.

A credible threat is a threat that does not harm the threatener if it is carried out.

FIGURE 6 Entry and Entry-Blocking Strategy Possible Choices of Old Firm

Possible Reactions of New Firm r

Ente

Don’t

ory

act ig F

Enter

B

Sma

ll Fa

ctor

y

Ente Don

r

Profits (millions $) Old Firm New Firm –2

–2

4

0

2

2

6

0

’t En

ter

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

256

Part 3

Markets and the Price System

The graph shows that the best outcome for the old firm occurs when it builds a small factory and the new firm decides not to enter. In that case, the old firm will earn $6 million, whereas the new firm will earn nothing, because it never starts up. However, if the old firm does decide to build a small factory, it can be fairly sure that the new firm will open up for business, because the new firm can then earn $2 million (rather than zero), as shown by the dashed lines. In the process, the old firm’s profit will be reduced, also to $2 million. If the old firm builds a big factory, its increased output will depress prices and profits. The old firm will now earn only $4 million if the new firm stays out, as shown by the asterisk line, whereas each firm will lose $2 million if the new firm enters. Obviously, if the old firm builds a big factory, the new firm will be better off staying out of the business rather than subjecting itself to a $2 million loss. What size factory, then, should the old firm build? When we consider the firms’ interactions, to protect itself the old firm must clearly build the large factory with its excess capacity—because this decision will keep the new firm out of the industry, leaving the old firm with a $4 million profit. The moral of the story: “Wasting” money on excess capacity may not be wasteful to the oligopolist firm if it protects the firm’s long-term interest. Of course, game theory is a much richer topic than we have explained here. For example, game theory also provides tools for economists and business managers to analyze coalitions that include groups of firms. It indicates, for cases involving more than two firms, which firms would do well to align themselves together against others. People other than economists also have used game theory to analyze a variety of complicated problems outside the realm of oligopoly theory. Management training programs employ its principles, as do a number of government agencies (see “Application: Game Theory and FCC Auctions” below). Political scientists and military strategists use game theory to formulate and analyze strategy.

Since 1994, the Federal Communications Commission (FCC) has conducted competitive bidding auctions of licenses to parts of the electromagnetic spectrum used for such communications services as cell phones and pagers. The FCC used game theory when it designed the online auctions of these so-called rights to the airways, and the bidding companies must figure out for themselves how much to offer for the right to service a particular region. The FCC might simply have decided to price the licenses for the various available regions itself. By conducting auctions, it places the decision-making onus on the bidding companies and their hired game-theorist consultants. The FCC prohibits collusion by the bidders, so each one must decide which sectors it can serve most efficiently, and each must anticipate its competitors’ most likely moves and countermoves. The FCC runs these national online auctions continuously. For example, one recent auction offered licenses in the Automated Maritime Telecommunications System (AMTS) spectrum. AMTS is a specialized system of coast stations that provide integrated and interconnected marine voice and data communications, somewhat like a cellular phone system, for tugs, barges, and other vessels on the waterways. The auction raised a total of $1,057,365 from four winning bidders for 10 licenses.

SOURCE: © Paul A. Souders/CORBIS

Application: Game Theory and FCC Auctions

SOURCE: U.S. Federal Communications Commission, http://www.fcc.gov.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 12

257

Between Competition and Monopoly

MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION, OLIGOPOLY, AND PUBLIC WELFARE How well or poorly do monopolistically competitive or oligopolistic firms perform, from the viewpoint of the general welfare? We have seen that their performance can leave much to be desired. For example, the excess capacity theorem showed us that monopolistic competition can lead to inefficiently high production costs. Similarly, because market forces may not sufficiently restrain their behavior, oligopolists’ prices and outputs may differ substantially from socially optimal levels. In particular, when oligopolists organize themselves into a successful cartel, prices will be higher and outputs lower than those associated with their perfectly competitive counterparts. Moreover, some people believe that misleading advertising by corporate giants often distorts consumers’ judgments, leading them to buy things they do not need and would otherwise not want. Many social critics feel that such corporate giants wield political power, economic power, and power over the minds of consumers—power that undermines the benefits of Adam Smith’s invisible hand. Because oligopoly behavior varies so widely, the social welfare implications differ from case to case. Some recent economic analysis, however, provides one theoretical case in which oligopolistic behavior and performance quality can be predicted and judged unambiguously.9 The analysis also can serve as a model for government agencies that are charged with the task of preventing harmful anticompetitive behavior by oligopolistic firms. In this theoretical case, called a perfectly contestable market, entry into or exit from the market is costless and unimpeded. Here, the constant threat of the possible entry by new firms forces even the largest existing firm to behave well—to produce efficiently and never overcharge. Otherwise, the firm will be threatened with replacement by an entrant that offers to serve customers more cheaply and efficiently. We define a market as perfectly contestable if firms can enter it and, if they choose, exit it without losing the money they invested. The crucial issue here is not the amount of capital required to enter the industry, but whether an entrant can withdraw the investment if it wishes. For example, if market entry requires investing in highly mobile capital (such as airplanes, trucks, or river barges, which can be moved around easily), the entrant may be able to exit quickly and cheaply.10 For instance, if a barge operation decides to serve the lower Mississippi River but finds business disappointing, it can easily transfer its boats to, say, the Ohio River. A profitable market that is also contestable therefore attracts potential entrants. Because no barriers to entry or exit exist, firms incur little risk by going into such a market. If their entry turns out to have been a mistake, they can move to another market without loss. Because perfect competition requires a large number of firms, all of them small relative to the size of the industry, no industry with economies of large-scale production can be perfectly competitive. However, markets that contain a few relatively large firms may be highly contestable, although they are certainly not perfectly competitive. But no realworld industry is perfectly contestable, just as no industry is perfectly competitive. The constant threat of entry forces oligopolists to perform well. Even monopolists must perform well if they do business in a highly contestable market. In particular, perfectly contestable markets have at least two socially desirable characteristics. First, the freedom of entry eliminates any excess economic profits, so in this respect contestable markets

A market is perfectly contestable if entry and exit are costless and unimpeded.

9 See William J. Baumol, John C. Panzar, and Robert D. Willig, Contestable Markets and the Theory of Industry Structure, rev. ed. (San Diego: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich, 1988). 10 Earlier it was thought that air transportation could be classified as a highly contestable industry, but recent evidence suggests that although this judgment may be correct, the story is more complicated than it may initially seem.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

258

Part 3

Markets and the Price System

resemble perfectly competitive markets. For example, if the current opportunity cost of capital is 12 percent, whereas the firms in a contestable market are earning a return of 18 percent, then new firms will enter the market, expand the industry’s outputs, and drive down the prices of its products to the point at which no firm earns any excess profit. To avoid this outcome, established firms must expand output to a level that precludes excess profit. Second, inefficient enterprises cannot survive in a perfectly contestable industry because cost inefficiencies invite replacement of the existing firms by entrants that can provide the same outputs at lower cost and lower prices. Only firms operating at the lowest possible cost can survive. In sum, firms in a perfectly contestable market will be forced to operate as efficiently as possible and to charge prices as low as long-run financial survival permits. The theory of contestable markets has been widely used by courts and government agencies concerned with the performance of business firms and provides workable guidelines for improved or acceptable behavior in industries in which economies of scale mean that only a small number of firms can or should operate.

A GLANCE BACKWARD: COMPARING THE FOUR MARKET FORMS We have now completed the set of chapters that has taken us through the four main market forms: perfect competition, monopoly, monopolistic competition, and oligopoly. We hope you have absorbed a lot of information about the workings of these market forms as you read through Chapters 10 through 12, but the large quantity of detail is likely to be confusing. Table 5 presents an overview of the main attributes of each of the market forms to facilitate comparison. It shows that • Perfect competition and pure monopoly are concepts useful primarily for analytical purposes—we find neither very often in reality. There are many monopolistically competitive firms, and oligopolistic firms account for the largest share of the economy’s output. • Profits are zero in long-run equilibrium under perfect competition and monopolistic competition because entry is so easy that high profits attract new rivals into the market.

TABLE 5 Attributes of the Four Market Forms

Number of Firms in the Market

Frequency in Reality

Perfect competition

Very many

Rare (if any)

Pure monopoly Monopolistic competition

One

Rare

Many

Widespread Produces large share of GDP

Market Form

Oligopoly

Few

Entry Barriers

Public Interest Results

Long-Run Profit

None Likely to be high

Good Outputs not optimal

Zero May be high

Minor

Inefficient

Zero

Varies

Varies

Varies

Equilibrium Conditions MC 5 MR 5 AC 5 AR 5 P MR 5 MC MR 5 MC AR 5 AC

Varies

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 12

Between Competition and Monopoly

259

• Consequently, AC 5 AR in long-run equilibrium under these two market forms. In equilibrium, MC 5 MR for the profit-maximizing firm under any market form. However, under oligopoly, firms may adopt the strategies described by game theory or they may pursue goals other than profits; for example, they may seek to maximize sales. Therefore, in the equilibrium of the oligopoly firm, MC may be unequal to MR. • As we will confirm in Chapter 14, the behavior of the perfectly competitive firm and industry theoretically leads to an efficient allocation of resources that maximizes the benefits to consumers, given the resources available to the economy. Monopoly, however, can misallocate resources by restricting output in an attempt to raise prices and profits. Under monopolistic competition, excess capacity and inefficiency are apt to result. And under oligopoly, almost anything can happen, so it is impossible to generalize about its vices or virtues. As will be discussed in Chapter 16, some analysts believe oligopolists have made a significant contribution to the economic growth of the past two centuries that has brought a spectacular increase in average incomes in the world’s wealthier countries.

| SUMMARY | 1. Under monopolistic competition, there are numerous small buyers and sellers; each firm’s product is at least somewhat different from every other firm’s product— that is, each firm has a partial “monopoly” over some product characteristics, and thus a downward-sloping demand curve; there is freedom of entry and exit; and all relevant information is known to the sellers and buyers. 2. In long-run equilibrium under monopolistic competition, free entry eliminates economic profits by forcing the firm’s downward-sloping demand curve into a position of tangency with its average cost curve. Therefore, output will be below the point at which average cost is lowest. As a result, monopolistic competitors are said to have excess capacity. 3. An oligopolistic industry is composed of a few large firms selling similar products in the same market. 4. Under oligopoly, each firm carefully watches the major decisions of its rivals and often plans counterstrategies. As a result, rivalry is often vigorous and direct, and the outcome is difficult to predict. 5. One model of oligopoly behavior assumes that oligopolists ignore interdependence and simply maximize profits or sales. Another model assumes that they join together to form a cartel and thus act like a monopoly. A third possibility is price leadership, where one firm sets prices and the others follow suit. 6. A firm that maximizes sales will continue producing up to the point where marginal revenue is driven down to zero. Consequently, a sales maximizer will produce more than a profit maximizer and will charge a lower price. 7. If a firm thinks that its rivals will match any price cut but fail to match any price increase, its demand curve becomes “kinked” and its price will be sticky—in other words, price will be adjusted less frequently

than would be true under either perfect competition or pure monopoly. 8. Game theory provides new tools for the analysis of business strategies under conditions of oligopoly. 9. A payoff matrix shows how much each of two competitors (players) can expect to earn, depending on the strategic choices each of them makes. It is used to analyze the reasoning that applies and the possible outcomes when the payoff to any oligopolist depends on what the other oligopolists in the market will do, so that they are all interdependent. 10. A dominant strategy for one of the competitors in a game is a strategy that will yield a higher payoff than any of the other strategies that are possible, no matter what choice of strategy is made by competitors. So selection of a dominant strategy, where it is possible, is a good way for a competitor to avoid risk. 11. In a maximin strategy, the player takes the strongest possible precautions against the worst possible outcome of any move it selects. 12. In a Nash equilibrium, each player adopts the move that yields the highest possible payoff to itself, given the move selected by the other player. 13. A zero-sum game is one in which exactly the amount one competitor gains must be lost by other competitors. The zero-sum game is a useful analytic concept, although rare in the real world. 14. In repeated games, a firm can seek to acquire a reputation that induces the other player to make decisions that do not damage its interests. It may also promote its goals by means of credible threats. 15. Monopolistic competition and oligopoly can be harmful to the general welfare, but because behavior varies widely, the implications for social welfare also vary from case to case.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

260

Part 3

Markets and the Price System

| KEY TERMS | cartel

243

Nash equilibrium

253

repeated game

credible threat 255

oligopoly

dominant strategy 250

payoff matrix

kinked demand curve

perfectly contestable market

maximin criterion

249

252

monopolistic competition

241

237

price war

sales maximization

250

price leadership

254

sticky price 257

246

249

zero-sum game

253

245

245

| TEST YOURSELF | 1. Using game theory, set up a payoff matrix similar to one that Volkswagen’s management might employ in analyzing the problem presented in Discussion Question 5.

3. In the payoff matrix in Table 2, which is Firm B’s dominant strategy? Show the calculation that leads to that conclusion.

2. Test Yourself Question 4 at the end of Chapter 11 presented cost and demand data for a monopolist and asked you to find the profit-maximizing solution. Use these same data to find the sales-maximizing solution. In terms of the firm’s MR, explain why the answers are different.

4. You are given a payoff matrix for a zero-sum game. You see that for one pair of strategy choices by the two firms, A’s payoff is 9 and B’s payoff is 6. For a second set of strategy choices, A’s payoff is 7. What is B’s payoff?

| DISCUSSION QUESTIONS | 1. How many real industries can you name that are oligopolies? How many operate under monopolistic competition? Perfect competition? Which of these is most difficult to find in reality? Why do you think this is so? 2. Consider some of the products that are widely advertised on television. By what kind of firm is each produced—a perfectly competitive firm, an oligopolistic firm, or another type of firm? How many major products can you think of that are not advertised on TV? 3. In what ways may the small retail sellers of the following products differentiate their goods from those of their rivals to make themselves monopolistic competitors: hamburgers, radios, cosmetics? 4. Pricing of securities on the stock market is said to be carried out under conditions in many respects similar to perfect competition. The auto industry is an oligopoly. How often do you think the price of a share of Ford Motor Company’s common stock changes? How about the price of a Ford Explorer? How would you explain the difference?

5. Suppose that Volkswagen hires a popular singer to advertise its compact automobiles. The campaign is very successful, and the company increases its share of the compact-car market substantially. What is Ford likely to do? 6. A new entrant, Bargain Airways, cuts air fares between Eastwich and Westwich by 20 percent. Biggie Airlines, which has been operating on this route, responds by cutting fares by 35 percent. What does Biggie hope to achieve? 7. If air transportation were perfectly contestable, why would Biggie Airlines (see Discussion Question 6) fail to achieve the ultimate goal of its price cut? 8. Which of the following industries are most likely to be contestable? a. Aluminum production b. Barge transportation c. Automobile manufacturing Explain your answers.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 12

9. Since the deregulation of air transportation, a community served by a single airline is no longer protected by a regulatory agency from monopoly pricing. What market forces, if any, restrict the ability of the airline to raise prices as a pure monopolist would? How effective do you think those market forces are in keeping airfares down?

Between Competition and Monopoly

261

10. Explain, for a repeated game: a. Why it may be advantageous to have the reputation of being a tough guy who always takes revenge against anyone who harms your interests b. Why it may be advantageous to have a reputation of irrationality

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Limiting Market Power: Regulation and Antitrust . . . the one law you can’t repeal is supply and demand. W I L L I AM SAFI RE, T HE NEW YO R K T IMES, JULY 13, 1998

T

o protect the interests of the public when industries are, or threaten to become, monopolistic or oligopolistic, government in the United States uses two basic tools. Antitrust policy seeks to prevent acquisition of monopoly power and to ban certain monopolistic practices. All business firms are subject to the antitrust laws. In addition, some industries are regulated by rules that constrain firms’ pricing and other decisions. Generally, only firms suspected of having the power to act like monopolists are regulated in this way.

C O N T E N T S THE PUBLIC INTEREST ISSUE: MONOPOLY POWER VERSUS MERE SIZE

USE OF ANTITRUST LAWS TO PREVENT COMPETITION

PART 1: ANTITRUST LAWS AND POLICIES

PART 2: REGULATION

MEASURING MARKET POWER: CONCENTRATION

WHAT IS REGULATION?

Concentration: Definition and Measurement—The Herfindahl-Hirschman Index The Evidence of Concentration in Reality

A CRUCIAL PROBLEM FOR ANTITRUST: THE RESEMBLANCE OF MONOPOLIZATION AND VIGOROUS COMPETITION ANTICOMPETITIVE PRACTICES AND ANTITRUST Predatory Pricing The Microsoft Case: Bottlenecks, Bundling, and Network Externalities

PUZZLE: WHY DO REGULATORS OFTEN RAISE

PRICES?

SOME OBJECTIVES OF REGULATION Control of Market Power Resulting from Economies of Scale and Scope Universal Service and Rate Averaging

THE PROS AND CONS OF “BIGNESS” Economies of Large Size Required Scale for Innovation

DEREGULATION The Effects of Deregulation

PUZZLE REVISITED: WHY REGULATORS OFTEN

PUSH PRICES UPWARD

CONCLUDING OBSERVATIONS

TWO KEY ISSUES THAT FACE REGULATORS Setting Prices to Protect Consumers’ Interests and Allow Regulated Firms to Cover Their Costs Marginal versus Average Cost Pricing Preventing Monopoly Profit but Keeping Incentives for Efficiency and Innovation

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

264

Part 3

Markets and the Price System

THE PUBLIC INTEREST ISSUE: MONOPOLY POWER VERSUS MERE SIZE

Economies of scale are savings that are obtained through increases in quantities produced. Scale economies occur when an X percent increase in input use raises output by more than X percent, so that the more the firm produces, the lower its per unit costs become. Monopoly power (or market power) is the ability of a business firm to earn high profits by raising the prices of its products above competitive levels and to keep those prices high for a substantial amount of time.

In Chapters 11 and 12, we learned that when an industry is a monopoly or an oligopoly, the result may not be as desirable in terms of the public interest as it would be if the industry were perfectly competitive. Yet for many industries anything like perfect competition is an impossible goal, and perhaps even an undesirable one. This is true, notably, when the industry’s technology provides economies of scale, meaning, as you will remember, that the more of its product a firm supplies, the lower the cost of supplying a unit of that product. Scale economies therefore mean that in competition between a large firm and a small one, the big one can usually win. As a result, industries with scale economies usually end up having a small number of firms, each of which has a large share of the industry’s sales. In other words, such an industry is usually fated to be a monopoly or an oligopoly. But what is so bad about that? Sometimes it is not bad at all, because economies of scale, by definition, allow the larger firms to supply the public at lower cost, though of course they do not always do so. In other cases, the public interest will be threatened, because some or all of the firms in the industry will possess monopoly power. Monopoly power (or market power) is usually defined as the ability of a firm to earn high profits by raising and keeping the prices of its products substantially above the levels at which those products would be priced in competitive markets. That is, a firm with monopoly power can charge high prices and get away with it—the market will not punish it for doing so. In a competitive industry, in contrast, the market will punish a high-price firm by the loss of its customers to rivals with lower prices. Thus, monopoly power is undesirable for several reasons, some of them obvious: • High prices reduce the wealth of consumers. The use of monopoly power is obviously undesirable to consumers because no one likes to pay high prices for purchased commodities. Such high prices may make the firm with monopoly power rich and make the consumers of its products poor. These effects on the distribution of wealth are generally, for obvious reasons, considered undesirable. • High prices lead to resource misallocation. Economists give greater emphasis to a second undesirable effect of prices that exceed the competitive level. Such prices tend to reduce the quantities of the products that consumers demand. In this case, smaller quantities of labor, raw materials, and other inputs will be devoted to production of these high-priced products relative to the quantities that would best serve consumer interests. More of those inputs will therefore be transferred to the products of competitive industries. The result will be underproduction of the products priced at monopoly levels and overproduction of the products of competitive industries. So, as a result of the exercise of monopoly power, the economy does not produce the mix of outputs that best serves the public interest. • Monopoly power creates an obstacle to efficiency and innovation. A firm with monopoly power is a firm that does not face much effective competition—and consequently it does not have as much reason to fear loss of business to others. Where this is so, there is little incentive for management to make the effort to produce efficiently with a minimum of waste or to undertake the expense and risks of innovation. The result is that products may be of poorer quality than they would if the company possessed no monopoly power, and there will be waste in the production process. But, as we will see presently, some economists have suggested another side to this story. The efficiency problems inherent in monopoly power are among the main reasons for governmental intervention controlling business firms’ behavior and other attributes. The critical problem is control of monopoly power and prevention of acts by firms that are designed either to harm or destroy rivals, or to curb the use of that power to exploit the public. There is a widespread misconception that all big firms have monopoly power, so that the primary purpose of antitrust or regulatory activity should be to break up as many

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 13

265

Limiting Market Power: Regulation and Antitrust

large firms as possible and to constrain the pricing of all large firms that cannot be broken into smaller ones. But this is not a valid conclusion. It is true that firms that have a very small share of their industry’s sales cannot wield market power. For reasons studied in Chapter 10, such small firms are price takers, not price makers. They must simply accept the price determined by supply and demand in a competitive market, or the prices determined by larger firms in their industry if those large firms do have market power. But although firms with small market shares never have market power, the converse is not true: Large firms do not always have market power—though some of them surely do. Why may such power elude the big firm? In an oligopoly characterized by fierce rivalry, each firm may be prevented by the actions of its competitors from raising its price above competitive levels. For example, Coca-Cola and Pepsi each have a very large share of the soft-drink market. It is well known that there is no love between the two companies, so neither dares to raise its prices substantially for fear of driving customers into the arms of its unloved competitor. Even a monopoly may have little or no monopoly power if entry into its industry is cheap and easy. Such a firm knows that it can retain its monopoly only if its behavior is not monopolistic. If it tries to raise its price to monopoly levels for any substantial period of time, then its rivals will have an opportunity to come in and take some or all of its business away. So in industries where entry is very easy, a large firm will have no monopoly power because the perpetual threat of potential entry will keep it from misbehaving. For this reason, government agencies concerned with monopoly issues often explicitly avoid interfering with the actions of firms in industries where entry is clearly cheap and easy. The primary threat of monopoly and oligopoly to the public interest is monopoly power. This power can lead to excessive prices that exploit consumers, misallocation of resources, and inefficient and noninnovative firms. But firms that are big do not necessarily have market power.

In Part 1 of this chapter, we will discuss how the antitrust laws are used to deal with these issues. In Part 2, we turn to regulation—a second way of dealing with the problems.

PART 1: ANTITRUST LAWS AND POLICIES In Part 2 of this chapter, we will describe the process of regulation, which governments use to oversee monopoly or oligopoly firms that are deemed to have dangerous power to control their markets. In Part 1, we will now analyze the first of government’s instruments for protecting competition: antitrust policy. Antitrust policy refers to programs that preclude the deliberate creation of monopoly and prevent powerful firms from engaging in related “anticompetitive practices.” Firms accused of violating the U.S. antitrust laws are likely to be sued by the federal government or other private firms. Antitrust suits seek to prevent such undesirable behavior from recurring, provide compensation to the victims, and punish offenders via fines or even imprisonment. For a very brief description of the most notable U.S. antitrust laws see Table 1, “Basic Antitrust Laws,” on page 266. The antitrust agencies generally are not allowed to decide that a firm has violated the antitrust laws. They can only sue a company they suspect of violating those laws in the courts and provide evidence supporting their allegations against the firm, seeking to get the court to punish the claimed misbehavior and prevent its continuation. Still, even the threat of such a lawsuit is a serious matter to the firm, because of the possible punishment if it loses the case and because fighting such a lawsuit can cost the firm hundreds of millions of dollars. What justifies investment of so much power in such government agencies as the Department of Justice and the Federal Trade Commission? What are the purposes of the antitrust laws? How well has antitrust policy succeeded? These are the issues that we will discuss in this part of the chapter.

Antitrust policy refers to programs and laws that preclude the deliberate creation of monopoly and prevent powerful firms from engaging in related “anticompetitive practices.”

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

266

Part 3

Markets and the Price System

TABLE 1 Basic Antitrust Laws Name

Date

Major Provisions

Sherman Act

1890

Clayton Act

1914

Federal Trade Commission Act

1914

Robinson-Patman Act

1936

Celler-Kefauver Antimerger Act

1950

Prohibits “all contracts, combinations and conspiracies in restraint of trade” (Section 1) and monopolization in interstate and foreign trade (Section 2). Prohibits price discrimination, “exclusive contracts” under which sellers prevent buyers from purchasing goods from the sellers’ competitors, and “tying contracts” under which a customer who wants to buy some product from a given seller is required as part of the price to agree to buy another product or products from that same seller. Prohibits acquisition by one corporation of another’s shares if these acts are likely to reduce competition or tend to create monopoly. Prohibits directors of one company from sitting on the board of a competitor’s company. Established the FTC as an independent agency with authority to prosecute unfair competition and to prevent false and misleading advertising. Prohibits special discounts and other discriminatory concessions to large purchasers unless based on differences in cost or “offered in good faith to meet an equally low price of a competitor.” Prohibits any corporation from acquiring the assets of another where the effect is to reduce competition substantially or to tend to create a monopoly.

The charming courtroom is old but recently refurbished, and the air-conditioning is inadequate. It is often difficult to hear what is happening. The defendant firm has been accused of predatory pricing—that is, of charging very low prices in order to drive a competitor out of the market—and is defending itself against a judgment that can run into the billions of dollars. For the past two months, both sides have called many witnesses— company executives, accountants, statisticians. The female lawyers are dressed in conservative outfits; the men in somewhat seedy twopiece suits. It would not do to appear too wealthy, for this is a jury trial, and the men and women jurors wear casual attire including sneakers, jeans, and sports clothes. Although determined to see justice done, they are having a hard time staying awake under a hurricane of technical arguments and contradictory figures. The judge follows the proceedings closely, often interrupting with questions of her own. Sometimes she jokes with the witnesses. The lawyers call in an expert witness who is a specialist in the field—in this case, an economist who has written on predatory pricing. He explains to the court and the jury the current thinking of the economics profession on the definition of predatory pricing and the standards by which one judges whether or not it has occurred. He is persuasive.

SOURCE: © Comstock Images/Jupiterimages

You Are There: An Antitrust Trial

But the judge and jury have already heard from another economist, equally distinguished, representing the other side. Their analyses, which were quite technical, reached opposite conclusions though they agree on analytic procedures. Which one are the jurors to believe, and on what basis?

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 13

267

Limiting Market Power: Regulation and Antitrust

The Size and Scope of an Antitrust Case Alleged violations of the antitrust laws are usually dealt with by bringing the accused firm to court or by threatening to sue it in the hope that the accused firm will surrender and accept a compromise. Antitrust suits are frequently well-publicized affairs because the accused firms are often the giants of industry—such famous names as Standard Oil, U.S. Steel, the Aluminum Company of America (Alcoa), General Electric, International Business Machines (IBM), American Telephone and Telegraph (AT&T), and Microsoft all have appeared in such proceedings. Even some of the nation’s most prestigious colleges and universities have been accused of engaging in a pricing conspiracy. The magnitude of an antitrust suit is difficult to imagine. After the charges have been filed, it is not unusual for more than five years to elapse before the case even comes to trial. The parties

spend this period laboriously preparing their cases. Dozens of lawyers, scores of witnesses, and hundreds of researchers are likely to participate in this process. The trial itself also can run for years. A major case produces literally thousands of volumes of material, and it can easily cost the defendant several hundred million dollars, even if it wins. In addition, if it loses, the defendant may have to pay billions of dollars in fines. As you may imagine, the power of the government or another firm to haul a company into court on antitrust charges is an awesome one. Win, lose, or draw, such a case imposes a very heavy burden on the accused firm, draining its funds, consuming the time and attention of its management, and delaying business decisions until the outcome of the legal proceedings is determined.

MEASURING MARKET POWER: CONCENTRATION Concentration: Definition and Measurement— The Herfindahl-Hirschman Index It is generally agreed that a firm is not strong enough to violate the antitrust laws if it possesses no monopoly power—that is, no power to prevent entry of competitors and to raise prices substantially above competitive levels. So in antitrust lawsuits one issue that is almost invariably argued about is whether the accused company does or does not have monopoly power. In enforcing the antitrust laws, one piece of evidence that the U.S. Department of Justice and the Federal Trade Commission use to test whether a firm under investigation for antitrust violations is likely to possess monopoly power is the concentration of the markets in which the firm carries out its activities. A market or an industry is said to be highly concentrated if it contains only a few firms, most or all of which sell a large share of the industry’s products. In contrast, an industry with many small firms is said to be unconcentrated. Thus, concentration is a useful index of the relative bigness of the firms in the industry. Earlier, we noted that big firms do not always have market power, whereas relatively small firms never (or almost never) do. Still, concentration is one useful piece of evidence in deciding whether market power exists in any case under investigation. In particular, if the accused firm can convince the court that it has no such power, the case is likely to be dismissed by the court. Concentration is measured in a number of ways. The most straightforward method is to calculate what share of the industry’s output is sold by some selected number of the industry’s firms. Most often a four-firm concentration ratio is used for this purpose. Thus, if the four largest firms in an industry account for, say, 58 percent of the industry’s sales, we say that the four-firm concentration ratio is 0.58. Another formula now widely used to measure concentration is the Herfindahl-Hirschman Index (HHI). This measure is used by the U.S. Department of Justice and the Federal Trade Commission, for example, to decide whether the proposed merger of two firms will lead to excessive concentration in a particular industry. The index is calculated by determining the market share of each of the firms in the industry, squaring each of these numbers, and adding them together. To quote one of the government documents, “For example, a market consisting of four firms with market shares of 30 percent, 30 percent, 20 percent, and 20 percent has an

Concentration of an industry measures the share of the total sales or assets of the industry in the hands of its largest firms. A concentration ratio is the percentage of an industry’s output produced by its four largest firms. It is intended to measure the degree to which the industry is dominated by large firms. The HerfindahlHirschman Index (HHI) is an alternative and widely used measure of the degree of concentration of an industry. It is calculated, in essence, by adding together the squares of the market shares of the firms in the industry, although the smallest firms may be left out of the calculation because their small market share numbers have a negligible effect on the result.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

268

Part 3

Markets and the Price System

Protection of Competition, Not Protection of Competitors

SOURCE: © Hisham Ibrahim/Photodisc/Getty Images

The courts have repeatedly emphasized that the antitrust laws are not intended to make life easier for individual firms that encounter difficulties coping with competitive market pressures. The following quotation from a recent decision of the U.S. Supreme Court makes this clear: The purpose of the Sherman Act is not to protect businesses from the workings of the market, it is to protect the public from the failure of the market.

SOURCE: Spectrum Sports Inc. v. McQuillan, US 122 L.Ed 2d 247 [1993], p. 506.

HHI of 2,600 (or, 302 1 302 1 202 1 202 5 2,600). The HHI ranges from 10,000 (in the case of a pure monopoly) to a number approaching zero (in the case of [near perfect competition]).”1 The government considers a market to be unconcentrated if its HHI number is less than 1,000, and highly concentrated if that number exceeds 1,800. The HHI offers at least two advantages over the four-firm concentration ratio. Unlike the latter ratio, HHI takes into account data on a much larger percentage of the firms in the market than just the top four. However, the calculation automatically magnifies the weight assigned to the market shares of the larger firms, because the square of a larger number is disproportionately larger than the square of a smaller number. This effect is considered desirable, because these larger firms are the reason the government worries about monopoly power in the market under consideration. It also explains why the HHI works as a measure of concentration. The HHI number rises when concentration grows because the larger the shares of the market’s total sales held by the big firms, the disproportionately larger the squared values of those shares will be. Ultimately, we care about concentration ratios if they are a good measure of market power. The question, then, is this: If an industry becomes more concentrated, will the firms necessarily increase their ability to price their products above competitive levels? Many economists have, in fact, concluded that although increased concentration often facilitates or increases market power, it does not always do so. Specifically, the following three conclusions are now widely accepted: • If, after an increase in concentration, an industry still has a very low concentration ratio, then its firms are very unlikely to have any market power either before or after the rise in concentration. • If circumstances in the industry are in other respects favorable for successful price collusion—that is, an agreement among the firms not to undercut one another’s prices or not to compete “too much” in other ways—a rise in concentration will facilitate market power. It will do so by reducing the number of firms that need to be consulted in arriving at an agreement and by decreasing the number of firms that have to be watched to make sure they do not betray the collusive agreement. • Where entry into and exit from the industry are easy and quite inexpensive, then even when concentration increases, market power will not be enhanced because an excessive price will attract new entrants that will soon force the price down.

1 Department of Justice and Federal Trade Commission, Horizontal Merger Guidelines, Washington, D.C., 1993, page 8, footnote.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 13

The Evidence of Concentration in Reality

269

Limiting Market Power: Regulation and Antitrust

TABLE 2 Concentration Ratios and Herfindahl-Hirschman Indexes for Selected Manufacturing Industries, 2002

Concentration data may be the best evidence Herfindahl-Hirschman that we have on the effectiveness of antitrust Index for 50 Largest programs. Table 2 shows concentration ratios Four-firm Companies in and Herfindahl-Hirschman Indexes in a numIndustry ratio the Industry ber of industries in the United States. We see Precision-turned products 4.1 13.1 that concentration varies greatly from industry Cement and concrete products 11.9 70.5 to industry: Automobiles, breakfast cereals, Womens’ and girls’ dresses 21.6 185.5 and aircraft are produced by highly concenFine jewelry 21.5 195.3 trated industries, but the cement, jewelry, and Bolts, nuts, screws, rivets, and washers 23.7 205.9 Computers and electronic products 18.0 135.0 women’s and girls’ clothing industries show Fluid milk 42.6 1060.4 very little concentration. Sporting and athletic goods 22.5 182.2 During the last century, concentration ratios Brooms, brushes, and mops 29.2 346.3 in the United States, on the average, have reMusical instruments 42.7 606.0 mained remarkably constant. It has been estiDolls and stuffed toys 50.8 798.2 Pharmaceutical preparations 34.9 504.6 mated that, at the beginning of the twentieth Ship and boat building 50.8 883.9 century, 32.9 percent of manufactured goods Mens’ and boys’ suits and coats 48.8 1049.0 were produced by industries in which the conFasteners, buttons, needles, and pins 53.1 1461.8 centration ratios were 50 percent or more Tortillas 56.1 2031.4 Cookies and crackers 66.6 1629.0 (meaning that at least 50 percent of industry Tires 76.1 1773.8 output was produced by the four largest firms). Aircraft 80.2 2947.6 By 1997, the figure had risen only to 33.5 perBreakfast cereal 78.4 2521.3 cent. These figures and those for other years are Automobiles 75.5 1910.9 shown in Table 3. As we see, over the course of Electric lamp bulbs and parts 89.6 2848.0 the twentieth century, concentration in individGuided missiles and space vehicles 95.3 Not disclosed Cigarettes 95.3 Not disclosed ual U.S. industries has shown little tendency to increase. SOURCE: U.S. Census Bureau, “Concentration Ratios in Manufacturing, 2002,” 2002 Economic Census, U.S. Department of Commerce, Economics and Statistics Administration, issued May 2006. http://www.census.gov/prod/ec02/ec0231sr1.pdf. Such information may suggest that the antitrust laws have to some degree been effective TAB LE 3 in inhibiting whatever trend toward bigness may actually exist. Even this very The Historical Trend in Concentration in Manufacturing cautious conclusion has been questioned by some observers, who argue that the Industries, 1901–1997 size of firms has been held down by market forces and technical developments (such as declining computer costs that make it easier for small firms to increase Percentage their efficiency, or the takeover of much of freight traffic from large railroads by of Value-Added in Industries small trucking firms). These observers argue that antitrust laws have made virwith Four-Firm tually no difference in the size and the behavior of American business.

A CRUCIAL PROBLEM FOR ANTITRUST: THE RESEMBLANCE OF MONOPOLIZATION AND VIGOROUS COMPETITION One problem that haunts most antitrust litigation is that vigorous competition may look very similar to acts that undermine competition and support monopoly power. The resulting danger is that the courts will prohibit, or the antitrust authorities will prosecute, acts that appear to be anticompetitive but are really the opposite. The difficulty occurs because effective competition by a firm is always tough on its rivals. It forces rivals to charge lower prices, to improve product quality, and to spend money on innovations that will cut their costs and improve their products. Competition will legitimately force competitors out of business if they are inefficient and therefore cannot keep their prices low or provide products of acceptable quality. When competition destroys a rival in this way, however, it is difficult to tell whether the firm was, so to speak, murdered or died of natural causes. In both cases, the surviving competitor bears some responsibility for its rival’s failure. On the one hand, if the cause of the rival’s demise is legitimate

Concentration Ratios over 50 Percent

Circa 1901 1947 1954 1958 1963 1966 1970 1972 1982 1987 1992 1997

32.9 24.4 29.9 30.2 33.1 28.6 26.3 29.0 25.2 27.9 26.4 33.5

SOURCES: P. W. McCracken and T. G. Moore, “Competitive and Market Concentration in the American Economy,” Subcommittee on Antitrust and Monopoly, U.S. Senate, March 29, 1973; F. M. Scherer, Industrial Market Structure and Economic Performance (Boston: Houghton Mifflin, 1980), p. 68; F. M. Scherer and David Ross, Industrial Market Structure and Economic Performance, 3rd ed. (Boston: Houghton Mifflin, 1990), p. 84; personal communication with Professor Frederick M. Scherer, March 10, 1993; and personal communication with Andrew W. Hait, Special Reports Branch, U.S. Bureau of the Census, December 2001.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

270

Part 3

Markets and the Price System

competition, consumers will benefit; on the other hand, if the end of the rival was part of a process of monopoly creation, then the public will end up paying. This very real issue constantly recurs in today’s antitrust litigation.

ANTICOMPETITIVE PRACTICES AND ANTITRUST A central purpose of the antitrust laws is to prevent “anticompetitive practices,” which are actions by a powerful firm that threaten to destroy competitors, or force competitors to compete less vigorously, or prevent the entry of new rivals.

Predatory Pricing

Predatory pricing is pricing that threatens to keep a competitor out of the market. It is a price that is so low that it will be profitable for the firm that adopts it only if a rival is driven from the market.

Typical of accusations of anticompetitive behavior is the claim, made frequently in antitrust cases, that the defendant has adopted unjustifiably low prices in order to force other firms to lose money, thereby driving competitors out of business. This practice is called predatory pricing. Deciding whether pricing is “predatory” is difficult, both for economists and for courts of law, because low prices generally benefit consumers. Therefore, the courts do not want to discourage firms from cutting prices by being too eager to declare that lower prices are intended to destroy a rival. One principle widely followed by the courts holds that prices are predatory only if they are below either marginal or average variable costs. The logic of this criterion as a test for whether prices are “too low” is that even under perfect competition, prices will not, in the long run, fall below that level, but will equal marginal costs. Even in cases where prices are below marginal or average variable costs, they may be held to be predatory only under two conditions: • If evidence shows that the low price would have been profitable only if it succeeded in destroying a rival or in keeping it out of the market. • When there is a real probability that the allegedly predatory firm could raise prices to monopoly levels after the rival was driven out, thereby profiting from its venture in crime. Many major firms—including AT&T, American Airlines, and Microsoft—have been accused of predatory pricing. The defendants typically argue that their low prices cover both marginal and average variable costs, that their prices are low because of superior efficiency, and that the lawsuit was brought to prevent the defendants from competing effectively. The courts have generally accepted these arguments. There have been many predatory pricing cases, but few convictions.

The Microsoft Case: Bottlenecks, Bundling, and Network Externalities The recent litigation involving Microsoft Corporation illustrates two other practices that can conceivably be anticompetitive. Microsoft is the enormously successful supplier of computer operating systems that enable you to communicate with and control your personal computer; it also supplies other very popular computer programs. Microsoft’s software sales are huge, and the company is clearly a tough and energetic competitor. The difficulty of distinguishing vigorously competitive behavior from anticompetitive acts is illustrated by the Microsoft antitrust case, in which the U.S. Department of Justice accused the firm of various anticompetitive practices. The Microsoft case raises many issues, two of which are discussed here as illustrations.

Abuse via Bottlenecks Microsoft’s Windows Vista, an operating system that runs on about 90 percent of all personal computers, is a prime example of a problem referred to as a “bottleneck”—a facility or product in the hands of a single firm, without which competitors find it difficult or even impossible to operate. To reach any substantial proportion of personal computer customers, the producer of any word processor, spreadsheet, or graphics program Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 13

271

Limiting Market Power: Regulation and Antitrust

must use Windows, and there seems little likelihood that any alternative to Windows Vista that is not produced by Microsoft will soon capture the major share of customers. The bottleneck exists in part because Windows Vista is widely considered a good program, but even more because user compatibility is desirable—computer users need to communicate with one another, and that task is easier if all of them employ the same operating system. That is, there exists a network of users of computer products who want to be able to communicate easily with one another and who therefore desire mutually compatible software. This preference gives Microsoft a big advantage, because it already has so many users that a new purchaser who values such compatibility will be reluctant to buy a competing product that will make it more difficult to communicate with those many users of the Microsoft products. The bottleneck problem arises because Microsoft itself supplies not only Windows Vista but also many applications (such as Word, a wordprocessing program; Excel, a spreadsheet program; and Internet Explorer, an Internet browser). There is nothing illegal about simply being the owner of a bottleneck. If company X is a railroad with the only train-bearing bridge over a river because no other rail line had the resources or the initiative to build its own bridge, that is surely not anticompetitive. The worry is that a bottleneck owner, like Microsoft, will use its bottleneck product, Windows Vista, in a way that favors its own programs and handicaps programs supplied by its competitors.

Bundling: Legitimate and Illegitimate Microsoft has promoted its own products by providing them more cheaply to computer manufacturers if these makers buy a bundle of Microsoft programs, rather than just Windows Vista alone. This practice means that rival producers of word processors, spreadsheets, and Internet browsers are handicapped in selling their products to PC owners. The question is whether Microsoft’s low bundle price is legitimate or if it constitutes a case of predatory pricing whose only purpose is to destroy competitors. Economists often take the position that a bundling discount is legitimate if it is less expensive for the firm to supply several products at once than to supply them one at a time and if the price cut corresponds to the cost saving. However, they question the legitimacy of the bundle discount if the cost saving is considerably less than the difference between the bundled price and the sum of the prices of the included products (when bought individually). However, even here, it is argued that if the price of the bundle exceeds its marginal cost or its average variable cost, it is not predatory.

Bundling refers to a pricing arrangement under which the supplier offers substantial discounts to customers if they buy several of the firm’s products, so that the price of the bundle of products is less than the sum of the prices of the products if they were bought separately.

USE OF ANTITRUST LAWS TO PREVENT COMPETITION Finally, let us turn to an issue that some observers consider very serious: the misuse of the antitrust laws to prevent competition. Many firms that have been unable to compete effectively on their own merits have turned to the courts to seek protection from their successful competitors—and some have succeeded. Firms that try to protect themselves in this way always claim that their rivals have not achieved success through superior ability but rather by means that they call “monopolization.” Sometimes the evidence is clear-cut, and the courts can readily discern whether an accused firm has violated the antitrust laws or whether it has simply been too efficient and innovative for the complaining competitor’s tastes. In other cases, the issues are complicated, and only a long and painstaking legal proceeding offers any prospect of resolving them. Various steps have been suggested to deal with the misuse of U.S. antitrust laws. In one proposal, if the courts decide that a firm has been falsely accused by another of violating the antitrust laws, then (as is done in other countries) the accuser will pay the legal costs of the innocent defendant. Another proposal is to subject such suits to prescreening by a government agency, as is done in Japan. But these issues are hardly open-and-shut, for there is no such thing as a perfect legal system. Anything that restricts anticompetitive, private antitrust suits will almost certainly inhibit legitimate attempts by individual firms to defend themselves from genuine acts of monopolization by rival enterprises (for more on this issue, see “Can Antitrust Laws Be Used to Prevent Competition?” on page 272). Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Part 3

Markets and the Price System

SOURCE: Doonesbury © G. B. Trudeau. Reprinted with permission of Universal Press Syndicate. All rights reserved.

272

Many observers are concerned that the antitrust laws are often used by inefficient firms to protect themselves from the competition of more efficient rivals. When they are unable to win out in the marketplace, the argument goes, firms simply file lawsuits against their competitors claiming that those rivals have achieved success by means that violate the antitrust laws. Not only do firms seek protection from the courts against what they describe as “unfair competition” or “predatory practices” but they often sue for compensation that, under the law, can sometimes be three times as large as the damages that they claim to have suffered. Moreover, even if the defendant is found innocent, it must normally pay the very high costs of the litigation itself. Aside from the enormous waste that such lawsuits entail, observers worry that they represent a perversion of the antitrust laws, which were, after all, designed to promote competition, not to prevent it. Two recent examples illustrate the nature of such litigation. These cases also demonstrate that the courts are often wise enough to throw out such attempts to use the antitrust laws to prevent competition.

Intimate Bookshop versus Barnes & Noble The Intimate Bookshop, Inc. (Intimate) was an independent bookseller with retail locations throughout the Mid-Atlantic United States. Shortly before it went out of business in 1999, Intimate sued several of its larger rivals, including Barnes & Noble, Inc. (B&N), claiming that Intimate’s business losses had been caused by the anticompetitive practices of the larger booksellers and publishers. Specifically, Intimate alleged that B&N was purchasing books from publishers at substantially lower (discriminatory) prices than those paid by Intimate and other independent retail bookstores. The court ruled against Intimate, finding that there was no evidence to show that its losses were caused by anticompetitive conduct (Southern District of New York, 2003).

SOURCE: Jupiterimages

Can Antitrust Laws Be Used to Prevent Competition?

West Penn versus UPMC and Highmark West Penn Allegheny Health Systems, Inc. (West Penn), a Pittsburgh area hospital, sued its larger competitor, University of Pittsburgh Medical Center (UPMC), and Highmark, Inc. (Highmark), a local insurance company with a 60 percent market share. At the time that the lawsuit was filed, West Penn was suffering financially, whereas UPMC’s revenue was rising dramatically. In its complaint, West Penn claimed that UPMC and Highmark had conspired to protect one another from competition via a campaign of anticompetitive and predatory conduct undertaken in an effort to “destroy” West Penn. Although the complaint alleged numerous instances of anticompetitive conduct, the court found that all of the allegations were unsupported by any factual specificity and “amount[ed] to nothing more than statements of suspicion.” The court also found fault with the relief West Penn sought, which included an order instating nondiscriminatory reimbursement rates that the court noted actually would hurt consumers by raising the costs of both heath care and health insurance (Western District of Pennsylvania, 2009).

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 13

273

Limiting Market Power: Regulation and Antitrust

PART 2: REGULATION We turn, next, to regulation, the other of the two traditional instruments used by government to protect consumers from exploitation by firms that are too powerful.

WHAT IS REGULATION? Regulation of industry is a process established by law that restricts or controls some specified decisions made by the affected firms; it is designed to protect the public from exploitation by firms with monopoly power. Regulation is usually carried out by a special government agency assigned the task of administering and interpreting the law. That agency also acts as a court in enforcing the regulatory laws.

“Won’t all these new rules impact adversely on the viability of small businesses with fewer than fifty employees?”

PUZZLE:

WHY DO REGULATORS OFTEN RAISE PRICES?

Regulation sometimes forces consumers to pay higher prices than they would pay in its absence. For instance, before the airline industry was deregulated, the flight between New York City and Washington, D.C.—an interstate trip that was controlled by the federal government—was more expensive than the flight between San Francisco and Los Angeles—a trip that was not controlled by the federal government, because it took place entirely within the state of California. The California trip was nearly twice as long as the East Coast trip, and it did not have a substantially lower cost per passenger mile for the airline. So why did regulators, whose job it is to protect the public interest, deliberately price the New York–Washington hop about 25 percent higher? Later in the chapter, you will be able to answer this question.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

SOURCE: © The New Yorker Collection, 1993, Ed Fisher from cartoonbank.com. All Rights Reserved.

“Regulation of industry” refers to the activities of a number of government agencies that enforce rules about business conduct enacted by Congress or rules that the agencies themselves have adopted. When an industry is suspected of possessing monopoly power and, because of scale economies or for other reasons, it is not considered feasible or desirable to bring effective competition into its markets, the regulatory agency imposes rules upon the firms designed to curb their use of the monopoly power. For example, the agency may place ceilings on the prices the regulated firms can charge, or it may require the firm to submit any change it desires in any of its prices to the agency. Such changes, then, are not permitted until they have been approved by the agency, sometimes after extensive (and expensive) hearings (that is, trials) before the agency, in which the opponents and supporters of the proposed changes, as well as their lawyers and their witnesses, have the opportunity to present their opinions. Regulations designed to limit market power, and economic behavior more generally, affect industries that together provide perhaps 10 percent of the gross domestic product (GDP) of the United States. The list includes telecommunications, railroads, electric utilities, oil pipelines, banks, and the stock markets. Both the federal government and the states have regulatory agencies devoted to such tasks. Despite its good intentions, regulation has been criticized as a cause of inefficiency and excessive costs to the consuming public. The basic fact about regulation and other forms of government intervention that are designed to affect the operations of markets is that neither markets nor governmental agencies always work perfectly. In an uncontrolled market, for example, monopoly power can damage the public interest, but excessive or poorly conceived regulations or antitrust decisions also can prove very harmful.

274

Part 3

Markets and the Price System

SOME OBJECTIVES OF REGULATION The regulatory agencies, lawyers, and economists recognize a number of reasons that may justify the regulation of an industry. A primary purpose of regulation is, of course, prevention of abuse of monopoly power. We have seen that such power can easily be acquired in industries characterized by economies of scale and scope and that this power can be used by firms to impose prices that exploit the consumer. We have already discussed these as problems that antitrust activity is designed to control. But this is also a fundamental goal of economic regulation. In contrast, there are other issues that are relevant only to regulation. The following is an example.

Control of Market Power Resulting from Economies of Scale and Scope

Economies of scope are savings that are obtained through simultaneous production of many different products. They occur if a firm that produces many commodities can supply each good more cheaply than a firm that produces fewer commodities.

F I GURE 1

Price and Cost per Unit

Economies of Scale

As we noted at the beginning of this chapter, a major reason for regulation of industry is to prevent the use of or acquisition of market power by regulated firms. In some industries, it is far cheaper to have production carried out by one firm than by many, and the relatively large firms that result may gain market power. One cause is economies of largescale production. Railroad tracks are a particularly good example of such economies of scale. The total cost of building and maintaining the tracks when 100 trains traverse them every day is not much higher than when only one train uses them. So, substantial savings in average cost result when rail traffic increases. As we saw in Chapter 7, scale economies lead to an average cost (AC) curve that goes downhill as output increases (see Figure 1). This means that a firm with a large output can cover its costs at a price lower than a firm whose output is smaller. In the figure, point A represents the larger firm whose AC is $5, whereas point B is the smaller firm with an AC of $7. A single, large firm also may have a cost advantage over a group of small firms when it is cheaper to produce a number of different commodities together rather than making each separately in a different firm. Savings made possible by simultaneous production of many different products by one firm are called economies of scope. One clear example of economies of scope is the manufacture of both cars and trucks by the same producer. The techniques employed in producing both commodities are similar, which provides a cost advantage to firms that produce both types of vehicles. In industries characterized by great economies of scale and scope, costs will be much higher if government intervenes to preserve a large number of small, and therefore costly, firms. Moreover, where economies of scale and scope are strong, society will not be able to preserve free competition, even if it wants to. The large, multiproduct firm will have so great a cost advantage over its rivals that the small firms simply will be unable to survive. Where monopoly production is cheapest, so that free competition is not sustainable, the industry is a natural monopoly. When monopoly is cheaper, society may not want to have competition; if free competition is not sustainable, it will not even have a choice in the matter.

B $7 A

5 P

AC 3 MC

0

50 100 Quantity Produced per Year

Even if society reconciles itself to monopoly in such cases, it will generally not want to let the monopoly firm wield its market power without limits. Therefore, it will consider regulating the company’s decisions on matters such as pricing. The first and most universal problem facing the regulator is how to prevent the regulated firm from pricing and taking other actions that exploit the public and undermine the efficiency of the market, but to do so in ways that do not destroy the regulated firm or prevent it from serving the public effectively.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 13

275

Limiting Market Power: Regulation and Antitrust

Universal Service and Rate Averaging A second type of problem in the analysis of regulation stems from another objective of regulation of the prices and other choices of firms in a regulated industry—the desire for “universal service.” By this regulators mean the availability of service to everyone at “reasonable prices,” particularly to impoverished consumers and small communities where the limited scale of operations may make costs extremely high. In such cases, regulators may encourage or require a public utility (such as an electric power supplier) to serve some of its consumers at a financial loss. This loss on some sales is financially feasible only when the regulated firm is permitted to make up for it by obtaining higher profits on its other sales. Charging higher prices to one set of customers to finance lower prices to another customer group is called cross-subsidization. This sort of cross-subsidization is possible only if the regulated firm is protected from price competition and free entry of new competitors in its other, more profitable markets (in which it charges the higher prices that subsidize the financing of the mandated low prices). If no such protection is provided, potential competitors will sniff out these profit opportunities in the markets where service is supplied at prices well above cost. Many new firms will enter the business and drive prices down in those markets—a practice referred to as cream skimming. The entrants choose to enter only the profitable markets and skim away the “cream” of the profits for themselves, leaving the unprofitable markets (the skimmed milk?) to the supplier that had attempted to provide universal service. This phenomenon is one reason why regulatory rules, until recently, made it very difficult or impossible for new firms to enter when and where they saw fit. Airlines and telecommunications are two industries in which these issues have arisen frequently. In both cases, it was feared that without regulation of entry and rates, or special subsidies, less populous communities would effectively become isolated, losing their airline services and obtaining telephone service only at cripplingly high rates. Many economists question the validity of this argument for regulation, which, they say, calls for hidden subsidies of rural consumers by everyone else. The airline deregulation act provided for government subsidies to help small communities attract airline service. In fact, this market has since been taken over to a considerable extent by specialized “commuter” airlines flying much smaller aircraft than the major airlines, which have withdrawn from many such routes. A similar issue affects the U.S. Postal Service, which charges the same price to deliver a letter anywhere within the United States, regardless of the distance or the special difficulties and costs of a particular route. To maintain this pricing scheme, the law must protect the Postal Service from direct competition in many of its activities—otherwise, its extreme form of uniform pricing would soon deprive it of its most profitable routes. Thus, the goal of providing universal service leads to the regulation of entry into and exit from the affected industry, and not just price control.

Cross-subsidization means selling one product of the firm at a loss, which is balanced by higher profits on another of the firm’s products.

TWO KEY ISSUES THAT FACE REGULATORS Regulators around the world face (at least) two critical issues that are of fundamental importance for economic policy. They are at the heart of recent legal battles before regulatory agencies almost everywhere.

Setting Prices to Protect Consumers’ Interests and Allow Regulated Firms to Cover Their Costs When governments regulate prices, they usually want to prevent those prices from being so high that they bring monopoly profits to the firm. At the same time, governments want to set prices at levels that are “compensatory”; that is, the prices must be sufficiently high to enable the firms to cover their costs and, consequently, to survive financially.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

276

Part 3

Markets and the Price System

Regulators also are asked to select prices that best serve the public interest. These goals, as we will see next, can often be at odds. • Prices intended to promote the public interest may cause financial problems for firms. The discussion in Chapter 10 implied that the consumer’s welfare is most effectively promoted by setting the price of a product equal to that product’s marginal cost, and this will be further confirmed in Chapter 14. But as we will show presently, such a rule would condemn many regulated firms to bankruptcy. What should the regulator do in such a case? • Preventing firms with monopoly power from earning excessive profits without eliminating all incentives for efficiency and innovation may prove difficult. The firm’s incentive and reward for the effort and expenditure needed to improve efficiency and to innovate is the higher profit that it expects to obtain if it succeeds. But a frequent objective of regulation is to put a ceiling on profit to prevent monopoly earnings. How can monopoly profits be prevented without destroying incentives? Let’s now analyze these issues, which arise frequently in today’s crucial regulatory policy debates.

Marginal versus Average Cost Pricing Regulatory agencies often have the task of controlling the prices of regulated firms. Acrimonious debate over the proper levels for those prices has filled hundreds of thousands of pages of regulatory-hearing records and has involved literally hundreds of millions of dollars of expenditures in fees for lawyers, expert witnesses, and research. The central question has been: What constitutes the proper formula to set these prices? Where it is feasible, most economists favor setting price equal to marginal cost because, as we will show in Chapter 14, this pricing policy provides the incentive for firms to produce output quantities that serve consumers’ wants most efficiently. However, a serious practical problem often prevents use of marginal cost pricing: In many regulated industries, the firms would go bankrupt if all prices were set equal to marginal costs! This seems a startling conclusion, but it follows inescapably from three simple facts: Fact 1. Many regulated industries are characterized by significant economies of large-scale production. As we pointed out earlier, economies of scale are one of the main reasons why certain industries were regulated in the first place. Fact 2. In an industry with economies of scale, the long-run average cost curve is downward sloping. This means that the long-run average cost falls as the quantity produced rises, as was illustrated by the AC curve in Figure 1. Fact 2 is something we learned back in Chapter 7. The reason, to review briefly, is that where there are economies of scale, if all input quantities are doubled, output will more than double. But total costs will double only if input quantities double. Thus, total costs will rise more slowly than output and so average cost must fall. That is, average cost (AC) is simply total cost (TC) divided by quantity (Q), so with economies of scale, AC 5 TC/Q must decline when Q increases because the denominator, Q, rises more rapidly than the numerator, TC. Fact 3. If average cost is declining, then marginal cost must be below average cost. This fact follows directly from one of the general rules relating marginal and average data that were explained in the appendix to Chapter 8. Once again, the logic is simple enough to review briefly. If, for example, your average quiz score is 90 percent but the next quiz pulls your average down to 87 percent, then the grade on the most recent test (the marginal grade) must be below both the old and the new average quiz scores; that is, it takes a marginal grade (or cost) that is below the average to pull the average down. Putting these three facts together, we conclude that in many regulated industries, marginal cost (MC) will be below average cost, as depicted in Figure 1. Now suppose that regulators set the price (or average revenue, AR) at the level of marginal cost. Because

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 13

Limiting Market Power: Regulation and Antitrust

P then equals MC, P (5 AR) must be below AC and the firm must lose money, so “P equals MC” is simply not an acceptable option. What, then, should be done? One possibility is to set price equal to marginal cost and to use public funds to make up for the deficit. However, government subsidies to large regulated firms are not very popular politically and may also not be sensible. A second option, which is quite popular among regulators, is to (try to) set price equal to average cost. This method of pricing is, however, neither desirable nor possible to carry out except on the basis of arbitrary decisions. The problem is that almost no firm produces only a single commodity. Almost every company produces a number of different varieties and qualities of some product, and many produce thousands of different products, each with its own price. General Electric, for example, is perhaps best known for the home appliances it produces, but the company also runs the movie studio and cable television channels that comprise NBC Universal, a finance division that provides loans and other business services, and manufacturing divisions that produce everything from airplane engines to surgical accessories. In a multiproduct firm, we cannot even define AC 5 TC/Q, because to calculate Q (total output), we would have to add up all of the apples and oranges (and all of the other different items) that the firm produces. Of course, we know that we cannot add up apples and oranges. Because we cannot calculate AC for a multiproduct firm, it is hardly possible for the regulator to require P to equal AC for each of the firm’s products (although regulators sometimes think they can do so). One way of dealing with the issue is the price-cap approach that was invented by economists but is now widely employed in practice. The procedure and its logic will be described a little later in this chapter.

Preventing Monopoly Profit but Keeping Incentives for Efficiency and Innovation Opponents of regulation claim that it seriously impairs the efficiency of American industry and reduces the benefits of free markets. One obvious source of inefficiency is the endless paperwork and complex legal proceedings that prevent the firm from responding quickly to changing market conditions. In addition, economists believe that regulatory interference in pricing causes economic inefficiency. By forcing prices to differ from those that would prevail in a free, competitive market, regulations lead consumers to demand a quantity of the regulated product that does not maximize consumer benefits from the quantity of resources available to the economy. (This resource misallocation issue will be discussed in Chapter 15.) A third source of inefficiency may be even more important. It occurs because regulators often are required to prevent the regulated firm from earning excessive profits, while offering it financial incentives for maximum efficiency of operation and allowing it enough profit to attract the capital it needs when growing markets justify expansion. It would seem to be ideal if the regulator would permit the firm to earn just the amount of revenue that covers its costs, including the cost of its capital. Thus, if the current rate of profits in competitive markets is 10 percent, the regulated firm should recover its costs plus 10 percent on its investment and not a penny more or less. The trouble with such a rule is that it removes all profit incentive for efficiency, responsiveness to consumer demand, and innovation. In effect, it guarantees just one standard rate of profit to the firm, no more and no less—regardless of whether its management is totally incompetent or extremely talented and hard-working. Competitive markets do not work this way. Although under perfect competition the average firm will earn just the illustrative 10 percent, a firm with an especially ingenious and efficient management will do better, and a firm with an incompetent management is likely to go broke. It is the possibility of great rewards and harsh punishments that gives the market mechanism its power to cause firms to strive for high efficiency and productivity growth. When firms are guaranteed fixed returns no matter how well or how poorly they perform, gross inefficiencies often result. For example, many contracts for purchases of military equipment have prices calculated on a so-called cost-plus basis, meaning that the supplier is guaranteed that its costs will be covered and that, in addition, it will receive

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

277

278

Part 3

Markets and the Price System

some prespecified profit, removing a key incentive for management to work hard to improve the firm’s performance. Studies of such cost-plus arrangements have confirmed that they lead to enormous supplier inefficiencies. A regulatory arrangement that in effect guarantees a regulated firm its cost plus a “fair rate of return” on its investment obviously has much in common with a cost-plus contract. Fortunately, there are also substantial differences between the two, and so regulatory profit ceilings need not always have serious effects on the firm’s incentives for efficiency. How can one prevent regulated firms from earning excessive profits, but also permit them to earn enough to cover their legitimate costs, attract the capital they need, and, above all, still allow rewards for superior performance and penalties for poor performance?

Price Caps as Incentives for Efficiency A regulatory innovation designed to pre-

A price cap is a ceiling above which regulators do not permit prices to rise. The cap is designed to provide an efficiency incentive to the firm by allowing it to keep part of any savings in costs it can achieve.

vent monopoly profits while offering incentives for the firm to improve its efficiency is now in use in many countries—for electricity, telephones, and airport services in the United Kingdom, for example, and for telephone rates in the United States and elsewhere. Under this program, regulators assign ceilings (called price caps) for the prices (not the profits) of the regulated firms. However, the price caps (which are measured in real, inflation-adjusted terms—in other words, they are adjusted for changes in the purchasing power of money) are reduced each year at a rate based on the rate of cost reduction (productivity growth) previously achieved by the regulated firm. Thus, if the regulated firm subsequently achieves cost savings (by innovation or other means) greater than those it obtained in the past, the firm’s real costs will fall more rapidly than its real prices do, and it will be permitted to keep the resulting profits as its reward. Of course, there is a catch. If the regulated firm reduces its costs by only 2 percent per year, whereas in the past its costs fell 3 percent per year, the price cap will also fall at a 3 percent rate. The firm will therefore lose profits, although consumers will continue to benefit from falling real prices. So under this arrangement the firm is automatically punished if its cost-reduction performance does not keep up with what it was able to achieve in the past. Thus, under price-cap regulation, management is constantly forced to look for ever more economical ways of doing things. This approach clearly gives up any attempt to limit the profit of the regulated firm—leaving the possibility of higher profits as an incentive for efficiency. At the same time, it protects the consumer by controlling the firm’s prices. Indeed, it makes those prices lower and lower, in real terms.

THE PROS AND CONS OF “BIGNESS” We have described several goals for antitrust activity including control of monopoly power. Is it desirable, in addition to these regulatory goals, to try to make big firms become smaller? In other words, are the effects of “bigness” always undesirable? We have already seen that only relatively large firms have any likelihood of possessing monopoly power. We also have seen that monopoly power can cause a number of problems, including undesirable effects on income distribution, misallocation of resources, and inhibition of efficiency and innovation. But we also have seen that big firms, at least sometimes, do not possess monopoly power. More generally, there is another side of the picture. Bigness in industry can also, at least sometimes, benefit the general public. Again, this is true for a number of reasons.

Economies of Large Size Probably the most important advantage of bigness is found in industries in which technology makes small-scale operation inefficient. One can hardly imagine the costs if automobiles were produced in little workshops rather than giant factories. The notion of a small firm operating a long-distance railroad does not even make sense, and a multiplicity of firms replicating the same railroad service would clearly be incredibly wasteful.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 13

Limiting Market Power: Regulation and Antitrust

On these grounds, most policy makers have never even considered any attempt to eliminate bigness. Of course, it does not follow that every industry in which firms happen to be big is one in which big firms are best. Some observers argue that many firms, in fact, exceed the sizes required for cost minimization.

Required Scale for Innovation Some economists have argued that only large firms have the resources and the motivation for really significant innovation. Many important inventions are still contributed by individuals. But, because it is often an expensive, complex, and large-scale undertaking to put a new invention into commercial production, often only large firms can afford the funds and bear the risks that such an effort demands. Many studies have examined the relationships among firm size, industry competitiveness, and the level of expenditure on research and development (R&D). Although the evidence is far from conclusive, it does indicate that highly competitive industries composed of very small firms tend not to spend a great deal on research. Up to a point, R&D outlays and innovation seem to increase with size of the firm and the concentration of the industry. One reason for this is that many oligopolistic firms use innovation—new products and new processes—as their primary competitive “weapon,” forcing them, as time passes, to maintain and even increase their spending on R&D and other innovative activities. However, some of the most significant innovations introduced in the twentieth century have been contributed by firms that started very small. Examples include the airplane, alternating current (AC) electricity, the photocopier, and the electronic calculator. Yet, the important successive improvements in those products have characteristically come out of the research facilities of large, oligopolistic enterprises. The bottom line is that bigness in business firms receives a mixed score. In some cases it can produce undesirable results, but in other cases it is necessary for efficiency and low costs and offers other benefits to the public. A rule requiring regulators to combat bigness per se, wherever it occurs, is likely to have undesirable results and would, in any event, be unworkable.

DEREGULATION Because regulators have sometimes adopted rules and made decisions that were ill-advised and were demonstrably harmful to the public interest, and because the bureaucracy that is needed to enforce regulation is costly and raises business expenses, there have long been demands for reduced regulation. Beginning in the mid-1970s, Congress responded to such arguments by deregulating several industries, such as airlines and trucking, and eliminating most of the powers of the relevant regulatory agencies. In other industries, such as railroads and telecommunications, rule changes now give regulated firms considerably more freedom in decision making. This deregulation process is still under way.

The Effects of Deregulation One way to deal with the regulation difficulties just discussed is to shut regulation down—that is, simply to leave everything to the free market and get rid of the regulators. Many observers think that would be a good idea in a number of cases, but sometimes it would be unacceptable, as in markets that are virtually pure monopolies. Thus, the move toward deregulation has proceeded slowly, by eliminating regulation in some fields and reducing it in others. Deregulation’s effects in the United States are still being debated, but several conclusions seem clear.

1. Effects on Prices There seems little doubt that deregulation has generally led to lower prices. Airline fares, railroad freight rates, and telephone rates have all declined on the average (again, in real, inflation-adjusted terms) after total or partial deregulation.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

279

280

Part 3

Markets and the Price System

At least in the case of the airlines, however, the rate of decline slowed abruptly toward the end of the 1980s. Still, observers conclude that most of these prices are well below the levels that would have prevailed under regulation.

2. Effects on Local Services At first it was widely feared, even by supporters of deregulation, that smaller and more isolated communities would be deprived of services because small numbers of customers would make those services unprofitable. Some predicted that airlines, railroads, and telephone companies would withdraw from such communities once there was no longer any regulation to force them to stay. The outcome was not as serious as had been anticipated. For example, although larger airlines have left smaller communities, they have usually been replaced by smaller commuter airlines that have often provided more frequent service. In addition, the larger airlines inaugurated a new scheduling pattern called the “hub-and-spoke system” (see the discussion below), which enabled them to continue to serve less traveled destinations profitably. 3. Effects on Entry As a result of deregulation, older airlines invaded one another’s routes, several dozen new airlines sprang up, and about 10,000 new truck operators entered the market. Many of the trucking entrants have since dropped out of the industry, as profits and wages were driven down by competition. Almost all of the new airlines also ran into trouble and were sold to the older airlines. Since 1990, however, many small airlines have been launched and several are now the most profitable firms in the industry. A battle is now shaping up over whether the small airlines need special protection from tough competition by the larger airlines. Here it is also pertinent to note that although many of the small entrant airlines have perished, so have a number of very large carriers, including Eastern Airlines, Braniff, Pan Am, and TWA, all of which had once been major enterprises. 4. Effects on Unions Deregulation has badly hurt unions such as the Teamsters (of the trucking industry) and the Airline Pilots Association. In the new, competitive climate, firms have been forced to make sharp cuts in their workforces and to resist wage increases and other costly changes in working conditions. Indeed, there has been strong pressure for retrenchment on all of these fronts. It should not be surprising, then, that unions often oppose deregulation.

5. Effects on Product Quality The public has been unpleasantly surprised by another effect of deregulation. At least in the case of aviation, increased price competition has been accompanied by sharp reductions in “frills.” To cut costs, most airlines have eliminated free meals and limited the number of flights to avoid empty seats—which has increased crowding. To fill planes with more passengers, many airlines turned to “hub-and-spoke” systems (see Figure 2). Instead of running a flight directly from F I GURE 2 a low-demand airport, A, to another low-demand airport, B, the airline flies all A “Hub-and-Spoke” Airline passengers from Airport A to its “hub” at Airport H, where all passengers, from Routing Pattern many points of origin, who are bound for the same destination, Airport B, are brought together and asked to reboard an airplane flying to B. This system clearly E F saves money and gives passengers more options as the number of flights between hubs and spokes increases. At the same time, it is surely less convenient for pasA sengers than a direct flight from origin to destination. Critics of deregulation have placed a good deal of emphasis on the reductions in passenger comfort. Economists, however, argue that competition would not bring such results unless pasH sengers as a group prefer the reduction in fares to the greater standards of luxury that preceded them. B D

C

6. Effects on Safety Also in the case of airline deregulation (though the issue can well arise elsewhere), some observers have been concerned that cost cutting after deregulation would lead to skimping on safety measures. As Figure 3

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

281

Limiting Market Power: Regulation and Antitrust

Chapter 13

FIGU RE 3

2.0

Accidents per 100,000 Departures

1.8 1.6 1.4 All Accidents 1.2 1.0 0.8 Deregulation (1978)

0.6 0.4

Fatal Accidents

0.2 0 1960

1965

1970

1975

1980

1985

1990

1995

2000

NOTE: Accidents resulting from illegal acts, such as suicide or sabotage, are excluded from the National Transportation Safety Board’s accident rate computations.

shows, deregulation seems not to have increased the rate of airline accidents. Even so, deregulation may require special vigilance to guard against neglect of safety as a costcutting measure. In late 2001, this concern led Congress to legislate a government role in protecting the public from terrorist attacks. Some observers suggest that the reduced profits that competition caused in truck transportation has led truckers to cut corners in terms of safety.

7. Effects on Profits and Wages As the previous discussion suggested, deregulation has generally strengthened competition, and the increased power of competition has, in turn, tended to depress profits and wages. There is evidence that few airlines, including the largest carriers, have been able to earn profits as high as those in other competitive industries, on average, since the deregulation of the airlines more than two decades ago. Recent events such as the threat of terrorism and rising fuel prices have brought several large airlines to the brink of bankruptcy. This, of course, is just the other side of reduced prices to consumers. In some cases, the profit and wage cuts were very substantial and had significant consequences. The recent financial problems for airlines and trucking firms have already been noted, and the pressures for decreases in the very high earnings of airline pilots have prompted frequent confrontations between these workers and the airlines. The general conclusion is that deregulation has usually worked out well, but hardly perfectly in promoting the welfare of consumers. Indeed, partial deregulation has sometimes proved to be disastrous, as illustrated by what happened in the electricity industry in California in 2001. There, wholesale prices were deregulated, but tight ceilings were imposed on retail prices. Firms that bought at wholesale and sold at retail incurred great losses when wholesale prices increased, with a brief period of significant power shortages being the predictable result. The battle for deregulation is far from over. Even if those who wish for a return to the good old days of regulation (and there are some) do not succeed, many areas exist in which regulation of the old-time variety still retains its grip or has been reintroduced in disguised form.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

2005

SOURCE: National Transportation Safety Board, http://www.ntsb.gov. Data are for all scheduled service of U.S. airlines operating under 14 CFR 121.

U.S. Airline Accident Rates, 1960–2005

282

Part 3

Markets and the Price System

PUZZLE REVISITED:

WHY REGULATORS OFTEN PUSH PRICES UPWARD

We can now return to the puzzle we posed earlier: Why would regulators, who are supposed to protect the interests of the public, raise prices? The answer is that regulators sometimes push for higher prices when they want to prevent the demise of any existing firms in an industry. Earlier, we saw that strong economies of scale and economies of scope may make it impossible for a number of firms to survive. The largest firm in an industry may have such a big cost advantage over its competitors that it can drive them out of the market while still operating at a profit. Firms that are hurt by such competitive pressures often complain to regulatory commissions that the prices charged by a rival are “unfairly low.” These commissions, afraid that unrestrained pricing will reduce the number of firms in the industry, then attempt to “equalize” matters by imposing price floors (below which prices cannot be set). Such price floors are designed to permit all the firms in the industry to operate profitably, including those that operate inefficiently and incur costs far higher than their competitors’ costs. That is presumably why, under regulation, the New York–Washington, D.C., air fares were so high. Many economists maintain that this approach to pricing is a perversion of the idea of competition. The virtue of competition is that, where it occurs, firms force one another to supply consumers with products of high quality at low prices. Any firm that cannot achieve this goal is driven out of business by market forces. A regulatory arrangement may allow efficient and inefficient firms to coexist only by preventing them from competing with one another, but this arrangement merely preserves the appearance of competition while destroying its substance, and it forces consumers to pay the higher prices necessary to keep the inefficient firms alive.

CONCLUDING OBSERVATIONS As we noted at the beginning of this chapter, monopoly and monopoly power are rightly judged to cause market failure—they prevent the market from serving consumer interests most effectively by providing the products the public desires at the lowest possible prices. The alternative is government intervention, and governments, too, sometimes make imperfect decisions. Thus, before deciding whether to regulate more or deregulate, whether to toughen antitrust laws or loosen them, informed citizens should carefully weigh the prospects for market failure against the possibility of government failure in terms of the contemplated change. Certainly, monopolists have sometimes succeeded in preventing the introduction of useful new products. They have raised prices to consumers and held down product quality. In contrast, large firms have sometimes been innovative and their service to customers has been considered of high quality. Government has suffered its own missteps. It has initiated costly lawsuits, sometimes on questionable grounds. It has forced regulated firms to adopt pricing rules that were clearly not beneficial to consumers, and it has handicapped the operations of industries— for example, arguably for a time almost destroying the nation’s railroads. Yet government, too, has done useful things in influencing industry behavior, preventing various monopolistic practices, protecting consumers from impure foods and medications, and so on. Most economists believe that by the 1970s government intervention had clearly gone too far in some respects and that deregulation was, consequently, in the public interest. However, the general issue is hardly settled.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

283

Limiting Market Power: Regulation and Antitrust

Chapter 13

| SUMMARY | 1. Antitrust policy includes those policies and programs designed to control the growth of monopoly and to prevent big business from engaging in “anticompetitive” practices.

8. In the United States, regulation of prices and other economic decisions is generally applied only to large firms, including railroads, telecommunications, and gas and electricity suppliers.

2. Predatory pricing is pricing that is low relative to the marginal or average variable costs of the firm and so threatens to drive a competitor out of the market. For pricing to be considered predatory, there must also be a likelihood that if the prices do destroy a competitor, the firm will acquire market power enabling it to charge prices well above competitive levels.

9. In recent years, we have seen a major push toward reduction of regulation. Among the industries that have been deregulated in whole or in part are air, truck, and rail transportation.

3. Bundling refers to a price reduction given to customers who purchase several of the firm’s products simultaneously. It is considered unobjectionable if it is cheaper for the firm to bundle its products so that the price cut merely passes the savings on to customers. However, bundling can be used to destroy competitors that sell only some of the bundled products. 4. The evidence indicates that no significant increase in the concentration of individual U.S. industries into fewer, relatively larger firms occurred during the twentieth century. Evidence as to whether antitrust laws have been effective in preventing monopoly is inconclusive, and observers disagree on the subject. 5. Unregulated monopoly is apt to distribute income unfairly, produce undesirably small quantities of output, and provide inadequate motivation for innovation. 6. Sometimes, however, only large firms may have funds sufficient for effective research, development, and innovation. Where economies of scale are available, large firms may also serve customers more cheaply than can small ones. 7. Economic regulation is adopted to put brakes on the decisions of industries with monopoly power.

10. Among the major reasons given for regulation are (a) economies of scale and economies of scope, which make industries into natural monopolies, and (b) the universal service goal, which refers to the provision of service to poor people and isolated areas where supply is unprofitable. 11. Regulators often reject proposals by regulated firms to cut their prices, and sometimes the regulators even force firms to raise their prices. The purposes of such actions are to prevent “unfair competition” and to protect customers of some of the firm’s products from being forced to cross-subsidize customers of other products. Many economists disagree with most such actions, arguing that the result is usually to stifle competition and make all customers pay more than they otherwise would. 12. Economists generally agree that a firm should be permitted to cut its price as long as it covers its marginal cost. However, in many regulated industries, firms would go bankrupt if all prices were set equal to marginal costs. 13. By putting ceilings on profits to prevent monopoly earnings, regulation can eliminate the firm’s incentive for efficiency and innovation. Price caps, which put (inflation-adjusted) ceilings on prices, rather than profits, are used widely to deal with this problem.

| KEY TERMS | antitrust policy

265

bundling 271 concentration of an industry concentration ratios

267

267

cross-subsidization

275

monopoly power

264

economies of scale

264

predatory pricing

270

economies of scope

price cap

274

Herfindahl-Hirschman Index (HHI)

267

regulation

278 273

| DISCUSSION QUESTIONS | 1. Why is an electric company in a city often considered to be a natural monopoly? What would happen if two competing electric companies were established? How about telephone companies? How can changes in technology affect your answer? 2. Suppose that a 20 percent cut in the price of coastto-coast telephone calls brings in so much new business that it permits a long-distance telephone company to cut

its charges for service from Chicago to St. Louis, but only by 2 percent. In your opinion, is this practice equitable? Is it a good idea or a bad one? 3. In some regulated industries, regulatory agencies prevented prices from falling, and as a result many firms opened for business in those industries. In your opinion, is this kind of regulation competitive or anticompetitive? Is it a good idea or a bad one?

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

284

Part 3

Markets and the Price System

4. Regulators are highly concerned about the prevention of “predatory pricing.” The U.S. Court of Appeals has, however, noted that “the term probably does not have a well-defined meaning, but it certainly bears a sinister connotation.” How might one distinguish “predatory” from “nonpredatory” pricing? What would you do about it? 5. Do you think that it is fair or unfair for rural users of telephone service to be cross-subsidized by other telephone users? 6. To provide incentives for increased efficiency, several regulatory agencies have eliminated ceilings on the profits of regulated firms but instead put caps on their prices. Suppose that a regulated firm manages to cut its prices in half, but in the process it doubles its profits. Should rational consumers consider this to be a good or a bad development? Why? 7. A shopkeeper sells his store and signs a contract that restrains him from opening another store in competition with the new owner. The courts have decided that this contract is a reasonable restraint of trade. Can you think of any other types of restraint of trade that seem reasonable? Can you think of any that seem unreasonable? 8. Which of the following industries do you expect to have high concentration ratios: automobile production, aircraft manufacture, hardware production, pharmaceuticals, production of expensive jewelry? Compare your answers with the data in Table 2.

9. Why do you think the specific industries you selected in Discussion Question 8 are highly concentrated? 10. Do you think it is in the public interest to launch an antitrust suit that costs $1 billion? What leads you to your conclusion? 11. In Japan and a number of European countries, the antitrust laws were once much less severe than those in the United States. Do you think that this difference helped or harmed American industry in its efforts to compete with foreign producers? Why? 12. Can you think of some legal rules that may discourage the use of antitrust laws to prevent competition while at the same time not interfering with legitimate antitrust actions? 13. During the oil crisis in the 1970s, long lines at gas stations disappeared soon after price controls were removed and gas prices were permitted to rise. Should this event be interpreted as evidence that the oil companies have monopoly power? Why or why not? 14. Some economists believe that firms rarely attempt predatory pricing because it would be a very risky act even if it were legal. Why may this be so? 15. Firm X cuts its prices, and competing Firm Y soon goes out of business. How would you judge whether this price cut was an act of legitimate and vigorous competition or an anticompetitive act?

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Part

The Virtues and Limitations of Markets

T

his book is not a piece of propaganda. And so we recognize that, like most institutions, the market has both shortcomings and benefits, and one of our goals is to describe them both as dispassionately as we can. Chapter 14 describes and analyzes a snapshot picture of the market at its best, showing how remarkably well it can coordinate the vast number of activities and decisions that drive our economy. The next chapter, in contrast, investigates some of the important ways in which the market mechanism, if left entirely to itself, fails to serve the public interest well. In Chapter 15 as well as in Chapter 17, we examine what can be done to remedy these deficiencies—or at least to reduce their undesirable consequences. In Chapter 16, the growth chapter, we depict the economy in motion. There we will see the most incredible of all the accomplishments of the market economy in its ability to bring remarkable increases in standards of living and innovative products that could hardly have been imagined by our ancestors. In short, as Chapter 16 will demonstrate and begin to explain, the growth performance of the market has totally outstripped that of any economy in previous history. Finally, Chapter 18 introduces you to the tax system and the effects of the government on resource allocation in the market economy.

C H A P T E R S 14 | The Case for Free Markets I: The Price System

15 | The Shortcomings of Free Markets

16 | The Market’s Prime

17 | Externalities, the

Environment, and Natural Resources

18 | Taxation and Resource Allocation

Achievement: Innovation and Growth

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

The Case for Free Markets I: The Price System If there existed the universal mind that . . . would register simultaneously all the processes of nature and of society, that could forecast the results of their inter-reactions, such a mind . . . could . . . draw up a faultless and an exhaustive economic plan. . . . In truth, the bureaucracy often conceives that just such a mind is at its disposal; that is why it so easily frees itself from the control of the market. L EON TROTSKY, A L EADER OF THE RU S SI AN REVOLU TI ON

O

ur study of microeconomics focuses on two crucial questions: What does the market do well, and what does it do poorly? By applying what we learned about demand in Chapters 5 and 6, supply in Chapters 7 and 8, and the functioning of perfectly competitive markets in Chapter 10, we can provide a fairly comprehensive answer to the first part of this question. This chapter describes major tasks that the market carries out well—some, indeed, with spectacular effectiveness. We begin by recalling two important themes from Chapters 3 and 4. First, because all resources are scarce, a society benefits by using them efficiently. Second, to do so, an economy must somehow coordinate the actions of many individual consumers and producers. Specifically, society must somehow choose • How much of each good to produce • What input quantities to use in the production process of each commodity • How to distribute the resulting outputs among consumers

C O N T E N T S PUZZLE: CROSSING THE SAN FRANCISCO–OAKLAND BAY BRIDGE: IS THE PRICE RIGHT?

EFFICIENT RESOURCE ALLOCATION AND PRICING Pricing to Promote Efficiency: An Example Can Price Increases Ever Serve the Public Interest?

SCARCITY AND THE NEED TO COORDINATE ECONOMIC DECISIONS

Input-Output Analysis: The Near Impossibility of Perfect Central Planning Which Buyers and Which Sellers Get Priority?

HOW PERFECT COMPETITION ACHIEVES EFFICIENCY: A GRAPHIC ANALYSIS HOW PERFECT COMPETITION ACHIEVES OPTIMAL OUTPUT: MARGINAL ANALYSIS The Invisible Hand at Work

Other Roles of Prices: Income Distribution and Fairness Yet Another Free-Market Achievement: Growth versus Efficiency

PUZZLE RESOLVED: SAN FRANCISCO BRIDGE PRICING REVISITED

TOWARD ASSESSMENT OF THE PRICE MECHANISM

Three Coordination Tasks in the Economy

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

288

Part 4

The Virtues and Limitations of Markets

As suggested by the opening quotation (from someone who was certainly in a position to know), these tasks are exceedingly difficult for a centrally planned economy. That overwhelming difficulty surely contributed to the fall of communism in the late 1980s, and the same difficulty shows up in the few remaining centrally planned economies, such as North Korea and Cuba. But, for the most part, those same tasks appear to be rather simple for a market system. This is why observers with philosophies as diverse as those of Adam Smith and the Russian Revolution’s Leon Trotsky have admired the market, and why even countries that maintain very strong central governments have now moved toward market economies. Do not misinterpret this chapter as a piece of salesmanship. Here, we study the market mechanism at its theoretical very best—when every good is produced under the exacting conditions of perfect competition. Some industries in our economy are reasonable approximations of perfect competition, but many others are as different from this idealized world as the physical world is from a frictionless vacuum tube. Just as the physicist uses the vacuum tube to study the laws of gravity, the economist uses the theoretical concept of a perfectly competitive economy to analyze the virtues of the market. We will spend plenty of time in later chapters studying its vices.

CROSSING THE SAN FRANCISCO–OAKLAND BAY BRIDGE: IS THE PRICE RIGHT?

In California, the San Francisco–Oakland Bay Bridge is very heavily traveled. The large volume of toll-paying traffic has probably long since paid for the cost of building this bridge, although that is less likely for the nearby San Mateo–Hayward and Dumbarton bridges, which are less crowded. Yet economists argue that the price charged to use the San Francisco–Oakland Bay Bridge should be higher than the prices charged for use of the other two bridges. Why does that make sense? Before you have finished reading this chapter, you may even agree with this seemingly unfair proposition.

SOURCE: © Roger Allyn Lee/SuperStock

PUZZLE:

EFFICIENT RESOURCE ALLOCATION AND PRICING

An efficient allocation of resources is one that takes advantage of every opportunity to make some individuals better off in their own estimation while not worsening the lot of anyone else.

The fundamental fact that inputs are scarce means that there are limits to the volume of goods and services that any economic system can produce. In Chapter 3 we illustrated the concept of scarcity with a graphic device called a production possibilities frontier, which we repeat here for convenience as Figure 1. The frontier, curve BC, depicts all combinations of motorboats and milk that a hypothetical society can produce given the limited resources at its disposal. For example, if it decides to produce 300 motorboats, it will have enough resources left over to produce no more than 500 billion quarts of milk (point D). Of course, it is possible, then, to produce fewer than 500 billion quarts of milk—at a point, such as G, below the production possibilities frontier. But if a society makes this choice, it is wasting some of its potential output; that is, it is not operating efficiently, as will be explained presently. In Chapter 3 we defined efficiency rather loosely as the absence of waste. Because this chapter discusses primarily how a competitive market economy allocates resources efficiently, we now need a more precise definition. It is easiest to define an efficient allocation of resources by saying what it is not. For example, suppose that we could rearrange our resource allocation so that one group of people would get more of the things it wanted while no one else would have to give up anything. Then, the failure to change the allocation of resources to take advantage of this so far as yet unused opportunity would surely be wasteful—that is, inefficient. When society has taken advantage of every such opportunity for improvement, so that no such possibilities remain for making some people better off without making others worse off, we say that the allocation of resources is efficient.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

289

The Case for Free Markets I: The Price System

To see what this implies for our analysis, let us see what an inefficient set of output quantities looks like in our graph. Because point G in Figure 1 is below the frontier, there must be points like E on the frontier that lie above and to the right of G. At point E, we get more of both outputs without any increase in the available input supply, so it is possible to make some people better off without harming anyone. Thus, no point below the frontier can represent an efficient allocation of resources. By contrast, every point on the frontier is efficient because, no matter where on the frontier we start, we cannot get more of one good (by putting more of the available inputs into production of that item) without taking away those input quantities for, and so thereby giving up some of, the other. This discussion also shows that, normally, many particular allocations of resources will be efficient; in the example, every combination of outputs that is represented by a point on frontier BC can be efficient. As a rule, the concept of efficiency cannot tell us which of these efficient allocations is best for society. Yet, as we shall see in this chapter, we can use the concept of efficiency to formulate surprisingly detailed rules to steer us away from situations in which resources would be wasted.

700 B 600 Billions of Quarts of Milk

Chapter 14

D

500

400

E G

300 200

F

100

0

C 100

200

300

400

500

Motor Boats

FIGURE 1

Pricing to Promote Efficiency: An Example

Production Possibilities Frontier and Efficiency

San Francisco

Berkeley

Oakland

80

San Francisco– Oakland Bay Bridge Fr

17

an ci

sc

o

101

San Mateo–Hayward Bridge

92

92

B

a

Fremont

Dumbarton Bridge

84

Oc ea

B

n

Let’s consider which of these three choices uses society’s resources— commuter time, gasoline, and so on—most efficiently. The San Francisco–Oakland Bay Bridge is by far the most crowded of the five bridges, carrying approximately 254,000 vehicles per day, followed by the Golden Gate Bridge, which carries about 107,000 per day. The San Mateo–Hayward, Dumbarton, and Richmond–San Rafael bridges carry approximately 92,000, 64,000, and 71,000 vehicles per day, respectively.1

Bridge 101

Pacific

Route 1: Over the Richmond–San Rafael Bridge, across the Golden Gate Bridge, through San Francisco, and on southward via Highway 101 Route 2: Across the bay on the San Francisco–Oakland Bay Bridge and on southward via Highway 101, as before Route 3: Down the eastern shore of the bay, across the San Mateo–Hayward Bridge or the Dumbarton Bridge, and then on to Palo Alto (shown in blue in Figure 2)

San

We can use the real example in our opening puzzle about the San Francisco–Oakland Bay Bridge to illustrate the connection between efficiency and the way prices can guide efficient choices. Prices can make all the difference between efficiency and inefficiency FIGURE 2 by guiding the actions of both suppliers and their customers. We will see now that the Toll Bridges of the San prices (tolls) California transportation authorities charge drivers to use San Francisco Bay Area Francisco Bay area bridges can save some of the time that the drivers spend commuting—that is, they can make the commuting process more efficient. San Pablo We also will see that people may well reject the efficient solution with perBay San haps reasonable grounds for doing so. Rafael Richmond– San Rafael Figure 2 shows a map of the San Francisco Bay area, featuring the five Bridge 17 bridges that serve most of the traffic in and around the bay. A traveler going from a location north of Berkeley (point A) to Palo Alto (point B) can Golden A choose among at least three routes: Gate

Palo Alto

Traffic volume for the Golden Gate Bridge is a daily average for the period between July 2007 and June 2008 (accessed online at: http://goldengatebridge.org/research/crossings_revenues.php). Traffic volumes for the four other Bay area bridges are estimates based on one-way vehicle counts for October 21, 2009 (provided by the Bay Area Toll Authority’s Public Information Office).

1

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

84

290

Part 4

The Virtues and Limitations of Markets

To achieve efficiency, any driver who is indifferent about the two routes should take the one using the least crowded bridges. This would help reduce the amount of travel time wasted by the population as a whole. Specifically, in our illustration, Route 1, using the Golden Gate Bridge, is not a socially desirable way for our driver to get to Palo Alto because it adds too many miles to the trip and because it requires two bridge crossings. Route 2, with its use of the San Francisco–Oakland Bay Bridge, is even worse because of the added delays it causes for everyone else. Route 3, for drivers who are indifferent about these options, is the best choice from the viewpoint of the public interest. This does not mean that it is socially efficient to equalize the traffic among the routes, but it certainly would help travelers get where they are going more quickly if transportation authorities could induce some drivers (those who care least about which of the routes they take) to leave the most crowded routes and switch over to some less crowded ones. Appropriate prices can promote this sort of efficiency in bridge utilization. Specifically, if higher prices (very likely substantially higher prices) were charged for drivers to cross the most crowded bridges (on which space is a scarce resource), balanced by lower prices on the uncrowded bridges, then more drivers could be induced to use the uncrowded bridges. This is the same reasoning that leads economists to advocate low prices for abundant natural resources and high prices for scarce ones.

Can Price Increases Ever Serve the Public Interest? This discussion raises a point that people untrained in economics always find extremely difficult to accept: Low prices may not always serve the public interest! The reason is pretty clear. If a price, such as the toll charged for crossing a crowded bridge or the price of gasoline, is set “too low,” then consumers will receive the “wrong” market signals. Low prices will encourage them to crowd the bridge even more or to consume more gasoline, thereby squandering society’s scarce resources and contributing to the global warming threat. A striking historical illustration brings out the importance of this role of prices. In 1834, University of Dublin economics professor, Mountifort Longfield, lectured about the price system. He offered the following example: Suppose the crop of potatoes in Ireland was to fall short in some year [by] one-sixth of the usual consumption. If [there were no] increase of price, the whole . . . supply of the year would be exhausted in ten months, and for the remaining two months a scene of misery and famine beyond description would ensue. . . . But when prices [increase] the sufferers [often believe] that it is not caused by scarcity. . . . They suppose that there are provisions enough, but that the distress is caused by the insatiable rapacity of the possessors . . . [and] they have generally succeeded in obtaining laws against [the price increases] . . . which alone can prevent the provisions from being entirely consumed long before a new supply can be obtained.2 You may be intrigued to know that this talk was given some 10 years before the great potato famine, which caused unspeakable misery and death by starvation and brought many people from Ireland to the United States. The story of the actual potato famine in Ireland is much more complex than Longfield’s discussion indicates. Still, the implications of his lecture about the way the price system works are entirely valid. We can perhaps rephrase Longfield’s reasoning more usefully. If the crop fails, potatoes become scarcer. If society is to use its scarce resources efficiently, stretching out the potato supply to last until the next crop arrives, it must cut back on the consumption of potatoes during earlier months—which is just what rising prices will do automatically if free-market mechanisms are allowed to work. However, if the price is held artificially low, consumers will use society’s resources inefficiently. In this case, the inefficiency shows up in the form of famine and suffering when people deplete this year’s crop months before the next one is harvested.

Mountifort Longfield, Lectures on Political Economy Delivered in Trinity and Michaelmas Terms (Dublin: W. Curry, Jr., and Company; 1834), pp. 53–56.

2

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 14

291

The Case for Free Markets I: The Price System

“91 Express Lanes” is a four-lane, 10-mile toll road built in the median of California’s crowded Riverside Freeway (State Road 91). Opened in 1995, it was the first variable-priced and fully automated highway in the United States. By varying the price that drivers must pay to use these lanes, the traffic authorities control the congestion on the road and keep the traffic moving. For example, tolls in October 2009 ranged from $1.30 at the most uncongested times (like 3 o’clock in the morning) all the way up to $9.90 during the worst of the rush hour. Faced with high tolls during commuting hours, some drivers choose not to use the lanes at that time. Since 1995, the lanes have saved more than 32 million hours of commuting time. The Orange County Transportation Authority estimates that these time savings are worth $480 million in added economic productivity and quality-of-life benefits. SOURCE: Orange County Transportation Authority, http://www.91expresslanes.com/ learnabout/snapshot.asp.

SOURCE: © Courtesy of the Orange Country Transportation Authority

Using Economic Principles to Reduce Highway Congestion in Orange County, California

It is not easy to accept the notion that higher prices can serve the public interest better than lower ones. Politicians who voice this view are in the position of the proverbial parent who, before spanking a child, announces, “This is going to hurt me much more than it hurts you!” Because advocacy of higher prices courts political disaster, the political system often rejects the market’s increased price solution when resources suddenly become scarcer. The way that airport officials price landing privileges at crowded airports offers a good example. Airports become particularly congested at “peak hours,” just before 9 A.M. and just after 5 P.M. These times are when passengers most often suffer long delays. But many airports continue to charge bargain landing fees throughout the day, even at those crowded hours. That makes it attractive for small corporate jets or other planes carrying only a few passengers to arrive and take off at those hours, worsening the delays. Higher fees for peak-hour landings can discourage such overuse, but they are politically unpopular, and many airports are run by local governments. So we continue to experience late arrivals as a normal feature of air travel. (See “Using Economic Principles to Reduce Highway Congestion in Orange County, California” above for a successful example of pricing to reduce congestion.) ATTEMPTS TO REPEAL THE LAWS OF SUPPLY AND DEMAND: THE MARKET STRIKES BACK As we saw in our list of Ideas for Beyond the Final Exam, keeping prices low when an increase is appropriate can have serious consequences. We have just observed that it can worsen the effects of shortages of food and other vital goods. We know that inappropriately low prices caused nationwide chaos in gasoline distribution after the sudden decline in Iranian oil exports in 1979. In times of war, constraints on prices have even contributed to the surrender of cities under military siege, deterring those who would otherwise have risked smuggling food supplies through enemy lines. Low prices also have discouraged housing construction in cities where government-imposed upper limits on rents made building construction a losing proposition. Of course, in some cases it is appropriate to resist price increases—when unrestrained monopoly would otherwise succeed in gouging the public, when taxes are imposed on products capriciously and inappropriately, and when rising prices fall so heavily on poor people that rationing becomes the more acceptable option. Before tampering with the market mechanism we must carefully evaluate the potentially serious and even tragic consequences that artificial restrictions on prices can produce.

IDEAS FOR BEYOND THE FINAL EXAM

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

292

Part 4

The Virtues and Limitations of Markets

SCARCITY AND THE NEED TO COORDINATE ECONOMIC DECISIONS

SOURCE: © The New Yorker Collection 1992 Dana Fradon from cartoonbank.com. All Rights Reserved.

Efficiency becomes a particularly critical issue when we concern ourselves with the workings of the economy as a whole, rather than with narrower topics such as choosing among bridge routes or deciding on the output of a single firm. We can think of an economy as a complex machine with literally millions of component parts. If this machine is to function efficiently, we must find some way to make the parts work in harmony. A consumer in Madison, Wisconsin, may decide to purchase two dozen eggs, and on the same day thousands of shoppers throughout the country may make similar decisions. None of these purchasers knows or cares about the decisions of the others. Yet scarcity requires that these demands must somehow be coordinated with the production process so that the total quantity of eggs demanded does not exceed the total quantity supplied. Consumers, supermarkets, wholesalers, shippers, and chicken farmers must somehow arrive at mutually consistent decisions, in this case with an increase in egg supplies or a decrease in demand for them; otherwise, the economic process will deteriorate into chaos, as will millions of other such decisions. A machine cannot run with a few missing parts. In a planned or centrally directed economy, we can easily imagine how such coordination takes place—though implementation is far more difficult than conception. Central planners set production targets for firms and sometimes tell firms how to meet these targets. In extreme cases, consumers may even be told, rather than asked, what they are allowed to consume. In contrast, a market system uses prices to coordinate economic activity. High prices discourage consumption of the scarcest resources and, where possible, induce expansion of their supplies, whereas low prices discourage consumption of comparatively abundant resources. In this way, Adam Smith’s invisible hand uses prices to organize the economy’s production. The invisible hand has an astonishing capacity to handle enormously complex coordination problems— even those that remain beyond computer capabilities. Like any mechanism, this one has its imperfections, some of them rather serious. But we should not lose sight of the tremendously demanding task that the market constantly does accomplish—unnoticed, undirected, and, in some respects, amazingly well. Let’s look at just how the market goes about coordinating economic activity.

“Corporate leaders gather in a field outside Darien, Connecticut, where one of them claims to have seen the invisible hand of the marketplace.”

Three Coordination Tasks in the Economy We recalled at the beginning of this chapter that any economic system, planned or unplanned, must find answers to three basic questions of resource allocation:

• Output selection. How much of each commodity should be produced, given limited supplies of the needed input resources? • Production planning. What quantity of each of the available inputs should be used to produce each good? • Distribution. How should the resulting products be divided among consumers? These coordination tasks may at first appear to be tailor-made for a regime of government planning like the one that the former Soviet Union once employed. Yet most economists (even, nowadays, those in the formerly centrally planned economies) believe that it is in exactly these tasks that central direction performs most poorly and, paradoxically, the undisciplined free market performs best, even though no one directs its overall activities. Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 14

293

The Case for Free Markets I: The Price System

To understand how the unplanned and unguided market manages the miracle of creating order out of what might otherwise be chaos, let’s look at how each of these questions is answered by a system of free and unfettered markets—the method of economic organization that eighteenth-century French economists named laissez-faire. Under laissezfaire, the government acts to prevent crime, enforce contracts, and build roads and other types of public works; it does not set prices, however, and interferes as little as possible with the operation of free markets. How does such an economy, though unmanaged and unguided by anyone, solve the three coordination problems?

Output Selection A free-market system decides what should be produced via what we have called the “law” of supply and demand. Where there is a shortage (that is, where quantity demanded exceeds quantity supplied), the market mechanism pushes the price upward, thereby encouraging more production and less consumption of the commodity in short supply. Where a surplus arises (that is, where quantity supplied exceeds quantity demanded), the same mechanism works in reverse: the price falls, discouraging production and stimulating consumption. As an example, suppose that millions of people wake up one morning with a change in taste and thereafter want more omelets. As a result, for the moment, the quantity of eggs demanded exceeds the quantity supplied, but within a few days, the market mechanism swings into action to meet this sudden change in demand. The price of eggs rises, which stimulates egg production. At first, farmers will simply bring more eggs to market by taking them out of storage. Over a somewhat longer time period, chickens that otherwise would have been sold for meat will be kept in the chicken coops laying eggs. Finally, if the high price of eggs persists, farmers will begin to increase their flocks, build more coops, and so on. Thus, a shift in consumer demand leads to a shift in society’s resources; more eggs are wanted, so the market mechanism sees to it that more of society’s resources are devoted to egg production and marketing. Similar reactions follow if a technological breakthrough reduces the input quantities needed to produce an item. Electronic calculators are a marvelous example. Calculators used to be so expensive that they could be found only in business firms and scientific laboratories. Then advances in science and engineering reduced their cost dramatically, and the market went to work. With costs sharply reduced, prices fell and the quantity demanded skyrocketed. Electronics firms flocked into the industry to meet this demand, which is to say that more of society’s resources were devoted to producing the calculators that were suddenly in such great demand. These examples lead us to conclude that:

Laissez-faire refers to a situation in which there is minimal government interference with the workings of the market system. The term implies that people should be left alone in carrying out their economic affairs.

Under laissez-faire, the allocation of society’s resources among different products depends on consumer preferences (demands) and the production costs of the goods demanded. Prices (and the resulting profitability of the different products) vary so as to bring the quantity of each commodity produced into line with the quantity demanded.

Notice that no bureaucrat or central planner arranges resource allocation. Instead, an unseen force guides allocation—the lure of profits, which is the invisible hand that guides chicken farmers to increase their flocks when eggs are in greater demand and guides electronics firms to build new factories when the cost of electronic products falls.

Production Planning Once the market has decided on output composition, the next coordination task is to determine just how those goods will be produced. The productionplanning problem includes, among other things, the division of society’s scarce inputs among enterprises. Which farm or factory will get how much of which materials? How much of the nation’s labor force? Of the produced inputs such as plant and machinery? Such decisions can be crucial. If a factory runs short of an essential input, the entire production process may grind to a halt. In reality, no economic system can select inputs and outputs separately. The input distribution between the production of cars and the manufacture of washing machines determines the quantities of cars and washing machines that society can obtain. However, it is simpler to think of input and output decisions as if they occur one at a time. Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

294

Part 4

The Virtues and Limitations of Markets

Poland’s Transition to a Free-Market Economy than that of other European Union member countries. Poland’s GDP per capita also varies significantly from region to region, and the gap between the country’s large urban centers and rural areas has increased steadily since the mid-1990s. As of 2005, GDP per capita in Warsaw was more than 2.5 times greater than the national average. Meanwhile, privatization continues slowly. Competition has increased in Poland’s telecommunications industry, but major selloffs of formerly state-controlled power suppliers have been delayed, and the country’s two major banking and insurance entities remain state-owned. Despite all of the good news, Poland still has much work to do.

SOURCE: © Raymond Gehman/CORBIS

SOURCES: Rudolf Herman, “Rural Poland: Ready for the Chop,” Central European Review, 1, no. 10 (August 1999); Stanislaw Gomulka, “Macroeconomic Policies and Achievements in Transition Economies, 1989–1999,” United Nations’ Economic Commission for Europe Annual Seminar, Geneva (May 2, 2000); Michael P. Keane and Eswar S. Prasad, “Poland: Inequality, Transfers, and Growth in Transition,” Finance & Development, 38, no. 1 (March 2001); Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD), OECD Territorial Reviews: Poland (Paris, OECD, 2008, accessed online at: http://www.oecd.org); and OECD, Policy Brief: Regional Development (Paris: OECD, November 2008, accessed online at: http://www.oecd.org).

SOURCE: © GROCHOWIAK EWA/CORBIS SYGMA

Nearly 20 years have passed since communism collapsed all over Eastern Europe and the former Soviet Union, ending economic central planning and heralding the emergence of a free market in these countries. Nowhere were these changes as dramatic as in Poland, where radical economic reforms constituted no less than “shock therapy.” Poland’s transformation into a market economy, though far from complete, has been nearly as drastic as the first post-communist government hoped. Poland had been saddled with a legendarily incompetent, old-fashioned, and badly managed economy, which in its depths managed to run out of things like matches and salt, its paltry living standards bequeathed by a centrally controlled economy. It reached out to the West for help in creating monetary, budget, trade, and legal regimes and is now one of the most robust economies in central Europe and, most recently, one of the newest members of the European Union. Poland’s economy has been growing at an impressive rate. Its average annual GDP grew by more than 4 percent between 1995 and 2005. But despite strong growth and lower unemployment (14 percent in 2006, down from rates as high as 50 percent following the collapse of communism), Poland’s GDP per capita remains much lower

Once again, under laissez-faire it is the price system that apportions labor, fuel, and other inputs among different industries in accord with those industries’ requirements. The firm that needs a piece of equipment most urgently will be the last to drop out of the market for that product when prices rise. If millers demand more wheat than is currently available, the price will rise and bring quantity demanded back into line with quantity supplied, always giving priority to those users who are willing to pay the most for grain because it is most valuable to them. Thus: In a free market, inputs are assigned to the firms that can make the most productive (most profitable) use of them. Firms that cannot make a sufficiently productive use of some input will be priced out of the market for that item.

This task, which sounds so simple, is actually almost unimaginably complex. It is so complex that it has helped to bring down many centrally planned systems because they could not handle the difficulties. We will return to this shortly, as an illustration of how difficult it is to replace the market by a central planning bureau, but first let us consider the third of our three coordination problems.

Distribution of Products among Consumers The third task of any economy is to decide what consumer gets which of the goods that has been produced. The objective is to Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 14

295

The Case for Free Markets I: The Price System

distribute the available supplies to match differing consumer preferences as well as possible. The price mechanism solves this problem by assigning the highest prices to the goods in greatest demand and then letting individual consumers pursue their own selfinterests. Consider our example of rising egg prices. As eggs become more expensive, people whose craving for omelets is not terribly strong will begin to buy fewer eggs. In effect, the price acts as a rationing device that apportions the available eggs among consumers who are willing to pay the most for them. Thus, the price mechanism has an important advantage over other rationing devices: It can respond to individual consumer preferences. If a centrally planned economy rations eggs by distributing the same amount to everyone (say, two eggs per week to each person), then everyone ends up with two eggs whether he likes eggs or detests them. The price system, on the other hand, permits each consumer to set his own priorities. Thus: THE TRADE-OFF BETWEEN EFFICIENCY AND EQUALITY The price system carries out the distribution process by rationing goods on the basis of preferences and relative incomes. Notice the last three words of the previous sentence. The price system does favor the rich, and this is a problem to which market economies must face up. However, we may still want to think twice before declaring ourselves opposed to the price system. If equality is our goal, might not a more reasonable solution be to use the tax system to equalize incomes and then let the market mechanism distribute goods in accord with preferences? We take this idea up in Chapter 18, in which we discuss tax policy.

IDEAS FOR BEYOND THE FINAL EXAM

We have just seen, in broad outline, how a laissez-faire economy addresses the three basic issues of resource allocation: what to produce, how to produce it, and how to distribute the resulting products. Because it performs these tasks without central direction and with no apparent concern for the public interest, many radical critics have predicted that such an unplanned system must degenerate into chaos. Yet unplanned, free-market economies are far from chaotic. Quite ironically, it is the centrally planned economies that have often ended up in economic disarray, whereas the invisible hand seems to go about its business seamlessly. Perhaps the best way to appreciate the free market’s accomplishments is to consider how a centrally planned system must cope with the coordination problems we have just outlined. Let us examine just one of them: production planning.

Input-Output Analysis: The Near Impossibility of Perfect Central Planning Of the three coordination tasks of any economy, the assignment of input to specific industries and firms has claimed the most attention of central planners. Why? Because the production processes of the various industries are interdependent. Industry X cannot operate without Industry Y’s output, but Industry Y, in turn, needs Industry X’s product. The metal supplying industry needs railroads, but the railroads cannot operate without metal for rails and other equipment. The output decisions of the two industries cannot escape this (nonvicious) circle. The entire economy can grind to a halt if planners do not solve such production-planning problems satisfactorily. Failure to adapt to this kind of interdependence has had dire consequences in North Korea, one of the last remaining centrally planned economies. Breakdowns of key economic activities such as the electric supply grid, transportation systems, and other basic industries have each exacerbated the others’ failures and created a terrible cycle of economic disaster that contributed to a severe famine in the late 1990s, which killed as many as 2 million people. Hunger continues to be a problem, with an estimated 37 percent of North Koreans still receiving food assistance.3 A simple example will further illustrate the point. Unless economic planners allocate enough gasoline to the trucking industry, products will not get to market. And unless planners allocate enough trucks to haul gasoline to gas stations, drivers will have no fuel. Thus, trucking activity depends on gasoline supply, but gasoline supply also depends on “Life Expectancy Plummets, North Korea Says,” The New York Times, May 16, 2001, http://www.nytimes.com; and “At the Heart of North Korea’s Troubles an Intractable Hunger Crisis,” The Washington Post, March 6, 2009, http://www.washingtonpost.com.

3

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

296

Part 4

The Virtues and Limitations of Markets

Input-Output Equations: An Example These are typical equations in an input-output analysis. In practice, however, such an analysis has dozens and sometimes hundreds of equations with similar numbers of unknowns. This, then, is the logic of input-output analysis.

E 2 0.2S 2 0.3C 5 15 The planner will also need such an equation for each of the two other industries, specifying for each of them the net amount intended to be left for consumers after the industrial uses of the product. The full set of equations will then be similar to the following:

E 2 0.2S 2 0.3C 5 15 S 2 0.1E 2 0.06C 5 7 C 2 0.15E 2 0.4S 5 10

SOURCE: © Steve Allen/Brand X Picture/Jupiterimages

Imagine an economy with only three outputs: electricity, steel, and coal. Let E, S, and C represent the respective dollar values of these outputs. Suppose that to produce every dollar’s worth of steel, $0.20 worth of electricity is used, so that the total electricity demand of steel manufacturers is 0.2S. Similarly, assume that coal manufacturers use $0.30 of electricity in producing $1 worth of coal, or a total of 0.3C units of electricity. Because E dollars of electricity are produced in total, the amount left over for consumers, after subtracting industrial demands for fuel, will be E (available electricity) minus 0.2S (used in steel production) minus 0.3C (used in coal production). Suppose further that the central planners have decided to supply $15 million worth of electricity to consumers. We end up with the electricity output equation:

trucking activity. We see again that the decision maker is caught in a circle. Planners must decide both truck and gasoline outputs together, not separately. Because the output required from any one industry depends on outputs from many other industries, planners can be sure that the production of the various outputs will be sufficient to meet both consumer and industrial demands only by taking explicit account of this interdependence among industries. If they change the output target for one industry, they must also adjust the targets for many other industries. But those changes in turn are likely to require readjustment of the first target change that started it all, leading to still more target change requirements, and so on, indefinitely.

Input-output analysis is a mathematical procedure that takes account of the interdependence among the economy’s industries and determines the amount of output each industry must provide as inputs to the other industries in the economy.

For example, if planners decide to provide consumers with more electricity, then more steel must be produced in order to build more electric generators. Of course, an increase in steel output requires that more iron ore be mined. More mining, in turn, means that still more electricity is needed to light the mines, run the elevators, perhaps operate some of the trains that carry the iron ore, and so on. Any single change in production triggers a chain of adjustments throughout the economy that require still more adjustments that lead to still more adjustments. There is a solution to this seemingly intractable problem, at least in theory. To decide how much of each output an economy must produce, the planner must use statistics to form a set of equations, one equation representing the input requirements for each product, and then solve those equations simultaneously. The simultaneous solution process deals effectively with the interdependence in the analysis—electricity output depends on steel production, but steel output depends on electricity production—and prevents it from becoming a vicious circle. The technique used to solve these complicated equations— input-output analysis—was invented by the late economist Wassily Leontief, who won the 1973 Nobel Prize for his work. The equations of input-output analysis illustrated in the box, “Input-Output Equations: An Example,” above take explicit account of the interdependence among industries by describing precisely how each industry’s target output depends on every other

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 14

The Case for Free Markets I: The Price System

297

industry’s target. To keep the discussion from growing too complicated, the example deals with a vastly oversimplified and imaginary economy that has only three industries. Only by solving these equations simultaneously for the required outputs of electricity, steel, coal, and so on can planners ensure a consistent solution that produces the required amounts of each product—including the amount of each product needed to produce every other product. The illustrative input-output analysis that appears in the box is not provided to make you a master at using the technique yourself. Its true purpose is to help you imagine how very complicated the problems facing central planners can become in the real world. Their task, although analogous to the one described in the box, is enormously more complex. In any real economy, the number of commodities is far greater than the three outputs in the example! In the United States, some large manufacturing companies deal in hundreds of thousands of items, and the armed forces keep several million different items in inventory. Planners must ultimately make calculations for each single item. It is not enough to plan the right number of bolts in total; they must make sure that the required number of each size is produced. (Try putting 5 million large bolts into 5 million small nuts.) To be sure that their plans will really work, they need a separate equation for every size of bolt and one for every size and type of nut. But then, to replicate the analysis described in the box, they would have to solve several million equations simultaneously! This task would strain even the most powerful computer’s capability, but that is not even the main difficulty. Worse still is the data problem. Each of our three equations requires three pieces of statistical information, making 3 3 3, or 9 numbers in total. The equation for electricity must indicate how much electricity is needed in steel production, how much in coal production, and how much is demanded by consumers, all on the basis of statistical information that is itself subject to error. Therefore, in a five-industry analysis, 5 3 5, or 25, pieces of data are needed; a 100-industry analysis requires 100 3 100, or 10,000, numbers, and a million-item input-output study might need 1 trillion pieces of information. Solving the data-gathering problems is no easy task, to put it mildly. Still other complications arise, but we have seen enough to conclude that:

Which Buyers and Which Sellers Get Priority? Because the supplies of all commodities are limited, some potential customers of a product will end up with none of it. And because demand is not infinite, some potential suppliers of a commodity will find no market available for them. So, which consumers get the scarce commodity and which firms get to supply the goods? Once again, the price mechanism comes to the rescue. Other things being equal, the price mechanism ensures that those consumers who want a scarce commodity most will receive it and that those sellers who can supply it most efficiently will get to supply the commodity.

SOURCE: Krododill, Sovfoto/Eastfoto

A full, rigorous central-planning solution to the production problem is a tremendous task, requiring an overwhelming quantity of information and some incredibly difficult calculations. Yet this very complex job is carried out automatically and unobtrusively by the price mechanism in an unplanned free-market economy.

In this cartoon from a Soviet humor magazine, one construction worker comments to another, “A slight mistake in the plans, perhaps.” It is interesting that there were many cartoons making fun of the inefficiencies of the Soviet economy in the humor magazines of the USSR before the collapse of communism.

To illustrate, let’s look at Figure 3, an ordinary supply-demand graph. For simplicity, suppose we are dealing here with a commodity such as a best-selling novel. We assume also that no one buys more than one copy of the book. The demand curve, DD, represents the widely differing preferences of 6,000 potential customers. The first Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

298

The Virtues and Limitations of Markets

Part 4

FIGURE 3 Supply-Demand Graph Showing That Price Excludes Only Buyers and Sellers Who Care the Least

D

S A

$70

a

B

60

b S'

50 Price

c

C E

40

e F

f 30 g

20

G

h

10

D S 0

S' 1

2

3

4

5

Quantity (in thousands)

6

7

8

1,000 of them are willing to pay as much as $70 for the book, as shown by point A on the demand curve (though they would, of course, prefer to pay less). Point B shows a second group of 1,000 buyers who will purchase the book at a price of $60 but refuse to spend $70 on it (because they care less about the book than the point A consumers). Similarly, point C represents the demand of a third group of consumers, to whom the book is even less important, so that they are willing to spend only $50 for a copy. And points E, F, and G represent sets of consumers with successively lower desires for the book, until at point G, consumers are willing to pay only $20 for the book. With SS as the supply curve, the equilibrium point is E, where SS and DD intersect. Under perfect competition, the market price of the book will be $40. Buyers at point A, to whom the book is worth $70, will be delighted to buy it for only $40. Similarly, buyers at points B, C, and E will also buy the book. But the consumers at points F and G, to whom the book is worth less than $40, will not buy the book. We can see in this example that the book will go to the consumers who value it most (in terms of money), and only those who value it least will be deprived of it.

The price mechanism always ranks potential consumers of a good in the order of the intensity of their preference for the good, as indicated by the amount they are willing to spend for it.

The price system’s priority to those consumers who assign most importance to a good goes one step further. Suppose that supply increases, with the supply curve shifting to the right, from SS to S'S' in the figure. Which consumers will get the increased quantity supplied? Answer: Of those consumers in the group of people who were previously denied the commodity, those who want it most intensely will acquire the product. In the graph, the shift in supply moves the equilibrium point from E to F, so point F consumers will now be included in the group of buyers of the book (along with point A, B, C, and E consumers), but the point G consumers still will not purchase the book. The book is worth more to point F consumers ($30) than it is to point G consumers, who value it at only $20. The price system seems to set the right priorities in deciding which prospective consumers of some specific good do receive some of it and which do not. Only one major imperfection arises in this argument, to which we will return in a moment. First, however, let’s look at Figure 3 again, this time from the supplying firm’s point of view. Assume that SS is the long-run industry supply curve. Point g on this curve represents the amount that the industry will supply if the price is $20—that is, the amount that will be supplied by firms whose average cost is no higher than $20, so that the price will cover their cost. Similarly, point f represents the output of all firms whose average cost is no higher than $30, so that the group of suppliers now includes some firms that are less efficient (they have higher average cost) than those at point g. At point e, some of the suppliers will have average costs of $40, but none of the suppliers who are able to make any sales will have an average cost higher than that level. Using the same reasoning, as we move farther along SS to points c, b, and a, increasingly inefficient firms will be included among the suppliers. Now we examine the supply-demand equilibrium point e, at which price is $40. Which suppliers will be able to market their products at this point? Answer: Those at points g, f, and e, but not firms at points c, b, and a, because no firm in the last three groups can cover its costs at the equilibrium price. Once again, the price mechanism does its job. It ranks Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 14

299

The Case for Free Markets I: The Price System

firms in order of their efficiency, as measured by long-run average costs, and brings business to the more efficient firms, leaving out the least efficient potential suppliers. This example illustrates yet another of the many desirable features of the price mechanism. But there is one fly in the ointment—at least on the demand side of the story. We saw that consumers in group G were likely to be denied the scarce commodity we are discussing, because they wanted it less than the other consumers. Group G consumers were willing to spend only $20 for the book, whereas the other consumers were willing to spend more for it. But what if some consumers in group G want the book very badly but are also very poor? This is an important question—one we will encounter again and again. The price mechanism is like a democracy, but one in which the rule is not “one person, one vote,” but rather, “one dollar, one vote.” In other words, under the price mechanism rich consumers’ preferences get much more attention than poor consumers’ desires.

HOW PERFECT COMPETITION ACHIEVES EFFICIENCY: A GRAPHIC ANALYSIS We have indicated how the market mechanism solves the three basic coordination problems of any economy—what to produce, how to produce it, and how to distribute the goods to consumers. Also, we have suggested that these same tasks pose almost insurmountable difficulties for central planners. One critical question remains: Is the allocation of resources that the market mechanism selects efficient, according to the precise definition of efficiency presented at the start of this chapter? The answer, under the idealized circumstances of perfect competition, is yes. A simple supply-and-demand diagram can be used to give us an intuitive view of why that is so. Focusing on the market for a single commodity, let us ask whether either an increase or a decrease in the amount of output produced by the market mechanism can yield a greater total net benefit to consumers and producers. Suppose the current output level of swimming lessons in a swimming pool (number of people being taught) is 20 and the total net benefit to all involved in the activity can somehow be evaluated in money terms at $500 per week. Then, if any other number of students yields a total net benefit less than $500, clearly we have reason to conclude that 20 students is the optimum. We will show that, in equilibrium under perfect competition, the market unerringly and automatically will drive toward an equilibrium exactly at that optimal output level, without any central direction, explicit guidance, or planning by anyone. That is one of the remarkable accomplishments of the market mechanism. To show this, let’s begin by defining consumer and producer benefits sufficiently precisely so we can measure them. In Chapter 5 (page 93), we already have encountered the concept we need for the consumer benefits: consumer’s surplus. And we will introduce a perfectly analogous concept, called producer’s surplus, for the other side of the market. Suppose Anne would be willing to purchase a full week of swimming lessons at any price up to $140, but when she arrives at the gym she sees that the lessons are available for sale at a price of $90. Because swimming lessons are worth $140 to her, and she only has to spend $90 to obtain them, the purchase provides her with a net benefit of $140 2 $90 5 $50. If the lessons had been priced at $140, the result of the purchase would have been a wash—she would have given up $140 and received in exchange a service worth exactly $140 to her. But because the market price happens to be $90, she obtains a net gain worth $50 to her—a surplus—from the transaction. So, as we did in Chapter 5, we define: The consumer’s surplus from a purchase is equal to the difference between the maximum amount the consumer would be willing, if necessary, to pay for the item bought and the price that the market actually charges. In a purchase by a rational consumer, the surplus will never be a negative number, because if the price is higher than the maximum amount the potential purchaser is willing to pay, he will simply refuse to buy it. Producer’s surplus is defined exactly analogously. If Ben, a swimming instructor, is willing to provide a week of lessons at any price from $30 up, but the market price happens to be $90, he receives a $60 surplus from the transaction—and is delighted to make such a sale. So we have the definition: The producer’s surplus from a sale is the difference between the market price of the item sold and the lowest price at which the supplier would be willing to provide the item.

The consumer’s surplus from a purchase is equal to the difference between the maximum amount the consumer would be willing, if necessary, to pay for the item bought and the price that the market actually charges. The producer’s surplus from a sale is the difference between the market price of the item sold and the lowest price at which the supplier would be willing to provide the item.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

300

Part 4

The Virtues and Limitations of Markets

Now that we know how the two surpluses are defined and how to measure them, our objective is to see how the total surplus to all buyers and sellers in a market is affected by the quantity produced and sold in the market. We will demonstrate a striking result: that at the perfectly competitive market output level—the output level at which the market supply and demand curves intercept—the total surplus for all participants is as large as possible. To do this, we must turn to our familiar supply-demand analysis and use it to show explicitly the roles played by Anne, Ben, and the others involved in the market. We begin with a table that assumes for simplicity that there are five potential buyers (Anne, Charles, Elaine, etc.) and five potential competing sellers (Ben, Debbie, etc.) in the market for swimming lessons. We see in Table 1 that at the weekly fee of $90 (third column in the table), Anne, to whom a week’s lessons are worth $140 (first column), obtains a consumer’s surplus of $50 5 $140 2 $90. Similarly, at that price, Charles obtains a surplus of just $30. The consumer’s surplus for these two customers is shown by the two light brown areas below the brown demand curve DD in Figure 4(a), corresponding to their purchases (two sets of lessons). For example, the left-most brown bar has its bottom at the price of $90 and its top at the $140 that the lessons are worth to Anne, so that the area of Anne’s brown bar area is equal to her surplus, $140 2 $90 5 $50. Similarly, Table 1 shows the producer’s surpluses that can be earned by the different potential instructors. For example, it shows that the $90 fee gives Ben a surplus of $60 5 $90 2 $30, because he would be willing to give the lessons even if the fee were as low as $30. In the same way, we see that Debbie obtains a surplus of $40. These two producers’ surpluses are shown in Figure 4(a) by the areas of the first two light blue bars areas between the blue supply curve SS and the $90 price line for those two sales. We also note that if both Anne and Charles received lessons, and both Ben and Debbie gave lessons, so that two sets of lessons were provided, the total surplus created by the market would be the sum of their four individual surpluses, $50 1 30 1 60 1 40 5 $180—which is the second entry in the fourth column in the table. This is also shown by the area DRTUVS in Figure 4(a) that lies between the brown demand curve and the blue supply curve when only two sets of lessons are provided. But comparison of Figures 4(a) and 4(b) shows us clearly that two lessons are not enough to make the total surplus generated by the market as large as possible. Specifically, if Elaine also takes lessons, and Frank provides them, this third transaction generates an additional consumer’s surplus of $20 and an additional producer’s surplus of $20, raising the total to $220. This larger total is shown by summing all the light brown and light blue areas between the demand and supply curves in Figure 4(b). One more set of lessons, the number at which the supply and demand curves intersect at PP, contributes no net gain in surplus, because George and Harriet value the lessons at exactly the prevailing price of $90. In buying and selling the service, these two people exchange money and services that are worth exactly the same to them. Increasing output further, by raising it to a fifth set of lessons, will actually reduce total surplus, because Irene, the potential student, values the lessons at less than their $90 price, whereas Jack, the potential instructor, considers his work worth $120. If Jack were to provide lessons to Irene, they both would obtain negative TABLE 1 Consumer’s and Producer’s Surplus in the Swimming Lesson Market (dollars)

Students Anne Charles Elaine George Irene

(1) Student’s Acceptable Maximum Price

(2) Individual Consumer’s Surplus

$140 120 110 90 80

$50 30 20 0 –10

(3) Actual Price

(4) Cumulative Total Surplus

(5) Individual Producer’s Surplus

(6) Instructor’s Acceptable Minimum Price

Instructors

$90 90 90 90 90

$110 5 50 1 60 180 5 110 1 30 1 40 220 220 180

$60 40 20 0 –30

$ 30 50 70 90 120

Ben Debbie Frank Harriet Jack

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

301

The Case for Free Markets I: The Price System

Chapter 14

Producer’s and Consumer’s Surplus: Two Swimmers

Producer’s and Consumer’s Surplus and Optimal Output

$140

D

120

R T 50

30

100 90 80 60

S -30

20 P

20

-10

P

D

40

60

U 40 V 20 S 0

1

2

3

4

5

Number of Students or Instructors

Consumer’s and Producer’s Surplus

FIGURE 4(b)

Consumer’s and Producer’s Surplus

FIGU R E 4(a)

$140

D

120

R T 50

30

100 90 80

S -30

20 P

20

-10

P

D

40

60 60

U 40 V 20 S 0

1

2

3

4

5

Number of Students or Instructors

surpluses, represented by the dark blue and dark brown bars toward the right of the graph. These negative surpluses bring the total surplus down from $220 to $180 (the last two entries in column 4 of the table), clearly a net loss to the economy. Now we come to the payoff from all this reasoning. Looking at Figure 4(a), we see that if total output stops short of the intersection of the supply and demand curve (interval PP), the light blue and brown areas will not be as large as possible. Similarly, if more than that quantity of swimming lessons is supplied, total surplus is decreased (Figure 4(b)). Only when the output quantity corresponds to the intersection of the supply and demand curves is the net surplus earned by both buyers and sellers as large as possible. Three conclusions follow: 1. Because under perfect competition the equilibrium output will be at the intersection of the supply and demand curves, a regime of perfect competition will select output levels that are optimal in terms of the public interest. They yield as large a sum of consumers’ and producers’ surpluses as possible. 2. If some influence such as monopoly forces output to be smaller (because price is higher) than that under perfect competition, the public interest will be damaged because the quantity of resources allocated to this market will be less than optimal. 3. If something like a government tax reduction induces suppliers to produce an output larger than the competitive level, that will also be a misallocation of resources damaging to the public welfare.

HOW PERFECT COMPETITION ACHIEVES OPTIMAL OUTPUT: MARGINAL ANALYSIS There is a second way to look at the optimality of outputs under perfect competition’s idealized circumstances, this time relating the discussion directly to the definition of efficiency given at the beginning of this chapter. Because a detailed proof of this assertion for all three coordination tasks is long and time-consuming, we will present the proof only for the task we have just been considering—output selection. We will show that, at least in theory, perfect competition does guarantee efficiency in determining the relative quantities of the different commodities that the economy produces. The proof comes in two steps. First, we derive a criterion for efficient output selection— that is, a test that tells us whether production is being carried out efficiently. Second, we show that the prices that emerge from the market mechanism under perfect competition automatically pass this test. Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

302

Part 4

The Virtues and Limitations of Markets

Step 1: Rule for Efficient Output Selection We begin by stating the rule for efficient output selection: THE IMPORTANCE OF THINKING AT THE MARGIN Marginal Analysis: Efficiency in the choice of output quantities requires that, for each of the economy’s outputs, the marginal cost (MC) of the last unit produced be equal to the marginal utility (MU) of the last unit consumed.4 In symbols:

IDEAS FOR BEYOND THE FINAL EXAM

MC 5 MU This rule is yet another example of the basic principle of marginal analysis that we learned in Chapter 8. The efficient decision about output quantities is the one that maximizes the total benefit (total utility) to society, minus the cost to society of producing the output quantities that are chosen. In other words, the goal is to maximize the surplus that society gains—total utility minus total cost. But, as we saw in Chapter 8, to maximize the difference between total utility and total cost, we must find the outputs that equalize the corresponding marginal figures (marginal utility and marginal cost), as the preceding efficiency rule tells us.

An example will help us to see explicitly why resource allocation must satisfy this rule to be deemed efficient. Suppose that the marginal utility of an additional pound of beef to consumers is $8 but its marginal cost is only $5. Then the value of the resources that would have to be used up to produce one more pound of beef (its MC) would be $3 less than the money value that consumers would willingly pay for that additional pound (its MU). By expanding the output of beef by one pound, society could get more (in MU) out of the economic production process than it was putting in (in MC). We know that the output at which MU exceeds MC cannot be optimal, because society would be better off with an increase in that output level. The opposite is true if the MC of beef exceeds the MU of beef. Thus, we have shown that, if any product’s MU is not equal to MC—whether MU exceeds MC or MC exceeds MU—the economy must be wasting an opportunity to achieve a net improvement in consumers’ welfare. This is exactly what we mean by saying society is using resources inefficiently. Just as was true at point G in Figure 1, if MC does not equal MU for some commodity, it is possible to rearrange production to make some people better off while harming no one else. It follows, then, that efficient output choice occurs only when MC equals MU for every good.5

Step 2: The Price System’s Critical Role Next, we must show that under perfect competition, the price system automatically leads buyers and sellers to behave in a way that equalizes MU and MC. To see this, recall from Chapter 10 that under perfect competition it is most profitable for each beef-producing firm to produce the quantity at which the marginal cost equals the price (P) of beef: MC 5 P

This must be so because, if the marginal cost of beef were less than the price, farmers could add to profits by increasing the size of the herd (or the amount of grain fed to the animals). The reverse would be true if the marginal cost of beef were greater than its price. Thus, under perfect competition, the lure of profits leads each producer of beef (and of every other product) to supply the quantity that makes MC 5 P. We also learned in Chapter 5 that each consumer will purchase the quantity of beef at which the marginal utility of beef in money terms equals the price of beef: MU 5 P Recall from Chapter 5 that we measure marginal utility in money terms—that is, the amount of money that a consumer is willing to give up for an additional unit of the commodity. Economists usually call this the marginal rate of substitution between the commodity and money. 5 Warning: As described in Chapter 15, markets sometimes perform imperfectly because the decision maker faces a different marginal cost than the marginal cost to society. This situation occurs when the individual who creates the cost can make someone else bear the burden. Consider an example: Firm X’s production causes pollution emissions that increase nearby households’ laundry bills. In such a case, Firm X will ignore this cost and produce inefficiently large outputs and emissions. We study such problems, called externalities, in Chapters 15 and 17. 4

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 14

The Case for Free Markets I: The Price System

If consumers did not do so, either an increase or a decrease in their beef purchases would leave them better off. Putting these last two equations together, we see that the invisible hand enforces the following string of equalities: MC 5 P 5 MU

If the MC of beef and the MU of beef both equal the same price, P, then they must equal each other. That is, it must be true that the quantity of beef produced and consumed in a perfectly competitive market satisfies the equation: MC 5 MU

This is precisely our rule for efficient output selection. Because the same must be true of every other product supplied by a competitive industry, Under perfect competition, producers and consumers will make uncoordinated decisions that we can expect automatically (and amazingly) to produce exactly the quantity of each good that satisfies the MC 5 MU rule for efficiency. That is, under the idealized conditions of perfect competition, the market mechanism, without any government intervention and without anyone else directing it or planning for it, is capable of allocating society’s scarce resources efficiently.

The Invisible Hand at Work This is truly an extraordinary result. How can the price mechanism automatically satisfy all of the exacting requirements for efficiency (that marginal utility equals marginal cost for each and every commodity)—requirements that no central planner can hope to handle because of the masses of statistics and the enormous calculations they entail? This seems analogous to a magician suddenly pulling a rabbit out of a hat! But, as always, rabbits come out of hats only if they were hidden there in the first place. What really is the mechanism by which our act of magic works? The secret is that the price system lets consumers and producers pursue their own best interests—something they are probably very good at doing. Prices are the dollar costs of commodities to consumers, so in pursuing their own best interests, consumers will buy the commodities that give them the most satisfaction per dollar. Under perfect competition, the price the consumer pays is also equal to MC, because the market’s incentives lead each supplier to supply that amount at which this is true. Because P 5 MC measures the resource cost (in every firm) of producing one more unit of the good, this means that when consumers buy the commodities that give them the most satisfaction for their money, they will automatically have chosen the set of purchases that yields the most satisfaction obtainable from the resources used up in producing those purchases. In other words, the market mechanism leads consumers to squeeze the greatest possible benefit out of the social resources used up in making the goods and services they buy. So, if resources are priced appropriately (P 5 MC), when consumers make the best use of their money, they must also be making the best use of society’s resources. That is the way the market mechanism ensures economic efficiency. When all prices are set equal to marginal costs, the price system gives correct cost signals to consumers. It has set prices at levels that induce consumers to use society’s resources with the same care they devote to watching their own money, because the money cost of a good to consumers has been set equal to the opportunity cost of the good to society. A perfectly analogous explanation applies to the decisions of producers.

This is the magic of the invisible hand. Unlike central planners, consumers need not know how difficult it is to manufacture a certain product or the scarcity of the inputs required by the production process. Everything consumers need to know about supply in making their decisions is embodied in the market price, which, under perfect competition, accurately reflects marginal costs. Similarly, producers do not need to know anything about the psychology and tastes of their individual customers—price movements tell them all they need to know when consumer preferences change. Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

303

304

Part 4

The Virtues and Limitations of Markets

Other Roles of Prices: Income Distribution and Fairness So far we have stressed the role of prices that economists emphasize most: Prices guide resource allocation. Prices also command the spotlight in another role: Prices influence the distribution of income between buyers and sellers. For example, high rents often make tenants poorer and landlords richer. This rather obvious role of prices draws the most attention from the public, politicians, and regulators, and we should not lose sight of it.6 Markets serve only those demands that are backed up by consumers’ desire and ability to pay. The market system may do well in serving poor families, because it gives them more food and clothing than a less efficient economy would provide. But the market system offers far more to wealthy families. Many people think that such an arrangement represents a great injustice, however efficient it may be. Often, people oppose economists’ recommendations for improving the economy’s efficiency on the grounds that these proposals are unfair. For example, economists frequently advocate higher prices for transportation facilities at the times of day when the facilities are most crowded. Economists propose a pricing arrangement called “peak, off-peak pricing” under which prices for public transportation are higher during rush hours than during other hours. The rationale for this proposal should be clear from our discussion of efficiency. A seat on a train is a much scarcer resource during rush hours than it is during other times of the day when the trains run fairly empty. Thus, according to the principles of efficiency outlined in this chapter, seats should be more expensive during rush hours to discourage those consumers with no set schedule from riding the trains during peak periods. The same notion applies to other services. Charges for long-distance telephone calls made at night are generally lower than those in the daytime. And in some places, electricity is cheaper at night, when demand does not strain the supplier’s generating capacity. Yet the proposal that transportation authorities should charge higher fares for public transportation during peak hours—say, from 8:00 A.M. to 9:30 A.M. and from 4:30 P.M. to 6:00 P.M.—often runs into stiff opposition. Opponents say that most of the burden of such higher fares will fall on lower-income working people who have no choice regarding the timing of their trips. For example, a survey of economists and members of Parliament in Great Britain found that, while high peak-period fares were favored by 88 percent of the economists, only 35 percent of the Conservative Party members of Parliament and just 19 percent of the Labour Party members of Parliament approved of this arrangement (see Table 2). We may TABLE 2 Replies to a Questionnaire

Question: To make the most efficient use of a city’s resources, how should subway and bus fares vary during the day? a. They should be relatively low during rush hour to transport as many people as possible at lower costs. b. They should be the same at all times to avoid making travelers alter their schedules because of price differences. c. They should be relatively high during rush hour to minimize the amount of equipment needed to transport the daily travelers. d. Impossible to answer on the data and alternatives given.

Economists

Conservative Party Members of Parliament

1%

0%

Labour Party Members of Parliament

40%

4

60

39

88

35

19

7

5

2

SOURCE: Excerpt from Samuel Brittan, Is There an Economic Consensus? p. 93. Copyright © 1973. Reproduced by permission of Samuel Brittan.

6

Income distribution is the subject of Part 5.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 14

The Case for Free Markets I: The Price System

305

P OLICY D E B AT E

User Charges for Public Facilities impeded by user charges. For instance, in New York there is no charge to cross four of the five bridges that connect Brooklyn and Queens with Manhattan. But each time new tolls are proposed, they are met with the cry, “Should I have to pay an admission fee into my own city?!”

SOURCE: © Ron Chapple/Thinkstock Images/Jupiterimages

At a time when budget cutting is the way to popularity for a politician, the notion of charging users for the services that government once gave away for free is under debate. Economists have often advocated such charges for the use of roads, bridges, museums, educational facilities, and the like. Of course, it’s true that if the services are provided for “free,” the public has to pay for them anyway—just more indirectly through taxes. But if people are asked to pay directly for such services, it can make a big difference. As an example, let’s say a road is financed out of general taxes. In this circumstance, it does not matter how many times Sabrina, the owner of an independent trucking firm, uses the road. She pays the same amount whether she uses it twice a year or every day. But if Sabrina has to pay a toll every time she uses the road, she will have a strong incentive to avoid unnecessary use. That is why advocates of pricing to promote economic efficiency propose more substantial user charges, not only for roads and bridges but also for admission to national parks, for the use of publicly owned grazing lands, and for the use of the television and radio spectrums by broadcasters. Opponents of user charges contend that these fees are unfair to poor people. Besides, it is argued, the use of public facilities such as libraries, museums, and schools should be encouraged rather than

surmise that these members of the British Parliament reflected the views of the public more accurately than did the economists. In this case, people simply found the efficient solution unfair, and so they refused to adopt it.

Yet Another Free-Market Achievement: Growth versus Efficiency This chapter has followed the economist’s standard approach in evaluating the market mechanism. Economists usually stress efficiency in resource allocation and the role of the market in ensuring such efficiency—the division of resources among alternative uses in a way that misses no opportunity to increase consumer net benefits. Some other admirers of the market do not place their main emphasis on the free market’s efficiency accomplishments. A very diverse group, including businesspeople, politicians, economic historians, leaders such as Dmitry Medvedev and Hu Jintao in formerly communist economies that have become more market-oriented, and even Marxists, appreciate the market primarily for a very different reason—the extraordinary growth in output that market economies have achieved and the historically unprecedented abundance that has resulted. Historians have estimated that before the arrival of the capitalistic market mechanism, output per person grew with glacial slowness. Today an average American can afford nearly seven times the quantity of goods and services that an individual’s income bought 100 years ago. Undoubtedly, the failure to achieve substantial growth and prosperity (and not just inefficiencies in allocating goods) helped to bring about the fall of communism in eastern Europe. Even Karl Marx stressed this role of the market mechanism, waxing lyrical in his description of its accomplishments. Chapter 16 will return to this subject, indicating what a free-market economy can accomplish in terms of economic growth. Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

306

Part 4

The Virtues and Limitations of Markets

PUZZLE RESOLVED:

SAN FRANCISCO BRIDGE PRICING REVISITED

Our earlier example of the San Francisco Bay area bridges also raises fairness issues. Recall that we concluded from our analysis that efficient bridge use requires higher tolls on the more crowded bridges. Because this principle seems so clear and rational, it is surprising to find out what the actual bridge tolls are: $5 on the Golden Gate Bridge and $4 on all other bridges, even though their average daily traffic varies, with the San Francisco–Oakland Bay Bridge by far the most crowded.7 From an efficiency point of view, this uniform toll seems irrational, with the relatively uncrowded bridges assigned the same toll as the most crowded bridge. The explanation lies in some widely held notions of fairness. Many people feel that it is fair for those who travel on a particular bridge to pay for its costs. In this view, it would be unjust for those who use the crowded San Francisco–Oakland Bay Bridge to pay more in order to subsidize the least crowded Dumbarton Bridge. Naturally, a heavily traveled bridge earns more toll payments and so recoups its building, maintenance, and operating costs more quickly. On the other hand, it is felt that the relatively few users of a less crowded bridge should make a fair contribution toward its costs. An economically irrational pattern of tolls does nothing to ease congestion on overcrowded bridges and thereby contributes to inefficiency. But one cannot legitimately conclude that advocates of such prices are “stupid.” Whether this pattern of tolls is or is not desirable must be decided, at least partly, on the basis of the public’s sense of what constitutes fairness and justice in pricing. It also depends on the amount that people are willing to pay in terms of delays, inconvenience, and other inefficiencies to avoid apparent injustices. Economics alone cannot decide the appropriate trade-off between fairness and efficiency. It cannot even pretend to judge which pricing arrangements are fair and which are unfair. But it can and should indicate whether a particular pricing decision, proposed because it is considered fair, will impose heavy inefficiency costs on the community. Economic analysis also can and should indicate how to appraise these costs, so that the issues can be evaluated on a rational, factual basis.

TOWARD ASSESSMENT OF THE PRICE MECHANISM We do not mean to imply in our discussion of the case for free markets that the freeenterprise system is an ideal of perfection, without flaw or room for improvement. In fact, it has a number of serious shortcomings that we will explore in subsequent chapters. But recognition of these imperfections should not conceal the price mechanism’s enormous accomplishments. We have shown that, under the proper circumstances, prices are capable of meeting the most exacting requirements of allocative efficiency—requirements that go well beyond any central planning bureau’s capacities. Even centrally planned economies use the price mechanism to carry out considerable portions of the task of allocation, most notably in the distribution of consumer goods. No one has invented an instrument for directing the economy that can replace the price mechanism, which no one ever designed or planned for, but which simply grew by itself, a child of the processes of history.

7 Toll schedules for the San Francisco Bay area bridges are from the Bay Area Toll Authority, http://bata.mtc.ca.gov/ tolls/schedule.htm, and the Golden Gate Bridge, Highway and Transportation District, http://www.goldengate.org. Note that nowadays these bridge authorities do encourage efficiency by providing faster carpool lanes for buses and cars with three or more passengers; these categories of vehicle cross the five bridges free of charge during weekday rush hours. And the introduction of an electronic toll collection system (FasTrak) that can process almost three times as many vehicles per hour as the manual collection has significantly improved efficiency and reduced congestion. Drivers who do not utilize FasTrak on the Golden Gate Bridge are charged an extra dollar to cross that bridge.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

The Case for Free Markets I: The Price System

Chapter 14

307

| SUMMARY | 1. Economists consider an allocation of resources to be inefficient if it wastes opportunities to change the use of the economy’s resources in any way that makes at least some consumers better off without harming anyone. Resource allocation is considered efficient if there are no such wasted opportunities. 2. Under perfect competition, the free-market mechanism adjusts prices so that the resulting resource allocation is efficient. It induces firms to buy and use inputs in ways that yield the most valuable outputs per unit of input. It distributes products among consumers in ways that match individual preferences. Finally, it produces commodities whose value to consumers exceeds the cost of producing them and assigns the task of production to the potential suppliers who can produce most efficiently.

that maximizes the sum of the consumers’ and producers’ surpluses derived by everyone in the community. Perfectly competitive equilibrium achieves this goal, at least in theory. 5. Efficient decisions about what goods to produce require that the marginal cost (MC) of producing each good be equal to its marginal utility (MU) to consumers. If the MC of any good differs from its MU, then society can improve resource allocation by changing the amounts produced. 6. Because the market system induces firms to set MC equal to price, and it induces consumers to set MU equal to price, it automatically guarantees satisfaction of the condition that MC should equal MU.

a. How much of each good to produce

7. Improvements in efficiency occasionally require some prices to increase so as to stimulate supply or to prevent waste in consumption. This is why price increases can sometimes be beneficial to consumers.

b. What quantities of available inputs to use in producing the different goods

8. In addition to resource allocation, prices influence income distribution between buyers and sellers.

c. How to distribute the goods among different consumers

9. The price mechanism can be criticized on the ground that it is unfair because it accords wealthy consumers preferential treatment.

3. Resource allocation involves three basic coordination tasks:

4. An optimal allocation of society’s resources among the commodities the economy produces and consumes is one

| KEY TERMS | consumer’s surplus

299

efficient allocation of resources 288

input-output analysis laissez-faire

296

producer’s surplus 299

293

| TEST YOURSELF | 1. What possible social advantages of price increases arise in the following cases? a. Charging higher prices for electrical power on very hot days when many people use air conditioners b. Raising water prices in drought-stricken areas 2. In the discussion of Figure 3, there is a set of numbers indicating how much different buyers would be willing to

pay for a book. Construct a table for these buyers like the first three columns in Table 1, indicating their consumer’s surpluses. 3. As in the previous question, use the numbers in Figure 3 to determine the producer’s surpluses and complete your table to correspond to the remaining columns of Table 1.

| DISCUSSION QUESTIONS | 1. Discuss the fairness of the two proposals included in Test Yourself Question 1. 2. Using the concepts of marginal cost (MC) and marginal utility (MU), discuss the nature of the inefficiency in each of the following cases: a. An arrangement that offers relatively little coffee and much tea to people who prefer coffee and does the reverse for tea lovers

b. An arrangement in which skilled mechanics are assigned to ditch digging and unskilled laborers to repairing cars c. An arrangement that produces a large quantity of trucks and few cars, assuming that both cost about the same amount to produce and to run but that most people in the community prefer cars to trucks

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

308

Part 4

The Virtues and Limitations of Markets

3. In reality, which of the following circumstances might give rise to each of the situations described in Discussion Question 2 above?

5. In a free market, how will the price mechanism deal with each of the inefficiencies described in Discussion Question 2?

a. Regulation of output quantities by a government

6. In the early months after the end of communism in Eastern Europe, there seems to have been an almost superstitious belief that the free market could solve all problems. What sorts of problems do you think the leaders and the citizens of those countries had in mind? Which of those problems is there good reason to believe the market mechanism actually can deal with effectively? What disappointments and sources of disillusionment should have been expected? Which disappointments have resulted?

b. Rationing of commodities c. Assignment of soldiers to different jobs in an army 4. We have said that the economy’s three coordination tasks are output selection, production planning, and product distribution. Which of these is done badly in the cases described in Discussion Questions 2a, 2b, and 2c?

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

The Shortcomings of Free Markets When she was good She was very, very good, But when she was bad She was horrid.

W

HENRY WADSWORTH LONG FE LLOW

hat does the market do well, and what does it do poorly? These questions are the focus of our microeconomic analysis, and we are well on our way toward finding their answers. In Chapters 4, 10, and 14, we explained the workings of Adam Smith’s invisible hand, the instrument by which a perfectly competitive economy allocates resources efficiently without any guidance from government. Of course, that perfectly competitive model is just a theoretical ideal, but our observations of the real world confirm the extraordinary accomplishments of the market mechanism. Freemarket economies have achieved levels of output, productive efficiency, variety in available consumer goods, and general prosperity that are unprecedented in history— and are now the envy of the formerly planned economies. We will discuss that phenomenal record of production and growth in detail in Chapter 16. Yet the market mechanism has its weaknesses. In Chapters 11 and 12, we examined one of these defects—the free market’s vulnerability to exploitation by large and powerful business firms, which can lead to both an inappropriate concentration of wealth and resource misallocation. Now we take a more comprehensive view of market failures and study some of the steps that can be taken to remedy them. Clearly, the market does not do everything we want it to do. Amid the vast outpouring of products in our economy, we also find appalling poverty, cities choked by traffic and pollution, and hospitals, educational institutions, and artistic organizations in serious financial trouble. Although our economy produces an overwhelming abundance of material wealth, it seems far less capable of reducing social ills and environmental damage. We will examine the reasons for these failings and indicate why the price system by itself may sometimes not be able to deal with them, and sometimes addresses them only after some governmentally imposed changes in the market’s pricing practices.

C O N T E N T S PUZZLE: WHY ARE HEALTH-CARE COSTS IN

How Does It Work in Practice?

WHAT DOES THE MARKET DO POORLY?

SOME OTHER SOURCES OF MARKET FAILURE

CANADA RISING?

EFFICIENT RESOURCE ALLOCATION: A REVIEW EXTERNALITIES: GETTING THE PRICES WRONG Externalities and Inefficiency Externalities Are Everywhere Government Policy and Externalities

PROVISION OF PUBLIC GOODS ALLOCATION OF RESOURCES BETWEEN PRESENT AND FUTURE

Imperfect Information: “Caveat Emptor” Rent Seeking Moral Hazard Principals, Agents, and Recent Stock Option Scandals

Why Are These “In-Person” Services Costing So Much More? Uneven Labor Productivity Growth in the Economy A Future of More Goods but Fewer Services: Is It Inevitable? Government May Make the Problem Worse

PUZZLE RESOLVED: EXPLAINING THE RISING

COSTS OF CANADIAN HEALTH CARE

MARKET FAILURE AND GOVERNMENT FAILURE

THE MARKET SYSTEM ON BALANCE

THE COST DISEASE OF SOME VITAL SERVICES: INVITATION TO GOVERNMENT FAILURE

EPILOGUE: THE UNFORGIVING MARKET, ITS GIFT OF ABUNDANCE, AND ITS DANGEROUS FRIENDS

Deteriorating Personal Services Personal Services Are Getting More Expensive

The Role of the Interest Rate

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

310

Part 4

The Virtues and Limitations of Markets

Our recognition of the market’s limitations emphatically does not imply that the public interest calls for abandoning the market. As we will see, many of the imperfections of this economic system are treatable within the market environment, sometimes even by making use of the market mechanism to cure its own deficiencies.

PUZZLE:

WHY ARE HEALTH-CARE COSTS IN CANADA RISING?

SOURCE: © Ron Chapple/Thinkstock Images/Jupiterimages

Long before the U.S. government made its ultimately successful attempt in 2010 to grapple with the problems of health care, Canada adopted a universal health-care program intended to solve the same problem in that country. For this purpose, the Canadian government imposed strong controls over prices and fees. Each province has one insurance plan that reimburses doctors according to a uniform fee schedule; hospitals are put on predetermined overall budgets; and patients pay very low direct, out-of-pocket costs. Many observers believe that Canada has created an efficient, user-friendly system, although some critics disagree. But Canadians clearly have not succeeded in containing costs. Despite the price controls, Canadian health-care costs have been rising persistently faster than the general inflation rate, just as they had in the United States, where there once were no such national rules to rein in rising health-care prices. Moreover, some observers contend that Canadian health services are getting worse, with longer waits for diagnostic tests and elective surgery and tighter restrictions on treatments available to patients. Does this trend mean that Canadian health services are especially inefficient or corrupt? There is no evidence for such suspicions. Then why have the Canadians been unable to brake the growth of their health-care costs? This chapter will help you to understand the answer to this question, with its important implications for U.S. policy.

WHAT DOES THE MARKET DO POORLY? Although we cannot list all of the market’s imperfections, we can list some major areas in which it has been accused of failing: 1. Market economies suffer from severe business fluctuations, unemployment, and inflation. (See Chapters 22–33.) 2. The market distributes income unequally. (See Chapter 21.) 3. Where monopoly markets are present, they allocate resources inefficiently. (See Chapter 11.) 4. The market deals poorly with the side effects of many economic activities such as pollution. 5. The market cannot readily provide “public goods,” such as national defense and street cleaning. 6. The market may do a poor job of allocating resources between the present and the future. 7. The market mechanism makes public and personal services increasingly expensive, which often induces socially damaging countermeasures by government. We discuss the first three items in the list elsewhere in this book, as indicated. This chapter deals with the remaining four. To help us analyze these cases, we will first briefly review the concept of efficient resource allocation, discussed in detail in Chapter 14.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

311

The Shortcomings of Free Markets

Chapter 15

EFFICIENT RESOURCE ALLOCATION: A REVIEW The basic problem of resource allocation is deciding how much of each commodity the economy should produce. At first glance, the solution may seem simple: the more, the better! But this is not necessarily so, as one of our Ideas for Beyond the Final Exam indicates. HOW MUCH DOES IT REALLY COST? Opportunity Costs: Outputs are not created out of thin air. We produce them from scarce supplies of fuel, raw materials, machinery, and labor. If we use these resources to produce, say, more jeans, then we must take resources away from some other products, such as backpacks. To decide whether increasing the production of jeans is a good idea, we must compare the utility of that increase with the loss of utility in producing fewer backpacks. This, as you recall, means we must consider the opportunity cost of increased output. It is efficient to increase the output of jeans only if society considers the additional jeans more valuable than the forgone backpacks.

To illustrate this idea, we repeat a graph you have seen several times in earlier chapters—a production possibilities frontier—but we put it to a somewhat different use here. Curve ABC in Figure 1 is a production possibilities frontier showing the alternative combinations of jeans and backpacks that the economy can produce by reallocating its resources between production of the two goods. Suppose that point B, representing the production of 8 million backpacks and 60 million pairs of jeans, constitutes the optimal resource allocation. We assume this combination of outputs is the only one that best satisfies society’s wants among all the possibilities that are attainable (given the technology and resources as represented by the production frontier). That is, we assume that the combination of outputs at point B on the frontier yields the highest total consumers’ plus producers’ surplus for the entire economy. Two questions are pertinent to our discussion of the price system: 1. What prices will get the economy to select point B; that is, what prices will yield an efficient allocation of resources? 2. How can the wrong set of prices lead to a misallocation of resources? We discussed the first question in detail in Chapter 14, where we saw that An efficient allocation of resources requires the prices that will be reached at equilibrium if there is perfect competition be equal to marginal cost; that is,

IDEAS FOR BEYOND THE FINAL EXAM

The production possibilities frontier is a curve that shows the maximum quantities of outputs it is possible to produce with the available resource quantities and the current state of technological knowledge. Resources are misallocated if it is possible to change the way they are used or the combination of goods and services they produce and thereby make consumers and producers better off.

FIGURE 1 The Economy’s Production Possibilities Frontier for the Production of Two Goods

This chapter is devoted mainly to the second question: How can the “wrong” prices cause a misallocation of resources? The answer to this question is not too difficult, and we can use the case of monopoly as an illustration. The “law” of demand tells us that a rise in a commodity’s price normally will reduce the quantity demanded. Suppose, now, that the backpack industry is a monopoly, so the price of backpacks exceeds their marginal cost—the price they would have in a perfectly competitive market.1 This will decrease the quantity of backpacks demanded below the 8 million that we have assumed to be socially optimal (point B in Figure 1). The economy will move from point B to a point such as K, where too few backpacks and too many pairs

Number of Backpacks Produced

P 5 MC 10

C B

8 K 6 4 2 0

20

40

60

80

A 100

Number of Jeans Produced NOTE: Numbers are in millions per year.

To review why price under monopoly may be expected to exceed marginal cost, you may want to reread Chapter 11, pages 223–225. 1

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

312

Part 4

The Virtues and Limitations of Markets

of jeans are being produced for maximal consumer satisfaction. By setting the “wrong” prices, then, the market induces individual consumers to buy quantities that are inconsistent with maximal welfare of all individuals as a group, and thereby prevents the most efficient use of the economy’s resources. If a commodity’s price is higher than its marginal cost, the economy will tend to produce less of that item than would maximize consumer benefits. The opposite will occur if an item’s price is lower than its marginal cost.

In the rest of this chapter, we will encounter several other significant instances in which the market mechanism may set the “wrong” prices, leading to sale of more of some goods and less of other goods than would yield the highest attainable benefits for the community as a whole.

EXTERNALITIES: GETTING THE PRICES WRONG

An activity is said to generate a beneficial or detrimental externality if that activity causes incidental benefits or damages to others not directly involved in the activity and no corresponding compensation is provided to or paid by those who generate the externality.

We start our discussion of what the market does imperfectly with the fourth item on our list of market failures (since we have studied the first three in previous chapters): The market deals poorly with the incidental side effects of economic activities. This flaw is one of the least obvious yet most consequential of the price system’s imperfections. Many economic activities provide incidental benefits to others for whom they are not specifically intended. For example, homeowners who plant beautiful gardens in front of their homes incidentally and unintentionally provide pleasure to neighbors and passersby, even though they receive no payment in return. Economists say that their activity generates a beneficial externality. That is, the activity creates benefits that are external to, or outside, the intentions and interests of those that are directly involved in the activity. Similarly, some activities incidentally and unintentionally impose costs on others. For example, the owners of a motorcycle repair shop create a lot of noise for which they pay no compensation to their deafened neighbors. Economists say these owners produce a detrimental externality. Pollution is the classic illustration of a detrimental externality. To see why externalities cause the price system to misallocate resources, you need only recall that the price system achieves efficiency by rewarding producers who serve consumers well—that is, at the lowest possible cost. This argument breaks down, however, as soon as some of the costs and benefits of economic activities are left out of the profit calculation. When a firm pollutes a river, it uses up some of society’s resources (for example, it depletes the valuable oxygen in the water) just as surely as when the firm burns coal. However, if the firm pays for coal but not for the use of clean water, we can expect the firm’s management to be economical in its use of coal and wasteful in its use of the water’s oxygen. By the same token, a firm that provides unpaid benefits to others is unlikely to be generous in allocating resources to the activity, no matter how socially desirable it may be. In an important sense, the source of the market mechanism’s difficulty here lies in society’s rules about property rights. Coal mines are private property; their owners will not let anyone take coal without paying for it. Thus, coal is costly and so is not used wastefully. But waterways usually are not private property. Because they belong to everyone in general, they belong to no one in particular. Therefore, anyone can use those waterways as free dumping grounds for wastes that spew poisons into the water and use up the water’s oxygen that is vital for underwater life. Because no one pays for the use of the socially valuable dissolved oxygen in a public waterway, people will use that oxygen wastefully. The fact that waterways are exempted from the market’s normal control procedures is therefore the source of a detrimental externality.

Externalities and Inefficiency Using these concepts, we can see precisely why an externality has undesirable effects on the allocation of resources. In discussing externalities, it is crucial to distinguish between

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

The Shortcomings of Free Markets

313

social and private marginal cost. We define marginal social cost (MSC) as the sum of two components: (1) marginal private cost (MPC), which is the share of an activity’s marginal cost that is paid for by the persons who carry out the activity, plus (2) incidental cost, which is the share paid by others. If an increase in a firm’s output also increases the smoke its factory spews into the air, then, in addition to direct private costs (as recorded in the company accounts), the expansion of production imposes incidental costs on others. These costs take the form of increased laundry bills, medical expenditures, outlays for air-conditioning and electricity, and the unpleasantness of living in a cloud of noxious fumes. These are all part of the activity’s marginal social cost. Where the firm’s activities generate detrimental externalities, its marginal social cost will be greater than its marginal private cost, while the business firm will base its pricing only on its private cost because it does not pay the remainder of the social costs of its operation (and generally does not even know how large that remaining cost is). In symbols, MSC . MPC, where MSC is the cost to the entire community, whereas the price charged by the firm is based on MPC. Therefore, the firm’s output must be too big because price will be below the truly relevant marginal cost, thereby increasing sales of the commodity that damages the public. In such a case, society would necessarily benefit if output of that product were reduced. It would lose some of the product but escape the high marginal social cost. We conclude that

The marginal social cost (MSC) of an activity is the sum of its marginal private cost (MPC) plus its incidental costs (positive or negative) that are borne by others who receive no compensation for the resulting damage to their well-being.

Chapter 15

The marginal private cost (MPC) is the share of an activity’s marginal cost that is paid for by the persons who carry out the activity.

Where a firm’s activity causes detrimental externalities, the marginal benefits of the output will be less than marginal social costs in a free market. Smaller outputs will be socially desirable.

Marginal Cost and Revenue

This relationship holds because private enterprise has no motivation to take into account any costs to others for which it does not have to pay. In fact, competition forces firms to produce at as low a private cost as possible, because if they don’t, rivals will be able to take their customers away. Thus, competition compels firms to make extensive use of resources for which they are not required to pay or pay fully. As a result, goods that cause detrimental externalities will be produced in undesirably large amounts, because they have social costs that are not paid by the supplier firms. The opposite, of course, holds for the case of external benefits. This situation is one where the marginal social benefit (MSB) is greater than the marginal private benefit (MPB). A clear example is an invention produced by Firm A that gives an idea for another new product or process to an engineer from a different firm, B. Firm B clearly benefits from Firm A’s research and development (R&D) spending, and B does not pay anything to A for this gain. In that case, the social benefit—the sum of the benefits to FIGU R E 2 the two firms together—will be Equilibrium of a Firm Whose Output Produces a Detrimental greater than the private benefit to Externality (Pollution) the inventor Firm A alone. Thus, the marginal private benefit to inMarginal vestment in R&D will be less than social cost the marginal social benefit, and Marginal less R&D will be carried out under private cost B A private enterprise than social optiMarginal mality requires. revenue These principles can be illustrated with the aid of Figure 2. This diagram repeats the two basic curves needed for analysis of the firm’s equilibrium: a marginal revenue curve and a marginal cost 0 35 100 curve (see Chapter 8). These curves Thousands of Tons of Paper represent the private costs and revper Year enues of a particular firm (in this

The marginal social benefit (MSB) of an activity is the sum of its marginal private benefit (MPB) plus its incidental benefits (positive or negative) that are received by others, and for which those others do not pay. The marginal private benefit (MPB) is the share of an activity’s marginal benefit that is received by the persons who carry out the activity.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

314

Part 4

The Virtues and Limitations of Markets

case, a paper mill). The mill maximizes profits by providing 100,000 tons of output, corresponding to the intersection between the marginal private cost and marginal revenue curves (point A). Now suppose that the factory’s wastewater pollutes a nearby estuary, so that its production creates a detrimental externality for which the owners do not pay. Then marginal social cost must be higher than marginal private cost, as shown in the diagram. The output of paper, which is governed by private costs, will be 100,000 tons (point A)—an excessive amount from the viewpoint of the public interest, given its environmental consequences. If, instead of being able to impose the external costs on others, the paper mill’s owners were forced to pay them, then their private marginal cost curve would correspond to the higher of the two cost curves. Paper output would then fall to 35,000 tons, corresponding to point B, the intersection between the marginal revenue curve and the marginal social cost curve. The same sort of diagram shows that the opposite relationship will hold when the firm’s activity produces beneficial externalities. The firm will produce less of its beneficial output than it would if it were rewarded fully for its activities’ benefits. Thus, Where the firm’s activity generates beneficial externalities, free markets will produce too little output. Society would be better off with larger output levels.

Tulip Output in Dozens

We can also see these results with the help of a production possibilities frontier diagram similar to that in Figure 1. In Figure 3, we see the frontier for two industries: electricity F IGURE 3 generation, which causes air pollution (a detrimental externality), and tulip growing, which makes an area more attractive (a beneficial externality). We have just seen that Externalities, Market Equilibrium, and detrimental externalities make marginal social cost greater than marginal private cost. Efficient Resource Hence, if the electric company charges a price equal to its Allocation own marginal (private) cost, that price will be less than the true marginal social cost. Similarly, in tulip growing, a price equal to marginal private cost will be above the true marginal cost to society. Earlier in the chapter, we saw that an industry that B charges a price above marginal social cost will reduce T quantity demanded through this high price, and so it will K produce an output too small for an efficient allocation of resources. The opposite will be true for an industry whose price is below marginal social cost. In terms of Figure 3, suppose that point B again represents the efficient allocation of resources, involving the production of E kilowatt0 E hours of electricity and T dozen tulips. Because the polluting electricity-generation company Electricity Output in Kilowatt-Hours charges a price below marginal social cost, it will sell more than E kilowatt-hours of electricity. Similarly, because tulip growers generate external benefits and so charge a price above marginal social cost, they will produce less than T dozen tulips. The economy will end up with the resource allocation represented by point K rather than that at point B. There will be too much smoky electricity production and too little attractive tulip growing. More generally: An industry that generates detrimental externalities will have a marginal social cost higher than its marginal private cost. If the price is equal to a firm’s own marginal private cost, it will therefore be below the true marginal cost to society. In this way, the market mechanism tends to encourage inefficiently large outputs of products that cause detrimental externalities. The opposite is true of products that cause beneficial externalities; private industry will provide inefficiently small quantities of these products.

Externalities Are Everywhere Externalities occur throughout the economy. Many are beneficial. A factory that hires unskilled or semiskilled laborers, for example, gives them on-the-job training and provides

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 15

315

The Shortcomings of Free Markets

the external benefit of better workers to future employers. Benefits to others are also generated when firms invent useful but unpatentable products, or even patentable products that can be imitated by others to some degree. Detrimental externalities are also widespread. Pollution by factories, cars, and trucks causes some of our most pressing environmental problems. The abandonment of buildings causes the quality of neighborhoods to deteriorate and is the source of serious externalities for cities. And these are only two of many significant examples. We have yet to mention the most threatening damaging externality of them all—global warming. The authors of this book cannot claim to be experts on the subject, which still gives rise to debate, though the skeptics who deny the dangers or the role of human actions in generating the emissions that are believed to be heating the climate seem to be retreating in their opposition. But it is clear that if the full threat materializes, the cost to humanity will be enormous, with flooding of cities, the turning of formerly flourishing areas into deserts, and possibly even worse. And the likely source of the problem is emissions, not only factories but you and we, the authors of this book, as we drive our cars and grill our steaks. This brings out an important point: Damaging externalities are caused not only by business firms. They are created by the military when they drive their tanks and fly their airplanes, by farmers when they spray their fields, and by consumers such as ourselves. We all do it. Although the market mechanism, acting on its own, does nothing to cure externality problems, there is more to the story. Market economies often have dirty air and rivers and suffer from the effects of improperly disposed toxic wastes, but that does not mean that nonmarket economies do any better. The communist countries of Eastern Europe and the Soviet Union long were known to have a dismal environmental record. When communism fell apart in those countries, the revealed horrors of environmental degradation were hard to believe. It became abundantly clear that central planning is not a guaranteed cure for environmental difficulties. Moreover, the market mechanism does offer an effective way of dealing with such difficulties. Although markets hardly can be claimed to protect the environment automatically, they offer us a powerful tool for doing so, as we will see shortly.

Government Policy and Externalities Because of the market’s inability to cope with externalities, governments support activities that are believed to generate external benefits. Governments subsidize education, not only because they know it helps promote equal opportunity for all citizens but also because they believe it generates beneficial externalities. For example, educated people normally commit fewer crimes than uneducated people do, so the more we educate people, presumably the less we need to spend on crime prevention. Also, academic research that is a by-product of the educational system has often benefited the entire population and has, indeed, been a major contributor to the nation’s economic growth. Biotechnology and advanced computing are just two major scientific breakthroughs that have stemmed from university research. It is believed that if education were offered only by profit-making institutions, the outputs of these beneficial services would be provided at less than optimal levels. Similarly, governments have begun to increase fines on companies that contribute heavily to air and water pollution. In the years just before George W. Bush’s administration, the U.S. Environmental Protection Agency levied more criminal fines and civil penalties against violators than ever before. This is done, of course, as a disincentive for the creation of socially damaging externalities. In other words, it brings the amounts that business firms pay closer to covering all of the costs that their activities generate. EXTERNALITIES: A SHORTCOMING OF THE MARKET CURED BY MARKET METHODS Externalities are really just failures to price resources so that markets will allocate them efficiently. One effective way to deal with externalities may be to use taxes and subsidies, making polluters pay for the costs they impose on society and paying the generators of beneficial externalities for the incidental benefits of their activities (which can be considered as an offset or deduction from the social cost of the activity).

IDEAS FOR BEYOND THE FINAL EXAM

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

316

Part 4

The Virtues and Limitations of Markets

Externalities Cured by Negotiation: The Coase Theorem We have just seen how the damage to the public interest that results from externalities can be prevented by government intervention— for example, by taxing damaging externalities. But there are cases in which the market mechanism can take care of the problem and even obtain an optimal outcome by negotiation between the individuals who produce the externalities and the individuals who are affected by them. This possibility was first recognized by Ronald Coase, who received the Nobel Prize in 1991. A simple example will bring out the logic of these cases. Imagine a very profitable factory that creates a lot of noise which prevents the owner of a nearby home from sleeping. Suppose it is possible for the factory owner to muffle the sound of his indispensable machinery at a cost of $10,000, but that the homeowner can protect himself by putting up a noise-muffling wall at a cost of $15,000. The obviously efficient outcome is for the homeowner to pay the factory owner $10,000, and perhaps a bit more, as an inducement to install the muffler, because that will cost the noise victim less than the $15,000 wall. This solution is clearly the socially optimal choice because it protects the victim at the lowest possible cost. But suppose that, instead of leaving the homeowner to fend for himself, the local municipality passes a law saying that the owner of the factory is responsible for the damage that the noise causes to the homeowner. Then the factory owner will again select the $10,000 muffler in the factory, rather than the wall in the home, because it is the least expensive way to comply with the law. This example illustrates the second and more surprising feature of the Coase theorem. For it shows that no matter which of the two parties has the upper hand, the outcome of the negotiation will be the

same: the noise will be muffled in the way that has the lowest cost. Even if the factory owner is not forced to fix the problem, it will pay the homeowner to bribe the factory owner to reduce the noise via the low-cost remedy. And if, instead, the law requires remedial action by the factory owner, he will do exactly the same thing. So, in such cases, there is no need for the government to intervene. But this ingenious idea has its limitations; there are a number of circumstances in which things do not work out so nicely. First, the story assumes that both parties are coolly rational—they just want to solve the problem at the lowest cost. But suppose the homeowner hates the factory owner and vows never to give the latter even a single dollar, no matter what the alternative costs. Then he will be stuck with either unceasing noise or a $15,000 bill to build a wall in his house. That isn’t the only problem with Coase’s proposed solution. Suppose a costly lawsuit is required to get the owners to negotiate. Or suppose there are hundreds of houses nearby, with the noise preventing all the residents from sleeping. Then what is required for the Coase solution to work is a successful negotiation involving hundreds of homeowners and the factory owner. Everyone knows that negotiation involving such a mob will be time consuming, costly, and often yield irrational results. To take this objection even farther, imagine trying to use the Coase solution to solve the pollution problems caused by the hundreds of thousands of automobiles that travel through a major city every day. Surely, only chaos would result. And the externalities on which global warming is blamed are even more complex and involve literally billions of parties. So there are clearly times and places where government intervention in the public interest is indispensable.

For example, the analysis implies that firms that generate beneficial externalities should be given subsidies per unit of their output equal to the difference between their marginal social costs and their marginal private costs. Similarly, detrimental externalities should be taxed so that the firm will have to pay the entire marginal social cost. In terms of Figure 2, after paying the tax, the firm’s marginal private cost curve will shift up until it coincides with its marginal social cost curve, so the market price will be set in a manner consistent with efficient resource allocation. Although this approach works well in principle, it is often difficult to carry out in reality. Social costs are rarely easy to estimate, partly because they are so widely diffused throughout the community (everyone is affected by pollution) and partly because it is difficult to assess many of the costs and benefits (effects on health, unpleasantness of living in smog) in monetary terms. In Chapter 17, which focuses on environmental problems, we will continue our discussion of the pros and cons of the economist’s approach to externalities and will outline alternative policies for their control.

PROVISION OF PUBLIC GOODS A second area in which market failure occurs is the provision of what economists call public goods. Public goods are socially valuable commodities whose provision, for reasons we will explain, cannot be financed by private enterprise, or at least not at socially desirable prices. Thus, government must pay for public goods if they are to be provided

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

The Shortcomings of Free Markets

317

at all. Standard examples of public goods include everything from national defense to coastal lighthouses. It is easiest to explain the nature of public goods by contrasting them with private goods, which are at the opposite end of the spectrum. Private goods are characterized by two important attributes. One can be called depletability. If you eat an apple or use a gallon of gasoline, there is that much less fruit or fuel in the world available for others to use. Your consumption depletes the supply available for other people, either temporarily or permanently. But a pure public good is like the legendary widow’s jar of oil, which always remained full, no matter how much oil was poured out. For example, once snow has been removed from a street, improved driving conditions are available to every driver who uses that street, whether 10 or 1,000 cars pass that way. One passing car does not make the road less snow-free for the next driver. The same is true of spraying swamps near a town to kill malarial mosquitoes. The cost of spraying is the same whether the town contains 10,000 or 20,000 people. A resident of the town who benefits from this service does not deplete its advantages to others. The other property that characterizes private goods but not all public goods is excludability, meaning that anyone who does not pay for the good can be excluded from enjoying its benefits. If you do not buy a ticket, you are excluded from the basketball game. If you do not pay for an electric guitar, the storekeeper will not hand it over to you. But some goods or services, once provided to anyone, automatically become available to many others whom it is difficult, if not impossible, to exclude from the benefits. When the street is cleared of snow, everyone who uses the street benefits, regardless of who paid for the snowplow. If a country provides a strong military, every citizen receives its protection, even persons who do not want it. A public good is defined as a good that lacks depletability. Very often, it also lacks excludability. Notice two important implications. First, because nonpaying users usually cannot be excluded from enjoying a public good, suppliers of such goods will find it difficult or impossible to collect fees for the benefits they provide. This is the so-called free-rider problem. How many people, for example, would voluntarily spend close to $6,000 a year to support our national defense establishment? Yet this is roughly what it costs per American family. Services such as national defense and public health, which are not depletable and where excludability is impossible, cannot be provided by private enterprise because people will not pay for what they can get free. Because private firms are not in the business of giving services away, the supply of public goods must be left to government and nonprofit institutions. The second implication we notice is that, because the supply of a public good is not depleted by an additional user, the marginal (opportunity) cost of serving an additional user is zero. With marginal cost equal to zero, the basic principle of optimal resource allocation (price equal to marginal cost) calls for provision of public goods and services to anyone who wants them at no charge. In other words, not only is it often impossible to charge a market price for a public good, it is often undesirable as well. Any nonzero price would discourage some users from enjoying the public good; but this would be inefficient, because one more person’s enjoyment of the good costs society nothing. To summarize:

A public good is a commodity or service whose benefits are not depleted by an additional user and from which it is generally difficult or impossible to exclude people, even if the people are unwilling to pay for the benefits.

Chapter 15

A private good is a commodity characterized by both depletability and excludability. A commodity is depletable if it is used up when someone consumes it. A commodity is excludable if someone who does not pay for it can be kept from enjoying it.

It is usually not possible to charge a price for a pure public good because people cannot be excluded from enjoying its benefits. It may also be undesirable to charge a price for it because that would discourage some people from benefiting, even though using a public good does not deplete its supply. For both of these reasons, government supplies many public goods. Without government intervention, public goods simply would not be provided.

Referring back to our example in Figure 1, if backpacks were a public good and their production were left to private enterprise, the economy would end up at point A, with zero production of backpacks and a far greater output of jeans than is called for by efficient allocation (point B). Usually, communities have not let that happen; today they devote a substantial proportion of government expenditure—indeed, the bulk of municipal budgets—to financing of public goods or services believed to generate substantial

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

318

Part 4

The Virtues and Limitations of Markets

external benefits. National defense, public health, police and fire protection, and research are among the services governments provide because they offer beneficial externalities or are public goods.

ALLOCATION OF RESOURCES BETWEEN PRESENT AND FUTURE A third area in which market failure occurs is the division of benefits between today and tomorrow. When a firm invests in a new plant and equipment, more resources are devoted to expanding its capacity to produce consumer goods in the future. But if we devote inputs to building new factories and equipment that will add to production tomorrow, those resources then become unavailable for consumption now. Fuel used to make steel for a new factory building cannot be used to heat homes or drive cars. Thus, the allocation of inputs between current consumption and investment—their allocation between present and future—influences how fast the economy grows. Investment in education has a similar role, because people who are educated today are likely to be more effective producers tomorrow, and if education enables them to contribute inventions, that may increase tomorrow’s production even more. That is why economists refer to education as “investment in human capital,” thereby thinking of more educated people as analogous to machinery in the factory whose efficiency is increased by modernization. In principle, the market mechanism should be as efficient in allocating resources between present and future uses as it is in allocating resources among different outputs at any one time. If future demands for a particular commodity, such as personal computers, are expected to be higher than they are today, it pays manufacturers to plan now to build the necessary plant and equipment so they will be ready to turn out the computers when the market expands. More resources are thereby allocated to future consumption. We can analyze the allocation of resources between present and future with the aid of a production possibilities frontier diagram, such as the one in Figure 1. The question now is how much labor and capital to devote to producing consumers’ goods and how much to devote to construction of durable facilities to produce output in the future. Then, instead of jeans and backpacks, the graph will show consumers’ goods and number of facilities on its axes, but otherwise it will be exactly the same as Figure 1. The profit motive directs the flow of resources between one time period and another, just as it handles resource allocation among different industries in a given period. The lure of profits directs resources to those products and those time periods in which high prices promise to make output most profitable. But at least one feature of the process of resource allocation among different time periods distinguishes it from the process of allocation among industries—the special role that the interest rate plays in allocation among time periods.

The Role of the Interest Rate If receipt of a given amount of money is delayed until some future time, the recipient incurs an opportunity cost—the interest that the money could have earned if it had been received earlier and invested. For example, if the prevailing interest rate is 9 percent and you can persuade someone who owes you $100 to make that payment one year earlier than originally planned, you come out $9 ahead (because you can take the $100 and invest it at 9 percent). Put another way, if the interest rate is 9 percent and the payment of $100 is postponed for one year, you lose the opportunity to earn $9. Thus, the interest rate determines the opportunity cost to a recipient who gets money at some future date instead of now—the lower the interest rate, the lower the opportunity cost. For this reason, as we will see in greater detail in Chapter 19: Low interest rates will persuade people to invest more now in factories and equipment, because that will reduce the opportunity cost of these investments, which yield a large portion of their money returns in the future. Thus, more resources will be devoted to the future by investment in durable production facilities now if interest rates are low. Similarly, high interest rates make durable investment less attractive, because it yields

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 15

The Shortcomings of Free Markets

much of its benefit only in the future, when it is too late to obtain much of the interest payment that earlier receipt of the earnings would have made possible. Therefore, high interest rates tend to increase the public’s use of resources for output today at the expense of reduced future output tomorrow.

On the surface, it seems that the price system can allocate resources among different time periods in the way consumers prefer, because the supply of and demand for loans, which determine the interest rate—the price of a loan—reflects the public’s preferences between present and future. Suppose, for example, that the public suddenly became more interested in future consumption (say, people wanted to put more money away for their retirement years). People would save more money, the supply of funds available for lending would increase relative to demand, and interest rates, the price of a loan of money, would tend to fall. This would stimulate investment and add to the future output of goods at the expense of current consumption. But economists have raised several questions about how effectively the market mechanism allocates resources among different time periods in practice.

How Does It Work in Practice? One thing that makes economists uneasy is that the interest rate (which is the price that controls resource allocation over time) is also used for a variety of other purposes. For instance, sometimes the interest rate is used to deal with business fluctuations. For instance, the government will take steps to push interest rates down in order to induce people to borrow and increase their spending and thereby stimulate business. For this and other similar reasons, governments frequently manipulate interest rates. For example, during the economic crisis of 2007–2008, the Federal Reserve Board—the organization that oversees the activities of banks in the United States—reduced interest rates repeatedly in order to make it cheaper for consumers and firms to borrow and buy consumers’ goods or to invest in new plant and equipment. In doing so, policy makers seem to give little thought to the effects on resource allocation between present and future, so we may well worry whether the resulting interest rates were the most appropriate from that point of view. Second, some economists have suggested that even when the government does not manipulate the interest rate, the market may devote too large a proportion of the economy’s resources to immediate consumption. One British economist, A. C. Pigou, argued that people suffer from a “defective telescopic faculty”—that they are too shortsighted to give adequate weight to the future. A “bird in the hand” point of view leads people to spend too much on today’s consumption and commit too little to tomorrow’s investments. Third, our economy shortchanges the future when it despoils irreplaceable natural resources, exterminates whole species of plants and animals, floods canyons, “develops” attractive areas into acres of potential slums, and so on. Worst of all, industry, the military, and individuals bequeath a ticking time bomb to the future when they leave behind lethal and slow-acting toxic residues. For example, nuclear wastes may remain dangerous for hundreds or even thousands of years, but their disposal containers are likely to fall apart long before the contents lose their lethal qualities. Such actions are essentially irreversible. If a factory is not built this year, the deficiency in facilities provided for the future can be remedied by building it next year. But a natural canyon, once destroyed, can never be replaced. For this reason, Many economists believe that irreversible decisions have a special significance and must not be left entirely to the decisions of private firms and individuals—that is, to the market.

Some writers, however, have questioned the general conclusion that the free market will not invest enough for the future. They point out that our economy’s prosperity has increased fairly steadily from one decade to the next, and that there is reason to expect future generations to have far higher real average incomes and an abundance of consumer goods than we have today, just as we are economically better off than our grandparents. Pressures to increase future investment then may be like taking from the poor to give to the rich—a sort of backward Robin Hood redistribution of income.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

319

320

Part 4

The Virtues and Limitations of Markets

SOME OTHER SOURCES OF MARKET FAILURE We have now surveyed some of the most important imperfections of the market mechanism, but our list is not complete, and it can never be. In this imperfect world, nothing ever works out ideally. Indeed, by examining anything with a sufficiently powerful microscope, one can always detect more blemishes. However, some significant items were omitted from our list. We will conclude with a brief description of three of them and discuss a fourth of special current interest in somewhat greater detail.

Imperfect Information: “Caveat Emptor” In our analysis of the virtues of the market mechanism in Chapter 14, we assumed that consumers and producers have all the information they need to make good decisions. In reality, this is rarely true. When buying a house or secondhand car or when selecting a doctor, consumers are vividly reminded of how little they know about what they are purchasing. The old cliché, “caveat emptor” (let the buyer beware), applies. Obviously, if participants in the market are ill-informed, they will not always make the optimal decisions described in our theoretical models. (For more on this issue, see “Asymmetric Information, ‘Lemons,’ and Agents,” on the next page.) Yet not all economists agree that imperfect information is really a failure of the market mechanism. They point out that information, too, is a commodity that costs money to produce. Neither firms nor consumers have complete information because it would be irrational for them to spend the enormous amounts needed to get it. As always, compromise is necessary. One should, ideally, stop buying information at the point where the marginal utility of further information is no greater than its marginal cost. With this amount of information, the business executive or the consumer would be able to make what we call “optimally imperfect” decisions.

Rent Seeking

Rent seeking refers to unproductive activity in the pursuit of economic profit—in other words, undeserved profit in excess of competitive earnings.

Moral hazard refers to the tendency of insurance to discourage policyholders from protecting themselves from risk.

An army of lawyers, expert witnesses, and business executives crowd our courtrooms and cause enormous costs to pile up through litigation. Business firms seem to sue each other at the slightest provocation, wasting vast resources and delaying business decisions. Why? Because it is possible to make money by such seemingly unproductive activities— through legal battles over profit-making opportunities. For example, suppose that a municipality awards a contract to produce electricity to Firm A, offering $20 million in profit. It may be worthwhile for Firm B to spend $5 million in a lawsuit against the municipality and Firm A, hoping that the courts will award it the contract (and thus the $20 million profit) instead. In general, any source of unusual profit, such as a monopoly, tempts firms to waste economic resources in an effort to obtain control of that source of profit. This process, called rent seeking (meaning that the firms hope to obtain earnings without contributing to production), is judged by some observers to be a major source of inefficiency in our economy. (For more on rent seeking, see pages 408–409 in Chapter 19.)

Moral Hazard Another widely discussed problem for the market mechanism is associated with insurance. Economists view insurance—which is the provision of protection against risk—as a useful commodity, like shoes or information. But insurance also encourages the very risks against which it provides protection. For example, if an individual has a valuable stamp collection that is fully insured against theft, she has little motivation to protect it against burglars, because if it is stolen she will get her money back from the insurance company. She may, for example, fail to lock it up in a safe-deposit box. This problem—the tendency of insurance to encourage the source of risk—is called moral hazard, and it makes a free market in insurance difficult to operate.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 15

321

The Shortcomings of Free Markets

Asymmetric Information, “Lemons,” and Agents already deserted the sinking ship with large bonus payments, having sold their company stocks while the price was still high. Asymmetric information is crucial here. Principals usually know only imperfectly whether their agents are serving their interests faithfully and efficiently or are instead neglecting or even acting against the principals’ interests to pursue selfish interests of their own. Misuse of the principals’ property, embezzlement, and political corruption are extreme examples of such dereliction of duty by agents and, unfortunately, they seem to occur often. One way that has been used to address the asymmetric information problem that has often failed spectacularly is based on the following logic. If the earnings of corporate management can be linked quite tightly to company profits or based on the market value of company shares, then by promoting the welfare of stockholders, managers will make themselves better off. Shareholders, even though they know only imperfectly what management is doing, can have greater confidence that management will try to serve their interests well. We will presently discuss what has gone wrong with this approach.

SOURCE: © Photopia

Have you ever wondered why a six-month-old car sells for so much less than a brand-new one? Economists offer one explanation, having to do with imperfect information. The problem is that some small percentage of new automobiles are “lemons” that are plagued by mechanical troubles. The new-car dealer probably knows no more than the buyer about whether a particular car is a lemon. The information known to the two parties, therefore, is said to be symmetric, and there is a low probability that a car purchased from a new-car dealer will turn out to be a lemon. In the used-car market, however, information is asymmetric. The person selling the used car knows very well whether the car is a lemon, but the buyer does not. Moreover, a seller who wants to get rid of a relatively new car is likely to be doing so only because it is a lemon. Potential buyers realize that. Hence, if a person is forced to sell a good new car because of an unexpected need for cash, he will be stuck with a low price because he cannot prove that his car really works well. The moral is that asymmetric information also tends to harm the honest seller. In addition, asymmetric information leads to the principal-agent problems, which are discussed in the text and whose analysis is a major concern of recent economic research. Principal-agent and asymmetric information problems are said to have played a major part in the much-publicized Enron debacle. When that huge energy trading firm collapsed, stockholders—the “principals” (including Enron employees whose retirement money was invested in the firm)— lost their savings. Stockholders are called principals because they are, according to the law, the owners of the firm. But Enron’s management, the stockholders’ employees (their hired agents), had

Principals, Agents, and Recent Stock Option Scandals Yet another important area of concern about the performance of the unconstrained market is called the “principal-agent problem,” which has just been mentioned. The economy contains many activities so large and complex that it is out of the question for them to be organized and operated by those most directly concerned. The most striking example is provided by our representative democracy that is, in theory, run by “We the people.” But it is obvious that it would be quite impractical to assemble all of the citizens of the country to discuss and decide on the details of proposed legislation on complex matters such as trade policy or rules for protection of the environment. So, instead, the U.S. Constitution requires us to hire politicians via the election process to run the country on our behalf. In economic terminology, we would say that the citizens are the principals in the activity of running the country, and the president and members of Congress are the agents who are hired by us, the principals, to operate the country on our behalf. A second example, the one on which we will focus here, is the running of a corporation. A giant corporation such as Intel (the largest producer of microprocessors for computers) has thousands of stockholder-owners. And, like citizens of a country, they are also too numerous to run the firm day by day, making the thousands of required decisions. So these principals, too, hire agents—the corporate management—to do the job. The assigned task of the agents is to run the corporation in a way that best promotes the interests of the stockholders. The main problem that besets this arrangement, like all principal-agent arrangements, is that the agents cannot always be trusted. All too often they put their own interests ahead of those of their principals, in clear dereliction of duty. Indeed, in just this decade so far, there has been what seems like a flood of corporate scandals, with managements

Agents are people hired to run a complex enterprise on behalf of the principals, those whose benefit the enterprise is supposed to serve.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

322

Part 4

The Virtues and Limitations of Markets

A stock option is a contract that permits its owner to buy a specified quantity of stocks of a corporation at a future date, but at the price specified in the contract rather than the stock’s market price at the date of purchase.

having indiscriminately betrayed stockholders and employees while obtaining for themselves hundreds of millions of dollars as their supposedly merited rewards. (For examples, see the feature box in Chapter 9 on “Corporate Scandals.”) Economic analysis suggests a solution to the problem: Arrange for the amount that the agents are paid to depend on the degree to which their actions succeed in benefiting the principals. Pay the agents a lot if they achieve much for the principals, and pay them little if they don’t. If such an incentive scheme is established, the agents can do well for themselves only by doing well for the stockholders. The only trouble with this solution is that it is easier to describe on paper than to carry out in practice. First, it is not easy to measure what the agents have actually accomplished. If the company’s sales increased, was that because of something management did, or was it largely an accident? The second problem is that unscrupulous managers can often find ways to get around such rules via legal maneuvers or by appointing friends and allies to the company’s board of directors, rather than even-handed appointees who can assure the honesty and competence of management. One seemingly clever device was thought up to do the job of rewarding management for what they achieve: the employee stock option. But corruption within firms and irrational tax laws that undermine their effectiveness, among other impediments, have prevented stock options from doing the job they were intended to do. Let us see what stock options are and why they have often been ineffective. A stock option is, in effect, a contract that allows the person who owns the option to buy a specified quantity of the company’s stock at some date in the future that can be chosen, within specified limits, by the owner. But when the option owner pays for the stock, he pays not the price on the day the stock is bought but, rather, the price of the stock on the day the option was obtained. For example, suppose the price of the stock was $40 on February 12, the day the option was acquired. On March 23, the owner considers using the option to buy the stock. If the price has fallen to $30, the option owner will decide not to buy any stock because, if he did, the option contract would require him to spend $40 for a stock worth only $30, clearly a losing proposition. But suppose the stock had gone in the other direction and, on the proposed purchase date, the share’s price had risen to $60. Since this means that the option owner could acquire a stock worth $60 for only $40, it would give him an immediate $20 profit—a very good deal. When the price of the company’s stock goes down, stock options are not used. Thus, the owner of the option loses only what was paid for the option, if anything. But if the price of the stock rises, the owner can make a profit by “exercising the option”; that is, by using it to buy the stock and pocketing the difference between the price specified in the option and the value of the stock at the time it is bought.

If stock options are granted to a corporation’s management under appropriate rules, they may well be a powerful way to deal with the principal-agent problem in corporations. For if managers who own stock options work harder to make the company successful, their actions can raise the market price of the corporation’s stock, thereby benefiting the stockholders as well as themselves. In other words, a gift or sale of stock options to management can help align the interests of stockholders and management: They both want the stock price to rise. Few other instruments can ensure such compatibility between the interest of stockholders and managers. However, the conditions under which stock options are now granted are far from this ideal. They can, for instance, lead management to focus on short-term gains in stock prices, rather than on the long-run performance of the firm. They reward management even when the firm’s performance is worse than that of the industry and that of the stock market as a whole. And subservient boards of directors often provide staggering and probably undeserved managerial compensation in the form of huge gifts of stock options. Unscrupulous managers have learned ways to manipulate stock options and undermine their benefits to stockholders. For instance, there have been cases in which management sent out misleading information indicating, falsely, that the company was about to make large profits. This raised the price of its stock temporarily, giving the holders of

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 15

The Shortcomings of Free Markets

stock options an opportunity to use them quickly to buy the stocks at the low prices specified in the options and quickly sell the shares while their market price was still high, thus making a large profit for themselves. Such problems are best attacked directly by requiring the issue of stock options to management to satisfy provisions such as the following: 1. That exercise of those stock options should not be permitted for some substantial period of time, say five years, after they are initially offered; 2. That the stock options be performance-based, meaning that they are contingent on performance by the firm that exceeds that of comparable firms or of the firm’s own past record, with the number of stock options granted to management proportioned to the magnitude of the superiority of the firm’s performance; 3. That any such grant of options to management be subject to approval by vote of the firm’s stockholders; and 4. That the sale of such shares by top management be made public promptly. Stock options granted on these terms may well lead to a dramatic change in the incentives facing management—and in the desired direction. If the improved incentives created by options succeed in their purpose of fostering higher earnings, the gift of options to management may involve no cost to stockholders. On the contrary, earnings per share will probably be higher than they would otherwise have been, and both managers and shareholders will benefit. But unfortunately, the existing rules do not contain such provisions to protect the interests of the shareholders (the principals). There are even rules that discourage some of those provisions. For example, under current tax rules, a company obtains some tax advantages if it uses stock options as part of management’s compensation. But the law offers those advantages only if the grant of options is not made to depend on how well management performs for the company. Only if the options are given outright, with no difference in reward between cases where management performs its job well and where it does badly, do the current rules offer a tax benefit to the company.

MARKET FAILURE AND GOVERNMENT FAILURE We have pointed out some of the invisible hand’s most noteworthy failures. We seem forced to the conclusion that a market economy, if left entirely to itself, is likely to produce results that are, at least in some respects, far from ideal. We have noted in our discussion, either directly or by implication, some of the things that government can do to correct these deficiencies. But the fact that government often can intervene in the economy’s operation in a constructive way does not always mean that it actually will succeed in doing so. Governments cannot be relied on to behave ideally, any more than business firms can be expected to do so. It is difficult to make this point in a suitably balanced way. Commentators too often stake out one extreme position or the other. Some people think the market mechanism is inherently unfair and biased by the greed of those who run its enterprises and they look to the government to cure all economic ills. Others deplore government intervention and consider the public sector to be the home of every sort of inefficiency, graft, and bureaucratic stultification. The truth, as usual, lies somewhere in between. Governments, like humans, are inherently imperfect. The political process leads to compromises that sometimes bear little resemblance to rational decisions. For example, legislators’ versions of the policies suggested by economic analysis are sometimes mere caricatures of the economists’ ideas. (For a satirical editorial illustrating this point, see “The Politics of Economic Policy.”) Yet often the problems engendered by an unfettered economy are too serious to be left to the free market. The problems of inflation, environmental decay, and the provision of public goods are cases in point. In such instances, government intervention is likely to yield substantial benefits to the general public. However, even when some government action is clearly warranted, it may be difficult or impossible to calculate the optimal degree

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

323

324

Part 4

The Virtues and Limitations of Markets

The Politics of Economic Policy

If the administration adopts the Kahn plan, recent history offers a pretty clear view of the rest of the story. Mr. Kahn will draft a one-page bill to raise the tax on the one kind of gas and lower it on the other. But the White House political staff will immediately point out that his draft fails to address profound questions of social equity. What about the poor, who buy leaded gas because it’s cheaper? What about young people driving old cars? What about the inhabitants of lower Louisiana, who need their outboard motors to get around the swamps and bayous? There will have to be a rebate formula. It will take into account each family’s income, the number and ages of its various automobiles and the distance from its front doorstep to the bus stop. The legislative draftsmen at the Energy Department have had a lot of experience with that kind of formula and eventually the 53-page bill will be sent to Congress. . . . The real fun will start when it arrives at the Senate Finance Committee. First the committee will add tuition tax credits for families with children in private schools. Then, warming to its work, it will vote

import quotas on straw hats from Hong Kong, beef from Argentina and automobiles from Japan. . . . [I]t will then add several obscure but pregnant provisions that seem to refer to the tax treatment of certain oil wells in the Gulf states. When the 268-page bill comes to the Senate floor, the administration will narrowly manage to defeat an amendment to improve business confidence by repealing the capital-gains tax and returning to the gold standard. When the bill gets back to the House, liberal Democrats will denounce it as an outrage and declare all-out war. They will succeed in getting all references to gasoline taxes and the environment stricken—but not, unfortunately, the import quotas or the obscure tax changes for the oil wells. By the time the staff of the Joint Committee on Taxation has straightened out a few technical difficulties, the bill will run to 417 pages and Ralph Nader will be calling on President Carter to veto it. But the feeling at the White House will be that Congress has worked so long and hard on the bill that he has no choice but to sign it. By the time the bill is finally enacted, Mr. Kahn might well wish he had chosen some other instrument of policy. SOURCE: The Museum of Modern Art, New York, NY Digital Image © The Museum of Modern Art/Licensed by SCALA/Art Resource, NY

In 1978, Alfred Kahn, a noted economist who served in the administration of President Jimmy Carter, advocated reducing pollution by raising the tax on leaded gasoline and lowering the tax on unleaded gasoline. The Washington Post, in an editorial excerpted here, agreed that Kahn’s idea was a sound one but worried about what might emerge from Congress:

SOURCE: Alfred E. Kahn, “The Politics of Economic Policy” from the Washington Post, December 26, 1978. Reprinted by permission of Alfred E. Kahn, Robert Julius Thorne Professor of Political Economy, Emeritus, Cornell University.

of governmental intervention. There is, then, the danger of intervention so excessive that the society might have been better off without it. In other areas, the market mechanism is likely to work reasonably well, and small imperfections do not constitute adequate justification for government intervention. In any event, even where government action is appropriate, we must consider market-like instruments as one possible way to correct market mechanism deficiencies. The tax incentives described earlier in our discussion of externalities are an outstanding example of what we have in mind.

THE COST DISEASE OF SOME VITAL SERVICES: INVITATION TO GOVERNMENT FAILURE As our final example, we consider next a problem that is not strictly a failure of the market mechanism. Rather, it is a case where the market’s behavior creates that illusion and often leads to ill-advised government action that threatens the general welfare. This problem concerns dramatically rising prices, as typified by health-care and college tuitions. (For more on health-care costs and the 2010 U.S. health-care reforms, see “The Economics of America’s 2010 Health-Care Reform” on page 328.) As a reader of this book, you are well aware that your attendance at an American college is likely to cost as much as $50,000 per year. When the older of the two authors of this book attended graduate school in the mid-1900s, the fee was a little over $100 per year. That is a dramatic rise in cost, and it has hit not only college tuitions. In this section, we will examine the reasons for these rising prices and other disturbing developments in the affected segments of the economy.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

The Shortcomings of Free Markets

Chapter 15

Deteriorating Personal Services

SOURCE: By Rose for Byrd Newspapers, Harrisburg, VA

Over the years, general standards of living have increased and our material possessions have multiplied. But at the same time, our communities have experienced a decline in the quality of a variety of public and private services. Not just in the United States, but throughout the world, streets and subways, for example, have grown increasingly dirty. Bus, train, and postal services have all been cut back. Amazingly enough, in the 1800s in suburban London, there were twelve mail deliveries per day on weekdays, including Saturdays, and one on Sundays! Today, mail service in the United Kingdom is hardly a subject of admiration anymore. Parallel cutbacks have occurred in the quality of private services. Milk once used to be delivered to individual homes every day, and it was not necessary to push five buttons successively on the telephone to get to speak to a human being at the bank. Doctors almost never visit patients at home anymore. In many areas a house call, which 50 years ago was a commonplace event, now occurs only rarely. Another example, although undoubtedly a matter for less general concern, is the quality of food served in restaurants. Even some of the most elegant and expensive restaurants serve frozen and reheated meals—charging high prices for what amounts to little more than TV dinners.

Personal Services Are Getting More Expensive Perhaps most distressing of all, and closely connected with the problems just described, is the persistent and dramatic rise in the cost of what we call personal services—services that require face-to-face, in-person interaction between the supplier and the consumer, such as health care and education. As a college student, you know how fast college tuitions have been increasing. But you may not realize that the cost of a hospital stay has been going up even more rapidly. Worse still, the cost of health care has denied adequate health services to a substantial portion of our population—the poor and even some members of the middle class. These cost increases have prompted most industrialized countries— most recently, the U.S.—to adopt health-care regulations aimed at controlling costs and keeping care affordable for their citizens. Consider these facts: Between 1948 and 2008, the Consumer Price Index (CPI) (an official measure of overall price rises in the economy) increased at an average rate of about 3.7 percent per year, whereas the price of physicians’ services rose about 5.2 percent per year. This difference seems tiny, but compounded over those 60 years it had the effect of increasing the price of a doctor visit, measured in dollars of constant purchasing power, by 229 percent. In the last three decades, the price of hospital care also skyrocketed: The average price of inpatient hospital services increased at an annual rate of about 7.86 percent, compounded continuously. This amounts to a nearly 300 percent increase since 1948, measured in constant dollars from which the effects of inflation have been eliminated.2 Virtually every major industrial nation has tried to prevent health-care costs from rising faster than its economy’s overall rate of inflation, but none has succeeded, as Figure 4 shows. In this graph, the bar for each country shows its average yearly rate of increase in

These figures were derived from data provided by the U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, available at http://www.bls.gov.

2

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

325

326

Part 4

The Virtues and Limitations of Markets

FIGU R E 4 Average Annual Growth Rates in Real Health-Care Expenditure per Capita between 1960 and 2006

6

4

3

2

1

0

Japan

Average Annual Growth Rates in Real Education Expenditure between 1995 and 2004

Real Average Annual Increase (percentage)

5

United Kingdom

4 3.5 3 2.5 2 1.5 1 0.5 United States

Germany

Netherlands

real (inflation-adjusted) health-care spending per person between 1960 and 2006. It is clear that the United States did not exhibit the highest rate of increase in real health-care costs. The cost of education has a similar record—costs in the United States have increased at an average annual rate of 4.5 percent per year in the last decade. Between 1995 and 2004, U.S. increases in education costs were the highest among a group of seven top industrial countries, as shown in Figure 5. These are remarkable statistics, particularly because doctors’ earnings have barely kept up with the economy’s overall inflation rate in the post–World War II time period, and teachers’ salaries actually fell behind. Persistent cost increases have also plagued other services such as postal delivery and libraries. The soaring costs of education, health care, and police and fire protection place a terrible financial burden on municipal budgets.

4.5

0

Canada

United Denmark Netherlands Japan Kingdom

NOTE: Data for 1996–1999 were not available.

Germany

Italy

SOURCE: derived from OECD Education at a Glance 2007, “Change in Expenditure on Educational Institutions,” accessed online at: http://www.oecd.org.

F I GURE 5

United States

SOURCE: derived from OECD Stat Extracts, “Total Expenditure on Health per Capita,” accessed online at: http://stats.oecd.org.

Real Average Annual Increase (percentage)

5

Why Are These “In-Person” Services Costing So Much More? What accounts for the ever-increasing costs? Are they attributable to inefficiencies in government management or to political corruption? Perhaps to some degree to both. But there is also another and a more significant reason—one that cannot be avoided by any municipal administration no matter how pure its conduct and efficient its bureaucrats and one that affects personal

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

The Shortcomings of Free Markets

327

services provided by the private sector of the economy just as severely as it does the public sector. The common influence underlying all of these problems of rising cost and deterioration in service quality, which is economic in character and expected to grow even more serious with time, has been called the cost disease of the personal services. This “cost disease” stems from the basic nature of personal services: They usually require face-to-face interaction between those who provide the service and those who consume it. Doctors, nurses, teachers, and librarians all engage in activities that require direct, in-person interaction. Moreover, the quality of the service deteriorates if less personal time is provided by doctors, teachers, and librarians to each user of their services.

The cost disease of the personal services is the tendency of the costs and prices of these services to rise persistently faster than those of the average output in the economy.

Chapter 15

Uneven Labor Productivity Growth in the Economy In other parts of the economy, such as manufacturing, no direct personal contact between the consumer and the producer is required. For instance, the buyer of an automobile usually has no idea who worked on its assembly and could not care less how much labor time went into its production. A labor-saving innovation in auto production need not imply a reduction in product quality. As a result, over the years it has proved far easier for technological change to save labor in manufacturing than to save labor in providing many services. In the post–World War II period, for instance, productivity in the United States’ (non-farm) business sector grew by an average of 2.2 percent per year.3 Meanwhile, labor productivity in elementary and secondary education actually declined, with the average number of pupils per teacher in public schools falling from about 25 pupils per teacher in 1960–61 to about 15 pupils per teacher in 2006–07.4 However, this decline may be due, in part, to smaller class sizes. These disparate productivity performances have grave consequences for prices. When manufacturing wages rise by roughly 2 percent, the cost of manufactured products need not rise because increased output per worker can make up for the rise in wages. But the nature of many personal services makes it very difficult to introduce labor-saving devices in those parts of the service sector. A 2 percent wage increase for teachers or police officers is not usually offset by higher output per worker and must lead to an equivalent rise in municipal budgets. Similarly, a 2 percent wage increase for hairdressers must lead beauty salons to raise their prices. In the long run, wages for all workers throughout the economy tend to go up and down together, for otherwise an activity whose wage rate falls seriously behind will tend to lose its labor force. So autoworkers and police officers will see their wages rise at roughly the same rate in the long run. But if output per worker—labor productivity—on the assembly line advances, while productivity in the police patrol car does not, then police protection grows ever more expensive, relative to manufacturing, as time goes on. Because labor productivity improvements are very difficult to achieve for most personal services, their costs can be expected to rise more rapidly, year in and year out, than the costs of manufactured products do. Over a period of several decades, this difference in the growth rate of costs of the two sectors adds up, making services enormously more expensive compared with manufactured goods. This imbalance explains why personal services have grown steadily more expensive compared to goods, and they are likely to continue to do so.

A Future of More Goods but Fewer Services: Is It Inevitable? If some services continue to get ever more expensive in comparison to goods, the implications for life in the future are profound indeed. The cost disease portends a world in which the typical home contains an abundance of goods—luxuries and furnishings that we can hardly imagine. But it is a home that may be surrounded by garbage and perhaps by violence. The cost disease also portends a future in which the services of doctors, Bureau of Labor Statistics, “Productivity Change in the Nonfarm Business Sector, 1947–2008” (chart), 2009, accessed online: ftp://ftp.bls.gov/pub/special.requests/opt/lpr/mfgbardata.txt.

3

4 Thomas D. Snyder, Sally A. Dillow, and Charlene M. Hoffman, Digest of Education Statistics 2008, Chapter 2, Figure 6, p. 57, Washington, D.C.: National Center for Education Statistics, 2009.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

328

Part 4

The Virtues and Limitations of Markets

teachers, and police officers are increasingly mass-produced and impersonal, and in which arts and crafts are increasingly supplied only by amateurs because the cost of professional work in these fields is too high. But this future is by no means inevitable. To see why, we must first recognize that the problem’s source, paradoxically, is the growth in our economy’s productivity, the amount of output each worker creates in an hour—or rather, the unevenness of that growth. Trash removal costs go up not because garbage collectors become less efficient, but because labor in automobile manufacturing becomes more efficient, thus enhancing the sanitation worker’s potential value on the automotive assembly line. The sanitation worker’s wages must go up to keep him at his garbage removal job. But increasing productivity in goods manufacturing does not make a nation poorer. It does not make us unable to afford things that we could afford in the past. Indeed, increasing productivity (that is, more output from each work-hour) means that we can afford more of all things—televisions, electric toothbrushes, cell phones, medical care, education, and other services. The role of services in the nation’s future depends on how we order our priorities. If we value services sufficiently, we can have more and better services—at some sacrifice in the growth rate of manufactured goods. Whether that is a good choice for society is not for economists to say. But society does have a choice, and if we fail to exercise it, matters may proceed relentlessly toward a world in which material goods are abundant and many things that most people now consider primary requisites for a high quality of life are scarce.

The Economics of America’s 2010 Health-Care Reform need to use any of the protection they have purchased. Health insurance works similarly. So, if all of the healthy people were to decline to purchase insurance, only the sick would pay in (and, in turn, require payouts to cover the cost of their medical treatments). Such an insurance scheme would likely go bankrupt. The proponents of the 2010 health-care reform supported it primarily because of the protection it offers to poor and middle-class Americans and to small business firms, for whom rising health-care costs have been a growing burden. But whatever its virtues and vices, there is little reason to expect the new law to end the rapidly rising costs of health care that are explained in this chapter. The fact is that countries throughout the world have tried many different forms of regulation in order to prevent these costs from rising. But few, if any, have succeeded.

SOURCE: JASON REED/Reuters/Landov

For more than 50 years, a succession of U.S. presidents attempted unsuccessfully to pass legislation allowing most or all American citizens access to affordable health insurance. Until 2010, the U.S. was the only prosperous country in the world that did not offer such protection. But now, after a bitter battle between Republicans and Democrats, reforms that will provide financial protection to some 32 million previously uninsured people have been signed into law. The new law prohibits private insurers from rejecting child applicants who have preexisting medical conditions or from charging more to policy holders with medical problems. Insurers also will be forbidden to set a ceiling on a person’s lifetime medical expenditures, and children can now be included in their parents’ insurance until age 26. Government subsidies will help some families and small businesses purchase their insurance. New taxes levied on wealthy families’ investment income and on high-end insurance plans will help to pay for these reforms. Perhaps the most controversial aspect of the plan is the requirement that almost everyone (except the very poor) buy health insurance, with fines for those who refuse. Without this provision, however, the program would not work, for the logic of insurance is based on risk sharing. Consider an analogy based on fire insurance for homeowners. Suppose that, on average, 99 out of every 100 insured homes are not destroyed by fire in a given year. In order to achieve adequate protection for all, the average homeowner who purchases fire insurance must pay only one percent of the cost of rebuilding a destroyed home because most homeowners will never

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 15

The Shortcomings of Free Markets

329

Government May Make the Problem Worse How does the cost disease relate to the central topic of this chapter—the market’s performance and its implications for the government’s economic role? Here the problem is that the market does give the appropriate price signals, but politicians in government are likely to misunderstand these signals and be misled to make decisions that do not promote the public interest most effectively. Health care is a good example. The cost disease itself is capable of causing health-care costs (say, the price of a hospital stay) to rise more rapidly than the economy’s inflation rate because medical care cannot be standardized enough to share in the productivity gains offered by automation and assembly lines. As a result, if we want to maintain standards of care in public hospitals, it is not enough to keep health-care budgets growing at the economy’s prevailing inflation rate. Those budgets must actually grow quickly and consistently in order to prevent a decline in quality. For example, when the inflation rate is 4 percent per year, hospitals’ budgets may need to increase by 6 percent annually. In these circumstances, something may seem amiss to a state legislature that increases its hospitals’ budgets by only 5 percent per year. Responsible lawmakers will doubtless be disturbed by the fact that the budget is growing steadily, outpacing the inflation rate, and yet standards of quality at public hospitals continue to slip. If the legislators do not realize that the cost disease is causing the problem, they will look for villains—greedy doctors, corrupt or inefficient hospital administrators, and so on. The net result, all too often, is a set of wasteful rules that hamper the freedom of action of hospitals and doctors inappropriately or that tighten hospital budgets below the levels that demands and costs would require if they were determined by the market mechanism rather than by government. In many cases, price controls are proposed for sectors of the economy affected by the cost disease—for medical services, insurance services, and the like. As we know, such price controls can, at best, merely eliminate the symptoms of the disease, and they often create problems that are sometimes more serious than the disease itself.5

PUZZLE RESOLVED:

EXPLAINING THE RISING COSTS OF CANADIAN HEALTH CARE

SOURCE: From The Wall Street Journal–Permission, Cartoon Features Syndicatee

This brings us back to the puzzle with which we began the chapter: Why have price controls failed to brake the rise in Canadian health-care costs? The answer is that the medical care system in Canada, like the health-care system in every other industrial country, is struggling with the effects of the cost disease of the personal services. As we have just seen, legislative fiat cannot abolish the productivity-growth patterns that force health-care costs to rise persistently and universally faster than the overall inflation rate. The governmentimposed price controls on doctors’ fees and hospital budgets have, in fact, led to long waiting lists for Canadians who need high-tech medical procedures and have reduced patients’ access to high-priced specialists. The Canadian government has been forced to ease up somewhat on price controls, allowing health-care prices to adapt more closely to costs so as to prevent more serious erosion of medical-care services. The provincial governments are also trying to hold down costs by squeezing the list of services covered by public health insurance, dropping such things as vision tests and physical therapy and forcing Canadians to pay for these things out of their own pockets. The overall quality of service apparently remains high, but the costs have risen persistently more rapidly than the overall inflation rate, just as in the United States. Figure 4 showed that the U.S. record of increasing health-care costs is by no means the best, but also not the worst, in this sample “What really makes this heaven is our great of six countries for the period 1960 to 2006. The conclusion is that, healthcare plan.” 5

See Chapter 4, pages 56–57 and 70–71.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

330

Part 4

The Virtues and Limitations of Markets

although the U.S. health-care reforms may or may not be desirable for other reasons, it is hardly a promising cure for the cost disease. Congress can declare both heart disease and the cost disease of the services to be illegal, but that will do little to cure either disease, and such a law may well impede more effective approaches to the problem. In sum, the cost disease is not a case where the market performs badly. Rather, it is a case in which the market appears to misbehave by singling out certain sectors through particularly large cost increases. Because the market seems to be working badly here, government reactions that can be highly damaging to the public interest are likely; that is, “government failure” may occur.

THE MARKET SYSTEM ON BALANCE This chapter, like Chapter 14, has deliberately offered a rather unbalanced assessment of the market mechanism. In Chapter 14, we extolled the market’s virtues; in this chapter, we catalogued its vices. We come out, as in the nursery rhyme, concluding that the market is either very, very good or it is horrid. There seems to be nothing moderate about the quality of performance of a market system. As a means of achieving efficiency in the production of ordinary consumer goods and responding to changes in consumer preferences, it is unparalleled. In the next chapter we will see that the market system’s performance in terms of innovation and income growth among members of the population is unmatched in human history. It is, in fact, difficult to overstate the accomplishments of the price system in these areas. By contrast, the market has proved itself incapable of coping with business fluctuations, income inequality, or the consequences of monopoly. It has proved to be a very poor allocator of resources among outputs that generate external costs and external benefits, and it has shown itself to be incapable of arranging for the provision of public goods. Some of the most urgent problems that plague our society—the deterioration of services in the cities, the despoliation of our atmosphere, the social unrest attributable to poverty—can be ascribed in part to one or another of these market system shortcomings. Most economists conclude from these observations that although the market mechanism is virtually irreplaceable, the public interest nevertheless requires considerable modifications in the way it works. Proposals designed to deal directly with the problems of poverty, monopoly, and resource allocation over time abound in economic literature. All of them call for the government to intervene in the economy, either by supplying directly those goods and services that, it is believed, private enterprise does not supply in adequate amounts or by seeking to influence the workings of the economy more indirectly through regulation. We discussed many of these programs in earlier chapters; we will explain others in future chapters.

EPILOGUE: THE UNFORGIVING MARKET, ITS GIFT OF ABUNDANCE, AND ITS DANGEROUS FRIENDS As we said at the end of Chapter 14, economists’ analysis of the free market’s accomplishments, although valid enough, may fail to emphasize its central contribution. The same can be said of their analysis of the market’s shortcomings. The market’s major contribution to the general welfare may well be its stimulation of productivity, which has yielded an abundance of consumer goods, contributed to increases in human longevity, created new products, expanded education, and raised standards of living to levels undreamed of in earlier societies. This is an accomplishment that is yet to be discussed (see Chapter 16). The main shortcoming of the market, according to many observers, lies in the arena of justice and injustice, a subject that economists are no more competent to address than anyone else. The perception that markets are cruel and unjust

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 15

The Shortcomings of Free Markets

331

springs from the very heart of the mechanism. The market mechanism has sometimes been described appropriately as the profit system, because it works by richly rewarding those who succeed in introducing attractive new products or in increasing efficiency sufficiently to permit sharp price reductions of other items. At the same time, it is unforgiving to those who fail, subjecting them to bankruptcy and perhaps to poverty. Both the wealth awarded to those who succeed and the drastic treatment accorded to those who fail are main sources of the markets’ productive power, but they also generate disenchantment and opposition. Consider what has happened in the newly “marketized” countries of Eastern Europe and Asia. Predictably, as enterprise in these countries was freed from government control, a number of wildly successful entrepreneurs have earned high incomes, leading to widespread resentment among the populace and calls for restrictions on entrepreneurial earnings. These critics do not seem to realize that a market without substantial rewards to successful entrepreneurs is a market whose engine has been weakened, if not altogether removed. Indeed, efficient and effectively competitive markets often elicit support from groups that, at the same time, do their best to undermine that competition. For example, regulators who seek to prevent “excessive competition,” and politicians in other countries who arrange for the sale of government enterprises to private owners only to constrain decision making by the new owners at every turn, are, in fact, doing their best to keep markets from working. When the general public demands price controls on interest rates, rents, and health-care services, it is expressing its unwillingness to accept the free market’s decisions. Businesspeople who tirelessly proclaim their support for the market system, but who seek to acquire the monopoly power that can distort its activities, are doing the same thing. In short, the market has many professed supporters who genuinely believe in its virtues but whose behavior poses a constant threat to its effectiveness. We cannot take for granted the success of the newly introduced market mechanism in Eastern Europe. The Russian economy, in its transition from communist government control, has come very slowly out of turmoil, as have other economies in Eastern Europe. Most remarkable has been the performance of China, which has moved rapidly to a market economy, despite its continued dedication to socialist political principles. Even in the older free-enterprise economies, we cannot simply assume that the market will emerge unscathed from the dangerous embrace of its most vocal supporters.

| SUMMARY | 1. At least seven major imperfections are associated with the market mechanism: a. Inequality of income distribution b. Fluctuations in economic activity (inflation and unemployment) c. Monopolistic output restrictions d. Beneficial and detrimental externalities e. Inadequate provision of public goods f. Misallocation of resources between present and future g. Deteriorating quality and rising costs of personal services

occurs when an economic activity incidentally creates benefits for others. 4. When an activity causes a detrimental externality, the activity’s marginal social cost (including the harm it does to others) must be greater than the marginal private cost to those who carry on the activity. The opposite will be true when a beneficial externality occurs. 5. If a product’s manufacture causes detrimental externalities, its price will generally not include all of the marginal social cost it causes, because part of the cost will be borne by others. The opposite is true for beneficial externalities.

2. Efficient resource allocation is a matter of balancing the benefits of producing more of one good against the benefits of devoting the required inputs to some other good’s production.

6. The market will therefore tend to overallocate resources to the production of goods that cause detrimental externalities and underallocate resources to the production of goods that create beneficial externalities. This imbalance is one of the Ideas for Beyond the Final Exam.

3. A detrimental externality occurs when an economic activity incidentally does harm to others who are not directly involved in the activity. A beneficial externality

7. A public good is a commodity (such as the guiding beam of a coastal lighthouse) that is not depleted by additional users. It is often difficult to exclude anyone from

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

332

Part 4

The Virtues and Limitations of Markets

the benefits of a public good, even those who refuse to pay for it. A private good, in contrast, is characterized by both excludability and depletability.

danger is that the agents will operate the enterprises so as to favor their own interests rather than those of the principals.

8. Free-enterprise firms generally will not produce a public good, even if it is extremely useful to the community, because they cannot charge money for the use of the good.

11. Because personal services—such as education, medical care, and police protection—are activities whose inherent value depends on face-to-face, in-person interaction, they are not amenable to labor-saving innovations and suffer from a cost disease. That is, their costs tend to rise persistently and considerably more rapidly than costs in the economy as a whole, where faster productivity increases offset rising input costs. The result can be a distortion in the supply of services by government or the imposition of unwise price controls when the rising cost is misattributed to greed and mismanagement.

9. Many observers believe that the market often shortchanges the future, particularly when it makes irreversible decisions that destroy natural resources. 10. Complex and large-scale enterprises such as huge corporations cannot be run day-to-day or effectively controlled directly by their owners, the principals. So they hire agents to run the enterprises on their behalf. The

| KEY TERMS | agents

321

marginal private benefit (MPB) 313

beneficial externality

312

cost disease of the personal services 327 depletability

317

detrimental externality excludability 317

marginal private cost (MPC)

production possibilities frontier 311

marginal social benefit (MSB) 313

public good

317

marginal social cost (MSC)

rent seeking

320

moral hazard 312

313

principals

313

resource misallocation

320

stock options

321

private good

311

322

317

| TEST YOURSELF | 1. What is the opportunity cost to society of a 100-mile truck trip? Why may the price of the gasoline used by the truck not adequately represent that opportunity cost? 2. Suppose that because of a new disease that attacks coffee plants, far more labor and other inputs are required to harvest a pound of coffee than before. How may that change affect the efficient allocation of resources between tea and coffee? How would the prices of coffee and tea react in a free market? 3. Give some examples of goods whose production causes detrimental externalities and some examples of goods whose production creates beneficial externalities.

4. Compare cleaning a dormitory room with cleaning the atmosphere of a city. Which is a public good and which is a private good? Why? 5. (More difficult) A firm holds a patent that is estimated to be worth $20 million. The patent is repeatedly challenged in the courts by a large number of (moneyseeking) firms, each hoping to grab away the patent. If anyone is free to challenge the patent so that there is free entry into the litigation process, how much will end up being spent in the legal battles? (Hint: Under perfect competition, should firms expect to earn any economic profit?)

| DISCUSSION QUESTIONS | 1. Give some other examples of public goods. In each case, explain why additional users do not deplete the good and why it is difficult to exclude people from using it. 2. Think about the goods and services that your local government provides. Which are “public goods” as economists use the term?

4. Explain why education is not a very satisfactory example of a public good. 5. In recent decades, college tuition costs have risen more rapidly than the general price level, even though the wages of college professors have failed to keep pace with the price level. Can you explain why?

3. Explain why the services of a lighthouse are sometimes used as an example of a public good.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

The Market’s Prime Achievement: Innovation and Growth Procter & Gamble has a world-class global research and development organization, with more than 7,500 scientists working in 22 research centers in 12 countries around the world. This includes 1,250 Ph.D. scientists. For perspective, this is larger than the combined science faculties at Harvard, Stanford, and MIT. P RO CT ER & GA M B L E, R&D’S F ORM U L A F OR SU CCE S S, P &G I NNOVATI ON HTTP ://W WW.PG . COM

M

any textbooks, including previous editions of this one, tend to give scant attention to the microeconomics of innovation and growth. This omission is astonishing, given the incredible contribution of the market in this arena to society’s economic welfare. It is an achievement whose magnitude was undreamed of by our ancestors, and its benefits far exceed those expected from any other possible modifications in the workings of the market that we know. In this chapter we will begin our discussion of the mechanism that underlies this economic revolution. First, we will try to give you some feeling for the magnitude of this accomplishment—something that is often overlooked because we have come to take innovation and growth for granted. We must note that there are (at least) five contributors to this achievement: government, universities, inventors, entrepreneurs, and competing oligopolists in the high-tech industries. Since here we are interested primarily in the contribution of the market, we will say little about the role of governments and universities, despite their importance. In this chapter we will focus on the part played by the oligopolists, leaving the critical role of the inventors and the entrepreneurs to Chapter 20 in the section of the book on the economy’s “factors of production,” that is, its main categories of productive inputs.

C O N T E N T S PUZZLE: HOW DID THE MARKET ACHIEVE ITS

MICROECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF THE INNOVATIVE OLIGOPOLY FIRM

THE MARKET ECONOMY’S INCREDIBLE GROWTH RECORD

The Large Enterprises and Their Innovation “Assembly Lines” The Profits of Innovation: Schumpeter’s Model Financing the Innovation “Arms Race”: High R&D Costs and “Monopoly Profits” How Much Will a Profit-Maximizing Firm Spend on Innovation? A Kinked Revenue Curve Model of Spending on Innovation Innovation as a Public Good

UNPRECEDENTED GROWTH?

INNOVATION, NOT INVENTION, IS THE UNIQUE FREE-MARKET ACCOMPLISHMENT SOURCES OF FREE-MARKET INNOVATION: THE ROLE OF THE ENTREPRENEUR Breakthrough Invention and the Entrepreneurial Firm

Effects of Process Research on Outputs and Prices

DO FREE MARKETS SPEND ENOUGH ON R&D ACTIVITIES? Innovation as a Beneficial Externality Why the Shortfall in Innovation Spending May Not Be So Big After All

THE MARKET ECONOMY AND THE SPEEDY DISSEMINATION OF NEW TECHNOLOGY CONCLUSION: THE MARKET ECONOMY AND ITS INNOVATION ASSEMBLY LINE

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

334

Part 4

The Virtues and Limitations of Markets

PUZZLE:

HOW DID THE MARKET ACHIEVE ITS UNPRECEDENTED GROWTH?

This chapter focuses on one extraordinary and important development, the unprecedented expansion in the amount that the market economies produce, on average, for each of their inhabitants and the flood of new products and other inventions that they provide to them. Never before in human history has economic performance ever come close to this achievement. There have, of course, been economies with a striking record of invention, and others have produced valuable contributions to knowledge about astronomy and materials related to other sciences. But none has come close to the enhancement of living standards in our economy and a number of others. What accounts for this near miraculous performance? What is the role of the market in this achievement? No one is absolutely certain of the answers to these questions, but economists have provided some of the relevant insights, insights that can be helpful in ensuring that our economic progress continues and can offer some useful guidance to the impoverished nations, most of whose residents continue to live in poverty.

THE MARKET ECONOMY’S INCREDIBLE GROWTH RECORD An activity is said to generate a beneficial or detrimental externality if that activity causes incidental benefits or damages to others not directly involved in the activity and no corresponding compensation is provided to or paid by those who generate the externality.

Per-capita income in an economy is the average income of all people in that economy. The productivity of an economy is the value of all goods and services produced there, divided by the total labor time devoted to the economy’s productive activities.

The past several chapters have tried to provide a balanced evaluation of the market, describing both its shortcomings and its accomplishments. Among its defects we have listed are attributes such as vulnerability to monopoly power, externalities such as damage to the environment, and a propensity to underproduce public goods. On the virtuous side, we showed how the market can allocate resources more efficiently and more in accord with consumer desires than planning and central direction. But we have saved the best for last—the free market’s incredible performance in terms of innovation and growth, in which it has far exceeded any other type of economy in ancient or recent history. Whatever else one may think of our economic system, its accomplishment in terms of enhanced income of the population is an astonishing achievement, not remotely paralleled anywhere in the previous history of the world. Although growth is often viewed as a macroeconomic topic, inventions are provided by individuals or individual laboratories and are brought to market by individual firms. So understanding innovation and its contribution to growth requires microeconomic analysis of the behavior of individual innovators and firms. This chapter will indicate the magnitude of the market’s growth accomplishment. Here, and in Chapter 20, we will use our microeconomic tools to analyze how the market has produced that achievement. Incidentally, part of the discussion may be considered both as a review of some of the analytic tools we have used before and as an additional illustration of the wide variety of subjects they can be used to investigate. In the free-market economies, the growth in per-capita income (average income per person) and productivity (output per hour of work) has been so enormous that we can hardly comprehend its magnitude. Still, a few numbers may begin to suggest what growth has accomplished. Today the income of an average American is about $43,368. In contrast, at the beginning of the twentieth century the average individual’s was less than $6,000, in terms of today’s purchasing power.1 And if income per person grows as rapidly in the twenty-first century as it did in the twentieth, in the year 2100 our descendants will be earning, on average, an amount equivalent approximately to the purchasing power of more than $300,000 today. Just think what you and your family could purchase if all of your savings and earnings were suddenly

Actually, the growth in per-capita income in the United States was even greater than this, very likely substantially so. We have used the most conservative estimate we could find, that of Angus Maddison, to avoid exaggeration of an already astonishing number.

1

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 16

335

The Market’s Prime Achievement: Innovation and Growth

multiplied by seven!2 Looked at another way, an average American family living around 1900 could afford only about one-seventh the food, clothing, housing, and other amenities that constitute the standard of living today. That figure is really incredible. Just try to imagine how your family’s life would be changed if you suddenly lost more than six out of seven dollars from all of your savings and earnings and you were forced to reduce the family’s consumption expenditure correspondingly. Such economic growth has never been experienced before. In contrast to this explosive expansion of income in recent centuries, average growth rates of per-capita incomes probably approximated zero for about the entire 1,500 years before the Industrial Revolution (around the time of George Washington). In 1776, even the wealthiest consumers in England, then the world’s richest country, could purchase perhaps only a half-dozen consumer goods that had not been available more than a thousand years earlier in ancient Rome. These new products included (highly inaccurate) hunting guns, (fairly inaccurate) watches, paper with printed material on it, window glass, and very little else. No sounds had ever been recorded, so we can never hear Washington’s voice. No one had traveled on land faster than on horseback. Messages delivered from the Old World to the New World required weeks and even months, so that the battle of New Orleans (1815) was fought after the peace treaty had been signed. And Roman citizens enjoyed a number of amenities, such as hot baths and paved roads, which had practically disappeared long before the American Revolution. The low income numbers and the resulting economic conditions of the lower economic classes before the Industrial Revolution and for quite a period beyond it are difficult for us to grasp. Regular famines—at least once per decade on average, with starvation widespread and corpses littering the streets—only began to disappear in the eighteenth century. Still, famines continued occasionally well into the nineteenth, and not only in Ireland. For example, in relatively wealthy Belgium, “During the great crisis of 1846, the newspapers would tell daily of cases of death from starvation. . . . [In one town] cases became so frequent that the local policeman was given the job of calling at all houses each day to see if the inhabitants were still alive.”3 But even the living standards of the upper classes were far from enviable (see “Discomforts of the Rich a Few Centuries Ago” on page 336). By comparison, in the past two centuries, per-capita incomes in the typical capitalist economy have risen by amounts ranging from several hundred to several thousand percent. Recent decades have yielded an unmatched outpouring of new products and services: the Internet, color television, the computer, jet aircraft, the VCR and DVD player, the microwave oven, the handheld calculator, the cellular telephone, and so on. And the flood of new products continues.4 Surely, part of the reason for the collapse of most of the world’s communist regimes was their citizens’ desire to participate in the growth miracle of the capitalist economies. There are, of course, many Americans who still live in poverty, but phenomena like mass starvation have disappeared. It is mainly in the nonmarket economies that one finds the 25 percent of the world population that still lives on the equivalent of about $1.25 per person per day.5 We can look at this enormous economic progress in the market economies from another angle: by examining how much work it takes to acquire the things we purchase. For

The Industrial Revolution is the stream of new technology and the resulting growth of output that began in England toward the end of the eighteenth century.

Capitalism is an economic system in which most of the production process is controlled by private firms operating in markets with minimal government control. The investors in these firms (called “capitalists”) own the firms.

Angus Maddison, The Nature and Functioning of European Capitalism: A Historical and Comparative Perspective (Groningen, Netherlands: University of Groningen, 1997), p. 34. Real income is not measured in actual dollars, but in dollars whose purchasing power is kept unchanged. 3 Adrien De Meeüs, History of the Belgians (New York: Frederick A. Praeger, 1962), p. 305. 4 “Could the Emperor Tiberius have eaten grapes in January? Could the Emperor Napoleon have crossed the Atlantic in a night? . . . Could Thomas Aquinas have . . . dispatched [a letter] to 1,000 recipients with the touch of a key, and begun to receive replies within the hour?” (J. Bradford DeLong, The Economic History of the Twentieth Century: Slouching Toward Utopia?, Chapter 2, p. 3, draft copy, http://www.j-bradford-delong.net.) 5 Shaohua Chen and Martin Ravallion, “The Developing World Is Poorer than We Thought, but No Less Successful,” Washington, D.C.: World Bank, 2008. 2

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

336

Part 4

The Virtues and Limitations of Markets

Discomforts of the Rich a Few Centuries Ago

Ten strenuous, abnormally frigid days were spent upon roads, bad enough in summer, now deep with snow. On the second day the carriage in which Wilhelmina was riding turned over.

She was buried under an avalanche of luggage. . . . Everyone expected a miscarriage and wanted Wilhelmina to rest in bed for several days. . . . Mountains appeared after Leibzig had been passed. . . . Wilhelmina was frightened by the steepness of the roads and preferred to get out and walk to being whacked about as the carriage jolted from boulder to boulder.

SOURCE: © Comstock Images/Jupiterimages

Earlier eras were characterized by miserable living conditions even for the wealthy and powerful. Their wealth did give them ostentatious clothing, exotic foods, and armies of servants. But the problem for them was that little of the technology of human comfort had yet been invented. The standards of discomfort for the rich and powerful before the Industrial Revolution are illustrated by the oft-cited report by the Princess Palatine (German sister-in-law of the mighty French king Louis XIV) that in the winter of 1695, the wine froze in the glasses at the king’s table in the Palace of Versailles! Even throughout the nineteenth century, in much of the United States it was expected that every winter the ink would freeze in the inkwells. A description of the 1732 journey of the pregnant Wilhelmina, favorite sister of Frederick the Great, between Berlin and Bayreuth is also revealing:

Statistics and other pieces of evidence tell a story consistent with such anecdotes. Using genealogical records, it has been estimated that between 1550 and 1700 the average longevity for the general male and female population slightly exceeded that for members of the nobility for a substantial part of this period.

SOURCES: Fernand Braudel, Civilization and Capitalism, 15th to 18th Century, vol. 1 (New York: Harper & Row, 1979), p. 299; Constance Wright, A Royal Affinity (London: Frederick Muller, 1965), p. 142; and Robert W. Fogel, “Nutrition and the Decline of Mortality since 1700: Some Preliminary Findings,” in S. L. Engerman and R. E. Gallman, eds., Long-Term Factors in American Economic Growth (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1986).

example, in 1919, the average U.S. worker had to labor nearly an hour to buy a pound of chicken. At today’s wages and poultry prices, less than 5 minutes of labor is required for the purpose! Figure 1 (Minutes of Work) shows how much cheaper a variety of snack foods have become over the past century. Food is not the only item that has become much less costly in terms of the labor time needed to pay for it. Figure 2 (Hours of Work) shows the great cost reductions of various FIGURE 1

60

57 50

50 40

30

27 19.9

20

10

19.9

19.9

9 1.5

0 Big Mac 1940/1997

Pizza 1958/1997

Soft drink 1900/1997

2 Candy bar 1900/1997

1.1 Chewing gum 1900/1997

3.6 2.3 Chips 1964/1997

SOURCE: Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas, “Time Well Spent: The Declining Real Cost of Living in America,” 1997 Annual Report, 1997.

Minutes of Work Time Needed to Purchase Items

Declining Real Labor Price of Junk Foods in the Twentieth Century

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

337

The Market’s Prime Achievement: Innovation and Growth

Chapter 16

FIGU R E 2

2,000

1,500

1,000 562

0

494

365

500 23

Color TV 1954/1997

15 VCR 1972/1997

57 42

456 15

0.76

Home Calculating movie device camera 1916/1997 1960/1997

9

Microwave oven 1947/1997

Cellular phone 1984/1997

But the magic of productivity growth has not yet succeeded in invading every sector of the U.S. economy. In particular, the process of college teaching seems to have been able to escape the cost-reducing ability of productivity growth. Figure 3 (Work Time Needed to Buy a College Education) shows the consequences. Between 1965 and 1995, the cost of a college education rose 33 percent at public universities, whereas at private universities it went up by more than 150 percent, from 500 to 1,300 labor hours. All of these figures on changing labor-value prices are taken from Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas, Time Well Spent: The Declining Real Cost of Living in America, 1997 Annual Report (Dallas, Tex., 1997). 7 The data cited here are evidently more than a decade old. Unfortunately, we have not been able to find any studies of the subject that are more recent. 6

Hours of Work Time Needed to Buy a College Education

types of electronic equipment—a cut of 98 percent in the cost of a color TV between 1954 and 1997, 96 percent in the cost of a VCR between 1972 and 1997, and 99 percent in the cost of a microwave oven between 1947 and 1997. Of course, the most sensational decrease of all has been in the cost of computers. Computer capability is standardized in terms of the number of MIPS (millions of instructions per second) that the computer is capable of handling. These days, it costs about 27 minutes of labor per 1 MIPS capacity. GDP (gross domestic In 1984, it cost the wages of 52 hours of labor; in 1970, the cost was 1.24 lifetimes of labor; product) is a measure of 6,7 and in 1944, the price was a barely believable 733,000 lifetimes of labor. In this chapter, the total amount the we will investigate the free market’s extraordinary record of growth and economic economy produces domestically in a year. progress. The history of the growth in income per person can be summed up with a graph depicting estimates of the United Kingdom’s GDP per capita for five centuries (Figure 4). It is clear that the pattern of the graph is characterized by a rising slope that grows dramatically ever steeper. FIGURE 3 The bottom line is that in the long run, the ecoWork Time Needed to Buy a College Education, nomic welfare of a nation’s entire population is 1965 versus 1995 heavily dependent on its performance in terms of innovation and the speed of growth in its production 1,400 per person, and no economy has been able to ap1,300 1965 proximate anything near these accomplishments of 1,200 1995 the modern market economies. 1,000

800

600

400

500

200 200 0

150 U.S. Private Universities U.S. Public Universities

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

SOURCE: Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas, “Time Well Spent: The Declining Real Cost of Living in America,” 1997 Annual Report, 1997.

2,467

2,500

SOURCE: Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas, “Time Well Spent: The Declining Real Cost of Living in America,” 1997 Annual Report, 1997.

Hours of Work Time Needed to Purchase Items

Declining Real Labor Price of Electronic Products in the Twentieth Century

338

Part 4

The Virtues and Limitations of Markets

FIGURE 4

Real per-capita GDP (1990 dollars)

20000 18000

$18,714

16000 14000 12000 10000 8000 6000 4000

$714 2000 0 1500 1550 1600

1650

1700 1750 Year

1800

1850

1900 1950 1998

SOURCE: Angus Maddison, The World Economy: A Millennial Perspective (Paris: Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, 2001).

Real GDP per Capita in the United Kingdom, 1500–1998

INNOVATION, NOT INVENTION, IS THE UNIQUE FREE-MARKET ACCOMPLISHMENT

Invention is the creation of new products or processes or the ideas that underlie them. Innovation is the process that begins with invention and includes improvement to prepare the invention for practical use and marketing of the invention or its products.

The search for explanations of the capitalist growth miracle must focus on its unprecedented outpouring of innovation, and to that we will soon turn. But first it is important to distinguish the key term innovation from the related word invention. Invention is used by economists to mean what its usual definition asserts: the creation of new products or processes, or at least the ideas that underlie them. But the term innovation means more than that; it refers to the entire extended process of which invention is only the initial step. Innovation includes development of the invention’s design to the point at which it is ready for practical use, its introduction to the market, and its subsequent utilization by the economy. The distinction is critical here because it underlies much of the difference between the accomplishments of the capitalist economy and those of any and all of its predecessors, including those earlier economies with remarkable records of invention. Invention is nothing new. Ancient China, for example, invented printing, paper, playing cards, the spinning wheel, the wheelbarrow, an elaborate water clock, the umbrella, and, of course, gunpowder, to name but a few. But despite China’s talent for the creation of novel technology, its performance in adoption and utilization of these inventions was hardly outstanding. More than once inventions were diverted to amusement rather than productive use or, like the wondrous water clock, soon forgotten.8 Even in the former Soviet Union, with its cadre of very capable scientists and engineers, there is evidence of a respectable record of invention but a remarkably poor record of utilization of these inventions—except in military activity. The reason is that the economic institutions in both ancient China and the former Soviet Union not only failed to offer incentives for innovative activity but actually provided strong motivation for its determined avoidance. In China, inventions often were confiscated by the government, with no reward for the inventors. In the former Soviet Union, factory managers resisted the installation of improved equipment or the adoption of improved products because the necessary retooling period could cut down the factory’s production, on which the manager’s reward was based. In short, although the free market’s record of invention is noteworthy, it is its performance in innovation that is unique. 8 This persisted into a much more recent era. Westerners bringing mechanical clocks as gifts to the Chinese emperors found that timekeeping accuracy elicited little appreciation, but marching or dancing figures run by the clockworks were highly valued.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 16

339

The Market’s Prime Achievement: Innovation and Growth

SOURCES OF FREE-MARKET INNOVATION: THE ROLE OF THE ENTREPRENEUR As already mentioned, there are many obvious sources of innovation. Some innovations are contributed by universities and government research agencies, which are not inherently market-driven. Then there are the well-known products of individual inventors, such as Thomas Edison and Alexander Graham Bell. In addition, innovative entrepreneurs, those who keep their eyes open for promising inventions and take action to see that they are employed effectively by business firms and others, play an important part in directing the inventions to their most effective uses. Finally, there are the outputs of industrial laboratories in giant corporations. These last two sources—the private entrepreneur and the giant corporations—clearly are directly embedded in the workings of the market economy. In this chapter we will focus on the role of the big firms in the economy’s innovation, leaving the entrepreneurs, the creators of new business firms, and their crucial place in the innovation process until later when we discuss the contribution and activities of this important factor of production in Chapter 20. Here we will only note that, throughout history, the presence or absence of innovating entrepreneurs appears to have been crucial for the growth and innovative accomplishments of their economies.

Stimulating Demand via Sensational New Products

It’s hard to determine the wackiest aspect of iPhone craziness leading up to the launch of Apple’s eagerly (to say the least) awaited venture into the cell-phone world on June 29. Was it the relentless media attention, which blended nuts-and-bolts business coverage with the obsessive overkill of a Paris Hilton stalkfest? Or was it the lunacy of the people dying to get those phones at the earliest possible moment? Standing outside New York’s Fifth Avenue Apple store on launch day, with dozens of reporters interviewing the masses who braved days of heat and rain to snare their palm-size prize, there was a sense of being in the middle of a Zeitgeist hurricane. The iPhone itself is off to a ring-a-ding start, selling an estimated 500,000 to 700,000 units the first weekend. And the reviews are uniformly positive. (My own take, after three weeks of iPhoning, still holds: though there’s still work to be done, the beautiful screen, the clever multitouch navigation and the welldesigned and -integrated applications make this gizmo a genuine breakthrough.) But sales figures and reviews don’t speak to the unprecedented hoopla. What was it that made a five-ounce slab of silicon, aluminum and glass so important to us? In part, you can chalk it up to the iPod factor. Before 2001, Apple was a company that made cool computers that only a small fraction of the public cared to buy. But over the next few years, 100 million customers discovered Apple’s tiny music player, and bonded with it as they had with no previous gadget. The same crowd

welcomed the news that Apple was going mobile. “Everyone we talk to hates their phones,” Steve Jobs told me the week before the launch, in an attempt to explain the iPhone anticipation. We’ve heard a lot recently about of the 40th anniversary of the Beatles’ landmark “Sgt. Pepper” album. Back in 1967, new releases by universally loved bands like the Beatles, the Rolling Stones and the Beach Boys were anticipated breathlessly, and greeted by monster sales, heated analysis and sonic ubiquity. In 1967, it was “All You Need Is Love.” In 2007, it’s “All You Need Is AT&T Activation.” Welcome to the summer of technolust.

SOURCE: © AP Images

The iPhone was perhaps the most talked about technological gadget of 2007, beginning with Steve Jobs’s announcement during his keynote talk at the 2007 MacWorld Expo and ending with Time naming it Invention of the Year. The following excerpt describes the anticipation surrounding the iPhone’s official launch on June 29:

SOURCE: From Steven Levy, “Why We Went Nuts About the iPhone; People hate their cell phones, Steve Jobs said, in attempting to explain the iPhone anticipation”, ‘Newsweek’, July 16, 2007, p. 13. Copyright © 2007 Newsweek, Inc. All rights reserved. Used by permission and protected by the Copyright Laws of the United States. The printing, copying, redistribution, or retransmission of the Material without express written permission is prohibited.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

340

Part 4

The Virtues and Limitations of Markets

Breakthrough Invention and the Entrepreneurial Firm Individual inventors and entrepreneurs continued to be the primary source of innovation in the market economies until the end of the nineteenth century, when large corporations began to play a critical role in the process. But the part played by large corporations is very different from that of the more freewheeling and flexible small enterprises. Research activity in large business organizations is inherently cautious and focuses on small, relatively limited improvements in current technology. The big established firms tend to avoid the great risks that revolutionary breakthroughs involve. The true breakthrough inventions, rather, are often still the domain of small or newly founded enterprises, guided by enterprising owners, although success of an invention can rapidly transform a start-up firm into a business giant. There is no clear boundary between inventions that can be considered revolutionary breakthroughs and those that are “merely” cumulative incremental improvements, but some inventions clearly fall into the former category. For example, the electric light, alternating electric current, the internal combustion engine, and the electronic computer must surely be deemed revolutionary. In contrast, successive models of washing machines and refrigerators—with each new model a bit longer-lasting, a bit less susceptible to breakdown, and a bit easier to use—clearly constitute a sequence of incremental improvements. There is a striking degree of asymmetry between small and large firms in their introduction of breakthrough versus incremental invention. The U.S. Small Business Administration has prepared a list of breakthrough innovations of the twentieth century for which small firms are responsible, and its menu of inventions literally spans the range from A to Z, from air-conditioning to the zipper. Included in the list are the cotton picker, the electronic spreadsheet, FM radio, the helicopter, the integrated circuit, the instant camera, quick-frozen food, the vacuum tube, and the photocopier, among a host of others, many of enormous significance for our economy (Table 1 reproduces part of the list). TABLE 1 Some Important Innovations by U.S. Small Firms in the Twentieth Century

Air-Conditioning Airplane Assembly Line Audio Tape Recorder Biosynthetic Insulin Catalytic Petroleum Cracking Cotton Picker Defibrillator DNA Fingerprinting Electronic Spreadsheet FM Radio Geodesic Dome Gyrocompass Research and development (R&D) is the activity of firms, universities, and government agencies that seeks to invent new products and processes and to improve those inventions so that they are ready for the market or other users.

Heart Valve Helicopter High Resolution CAT Scanner Human Growth Hormone Hydraulic Brake Integrated Circuit Microprocessor Nuclear Magnetic Resonance Scanner Optical Scanner Oral Contraceptives Overnight National Delivery Pacemaker Personal Computer

Photo Typesetting Polaroid Camera Portable Computer Prefabricated Housing Quick-Frozen Food Safety Razor Soft Contact Lens Solid-Fuel Rocket Engine Vacuum Tube Xerography X-Ray Telescope Zipper

SOURCE: U.S. Small Business Administration, The State of Small Business: A Report of the President, 1994 (Washington, D.C: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1995), p. 114.

A high proportion of the revolutionary new ideas of the past two centuries have been, and are likely to continue to be, provided by independent innovators who operate small business enterprises. The small entrepreneurial firms have played a leading role in the portion of business research and development (R&D) activity that is engaged in the search for the revolutionary breakthroughs that are such a critical part of the growth machine that is provided by the market economy.

MICROECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF THE INNOVATIVE OLIGOPOLY FIRM The Large Enterprises and Their Innovation “Assembly Lines” As we see in Figure 5, private investment in R&D has risen sharply in the last three decades (with only a few slowdowns in funding during those years). Increasingly, at least Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

341

The Market’s Prime Achievement: Innovation and Growth

Chapter 16

FIGU R E 5

220 200

Billions of 2000 Dollars

180 160 140 120 100 80 60 40 20 0 1970

1975

1980

1990

1985 Year

1995

2000

2004

SOURCE: National Science Board, Science and Engineering Indicators—2004 (Arlington, V.A.: National Science Foundation, 2004), http://www.nsf.gov.

Expenditures on Research and Development (R&D) by U.S. Business Firms (in real, inflation-adjusted terms), 1970–2004

in the United States, the financing for innovation has been supplied by large oligopolistic enterprises, rather than by independent inventors or small, newly founded entrepreneurial firms. In 2007, 90 percent of R&D expenditure in the United States was paid for by private companies; most of this outlay was provided by the larger firms.9 Even seemingly “low-tech” companies like the consumer products giant Procter & Gamble (noted for outputs like cleaning and personal care products) employ small armies of R&D personnel (as evidenced in the quotation at the beginning of the chapter). These large firms are driven to do this by powerful market pressures of competitive innovation. Innovation has, in fact, become a prime weapon of choice for competitive battles in substantial sectors of the economy. Of course, prices are still important, but it is improved products and methods of production that really capture the attention of the firm’s managers. Product lines as diverse as computers and computer software, automobiles, cameras, and machinery all feature constant improvements, which are instantly and widely advertised. The result is a kind of innovation arms race in which no firm in a high-tech industry can afford to fall behind its rivals. Indeed, only by staying abreast of the others can the firm hope to preserve its place in the market. In its innovation, it is forced to run as fast as it can just to stand still—because its rivals are doing the same. Any firm that can come up with a better model than its rivals will gain a critical advantage.

Firms in many high-tech industries—such as computers, medical equipment, aeronautics, and even automobiles—struggle for market position in this way. The managers of firms cannot afford to neglect R&D activities. For if a firm fails to adopt the latest technology— even if the technology is created by others—then rival firms can easily take the lead and make disastrous inroads into the slower firm’s sales. Often, for the firm, innovation is literally a matter of life and death.

A high-tech (hightechnology) firm or industry is one whose products, equipment, and production methods utilize highly advanced technology that is constantly modified and improved. Examples are the aerospace, scientific instruments, computer, communications, and pharmaceutical industries.

For instance, the U.S. National Science Foundation reports that, in 2007, the largest manufacturing firms (each employing 10,000 or more workers) accounted for 58 percent of R&D in the manufacturing sector of the economy (National Science Foundation, Division of Science Resources Statistics, “U.S. Business R&D Expenditures Increase in 2007: Small Companies Performed 19% of Nation’s Business R&D,”Arlington, V.A., July 2009, accessed online at: http://www.nsf.gov.).

9

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

342

Part 4

The Virtues and Limitations of Markets

Thus, especially in high-tech sectors, firms dare not leave innovation to chance, or to the haphazard contributions of independent inventors tinkering in their basements and garages. Rather, competitive markets force firms to take over the innovation process themselves and (in the immortal words of the great comedian W. C. Fields) “to remove all elements of chance” from the undertaking.10 Many business firms today routinely budget for R&D, hire scientists and engineers to do the job, and systematically decide how to promote and price their innovations. This “arms-race” feature of an industry’s innovation process probably plays a critical role in the continuing outpouring of innovations that characterize the market economy. The capitalist economy itself has become a giant innovation machine the predictable output of which is a stream of improved technology. Never in any other type of economy has there existed such an innovation machine—an assembly line that forces the economy to bring one invention after another from the drawing board all the way to the market, as though it were a meat plant producing frankfurters, rather than a high-tech enterprise generating product improvements.

In their effort to contain the risks inherent in the innovation process, large business firms have tended to slant their efforts toward small incremental improvements rather than revolutionary breakthroughs. User-friendliness, increased reliability, marginal additions to application, expansions of capacity, flexibility in design—these and many other types of improvement have come out of the industrial R&D facilities, with impressive consistency, year after year, and often preannounced and preadvertised. They produce longerlasting light bulbs, more reliable air bags to protect automobile passengers, and clearer TV screens. But they usually do not invent anything of the magnitude of the airplane, computer, or antibiotics. Thus, the products of these innovative activities are often modest, each making a very small improvement in a product or its production process. Nevertheless, taken in the aggregate, these small improvements have accomplished a great deal. An example is the airplane. The comfort, speed, and reliability of the modern passenger aircraft and the complexity and power of today’s military flying machines clearly have turned the Wright brothers’ original revolutionary device into a historical curiosity. Most of the sophistication, speed, and reliability of today’s aviation equipment is attributable to the combined incremental additions made by routine research activities in corporate facilities. There are even more startling examples of the innovative contributions of the large companies, whose incremental advances can compound to results of enormous magnitude. It is reported, for example, that between 1971 and 2007, the “clock speed” of Intel’s microprocessor chips—that is, the number of instructions each chip can carry out per second—increased by some three million percent, reaching about three billion computations per second. During the same time period, the number of transistors embedded in a single chip expanded by more than 35 million percent—from 2,300 in 1971 to 820 million in 2007.11 Added up, these advances surely contributed enormously more computing capacity than was provided by the original revolutionary breakthrough of the invention of the electronic computer. Of course, that initial invention was an indispensable necessity for all of the later improvements. But it is only the combined work of the two together that made possible the powerful and inexpensive apparatus that serves us so effectively today. Other careful observers have extended such examples and have concluded that incremental innovation activities of the large firms have been responsible for a very respectable share of the contribution of innovation to economic growth in the twentieth century. In the growth process, the individual entrepreneurs (whom we will discuss in Chapter 20) and the giant firms have played roles that are different but essential for one another. The

10 This phrase is uttered when Fields, playing a card shark, seeks to lure an unsuspecting novice into a card game, whereupon his intended victim questions the morality of “games of chance.” Fields hastens to reassure him: “Young man, when you play with me, all elements of chance have been removed!” 11 Intel Corporation, “The Evolution of a Revolution,” accessed online at: http://download.intel.com/pressroom/ kits/IntelProcessorHistory.pdf.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 16

343

The Market’s Prime Achievement: Innovation and Growth

Predicting the Future: A Feebleness of Imagination? distinction. While ordinary machines work by manipulating stuff, computers manipulate information, symbols which are essentially weightless. A bit of information, a 1 or a 0, can be indicated by a pencil mark in a checkbox, by a microscopic spot on a magnetic disk or by the briefest pulse of electricity or scintilla of light. According to Moore’s famous law, the number of components that can be packed onto a single chip doubles every year or two. The latest Pentium chip contains 42 million transistors, each doing the job of one of ENIAC’s glowing tubes but far more rapidly and efficiently. The end is not in sight. By some estimates, the shrinking will continue over coming decades until each component is the size of a single atom, registering a bit of information by the position of an orbiting electron.

SOURCE: © Bettmann/CORBIS

There is one area where futurists have suffered not from inflated hopes but from a feebleness of imagination: the information revolution. In an article titled “Brains That Click” in the March 1949 issue of Popular Mechanics, the author enthused over a state-of-theart supercomputer called the ENIAC (for Electronic Numerical Integrator and Computer). But he knew it was just the beginning. “Where a calculator like the ENIAC today is equipped with 18,000 vacuum tubes and weighs 30 tons,” he predicted, “computers in the future may have only 1,000 tubes and perhaps weigh only 11⁄2 tons.” Today’s amused denizens of the Internet have used their laptops and desktop PCs—each vastly more powerful than the pitiful ENIAC—to lampoon the quotation on scores of pages across the World Wide Web. Also spreading like a virus through cyberspace are words attributed to I.B.M.’s former chairman Thomas J. Watson in 1943: that there is a world market for perhaps five computers. Back then it seemed sensible that only nations or the largest corporations would be able to afford such mammoth contraptions. Again and again, prognosticators made the mistake of assuming that computers would be like rocket ships or other ordinary machines. The mightier you wanted to make them, the bigger, more expensive and more energy-hungry they would have to be. It defied common sense to envision what exists today, a technology where making something smaller causes it to be more powerful, with denser skeins of circuitry squeezed into increasingly tinier spaces. And that’s just the beginning of the magic. As the parts become closer together they can exchange information more rapidly. Designers can take a circuit diagram and photograph it onto a silicon chip. As the focus of the projector grows sharper, the circuits become finer and more tightly packed. With a design in place, chips can be stamped out like pages on a printing press. These devices—the most complex things produced by the human mind—can be made indefinitely small because of a crucial

SOURCE: From George Johnson, “Out of Place? A Virtual Space Odyssey; This Time, the Future Is Closer Than You Think”, ‘The New York Times’, December 31, 2000, http://www.nytimes.com. Copyright © 2000 by the New York Times Company. All rights reserved. Used by permission and protected by the Copyright Laws of the United States. The printing, copying, redistribution, or retransmission of the Material without express written permission is prohibited.

breakthrough ideas have been contributed disproportionately by the entrepreneurs in their pursuit of the temporary monopoly profits that successful innovations promise. The giant firms have specialized in a constant stream of incremental improvements that protect them from destruction by competitors who constantly seek to beat them at the innovation game. Together, the contributions of the two groups have played a critical role in the growth of the market economies as far back as ancient Mesopotamia, well before the rise of ancient Greece and Rome. But the internal R&D units of the giant firms had their inception only in the latter half of the nineteenth century. The innovation arm’s race in which no innovating firm dares to fall behind in its innovative efforts is an incredibly powerful mechanism underlying the tremendous economic growth accomplishments of the market economies.

Next, we turn from our description of the facts related to the market’s accomplishments in innovation and economic growth to see what the tools of microeconomic analysis can help us to understand about these achievements.

The Profits of Innovation: Schumpeter’s Model The modern microtheory of innovation and its rewards had its origins in the work of the late Professor Joseph Schumpeter. His model (1911) argues that the successful innovative entrepreneur’s reward is a monopoly profit, which accrues because the entrepreneur is Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

344

Part 4

The Virtues and Limitations of Markets

the first to bring a new product into the market. Having no rivals, that profit temporarily exceeds what can be earned under perfect competition. This high profit attracts imitating rivals into the market who seek to share those profits. By “reverse engineering” the new product, that is, by in effect taking it apart and seeing how it works, these imitators are able to enter the market with their rival product and thereby erode the initial entrepreneur’s “monopolistic”earnings. Eventually, those economic profits will be reduced to zero, because entry by imitators will continue as long as earnings are higher than that. The Schumpeterian analysis shows how the entrepreneur in this model is driven to work, without letup, for economic growth. To prevent termination of the monopoly rewards, the entrepreneur can never desist from further innovation and cannot rest on his laurels. Thus, the analysis clearly describes the tight association between innovative entrepreneurship and growth. But reality does not follow Schumpeter’s story in detail. As will be shown in Chapter 20, in reality the financial returns of many innovators are very low, and failure of their efforts and investments are not uncommon. Yet, many discussions of innovation start with the assumption that innovators can expect to earn very high profits. Indeed, huge rewards do often accrue to those who introduce unusually successful innovations. We have all heard of innovators like Thomas Edison, Alexander Graham Bell, and, more recently, Bill Gates, Steven Jobs, and others in the computer industry who have acquired great riches from their ability to invent or to bring innovations to market. Of course, for every successful innovator, many others have plowed their family savings into new gadgets and lost all they have spent. The evidence indicates that inventors on average earn zero economic profits, or even lose money. This possibility also appears likely when we consider big-business investment in R&D. As we saw in Chapter 10, if an industry is perfectly competitive, entry will occur until economic profits are forced down to zero. Put another way, perfect competition permits firms to earn just what they need to pay investors for the funds they provide—no more and no less. This must be so because if a typical firm in one industry earns more than firms in other industries, investors will put more money into the more profitable industry. Any excess economic profit will lead to an expansion of industry output, which will drive prices down and squeeze profits. Because there are some barriers to entry into innovation, we cannot be certain that economic profits from invention will tend exactly toward zero, but we can expect them to be very low on average. In other words, although inventive activity sometimes pays off handsomely, large R&D investments also can fail spectacularly, so that the average economic profits come out close to zero. In particular, a large firm with a big R&D division may work simultaneously on many possible innovations. The “law of averages” suggests that some of these efforts will fail and some will succeed. So we should not be surprised to find nearzero economic profit even in industries with a great deal of innovative activity. Although we have no systematic study of all inventive activities, high-tech industries provide a useful illustration—especially the computer industry, where many founders have made fortunes and received much publicity. According to corporate management guru Peter F. Drucker, “The computer industry hasn’t made a dime. . . . Intel and Microsoft make money, but look at all the people who were losing money all the world over. It is doubtful the industry has yet broken even.”12 But is this true everywhere? One study looked at companies that went public from 1975 to 1992, most of which were high-tech firms, and found their rate of return to be about average (that is, zero economic profit), once the researchers adjusted for risk and company size.13 In Chapter 20 we will see that the typical earnings of innovating entrepreneurs are apparently even lower.

As cited in Jane Katz, “To Market, to Market: Strategy in High-Tech Business,” Federal Reserve Bank of Boston Regional Review (Fall 1996), www.bos.frb.org. 13 Alon Brav and Paul A. Gompers, “Myth or Reality? The Long-Run Underperformance of Initial Public Offerings: Evidence from Venture and Nonventure Capital-Backed Companies,” Journal of Finance, 52, no. 5 (December 1997): 1791–1821. 12

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 16

The Market’s Prime Achievement: Innovation and Growth

Financing the Innovation “Arms Race”: High R&D Costs and “Monopoly Profits” In our discussion of the Schumpeterian model in the preceding section we hinted at our skepticism over what he describes as the monopoly profits of the entrepreneur. Largescale innovative activity is expensive. Firms must spend substantial amounts of money, year after year. In some firms, the costs of R&D can account for as much as 40 percent of the company’s total costs. If an innovative firm is to stay in business, the products it supplies must be priced so as to enable the firm to recover those expenditures. This effort requires an approach to pricing that is very different from the one we studied in earlier chapters. Previously we concluded that in a competitive market, prices tend to be set approximately equal to marginal costs, assuming this price would bring in enough revenue to keep the firm in business. To see the reason for the difference between this case and that of the innovative firm, consider the case of Jim—an organic wheat farmer—who decides to grow 1,000 more bushels of wheat than he did last year. That level of production will require him to rent x more acres of land, to buy y more bags of fertilizer and z more bags of seed, to hire h more hours of labor, and to borrow b more dollars from the bank. The prices of these inputs tell Jim how much he must spend to get the added output. If this added cost is divided by the 1,000 added bushels, we have an (approximate) calculation of the marginal cost of a bushel, including the marginal return to capital—Jim’s loan payment to the bank. If the price of organic wheat is set by the market so that it covers this amount, evidently price is equal to marginal cost and is also enough to keep the farm in business. It is enough to keep Jim’s farm going because all of his costs, including the cost of renting more land, are costs of adding to his output—in essence, all of his costs take the form of marginal or added costs. Contrast this case with a software firm that has just spent $20 million to create a valuable new computer program. If the firm supplies one more unit of the program (or even 1,000 more units of the program), what is its added cost? The answer is nearly zero—just the cost of making a new CD, packaging it, and shipping it. One of the firm’s main costs is that of R&D, but no added R&D cost is incurred when another purchaser acquires the already-designed program. So the firm’s heavy R&D expenditure contributes nothing to marginal cost. A price that covers only the marginal cost of one more copy of the program can hardly amount to more than, say, $5. That price cannot begin to cover the $20 million in R&D cost—a cost the firm will probably have to replicate in the next year to keep the program up-to-date and up to competitive standards. So, pricing software—or any other products of a firm with high and continuing R&D costs—at marginal cost is a recipe for financial suicide. Prices of the products of innovating firms simply cannot follow the familiar formula: P 5 MC. Rather, entry will force the expectable lifetime earnings of an invention just high enough to yield zero economic profit, covering marginal costs, opportunity costs, and the fixed cost of the invention’s R&D. True, the earnings will be higher initially, before imitators enter and depress market earnings. But those early high earnings will just be a substantial contribution to recovery of the fixed R&D outlays, not anything resembling monopoly profits. Of course, there are some cases in which innovators do earn monopoly profits, as is equally true in industries that contribute little innovation. But freedom of entry into the innovation process means that this will not be the ordinary state of affairs, as the courts of the United States have recognized in dealing with antitrust cases entailing innovation. Firms that are forced by competition to spend a great deal on research and development year after year, but that use the results of the R&D to improve a product whose marginal costs are low, cannot expect to recover their R&D costs if they set their prices equal or close to marginal costs, as occurs under perfect competition.

This pricing situation is troubling because it can mislead the government agencies charged with preventing firms from acting as monopolists. Many of the people who work in these agencies have been trained using textbooks such as this one, and they have come away from their studies with the valid (but possibly irrelevant) conclusion that under

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

345

346

Part 4

The Virtues and Limitations of Markets

perfect competition price must equal marginal cost. So, when they encounter prices in innovative firms that are nowhere near marginal costs, their suspicions are sometimes aroused. Is this firm exploiting the public by charging prices higher than marginal costs? Should something be done to make the company price its products as wheat farmer Jim does? We can see now that doing so may well bring innovative activity to a virtual standstill. Of course, most of the government authorities who are concerned with monopolistic behavior know better than that, but their suspicions are nevertheless aroused by finding cases of P . MC. In addition, some of them really do misunderstand the issue, and thereby constitute a threat to innovative activity by business.

How Much Will a Profit-Maximizing Firm Spend on Innovation? The legendary “Eureka! I have found it!” scenario, in which the lone inventor working in a basement or garage happens to come up with a brilliant invention, may not be amenable to conventional economic analysis. But innovation in a modern corporation is easier to analyze by using the standard tools of the theory of the firm because R&D budgeting looks a lot like other business decisions, such as those about how much to produce or how much to spend on advertising. We can study all of these standard business decisions using the same tools of marginal analysis that we studied in Chapters 5, 7, and 8. The key questions are: How much can we expect firms to spend on R&D? How much can they expect to earn by doing so? And how will competition affect their innovative activity? We have already just considered how much they can expect to earn and have asked and answered similar questions before, when we studied how basic marginal analysis addresses business decision making. If the firm seeks to maximize its profits, it will expand its spending on R&D up to the point at which the marginal cost of additional R&D equals the marginal revenue. By now, the logic should be familiar. A level of R&D spending (call it X dollars) at which marginal revenue (MR) is, for example, greater than marginal cost (MC) cannot possibly represent the profit-maximizing amount for the company to spend on R&D. For, if MR exceeds MC, the company can increase its profits by spending more than X dollars on R&D. The opposite will be true if MR , MC. In that case, the firm can increase its profits by decreasing R&D spending. So X dollars cannot be the optimal level of spending if, at that level of expenditure, either MR . MC or MR , MC. It follows that the profitmaximizing level of spending on R&D can only be an amount—say, Y dollars—at which MR 5 MC. You will recognize this argument, for we have repeated it many times in earlier chapters when we discussed other business decisions, such as those related to price and quantity of output. This analysis simultaneously tells us everything, and nothing, about the R&D decision. It tells us everything because its conclusion is correct. If the firm is a profit maximizer, and if we know its MR and its MC curves for R&D investment, then the MR 5 MC rule does, in theory, tell us exactly how much the profit-seeking firm should invest in R&D. But the discussion so far tells us nothing about the shape of “typical” marginal revenue and marginal cost curves for R&D, nor does it tell us how the competitive pressures that play such an important role in R&D decisions affect those curves. We turn next to these crucial matters.

A Kinked Revenue Curve Model of Spending on Innovation Our discussion thus far has left a basic question unanswered. If innovation is so expensive and so risky, and if the economic profits expected from innovation approach zero, why do firms do it? Why doesn’t every firm refuse to participate in this unattractive game? The answer, at least in part, is that competitive markets leave them no choice. If firms do not keep up with their competitors in terms of product attractiveness and improved process efficiency that lowers costs, they will lose out to their rivals and end up losing money. Clearly, firms prefer zero economic profits—profits that yield only normal competitive returns to investors—to negative profits and investor flight.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 16

The Market’s Prime Achievement: Innovation and Growth

SOURCE: © The New Yorker Collection 1983, Robert Weber from cartoonbank.com. All Rights Reserved.

This observation also enables us to investigate how much the firm will spend on R&D, using a microeconomic model very similar to one we encountered in Chapter 12—the kinked demand curve model that we used to explain why prices tend to be “sticky” in oligopoly markets. The underlying mechanism there was an asymmetry in the firm’s expectations about its competitors. The firm hesitates to lower its price for fear that its rivals will match the price cut, causing the firm to end up with only a few new customers but dramatically reduced revenues; that is, if the firm lowers its price it will be dealing with an inelastic demand curve. But the firm can be expected to fear that if it increases its price, the others will not follow suit, so that it will be left all by itself with an overpriced product. It will lose many customers—the relevant portion of its demand curve for price increases will be highly elastic. And we have seen that with an inelastic demand curve a price cut will reduce total revenue and the same is true of a price rise when demand is elastic. So, a firm with such beliefs will want to set its price at the industry level—no more and no less—and leave it there unless the competitive situation changes drastically. The innovation story is similar. Imagine an industry with, say, five firms of roughly equal size. Company X sees that each of the other firms in the industry spends approximately $20 million per year on R&D. Then our firm will generally find it unattractive to spend either less or more than this amount. It will not dare to spend much less than $20 million on its own R&D because if it does so, it risks falling behind its rivals in the unceasing race to introduce product improvements, for its rivals may well continue to spend the customary $20 million, leaving our firm’s next product model behind, without new features as attractive as those of rival products. But Company X will see little point in raising the ante to, say, $30 million because it knows that its competitors will be driven to follow suit, all of them simply expanding their innovative efforts simultaneously, with none gaining any new lead over its rivals. So neither a cut in R&D spending nor a rise in such spending will promise to add to profits, because rivals are likely to match any increased spending and nullify its prospective advantages, whereas the competitors can be expected not to replicate any R&D spending cut by our firm, hoping in this way to lure customers away from our enterprise. As a result, we can expect that the firms will hesitate to make any significant changes in the amount they spend on innovative activity, neither raising their expenditure nor reducing it. But that’s not the end of the story. All the firms in the industry will continue to invest the same amount as they have in the past, even if the cost of R&D shifts down moderately or some other minor change occurs, until one of them enjoys a research breakthrough leading to a wonderful new product. That fortunate firm will then expand its investment in the breakthrough product, because doing so will pay off even if the other firms in the industry match the increase. Thus the MR curve for the breakthrough firm will move to the right, and so will its profit-maximizing R&D budget level—to an amount larger than $20 million. Other companies in the industry will then be forced to follow. So now the industry norm will no longer be a $20 million annual investment but some larger amount, say, $25 million per firm. No firm will be the first to drop back to the old $20 million level, fearing that its rivals would not follow such a retrenchment move. So the MR 5 MC equilibrium point will now be $25 million of R&D spending. Again, the common story of armaments races among countries parallels the story of innovation battles among firms. The process we have just described assumes that competition forces firms in the industry to keep up with one ”You will never catch up with the new technology.” another in their R&D investments. But once they have

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

347

348

Part 4

The Virtues and Limitations of Markets

A ratchet is an arrangement that permits some economic variable, such as investment or advertising, to increase but prevents that variable from subsequently decreasing.

caught up, the investment level remains fairly constant until one firm breaks ranks and increases its spending. Then, all other firms follow suit, but none dares to drop back. Such an arrangement is described as a ratchet, in analogy to the mechanical device that prevents a wound-up spring from suddenly unwinding. This arrangement normally holds technological spending steady, sometimes permits it to move forward, but generally does not allow it to retreat. Thus, we can expect R&D spending to expand from time to time. Once the new level is reached, the ratchet—enforced by the competitive market—prevents firms from retreating to the previous lower level.14 Ratcheting acts as a critical part of the mechanism that produces the extraordinary growth records of free-enterprise economies and differentiates them from all other known economic systems. Competitive pressures force firms to run as fast as they can in the innovation race just to keep up with the others.

Innovation as a Public Good An innovation, once created, usually does not only contribute to the output of the firm that discovered the breakthrough. At little or no additional cost, the new technology can also add to the outputs produced by other enterprises, often in other industries. This public good property15 of technical knowledge enables those who adopt the innovation (with or without the inventor’s permission) to adopt it more cheaply. In Chapter 15, we used the term public good to describe any input or output that is not depleted when used once but rather can be used over and over by more users with little or no additional cost. Such goods can be made available to the entire public without additional cost over that of supplying it to a single individual. Analogously, R&D expenses need not be duplicated when firms use knowledge repeatedly to produce output. For instance, Thomas Edison and his colleagues worked for many months and used up much material before they finally found a way to create a viable light bulb. But they did not have to repeat that outlay on experiments to produce their second light bulb. Similarly, if Edison had permitted another firm to use the technology, that firm would not have needed to repeat the expensive research that yielded the first light bulb. Innovation is like the oil lamp in the ancient Hanukkah legend: a lamp that miraculously replenished its fuel and could provide light day after day without any additional oil. That is one distinguishing feature of any knowledge. Both coal and technical knowledge contribute to output. But when a ton of coal is used as fuel, it cannot be used again. A second ton of coal must be mined and burned to run the engine longer. Once technical knowledge is created, however, it can be used over and over again without ever being depleted.

Effects of Process Research on Outputs and Prices A product innovation is the introduction of a good or service that is entirely new or involves major modifications of earlier products.

As a last example of how standard analytic tools of microeconomic analysis can help us to deal with innovation, we turn to the effects of innovation on outputs and prices. We will consider a single monopoly firm that makes decisions independently of other enterprises’ activities and decisions. Innovation is often divided into two types: product innovations, which consist of the introduction of a new item (such as a photocopying machine or a video camera), and

This statement somewhat exaggerates the effectiveness of ratchets in preventing the economy from ever sliding backward in its R&D expenditures. After all, even in machinery, ratchets sometimes slip. Firms may, for example, be forced to cut back their R&D expenditure if business is extremely bad. They may also make mistakes in planning how much to spend on investment or become discouraged by repeated failures of their research division to come up with saleable products. The economy’s ratchets are indeed imperfect, but they nevertheless exist. They cannot completely prevent backsliding in R&D expenditure, but they can be a powerful influence that is effective in resisting such retreats. 15 For review of the concept of public goods, see Chapter 15, pages 316–318. 14

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 16

349

The Market’s Prime Achievement: Innovation and Growth

A process innovation is an innovation that changes the way in which a commodity is produced.

FI GURE 6 Effect of Process Innovations on Prices and Outputs

Price

process innovations, which entail an improvement in the way in which commodities are produced, making them cheaper to buy. At this point, we will discuss only process innovations, because they are easier to analyze. A successful process innovation can be expected to expand the output of the product that uses the process and to reduce the product’s price, for a very simple reason: A process innovation normally leads to a downward shift in the firm’s marginal and average cost curves but, because it involves no change in the product, it should not cause any change in the demand and marginal revenue curves. A standard graph familiar from earlier chapters can demonstrate these results. Figure 6 shows MR and DD (demand), the firm’s marginal revenue and demand (average revenue) curves, respectively, for the production of widgets. The graph also shows MC1, the marginal cost curve of widgets before the process innovation, and MC2, the marginal cost curve after the innovation is adopted. MC2 is naturally lower than MC1 because the innovaD tion has reduced the cost of making widgets. Before the innovation, the quantity produced by our profit-maximizing firm is P1 Q1, the quantity at which MR 5 MC1 (at MC1 P2 point E1). The corresponding price is P1, the point on the demand curve (DD) above MC2 quantity Q1. After the process innovation, E1 the marginal cost curve shifts downward to MC2. That new marginal cost curve meets E2 the downward-sloping MR curve at point E2, which lies to the right of E1. This means that the profit-maximizing output quantity must increase from Q1 to Q2, and, because MR of the downward slope of the demand curve, price must fall from P1 to P2. Thus, we have shown, as suggested earlier, that A cost-cutting process innovation increases the output and decreases the price of the product that a profitmaking firm supplies with the help of the innovation.

0

Q1

Q2

Quantity of Widgets Produced

DO FREE MARKETS SPEND ENOUGH ON R&D ACTIVITIES? We have seen that today’s market economies turn out innovations at a pace and complexity never seen before in human history. Business firms, the U.S. government, universities, and others spend a good deal on research and innovation. As we noted before, in 2007, more than $269 billion (about 1.9 percent of the United States’ total GDP) was spent on these activities, with business firms funding close to 90 percent of that amount.16 Yet we may well ask, is this amount too small or too large a share of GDP? That is, would the general public benefit or lose if more resources were devoted to innovation? Some economic analysis suggests that there is a fundamental reason for believing that, despite our impressive successes in this arena, we still do not spend enough. As usual, there is a trade-off to spending more than we currently do. If we devote more resources to innovation this year, less will be left over to produce clothing, food, or new

16 National Science Foundation, Division of Science Resources Statistics, “U.S. Business R&D Expenditures Increase in 2007,” Arlington, V.A., July 2009, accessed online at: http://www.nsf.org.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

D (AR)

350

Part 4

The Virtues and Limitations of Markets

TV programs—goods and services that contribute primarily to today’s consumption rather than tomorrow’s. With smaller supplies of these items, their prices will rise. On the other hand, if we devote more resources to innovation, we will probably get better and cheaper products in the future. So, as with any investment, R&D expenditures entail a trade-off between the present and the future. More R&D spending means that consumers get less to consume this year, but they get more and better products in the future. The question is, how much is enough?

Innovation as a Beneficial Externality

SOURCE: © The New Yorker Collection 1987, Bernard Schoenbaum from cartoonbank.com. All Rights Reserved.

Basic research refers to research that seeks to provide scientific knowledge and general principles rather than coming up with any specific marketable inventions.

Many economists believe that private enterprise does not devote enough resources to innovation, because the acquisition of new technical knowledge generates large externalities. Recall from Chapter 15 that an externality is an effect of a business transaction that benefits or hurts people other than those who directly take part in the transaction.17 For example, if a food supply firm finds it necessary to clean the snow off its street on a winter morning to get supplies to its restaurant customers on time, well before the slow municipal snow-removal effort is launched, then all the neighbors of the firm will benefit without having to contribute to the cost of rapid street clearing. Here, the business firm and its restaurant customers who are waiting for timely delivery are the direct participants in the transaction, and neighborhood homes receive the gains from the beneficial externality. So we see that sometimes externalities benefit unconnected third parties, rather than harming them, and then those who carry out the transaction reap only part of the benefits. As another example, suppose your roommate, an advanced engineering student, comes up with a more efficient battery that turns out to benefit laptop computer manufacturers, the makers of electric cars, and many others. Your roommate may get a prize for her work or may even receive a royalty payment from the companies that license her innovation. But she will not get all of the benefits. This is true of most innovations: They benefit the innovator to some degree, but large parts of the benefits—some estimates exceed 90 percent(!)18—also go to others. Such beneficial externalities mean that a firm that invests in R&D can expect to reap only a fraction of the profits from the innovation. Consequently, many economists believe that the free market induces private firms to invest less than the socially optimal amount in activities that generate external benefits, with innovation as a prime example. They believe that many innovations whose benefits would exceed their costs are never carried out because any firm that spent the money to produce the innovation would get only part of the benefit, and that part would be insufficient to cover the firm’s costs. Instead, governments finance a good deal of innovation and research activity, which is carried out in government laboratories and in research institutions such as universities. The externality problem is probably most severe for what is called basic research—that is, research that deals with science and general principles rather than improvement of a specific product. (Research ”Oh, if only it were so simple.”

For review, see Chapter 15, pages 312–316. See William D. Nordhaus, “Schumpeterian Profits in the American Economy: Theory and Measurement,” Working Paper 10433 (Cambridge, M.A: National Bureau of Economic Research, 2004). 17

18

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

The Market’s Prime Achievement: Innovation and Growth

351

of the latter sort, which is directly related to commercial or other uses, is called applied research.) For example, some further research on the nature of electricity and magnetism may yield enormous economic benefits in the near or distant future, but for the moment it satisfies only physicists’ curiosity. Few business firms will finance such research. Of course, the economy would be much less productive in the long run if no one did it. That is why the governments of the United States and a number of other industrialized countries finance basic research, and why economists generally favor such funding.

Applied research is research whose goal is to invent or improve particular products or processes, often for profit. Note, however, that the military and government health-related agencies provide examples of not-for-profit applied research.

Chapter 16

Why the Shortfall in Innovation Spending May Not Be So Big After All The notion that we are spending far too small a share of GDP on innovation is not really plausible. Looking about us, we see a flood of new products and processes, but certainly nothing that suggests a dearth of new technology. A number of economists are now offering reasons that suggest why there may be no shortfall, or why any shortfall that occurs may be relatively limited. Here only one of the reasons will be suggested: the existence of profitable markets in licensing of innovation to others. As we will see later in this chapter, many firms permit others, even their closest competitors, to use their private technology—for a fee. That fee becomes the market price for a license to use the technology. To take this idea to its extreme, imagine that all innovating firms are successful in profitably licensing their technology to every firm and individual that can benefit from it. Then the externality problem would disappear. The reason is straightforward: A beneficial externality, after all, is simply a good deed for which the doer of the deed is not paid, or not paid adequately, for the benefit he or she creates. For this reason, the outputs that yield beneficial externalities can generally be expected to be too low from the general welfare point of view. But if the supplier can somehow arrange to be paid sufficiently, the incentive to supply an adequate amount of the beneficial product will plainly be restored. So a profitable market for technology licenses is said to help in “internalizing the externality,” by getting the supplier paid for supplying the valuable innovation and by restoring the incentive for further innovation. A related but lesser-known phenomenon occurs when many firms try to reduce their risks by technology trading—getting paid for another firm’s use of its technology by receiving in exchange the right to use the other firm’s technology. This type of deal can be thought of as bartering, rather than selling, technology licenses. Either way, the innovator firm receives some compensation for the use of its technology by others. The implication is that even if innovating firms do not receive full compensation for the benefits that their technology provides to others, those firms seem to have become quite adept at getting some substantial portion of the appropriate payment. The result is that the innovation externalities may not be nearly as serious a handicap to innovation as the theory may have led some observers to suspect.

Technology trading is an arrangement in which a firm voluntarily makes its privately owned technology available to other firms either in exchange for access to the technology of the second company or for an agreed-upon fee.

THE MARKET ECONOMY AND THE SPEEDY DISSEMINATION OF NEW TECHNOLOGY Another attribute of the market economy that is vital for its growth is the fact that new technology now spreads with impressive speed, meaning that obsolete products and processes do not long survive or hold back economic growth. The evidence indicates that dissemination is not only surprisingly rapid but has also been growing more so with remarkable consistency for more than a century (see “The Speed-Up of Technology Dissemination” on page 352).

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

352

Part 4

The Virtues and Limitations of Markets

A recent study of 46 major product innovations found that, in less than a century, the average time between the commercial introduction of a new product and the time of entry of competitors supplying the same or similar products fell precipitously from almost 33 years at the inception of the twentieth century to just 3.4 years in the period 1967–1986.* Moreover, as shown in Figure 7 below, the decline was remarkably steady and persistent.

* Rajshree Agarwal and Michael Gort, “First Mover Advantage and the Speed of Competitive Entry, 1887–1986,” Journal of Law and Economics, XLIV (April 2001), pp. 161–177. The authors report that other studies support their results.

SOURCE: “Runner 2” by William J. Baumol

The Speed-Up of Technology Dissemination

What underlies this increase in the rapid spread of inventions? It may seem Increased Speed with Which Competition of Similar Products Faces the Seller of that when a business firm obtains a an Innovative Product promising new invention, it will naturally do all it can to bar its competitors’ 35 32.75 access to the new technology so as to re30 tain a competitive advantage over its rivals. In reality, this is often not so. If a 24.1 25 firm can get a sufficiently high price by licensing its technology to others, it may 20 be just as profitable to do that as to reserve the innovations for its own exclu13.84 15 sive use. This is not just a theoretical possibility. Newspaper reports indicate, 10 for example, that more than 20 percent 5.75 of IBM’s profits in 2000 were obtained 5 3.4 from its technology licenses. There is another incentive for firms to 0 trade innovations with others, including 1887–1906 1907–1926 1927–1946 1947–1966 1967–1986 their competitors. Fearing that their own SOURCE: Rajshree Agarwal and Michael Gort “First Mover Advantage and the Speed of Competitive Entry, 1887–1986,” laboratories may conceivably fail in all Journal of Law and Economics, XLIV (April 2001), pp. 161–177. R&D undertakings in a particular time period, while competitors may have better luck, firms often enter into agreements with a competitor to share all successful future innovations for a specified time period—say, the next five years. Such agreements reduce risk for both firms. In photography, for example, one camera manufacturer may introduce an improved automatic-focus device, a second firm may develop an automatic light adjustment, and a third may invent a way to make the camera more compact. Each of these three firms can keep its invention to itself, but if they get together and agree to produce cameras combining all their new features, they will be able to market a product clearly superior to anything produced individually. Cross licensing of patents They will also be in a far better position to meet competition from another camera occurs when each of two manufacturer. firms agrees to let the other Many firms and industries engage in this practice of cross licensing. For example, use some specified set of its IBM cross-licenses patents with each of its major competitors. One study of technology patents, either at a price exchange among American steel minimills, which are now world leaders in steel prospecified in their agreement ductivity, found that all but one of the 11 firms regularly and routinely exchanged inforor in return for access to the other firm’s patents. mation with the others. Firms would sometimes train the employees of competing Time Before Rival Inventions Appear (Years)

F I GURE 7

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 16

353

The Market’s Prime Achievement: Innovation and Growth

Even some of the largest companies in the world find that collaboration, rather than competition, can sometimes give them an advantage in the global economy. For instance, Sony and Sharp, two leading manufacturers of consumer electronics, have launched a joint venture to produce and sell high-definition Liquid Crystal Display (LCD) televisions. The two companies will jointly own Sharp’s newest LCD plant in Sakai City, Japan, which will produce LCD panels for both companies’ television lines. Part of the multinational conglomerate, Sony Group, Sony Corporation is a leading manufacturer of consumer electronics, with more than 170,000 employees in Japan. Sharp Corporation employs just 22,600 people in Japan, but specializes in manufacturing LCD televisions, DVD players, and Blu-ray Disc players. The Sony-Sharp joint venture allows Sharp to share the cost of its new LCD factory—the first in the world to use tenth-generation glass substrates—with Sony, which, in turn, will be able to incorporate Sharp’s leading-edge LCD panels into its new televisions.

SOURCE: ULTRA.F/Jupiter Images

Collaboration, Rather Than Competition, in Innovation

SOURCE: “Sharp and Sony Enter into Definitive Agreement regarding Joint Venture to Produce and Sell Large-Sized LCD Panels and Modules,” press release, July 30, 2009, accessed online at: http://www.sony.net/ SonyInfo/News/Press/200907/09-0730E/index.html.

firms or send their own personnel to competing facilities to help set up unfamiliar equipment.19 Indeed, business firms provide their technology to others for a profit so commonly that MIT has run a seminar teaching firms how to earn more from their technology-rental business. There is even an international association of technology licensing firms, with thousands of members. Inventions are becoming available more quickly to other firms, including competitors of the firms that own them. Moreover, competitive pressures ensure that these innovations are rapidly put to use.

CONCLUSION: THE MARKET ECONOMY AND ITS INNOVATION ASSEMBLY LINE Although we devoted a lot of attention to the virtues and vices of the market system in earlier chapters, those chapters barely mentioned what may be its greatest strength. Free-market capitalism has proved to be the most powerful engine of economic growth and innovation ever known. The increased creation, faster dissemination, and accelerated utilization of inventions is surely no accident. There is something about the way the modern economy works that makes it outstrip all of its predecessors in terms of the creation and utilization of new technology—and to do so with little letup for more than two centuries. Never before in history have the economic returns to the average person in the economically advanced economies risen so far and so quickly, and this, arguably, is by far the most spectacular economic accomplishment of the market mechanism.

| SUMMARY | 1. The growth records and per-capita incomes achieved by market economies far exceed those attained by any other form of economic organization. Innovation is one of the main sources of that economic growth. 2. Small firms created by entrepreneurs account for a substantial proportion of the economy’s breakthrough 19

inventions, whereas larger companies specialize in incremental improvements that over time often add up to very major advances. 3. Innovation in free-market economies is stimulated by competition among business firms, which try to outdo one another in terms of the attractiveness of their new

Eric Von Hippel, The Sources of Innovation (New York: Oxford University Press, 1988), p. 79.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

354

Part 4

The Virtues and Limitations of Markets

and improved products and in the efficiency of their productive processes.

7. Competition can force firms to set their R&D spending at levels corresponding to those of their rivals.

4. Innovative entrepreneurial firms are driven to provide a stream of innovations because otherwise rivals are likely to introduce substitute products that will erode the profits from any one innovation. Among large competing firms frequent innovation is a matter of life and death because a firm with obsolete products or processes will lose its customers to rivals.

8. The typical level of R&D spending in an industry will sometimes increase, but it will rarely decline because no firm dares to be the first to cut back on such spending.

5. The large amounts that competition forces many firms to spend on R&D and the low marginal costs of the consumer goods sometimes produced with the resulting innovations often mean that if the firms set P 5 MC, as is done under perfect competition, the innovating firms will not be able to recover their costs. 6. As with any other decision, a profit-maximizing firm will invest in R&D up to the point at which the expected MR equals the MC of that expenditure.

9. Process innovations can be shown by MR 5 MC analysis to increase outputs and decrease prices, even in monopoly firms. 10. Many economists believe that private investment in innovation will fall short of the socially optimal level, because the externalities from innovation mean that inventors do not obtain all of the benefits of their innovations. 11. Firms often seek to reduce the risks of their R&D activities by entering into agreements with other firms to share one another’s technology. They may also sell access to their technology to others.

| KEY TERMS | applied research 351

high-tech

basic research 350

Industrial Revolution

capitalism

innovation

335

341

product innovation 335

338

cross licensing 352

Invention

externality 334

per-capita income

GDP 337

process innovation

productivity ratchet

338 334 349

348

334

348

research and development (R&D) 340 technology trading

351

| DISCUSSION QUESTIONS | 1. To understand how much the free-enterprise economy has increased living standards, try to envision the daily life of a middle-class family in a major American city just after the Civil War, when the average purchasing power is estimated to have been less than one-ninth of today’s. What do you think they ate? How much clothing did they own? What were their living quarters like? What share of their budget was available for vacations and entertainment?

6. If average economic profits from investment in innovation are close to zero, why would many people be anxious to invest in innovation? 7. Explain how firms that share their technology with competitors benefit by improving their ability to compete against new entrants.

2. Name five common products introduced since you were born.

8. What are the possible advantages to the general welfare when firms make their technology automatically available to others (while, of course, charging a price for use of the technology)?

3. Name some companies that advertise that their products are “new” or “improved.”

9. Why may it be unprofitable for a firm to spend much more on R&D than its competitors do?

4. Explain why firms in an industry that spends a large amount of money on advertising may feel locked into their current advertising budgets, with no one firm daring to cut its expenditure. Describe the analogy with competition in innovation. 5. Alexander Graham Bell beat Elisha Grey to the patent office by several hours, so that Bell obtained the patent on the telephone. Imagine how much that patent turned out to be worth. How much do you think Grey got for his effort and expenditure on development of the invention? How does that help explain the possibility that average economic profits from innovation are close to zero?

10. Define the following terms: a. Externality b. Public good c. Ratchet Explain the applicability of these concepts to the innovative economy. 11. From the point of view of the general welfare, do you think spending on R&D in the United States is too low? Too high? Just about right? Why?

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Externalities, the Environment, and Natural Resources Environmental taxes are perhaps the most powerful tool societies have for forging economies that protect human and environmental health. DAVI D M AL I N RO ODM AN, WORL DWATCH I NSTI TU TE

E

conomics is useful in pointing out both the accomplishments of the market and its shortcomings. But that is only half the battle. Economic analysis would be quite arid if it could not offer us any remedial suggestions for dealing with the market’s shortcomings. In Chapter 13, we investigated one of the market’s important imperfections: monopoly, or limited competition. In this chapter, we will look at another significant market imperfection studied by microeconomists: externalities. In Chapter 15, we learned that externalities—the incidental benefits or damages imposed on people not directly involved in an economic activity—can cause the market mechanism to malfunction. In Part 1 of this chapter, we study a particularly important application of this idea: externalities as a way to explain environmental problems. We will consider the extent to which the price mechanism bears responsibility for these problems and see how that same mechanism can be harnessed to help remedy them. In Part 2 of this chapter, we address a closely related subject: the depletion of natural resources. We will discuss fears that the world is quickly using up many of its vital natural resources and see how the price mechanism can help with this problem as well.

C O N T E N T S PUZZLE: THOSE RESILIENT NATURAL RESOURCE SUPPLIES

BASIC APPROACHES TO ENVIRONMENTAL POLICY

ACTUAL RESOURCE PRICES IN THE TWENTIETH CENTURY

PART 1: THE ECONOMICS OF ENVIRONMENTAL PROTECTION

Emissions Taxes versus Direct Controls Another Financial Device to Protect the Environment: Emissions Permits

Interferences with Price Patterns Is Price Interference Justified? On the Virtues of Rising Prices

TWO CHEERS FOR THE MARKET

PUZZLE REVISITED: GROWING RESERVES OF EXHAUSTIBLE NATURAL RESOURCES

REVIEW—EXTERNALITIES: A CRITICAL SHORTCOMING OF THE MARKET MECHANISM The Facts: Is the World Really Getting Steadily More Polluted? The Role of Individuals and Governments in Environmental Damage Pollution and the Law of Conservation of Matter and Energy

PART 2: THE ECONOMICS OF NATURAL RESOURCES ECONOMIC ANALYSIS: THE FREE MARKET AND PRICING OF DEPLETABLE NATURAL RESOURCES Scarcity and Rising Prices Supply-Demand Analysis and Consumption

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

356

Part 4

The Virtues and Limitations of Markets

PUZZLE:

THOSE RESILIENT NATURAL RESOURCE SUPPLIES

It is a plain fact that the earth is endowed with only finite quantities of such vital resources as oil, copper, tin, and coal. This reality underlies many worried forecasts about the inevitable, and imminent, exhaustion of one resource or another. For instance, on page 370, “The Permanent Fuel Crisis” lists a number of bleak prophecies about oil production in the United States, all of which proved far off the mark. In reality, far from running out, available supplies of many key minerals and fuels are growing. Known supplies of most minerals have grown at least as fast as production and in many cases have far outstripped it. For example, in 1950 world reserves of tin were estimated at 6 million metric tons (mmt). Between 1950 and 2000, 11 mmt of tin were mined from the earth. Nonetheless, at the end of 2000 world reserves of tin had increased to 10 mmt. By the end of 2007, world reserves had declined to 6.1 mmt but were still considered to be in slight oversupply. Similarly, for iron ore (which is used to make steel), known U.S. stocks in 1950 were 46 mmt, but at the end of 2007, U.S. stocks had fallen to 2.9 mmt. A similar odd story is true for U.S. stocks of zinc, copper, and many more minerals.1 How is this possible? Aren’t the quantities of these resources finite? Economic principles, as we will see later in this chapter, help to clear up these mysteries.

PART 1: THE ECONOMICS OF ENVIRONMENTAL PROTECTION Environmental problems are not new. For example, in the Middle Ages, English kings repeatedly denounced the massive pollution of the river Thames, which, they reported, had grown so bad that it was impeding navigation of the tiny medieval ships! What is new and different is the attention we now give to environmental problems. Much of the increased interest stems from rising incomes, which have reduced our concerns about our most basic needs of food, clothing, and shelter and have allowed us the luxury of concentrating on the quality of life. Economic thought on the subject of environmental degradation preceded the outburst of public concern by nearly half a century. In 1911, the British economist Arthur C. Pigou wrote a remarkable book called The Economics of Welfare, which for the first time explained environmental problems in terms of externalities. Pigou also outlined an approach to environmental policy that is still favored by most economists today and is gradually winning over lawmakers, bureaucrats, and even cautious environmentalists (as the opening quotation suggests). His analysis indicated a system of monetary pollution charges that polluters are forced to pay can be an effective means to control pollution. In this way, the price mechanism can remedy one of its own shortcomings!

REVIEW—EXTERNALITIES: A CRITICAL SHORTCOMING OF THE MARKET MECHANISM An activity is said to generate a beneficial or detrimental externality if that activity causes incidental benefits or damages to others not directly involved in the activity, and no corresponding compensation is provided to or paid by those who generate the externality.

In our discussion in Chapter 15, we emphasized that externalities are found throughout the economy. For example, pollution of the air and waterways is to a considerable degree contributed by factories and motor vehicles as an incidental by-product of their activities that damages other members of society. Similarly, another car’s entry onto an overcrowded highway adds to delays that other travelers must endure, thereby causing those drivers and passengers to suffer a detrimental externality. But externalities can also be beneficial to third parties. In Chapter 16, when discussing the microeconomics of innovation U.S. Geological Survey, Historical Statistics for Mineral and Material Commodities in the United States, 2008, http://minerals.usgs.gov/ds/2005/140/#data; and U.S. Geological Survey, Minerals Yearbook: Tin, various years, http://minerals.usgs.gov/minerals.

1

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 17

357

Externalities, the Environment, and Natural Resources

and growth, we emphasized that the vital innovative activities, to which society devotes huge quantities of resources, usually provide beneficial externalities to persons who neither invest in innovation nor work in any research and development establishments. EXTERNALITIES: A SHORTCOMING OF THE MARKET THAT CAN BE CURED BY MARKET METHODS Because those who create harmful externalities do not pay for the damage done to others, they have little incentive to desist. In this way, the market tends to create an undesired abundance of damaging externalities. Similarly, because those who create beneficial externalities are not compensated for doing so, they have little incentive to supply as large a quantity as will best serve the interests of society. Therefore, the market tends to supply an undesirably small amount of such beneficial externalities. In sum, economists conclude that unless something is done about it, the market will provide an overabundance of harmful externalities and an undersupply of desirable ones. Either case is far from ideal. Externalities are one of our Ideas for Beyond the Final Exam because they have such important consequences for the welfare of society and the efficient functioning of the economy. They affect the health of the population and threaten our natural resource heritage and perhaps even the survival of the human race. This chapter discusses the character and magnitude of the problem and the methods that can be used to contain its harmful consequences.

IDEAS FOR BEYOND THE FINAL EXAM

In this chapter, we focus on one of the most highly publicized externalities—pollution. Toxic fumes from a chemical plant affect not only the plant’s employees and customers but also other people not directly associated with the plant. Because the firm does not pay for this incidental damage, the firm’s owners have no financial incentive to limit their emissions of pollution, especially because pollution controls cost money. Instead, the polluting firm will find it profitable to continue its toxic emissions as though the fumes caused no external damage to the community.

The Facts: Is the World Really Getting Steadily More Polluted? First, let’s look at the facts. The popular press often gives the impression that environmental problems have been growing steadily worse and that all pollution is attributable to modern industrialization and the profit system. The problems are, indeed, serious and some of them are extremely urgent, but it is nevertheless possible to exaggerate them. For one thing, pollution is nothing new. Medieval cities were pestholes; streets and rivers were littered with garbage and the air stank of rotting wastes—a level of filth that was accepted as normal. Early in the twentieth century, the automobile was actually hailed for its major improvement in the cleanliness of city streets, which until then had fought a losing battle against the proliferation of horse dung (see “Four-Legged Polluters” on page 359 for more on this issue). Since World War II, there has been marked progress in solving a number of pollution problems. Air quality has improved in U.S. cities during the past three decades, and concentrations of most air pollutants continue to decline. Most dramatic has been the nearly 100 percent decrease in ambient concentrations of lead since the 1970s. Figure 1 portrays the encouraging trends in national air pollution levels. With the exception of ozone, average concentrations are well below the national ambient air quality standards (NAAQS) established by the U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). Rapid declines in automobile pollution have played a large role in this improvement, along with decreases in emissions from power plants. There have also been some spectacular gains in water quality. In the Great Lakes region, where the Cuyahoga River once caught fire because of its toxic load and where Lake Erie was pronounced dead, tough pollution controls have gradually brought a recovery. The Europeans have made progress as well. For example, the infamous killing fogs of London, once the staple backdrop of British mystery fiction, are a thing of the past because of the air quality improvement since 1950. The Thames River has been cleaned up enough to allow large-scale fishing of giant conger eels to resume after a 150-year hiatus. Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

358

Part 4

The Virtues and Limitations of Markets

F IGURE 1

Parts per Million

Micrograms per Cubic Meter

0.030

NAAQS standard = 50 micrograms per cubic meter

80 60 40 20 0 1975

’80

’85

’90

Sulfur Dioxide

0.035

Particulate Matter

’95

’01

NAAQS annual standard = 0.03 parts per million

0.025 0.020 0.015 0.010 0.005 0 1975

’80

Parts per Million

Parts per Million

NAAQS annual standard = 0.053 parts per million

0.06 0.04 0.02 0 1975

’80

’85

’90

’95

0.08 0.04

New NAAQS 8-hour standard = 0.08 parts per million

’80

Micrograms per Cubic Meter

Parts per Million

8 4 ’85

’90

’85

’90

’95

’01

Lead

NAAQS 8-hour standard = 9 parts per million

’80

’01

0.12

Carbon Monoxide

0 1975

’95

Old NAAQS 1-hour standard = 0.12 parts per million

0.16

0 1975

’01

16 12

’90

Ozone (Smog)

Nitrogen Dioxide 0.08

’85

’95

’01

1.6 NAAQS standard = 1.5 micrograms per cubic meter

1.2 0.8 0.4 0 1975

’80

’85

’90

’95

’01

SOURCES: Council on Environmental Quality, Environmental Quality 1993, 24th Annual Report of the CEQ, Washington, D.C., April 1995; and U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, National Air Quality and Emissions Trends, various years, available at http://www.epa.gov. Special thanks to Joe Elkins of the U.S. Environmental Protection Agency for assistance in obtaining the latest air quality data.

Air Quality Trends in the United States, 1975–2001

NOTE: Measures are average ambient concentrations of the six pollutants for which the U.S. Environmental Protection Agency has established National Ambient Air Quality Standards (NAAQS). After 1987, particulate matter is measured by PM10 only, an indicator of those particles smaller than 10 micrometers.

The point is that pollution problems are not a uniquely modern phenomenon, nor is every part of the environment deteriorating relentlessly. Free-market economies certainly have no monopoly on pollution. Although it may seem that a centrally planned economy should be able to cope much better with the environmental problems caused by externalities, such economies have in reality been the biggest environmental disasters. China, the last large communist society, has some of the world’s worst air pollution, mainly from the burning of low-quality, high-sulfur coal and a dearth of pollution controls. Urban ozone levels in China are far greater than those in Los Angeles, a place where, Americans tend to think, smog was invented. Grave environmental problems also continue to plague Eastern Europe and the countries of the former Soviet Union. Poland, despite considerable improvement since 1989, continues to battle very serious air pollution problems. Particularly in the cities, high pollution levels contribute to health problems. The collapse of communism in the former Soviet Union revealed a staggering array of environmental horrors, including massive poisoning of air, ground, and water in the vicinity of industrial plants and the devastation of the Aral Sea, once the world’s fourth-largest inland sea, but now reduced to less than half its previous size. Many Russians live in environmentally hazardous conditions, and especially severe problems are found in Chechnya, where millions of barrels of oil have seeped into the ground from the region’s black-market oil industry. Radioactive pollutants from

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 17

Externalities, the Environment, and Natural Resources

359

Four-Legged Polluters Broadway’s affinity with ham has an enduring quality. In the 1860s, however, two species competed for attention in the heart of the city—one panting on stage, the other squealing and grunting in the streets. The pig in the city was a paradox—an element of rural culture transposed to urban life. Pigs roamed the streets rooting for food, the stink from their wastes poisoning the air. Because they ate garbage, the pigs were tolerated to a degree in the absence of adequate sanitation facilities. But this dubious contribution to municipal services was tiny in comparison with the nuisance they caused. From the nation’s capital to Midwestern “porkopolis,” we are told, squares and parks amounted to public hogpens. . . . in Kansas City the confusion and stench of patrolling hogs were so penetrating that Oscar Wilde observed, “They made granite eyes weep.”

Equine Smells In city streets clogged with automobiles, the vision of a horse and buggy produces strong nostalgia. A century ago it produced a different feeling—distress, owing to the horse for what he dropped and to the buggy for spreading it. Of the three million horses in American cities at the beginning of the twentieth century, New York had some 150,000, the healthier ones each producing between twenty and twenty-five pounds of manure a day. These dumplings were numerous on every street, attracting swarms of flies and radiating a

powerful stench. The ambiance was further debased by the presence on almost every block of stables filled with urine-saturated hay. During dry spells the pounding traffic refined the manure to dust, which blew “from the pavement as a sharp, piercing powder, to cover our clothes, ruin our furniture and flow up into our nostrils.” . . . The steadily increasing production [of manure] caused the more pessimistic observers to fear that American cities would disappear like Pompeii—but not under ashes.

SOURCE: © Bettmann/CORBIS

When Pigs Roamed Broadway

SOURCE: Excerpted from Otto L. Bettman, The Good Old Days—They Were Terrible! (New York: Random House; 1974), pp. 2–3.

50 years of plutonium production, processing, and storage at the Mayak industrial complex have turned nearby Lake Karachay into one of the most polluted places on earth. The result has been widespread illness and countless premature deaths in these areas.2 Yet our own environment here in the United States is hardly free from problems. Despite improvements, many U.S. urban areas still suffer many days of unhealthful air quality, particularly during the summer months. According to the EPA, approximately 105.6 million Americans (just over one-third of the population) were living in areas where pollution levels in 2006 still exceeded at least one of the national air quality standards adopted by the federal government.3 Ozone (the presence of which high above the earth protects humans from the fiercest part of the sun’s ultraviolet radiation) is the most important component of serious ground-level urban air pollution—smog—and remains a pervasive problem in the United States. Even formerly pristine wilderness areas are threatened by air pollution (see “Visibility Impairment from Air Pollution at Canyonlands National Park” on the next page). Our world is frequently subjected to new pollutants, some far more dangerous than those we have reduced, although less visible and less malodorous. Improperly dumped toxic substances—such as PCBs (polychlorinated biphenyls), chlorinated hydrocarbons, dioxins, heavy metals, and radioactive materials—can cause cancer and threaten life and health in other ways. The danger presented by some of these substances can persist for thousands of years, causing all but irreversible damage.

Central Intelligence Agency, The World Factbook, https://www.cia.gov; “Poland: Areas of Concern,” Resource Renewal Institute, http://www.rri.org; and “Russia: Environmental Issues,” U.S. Department of Energy, Energy Information Administration, http://www.eia.doe.gov. 3 U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, Office of Air Quality Planning and Standards, “Latest Findings on National Air Quality: Status and Trends Through 2006,” January 2008, Research Triangle Park, N.C.: U.S. EPA. 2

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Part 4

The Virtues and Limitations of Markets

SOURCE:© Ashley Cooper/CORBIS

360

This photo shows the significant glacial retreat in the Swiss Alps caused by global warming.

All these problems pale when compared to a global environmental threat—the long-term warming of the earth’s atmosphere. Scientists have demonstrated that the documented global warming of the past century, and especially in the past decade, is at least partly a consequence of human activities that have increased “greenhouse gases” in the atmosphere. Most climatologists agree that the carbon dioxide buildup from the burning of fossil fuels such as oil, natural gas, and coal is a prime contributor to this problem. Forecasts of future warming range from 1.8° to 6.3° Fahrenheit by the year 2100, a dramatic change that may shift world rain patterns, disrupt agriculture, threaten coastal cities with inundation, and expand deserts (for more on this topic, see “Big Arctic Perils Seen in Warming, Survey Finds” on the next page).

Although environmental problems are neither new nor confined to capitalist, industrialized economies, we continue to inflict damage on ourselves and our surroundings.

The Role of Individuals and Governments in Environmental Damage Many people think of industry as the primary villain in environmental damage. But this is not necessarily true. Although business firms do their share in harming the environment, private individuals and government are also major contributors.

For example, individual car owners are responsible for much of the air pollution in cities. Wood-burning stoves and fireplaces are a source of particulate pollution (smoke). Wastes from flush toilets and residential washing machines also cause significant harm. Governments, too, add to the problem. Municipal treatment plant wastes are a major source of water pollution. Military aircraft expel exhaust fumes and cause noise pollution. Obsolete atomic materials and by-products associated with chemical and nuclear weapons are among the most dangerous of all wastes, and their disposal remains an unsolved problem. Governments have also constructed giant dams and reservoirs that flooded farmlands and destroyed canyons. Swamp drainage has altered local ecology, and canal building has diverted the flow of rivers. The U.S. Army Corps of Engineers has been accused of acting on the basis of a so-called edifice complex.

Visibility Impairment from Air Pollution at Canyonlands National Park

. . . a clear day

. . . a hazy day

SOURCE: © Courtesy of USEPA

Even in such pristine and remote areas as Utah’s Canyonlands National Park, air pollution degrades visibility, as these two photos show.

SOURCE: U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, Office of Air & Radiation, Visibility Impairment, http://www.epa.gov/air/visibility/parks/canyonld.html.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 17

361

Externalities, the Environment, and Natural Resources

Pollution and the Law of Conservation of Matter and Energy The physical law of conservation of matter and energy tells us that objects cannot disappear—at most they can be changed into something else. Petroleum, for instance, can be transformed into heat (and smoke) or into plastic—but it will never vanish. This means that after a raw material has been used, either it must be used again (recycled) or it becomes a waste product that requires disposal. If it is not recycled, any input used in production must ultimately become a waste product. It may end up in some municipal dump; it may literally go up in smoke, contributing to atmospheric pollution; or it may be transformed into heat, warming up adjacent

Big Arctic Perils Seen in Warming, Survey Finds A comprehensive four-year study of warming in the Arctic shows that heat-trapping gases from tailpipes and smokestacks around the world are contributing to profound environmental changes, including sharp retreats of glaciers and sea ice, thawing of permafrost and shifts in the weather, the oceans and the atmosphere. The study, commissioned by eight nations with Arctic territory, including the United States, [and conducted by 300 scientists] says the changes are likely to harm native communities, wildlife and economic activity but also to offer some benefits, like longer growing seasons. . . . The report says that “while some historical changes in climate have resulted from natural causes and variations, the strength of the trends and the patterns of change that have emerged in recent decades indicate that human influences, resulting primarily from increased emissions of carbon dioxide and other greenhouse gases, have now become the dominant factor.” The Arctic “is now experiencing some of the most rapid and severe climate change on Earth,” the report says, adding, “Over the

Annual Mean Global Surface Air Temperature, 1880–2006

14.6

14.4 Temperature (°C)

SOURCE: National Aeronautics and Space Administration, Goddard Institute for Space Studies. http://www.giss.nasa.gov.

14.8

14.2

14.0

13.8

next years, climate change is expected to accelerate, contributing to major physical, ecological, social and economic changes, many of which have already begun. . . .” Prompt efforts to curb greenhouse-gas emissions could slow the pace of change, allowing communities and wildlife to adapt, the report says. But it also stresses that further warming and melting are unavoidable, given the century-long buildup of the gases, mainly carbon dioxide. . . . The potential benefits of the changes include projected growth in marine fish stocks and improved prospects for agriculture and timber harvests in some regions, as well as expanded access to Arctic waters. But the list of potential harms is far longer. The retreat of sea ice, the report says, “is very likely to have devastating consequences for polar bears, ice-living seals and local people for whom these animals are a primary food source.” Oil and gas deposits on land are likely to be harder to extract as tundra thaws, limiting the frozen season when drilling convoys can traverse the otherwise spongy ground, the report says. Alaska has already seen the “tundra travel” season on the North Slope shrink to 100 days from about 200 days a year in 1970. The report concludes that the consequences of the fastpaced Arctic warming will be global. In particular, the accelerated melting of Greenland’s two-milehigh sheets of ice will cause sea levels to rise around the world.

13.6

13.4 0 1880

1900

1920

1940

1960

1980

2006

SOURCE: From Andrew C. Revkin, “Big Arctic Perils Seen in Warming, Survey Finds”, in ’The New York Times’, October 30, 2004. Used by permission of the author.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

362

Part 4

The Virtues and Limitations of Markets

waterways and killing aquatic life. But the laws of physics tell us nothing can be done to make used inputs disappear altogether.

We create an extraordinary amount of solid waste—each American discards close to 4.6 pounds of trash every day, despite our efforts to reduce this waste. Fortunately, in the face of this rising tide of garbage, recycling rates for many commonly used materials (such as aluminum, paper, and glass) are rising in the United States and many other industrial countries. In the United States, recycling has increased substantially. According to the EPA, Americans recycled 33 percent of municipal solid waste in 2007, a rate that has more than tripled since 1980.4 As of 2005, 30 percent of the municipal waste generated by the 30 OECD member countries was recycled or composted—up from just 18 percent during the mid-1990s.5 Our very existence makes some environmental damage inevitable. To eat and protect ourselves from the elements, people must inevitably use up the earth’s resources and generate wastes. Environmental damage cannot be reduced to zero. As long as the human race survives, eliminating such damage completely is impossible.

Why do economists believe that, although environmental damage cannot be reduced to zero, the public interest requires it to be reduced below its free-market level? The reason is clear from our previous analysis: Why do economists conclude that the market mechanism, which is so good at providing approximately the right number of hockey sticks and hair dryers, generates too much pollution? Pollution is an externality, which means that it

The U.S. Environmental Protection Agency estimates that 7,100 American communities (covering about 25 percent of the U.S. population) operate “pay-as-you-throw” programs (also known as unit pricing or variable-rate pricing), in which residents are charged for the collection of household garbage based on the amount they throw away. This creates a direct economic incentive to generate less garbage and to recycle more of what is generated. Rather than paying a flat fee for waste disposal (or simply receiving waste disposal services without any sense of what the cost is—as is true when a municipality provides trash collection services and pays for them out of general revenues), these programs require residents to pay for municipal waste disposal based on the number of bags or cans of trash placed at the curb or dropped off at a trash disposal facility. It is no surprise that it works! It has been shown that variable-rate PAYT programs have substantially reduced the tonnage of waste shipped to disposal facilities. One recent study estimated that these programs have reduced residential disposal by about 17 percent, with 6 percent attributable to source reduction (less garbage generated), 5–6 percent attributable to increases in recycling, and 4–5 percent attributable to decreases in the amount of yard waste that residents put into their garbage cans.

SOURCE: © Brand X Pictures/Jupiterimages

Garbage! Economic Incentives to Create Less of It and Recycle More of It

SOURCE: Lisa Skumatz and David Freeman, “Pay as You Throw in the U.S.: 2006 Update and Analyses,” prepared for U.S. EPA by Skumatz Economic Research Associates, Superior, CO, December 2006.

4 U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, Municipal Solid Waste Generation, Recycling, and Disposal in the United States: Facts and Figures 2007, available at http://www.epa. gov. We should point out that recycling is not always as benign as it seems. The very process of preparing materials for reuse often can produce dangerous emissions. The recycling of waste oil is a clear example, because used petroleum products are often combined with toxic chemicals that can be released in the recycling process. 5 OECD Environmental Outlook to 2030, Paris: Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, 2008, p. 246, accessed online at: http://titania.sourceoecd.org/vl=1517583/cl=44/nw=1/rpsv/cgi-bin/ fulltextew.pl?prpsv=/ij/oecdthemes/99980061/v2008n1/s14/p459.idx.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 17

Externalities, the Environment, and Natural Resources

results from a price mechanism malfunction that prevents the market from doing its usual effective job of carrying out consumers’ wishes. Here, failure of the pricing system is caused by a pollution-generating firm’s ability to use up some of the community’s clean air or water without paying for the privilege. Just as the firm would undoubtedly use oil and electricity wastefully if they were available at no charge, so it will use “free” air wastefully, despoiling it with chemical fumes far beyond the level justified by the public interest. The problem is that price has not been permitted to play its usual role here. Instead of having to pay for the pure air that it uses up, a polluting firm gets that valuable resource free of charge. Externalities play a crucial role affecting the quality of life. They show why the market mechanism, which is so efficient in supplying consumers’ goods, has a much poorer record in terms of environmental effects. The problem of pollution illustrates the importance of externalities for public policy. The magnitude of our pollution problems is largely attributable to the fact that the market lets individuals, firms, and government agencies deplete such resources as clean water and pure air without charging them any money for using up those resources.

It follows that one way of dealing with pollution problems is to charge those who emit pollution, and those who despoil the environment in other ways, a price commensurate with the costs they impose on society.

BASIC APPROACHES TO ENVIRONMENTAL POLICY In broad terms, there are three ways to control activities that damage the environment: • Voluntary efforts, such as nonmandatory investment in pollution-control equipment by firms motivated by social responsibility or voluntary recycling of solid wastes by consumers. • Direct controls, which either (1) impose legal ceilings on the amount any polluter is permitted to emit or (2) specify how particular activities must be carried out. For example, direct controls may prohibit backyard garbage incinerators or highsulfur coal burning or require smokestack “scrubbers” to capture the emissions of power plants. • Taxes on pollution, tradeable emissions permits, or the use of other monetary incentives or penalties to make it unattractive financially for pollution emitters to continue to pollute as usual. As we will see next, all of these methods have useful roles.

1. Voluntarism Voluntarism, though admirable, often has proved weak and unreliable. Some well-intentioned business firms, for example, have voluntarily made sincere attempts to adopt environmentally beneficial practices. Yet competition has usually prevented them from spending more than token amounts for this purpose. No business, whatever its virtues, can long afford to spend so much on “good works” that rivals can easily underprice it. As a result, voluntary business programs sometimes have been more helpful to the companies’ public relations activities than to the environment. Yet voluntary measures do have their place. They are appropriate where surveillance and, consequently, enforcement is impractical, as in the prevention of littering by campers in isolated areas, where appeals to people’s consciences are the only alternative. And in brief but serious emergencies, which do not allow for time to plan and enact a systematic program, voluntary compliance may be the only workable approach. Several major cities have, for example, experienced episodes of temporary but dangerous concentrations of pollutants, forcing the authorities to appeal to the public for drastic emissions cuts. Public response to appeals requiring cooperation for short periods often has been enthusiastic and gratifying, particularly when civic pride was a factor. During the 1984 Summer Olympic Games, for example, Los Angeles city officials asked motorists Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

363

364

Part 4

The Virtues and Limitations of Markets

to carpool, businesses to stagger work hours, and truckers to restrict themselves to essential deliveries and to avoid rush hours. The result was an extraordinary decrease in traffic and smog, such that the 6,000-foot San Gabriel Mountains suddenly became visible behind the city. Direct controls are government rules that tell organizations or individuals what processes or raw materials they may use or what products they are permitted to supply or purchase.

Pollution charges (taxes on emissions) are taxes that polluters are required to pay. The amount they pay depends on what they emit and in what quantities.

2. Direct Controls Direct controls have traditionally been the chief instrument of environmental policy in the United States (the so-called command-and-control approach). The federal government, through the Environmental Protection Agency, formulates standards for air and water quality and requires state and local governments to adopt rules that will ensure achievement of those goals. For example, the standards for automobile emissions require new automobiles to pass tests showing that their emissions do not exceed specified amounts. As another example, localities sometimes prohibit industry’s use of particularly “dirty” fuels or require firms to adopt processes to “clean” those fuels.

3. Taxes on Pollution Emissions Most economists agree that relying exclusively on direct controls is a mistake and that, in most cases, financial penalties, or pollution charges, on polluters can do the same job more dependably, effectively, and economically. The most common suggestion is that governments permit firms to pollute all they want but be forced to pay a tax for the privilege, in order to make them want to pollute less. Under such a plan, the quantity of the polluter’s emissions is metered just like the use of electricity. At the end of the month the government sends the polluter a bill charging a stipulated amount for each gallon (or other unit) of emissions. (The amount can also vary with the emissions’ quality, with a higher tax rate being imposed on emissions that are more dangerous or unpleasant.) Thus, in such a scheme, the more environmental damage done, the more the polluter pays. Emissions taxes are deliberately designed to encourage polluters to take advantage of the tax loophole—by polluting less, the polluter can reduce the amount of tax owed. Businesses do respond to such taxes. One well-known example is the Ruhr River basin in Germany, where emissions taxes have been used for many years. Although the Ruhr is a heavily concentrated industrial center, the rivers that are protected by taxes are clean enough for fishing and other recreational purposes. Firms have also found it profitable to avoid taxes by extracting pollutants from their liquid discharges and recycling them. (See “Making the Polluter Pay” for another example of the response to taxes.)

Emissions Taxes versus Direct Controls It is important to see why taxes on emissions may prove more effective and reliable than direct controls. Direct controls rely on the criminal justice system for enforcement. But a polluter who violates the rules must first be caught. Then the regulatory agency must decide whether it has enough evidence to prosecute. Next, the agency must win its case in court. Finally, the court must impose a penalty strong enough to matter. If any one of these steps does not occur, the polluter gets away with the environmentally damaging activities.

Enforcement Issues Enforcement of direct controls requires vigilance and enthusiasm by the regulatory agency, which must assign the resources and persons needed to carry out enforcement. However, in many cases the resources devoted to enforcement are pitifully small. The effectiveness of direct controls also depends on the speed and rigor of the court system. Yet the courts are often slow and lenient. In the notorious case of the Reserve Mining Company, more than a decade of litigation was required to stop this company from pouring its wastes (which contain asbestos-like fibers believed to cause cancer) into Lake Superior, the drinking water source for a number of communities. Finally, direct controls work only if the legal system imposes substantial penalties on violators. In the late 1990s, there were some significant penalties imposed in several cases (for instance, in 1998 Louisiana Pacific Corporation was fined $37 million Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Externalities, the Environment, and Natural Resources

Chapter 17

365

Making the Polluter Pay In the Netherlands, a set of charges originally intended only to cover the costs of wastewater treatment has produced a classic demonstration of the pollution-preventing power of charges themselves. Since 1970, gradually rising fees for emissions of organic material and heavy metals into canals, rivers, and lakes have spurred companies to cut emissions, but without dictating how. Between 1976 and 1994, emissions of cadmium, copper, lead,

mercury, and zinc plummeted 86–97 percent, primarily because of the charges, according to statistical analyses. . . . And demand for pollution control equipment has spurred Dutch manufacturers to develop better models, lowering costs and turning the country into a global leader in the market. The taxes have in effect sought the path of least economic resistance—of least cost—in cleaning up the country’s waters.

Industrial Discharges of Selected Heavy Metals into Surface Waters of the Netherlands, 1976–1994 150

Lead

Zinc

100

Copper 75

Cadmium

50

25 Mercury 0 1976

1980

1984

1988

1992 1994

SOURCE: © Hill Creek Picutres/Index Stock Imagery, Inc.

Index (1976 = 100)

120

SOURCE: David Malin Roodman, “Getting the Signals Right: Tax Reform to Protect the Environment and the Economy” from Worldwatch Institute, Worldwatch Paper 134, 1997, http://www.worldwatch.org. Reprinted by permission.

for violations of the Clean Air Act; and in 1999 Royal Caribbean Cruises Ltd., one of the world’s largest cruise lines, agreed to pay $18 million for dumping oil and hazardous chemicals in U.S. waters). In 2007, American Electric Power (AEP) agreed to pay a $15 million civil penalty and a $4.6 billion settlement—the largest of its kind in the history of the Clean Air Act—for failing to install required pollution controls at some of its coal-fired electric power plants. Some polluters have served prison terms for their misdeeds. Much more often, however, large firms have been convicted of polluting and fined amounts beneath the notice of even a relatively small corporation. Spread out over 10 years, AEP’s $4.6 billion settlement looks pretty small next to the company’s $14.4 billion in revenues in 2008.6 Under the second Bush administration, environmental fines and the prosecution of polluters fell off significantly. In contrast, pollution taxes are automatic and certain. No one need be caught, prosecuted, convicted, and punished. The tax bills are sent out automatically by the untiring tax collector. The only sure way for the polluter to avoid paying pollution charges is to pollute less. “Record-Breaking $4.6 Billion Clean Air Act Settlement Announced,” National Resources Defense Council press release, October 9, 2007, accessed online: http://www.nrdc.org/media/2007/071009.asp.

6

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

366

Part 4

The Virtues and Limitations of Markets

Efficiency in Cleanup A second important advantage of emissions taxes is that they tend to cost less than direct controls. Statistical estimates for several pollution-control programs suggest that the cost of doing the job through direct controls can easily be twice as high as under the tax alternative. Why should there be such a difference? Under direct controls, emissions cutbacks are usually not apportioned among the various firms on the basis of ability to reduce pollution cheaply and efficiently. Suppose it costs Firm A only 3 cents per gallon to reduce emissions, whereas Firm B must spend 20 cents per gallon to do the same job. If each firm spews out 2,000 gallons of pollution per day, authorities can achieve a 50 percent reduction in pollution by ordering both firms to limit emissions to 1,000 gallons per day. This may or may not be fair, but it is certainly not efficient. The social cost will be 1,000 3 3 cents (or $30) to Firm A, and 1,000 3 20 cents (or $200) to Firm B, a total of $230. If the government had instead imposed a tax of 10 cents per gallon, Firm A would have done all the cleanup work by itself, at a far lower total cost. Why? Firm A would have eliminated its emissions altogether, paying the 3 cents/gallon cost to avoid the 10 cents/gallon tax. Firm B would have gone on polluting as before, because the tax would be cheaper than the 20 cents/gallon cost of controlling its pollution. In this way, under the tax, total daily emissions would still be cut by 2,000 gallons per day, but the total daily cost of the program would be $60 (3 cents 3 2,000 gallons) as opposed to $230 under direct controls. The secret of a pollution tax’s efficiency is straightforward. Only polluters that can reduce emissions cheaply and efficiently can afford to take advantage of the built-in loophole—the opportunity to save on taxes by reducing emissions. The tax approach therefore assigns the job to those who can do it most effectively—and rewards them by letting them escape the tax.

Advantages and Disadvantages Given all these advantages of the tax approach, why would anyone want to use direct controls? In three important situations, direct controls have a clear advantage: • Where an emission is so dangerous that it must be prohibited altogether. • Where a sudden change in circumstances—for example, a dangerous air-quality crisis— calls for prompt and substantial changes in conduct, such as temporary reductions in use of cars. Tax rule changes are difficult and time-consuming, so direct controls will usually do a better job in such a case. The mayor of a city threatened by a dangerous air-quality crisis can, for example, forbid use of private passenger cars until the crisis passes. • Where effective and dependable pollution-metering devices have not been invented or are prohibitively costly to install and operate. In such cases, authorities cannot operate an effective tax program because they cannot determine the emissions levels of an individual polluter and so cannot calculate the tax bill. The only effective option may be to require firms to use “clean” fuel or install emissions-purification equipment.

Emissions permits are licenses issued by government specifying the maximum amount the license holder is allowed to emit. The licenses are restricted to permit a limited amount of emissions in total. Often, they must be purchased from the government or on a special market.

Another Financial Device to Protect the Environment: Emissions Permits The basic idea underlying the emissions-tax approach to environmental protection is that financial incentives induce polluters to reduce their environmental damage. At least one other form of financial inducement can accomplish the same thing: requiring polluters to buy emissions permits that authorize the emission of a specified quantity of pollutant. Such permits can be offered for sale in limited quantities fixed by the government authorities at prices set by demand and supply. Under this arrangement, the environmental agency decides what quantity of emissions per unit of time (say, per year) is tolerable and then issues a batch of permits authorizing (altogether) just that amount of pollution. The permits are sold to the highest bidders,

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 17

Externalities, the Environment, and Natural Resources

with the price determined by demand and supply. The price will be high if the number of permits offered for sale is small and many firms need permits to carry out their industrial activities. Similarly, the price of a permit will be low if authorities issue many permits but the quantity of pollution that firms demand is small. Emissions permits basically work like a tax—they make it too expensive for firms to continue polluting as much as before. However, the permit approach has some advantages over taxes. For example, it reduces uncertainty about the quantity of pollution that will be emitted. Under a tax, we cannot be sure about this quantity in advance, because it depends on polluters’ future response to a given tax rate. In the case of permits, environmental authorities decide on an emissions ceiling in advance, then issue permits authorizing just that amount of emissions. When the U.S. EPA first introduced tradeable emissions permits in 1995, many people were outraged by the notion of such “licenses to pollute.” Nowadays, one hears few complaints, because tradeable permit programs have turned out to be such a huge success. One of the best examples is the “acid rain” market for sulfur dioxide permits (in which the main players are the large electricitygenerating utility companies). This “cap and trade” program (in which the EPA sets limitations on total SO2 emissions and issues the number of tradeable permits, called allowances, that will keep emissions within those limits) has lowered pollution levels while saving billions of dollars in polluter costs. In 2008, more than 13.9 million SO 2 allowances were traded, the vast majority in private over-the-counter transactions, with the EPA providing online systems of allowance tracking, emissions tracking, and continuous emissions monitoring. The Chicago Board of Trade runs EPA’s annual auction of a small percentage of allowances, which generates valuable information about the going price of allowances. These markets are open to anyone, so environmental activists can buy these permits and “retire” them, thereby improving the quality of the air (for example, during the 2004 auction, the Acid Rain Retirement Fund, a Portland, Maine–based nonprofit organization, bought 7 allowances at a price of $2,100; at the same time, Ohio-based American Electric Power bought 75,000 allowances for $20,813,800).7 (See “EPA’s Clean Air Markets” on page 368 for more on the sulfur dioxide market and other programs involving tradeable emissions permits.) Despite the good news about economic incentives in cap and trade for sulfur dioxide and other pollutants, it must be noted that politics can sometimes interfere with environmental programs. For example, in 2007 the U.S. Supreme Court overturned a Bush administration attempt to relax Clean Air Act rules for aging electric power plants. And, in another decision on the same day (April 2, 2007), the court held that the Clean Air Act gives the U.S. Environmental Protection Agency the power to regulate carbon dioxide and other global-warming pollutants, contrary to arguments by the Bush administration.

TWO CHEERS FOR THE MARKET In Part 1 of this chapter, we have learned that environmental protection cannot be left to the free market. Because of the large externalities involved, the market will systematically allocate insufficient resources to the job. However, this market failure does not imply that we should disregard the price mechanism. On the contrary, we have seen that a legislated market solution based on pollution charges may often be the best way to protect the environment. At least in this case, the market mechanism’s power can be harnessed to correct its own failings. We turn now, in the second part of this chapter, to the issue of natural resources, where the market mechanism also plays a crucial role.

7

Source: http://epa.gov/airmarkets.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

367

368

Part 4

The Virtues and Limitations of Markets

EPA’s Clean Air Markets The Environmental Protection Agency’s Clean Air Markets let participants in the sulfur dioxide (SO2) and nitrogen oxide (NOx) pollution permits markets record trades directly on the internet. A trading unit is called an allowance and is equivalent to one ton of air emissions. EPA’s tracking systems record official SO2 and NOx allowance transfers under existing emission “cap and trade” programs. Anyone anywhere in the world can participate in the market, and hundreds of companies, brokers, and individuals are already engaged in trading. Emissions “cap and trade” programs ensure that environmental goals are met (by setting a cap on emissions and allowing polluters to trade allowances among themselves), while providing companies with an alternative to the installation of costly pollution control technologies in complying with the law. This approach was first used nationally by EPA in its acid rain program to reduce SO2 and then utilized by the northeastern states to reduce NOx. It has also been used in Southern California to reduce SO2 and NOx and in Chicago to reduce volatile organic compounds, the prime ingredient in the formation of ground-level ozone (smog). The cap and trade programs effectively reduce air pollution by setting a permanent cap on emissions, then allowing trading within that cap. As a prerequisite to trading, EPA requires rigorous monitoring and reporting standards, and mandates that companies pay automatic fees to the government for any emissions above the legal limit. Rigorous monitoring is essential to ensuring certainty and consistency in the program and to confirming that each allowance traded represents one ton of emissions, regardless of where it is generated. It is this certainty and consistency that enable creation of a robust market for allowances, free from the need for government review and approval of transactions. EPA emphasizes, however, that no matter how many allowances a utility holds, it will not be permitted to emit amounts of pollutant that

SOURCE: © 2002 PhotoDisc

would violate the national or state atmospheric (ambient) healthprotection standards. Additional cap and trade programs have been proposed by Congress to reduce electricity industry emissions in the United States, and dozens of countries around the world are considering such programs.

SOURCE: U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, “$20 Billion Emission Trading Market Goes Online,” EPA Newsroom, www.epa.gov, December 4, 2001. The Clean Air Markets web site is at http://www.epa.gov/airmarkets.

PART 2: THE ECONOMICS OF NATURAL RESOURCES Since Fuel is become so expensive, and will of course grow scarcer and dearer; any new Proposal for saving the [fuel] . . . may at least be thought worth Consideration.

SOURCE: © Owen Franken/CORBIS

BENJAM I N FR AN KLI N , 1744

One of the most significant forms of environmental damage occurs when we waste natural resources. Earlier in this chapter, we saw that externalities can lead to just this sort of waste—as when governments, individuals, or business firms use up clean air and clean water without cost or penalty. There is a close analytic connection between the economics of environmental protection that we have just investigated and the economics of natural resources, to which we now turn. More than 30 years ago, the world was rocked by a sudden “energy crisis.” Oil prices shot up and consumers found themselves waiting in long lines to buy gasoline. This event had profound effects throughout the world

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 17

Externalities, the Environment, and Natural Resources

and ended the widespread assumption that the stock of natural resources was unlimited and simply ours for the taking. Indeed, back in the late 1970s and early 1980s, there was near panic about the threatened exhaustion of many natural resources. The front page of a leading magazine even asked, “Are we running out of everything?” Natural resources have always been scarce, and they have often been used wastefully. Nevertheless, we are not about to run out of the most vital resources. In many cases, substitutes are available, and many of the shortages of the 1970s can largely be ascribed to the folly of government programs rather than the imminent exhaustion of natural resources.

ECONOMIC ANALYSIS: THE FREE MARKET AND PRICING OF DEPLETABLE RESOURCES If statistics on known mineral reserves keep rising as surprisingly as those reported in the puzzle with which this chapter began, we may begin to regard them skeptically and question whether the statistics are wrong or whether we are really not running out of a number of valuable resources, despite their finite supply and their continued use. Is there another indicator of resource depletion that is more reliable? Most economists say there is one—the price of the resource.

Scarcity and Rising Prices According to economic analysis, a better indicator of the degree of depletion of a resource is its price. As a resource becomes scarcer, we expect its price to rise for several reasons. One reason is that we do not deplete a resource simply by gradually using up a homogeneous product, every unit of which is equally available. Rather, we generally use up the most accessible and highest-quality deposits first; only then do we turn to less accessible supplies that are more costly to retrieve or deposits of lower purity or quality. Oil is a clear example. First, Americans relied primarily on the most easily found domestic oil. Then they turned to imports from the Middle East with their higher transport costs. At that point it was not yet profitable to embark on the dangerous and extremely costly process of bringing up oil from the floor of the North Sea. We know that the United States still possesses a tremendous amount of petroleum embedded in shale (rock), but so far this oil has been too difficult and, therefore, too costly to extract. Increasing scarcity of a resource such as oil is not usually a matter of imminent and total disappearance. Rather, it involves exhaustion of the most accessible and cheapest sources so that new supplies become more costly.

Supply-Demand Analysis and Consumption Growing scarcity also raises resource prices for the usual supply-demand reason. As we know, goods in short supply tend to become more expensive. To see just how this process works for natural resources, imagine a mythical mineral, “economite,” consistent in quality, which has negligible extraction and transportation costs. How quickly will the reserves of this mineral be used up, and what will happen to its price as time passes? The basic law of pricing of a depletable resource tells us that as its stocks are used up, its price in a perfectly competitive market will rise every year by greater and greater dollar amounts.

Although we can predict the price of economite without knowing anything about its supply or consumer demand for it, we do need to know something about supply and demand to determine what will happen to economite’s consumption—the rate at which it will be used up.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

369

370

Part 4

The Virtues and Limitations of Markets

The Permanent Fuel Crisis

Past Petroleum Prophecies (and Realities) U.S. Production Date Rate Prophecy Reality 1866 0.005 Synthetics are available if oil In the next 82 years, the U.S. production should end. produces 37 billion barrels U.S. Revenue Commission with no need for synthetics. 1891 0.05 Little or no chance for oil in Production exceeds 14 billion Kansas or Texas. barrels in these two states U.S. Geological Survey since 1891. 1914 0.27 Total future production only More than 34 billion barrels 5.7 billion barrels. produced since 1914, or six Official of U.S. Bureau of Mines times the prediction. 1920 0.45 U.S. needs foreign oil and 1948 U.S. production synthetics; peak domestic exceeds consumption and is production almost reached. more than four times 1920 Director, U.S. Geological Survey output. 1939 1.3 U.S. oil supplies will last only New oil found since 1939 13 years. exceeds the 13 years’ supply Radio Broadcasts by Interior known at that time. Department 1947 1.9 Sufficient oil cannot be found 4.3 billion barrels found in in the United States. 1948, the largest volume in Chief of Petroleum Division, history and twice U.S. State Department consumption. 1949 2.0 End of U.S. oil supply almost Recent industry data show in sight. ability to increase U.S. Secretary of the Interior production by more than 1 million barrels daily in the next five years. NOTE: U.S. oil production rate in billions of barrels per year.

SOURCE: William M. Brown, “The Outlook for Future Petroleum Supplies,” in Julian L. Simon and Herman Kahn, eds., The Resourceful Earth: A Response to Global 2000 (Oxford, U.K.: Basil Blackwell; 1984), p. 362, who cite Presidential Energy Program, Hearings before the Subcommittee on Energy and Power of the Committee on Interstate and Foreign Commerce, House of Representatives, 1st session on the implication of the President’s proposals in the Energy Independence Act of 1975, Serial No. 94-20, p. 643. February 17, 18, 20, and 21, 1975.

Figure 2(a) is a demand curve for economite, DD, which shows the amount people want to use up per year at various price levels. On the vertical axis, we show how the price must rise from year to year from $100 per ton in the initial year to $110 per ton in the next year, and so on. Because of the demand curve’s negative slope, it follows that consumption of this mineral will fall each year. That is, if there is no shift in the demand curve, as in Panel (a), consumption will fall from 100,000 tons initially to 95,000 tons the next year, and so on. In reality, such demand curves rarely stay still. As the economy grows and population and incomes increase, demand curves shift outward—a pattern that has probably been true for most scarce resources. Such shifts in the demand curve will offset at least part Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

SOURCE: © Keith Wood/Stone/Getty Images

Humanity has a long history of panicking about the imminent exhaustion of natural resources. In the thirteenth century, a large part of Europe’s forests was cut down, primarily for use in metalworking (much of it for armor). Wood prices rose, and there was a good deal of talk about depletion of fuel stocks. People have been doing it ever since, as the accompanying table illustrates.

FIGURE 2 Consumption over Time of a Depletable Resource

D D2

Price per Ton

D1 Price per Ton

of the reduction in quantity demanded that results from rising prices. Nevertheless, rising prices do cut consumption growth relative to what it would have been if price had remained unchanged. Figure 2(b) depicts an outward shift in demand from curve D1D1 in the initial period to curve D2D2 a year later. If price had remained constant at the initial value, $100 per ton, quantity consumed per year would have risen from 100,000 tons to 120,000 tons. But because with a given supply curve price must rise, say to $110 per ton, quantity demanded will increase only to 110,000 tons. Thus, whether or not the demand curve shifts, we conclude:

371

Externalities, the Environment, and Natural Resources

Chapter 17

C

$121

B

110

A

100

$121 G

110 A

100

F D2 D1

D 0

0

88 95 100

100 110 120

Quantity Demanded

Quantity Demanded

(a)

(b)

NOTE: Quantity is in thousands of tons per year.

The ever-rising prices accompanying increasing scarcity of a depletable resource discourage consumption (encourage conservation). Even if quantity demanded grows, it will not grow as much as it would if prices were not rising.

ACTUAL RESOURCE PRICES IN THE TWENTIETH CENTURY

FI GURE 3 Prices of Lead, Zinc, and Copper, 1900–2004, in Real (Inflation-Adjusted) Terms

180 Price per Pound (in Constant 1982 Cents)

SOURCES: U.S. Bureau of the Census, Historical Statistics of the United States, Colonial Times to 1970, Washington, D.C.: 1975; Statistical Abstract of the United States, Washington, D.C.: various issues; U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, http://www.bis.gov; and U.S. Geological Survey, http://www.usgs.gov.

How do the facts match up with this theoretical analysis? Not too well, as we will see now. Figure 3 shows the behavior of the prices of three critical metals—lead, zinc, and copper— since the beginning of the twentieth century. This graph shows the prices of these three resources relative to other prices in the economy (in other words, the real prices, after adjustment for any inflation or deflation that affected the purchasing power of the dollar).

160 140 Copper

120 100 80 Zinc

60 40

Lead

20 0 1900

1910

1920

1930

1940

1950

1960

1970

1980 1990

2004

NOTE: Prices are in constant 1982 cents, as deflated by the producer price index for all commodities.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

372

The Virtues and Limitations of Markets

Part 4

What we find is that instead of rising steadily, as the theory leads us to expect, zinc prices remained amazingly constant, as has the price of lead, even though both minerals are gradually being used up. The price of copper has been all over the map but also has shown no upward trend. Figure 4 shows the real price of crude oil in the United States since 1948 (again, adjusted for inflation). It gives price at the wellhead—that is, at the point of production— with no transportation cost included. Notice how constant these prices were until the first “energy crisis” in 1973, when oil prices rose precipitously. A second and even more dramatic increase occurred in the late 1970s and early 1980s. After that, real oil prices remained well below their “energy crisis” levels, until 2003, when oil prices increased significantly again. In the summer of 2008, oil prices climbed well above $100 a barrel.8 FIGURE 4 90 80

Dollers per Barrel

70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 1948

1958

1968

1978 Year

1988

1998

2008

SOURCE: U.S. Department of Energy, Energy Information Administration, http://tonto.eia.doe.gov/dnav/pet/pet_pri_top.asp.

100

Average Price of Domestic Oil at the Wellhead, 1948–2008

Interferences with Price Patterns How does one explain this strange behavior in the prices of finite resources, which surely are being used up, even if only gradually? Although many things can interfere with price patterns, we will mention only three:

F I GURE 5 Price Effects of a Discovery of Additional Reserves

S1

Price per Ton

D

Before discovery

S2 After discovery

P1 P2 S1 D S2 0 Quantity in Millions of Tons

1. Discoveries of reserves whose existence was previously not suspected. If we were to stumble upon a huge and easily accessible reserve of economite, which came as a complete surprise to the market, the price of this mineral would obviously fall. The discovery of the new reserves leads people to recognize that the supply of economite is much larger than previously thought. A rightward shift of the supply curve (from curve S1S1 to curve S2S2) results, because the suppliers’ cost of any given quantity is reduced by the discovery, so it will pay them to supply a larger quantity at any given price. Like any outward shift in a supply curve, this change can be expected to cause a price decrease (from P1 to P2). A clear historical example was the Spaniards’ sixteenth-century discovery of gold and silver in Mexico and South America, which led to substantial

8 Jad Mouawad, “Oil Prices Take a Nerve-Rattling Jump Past $138,” The New York Times, June 7, 2008, accessed online at: http://www.nytimes.com.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 17

Externalities, the Environment, and Natural Resources

S

Price per Ton

drops in European prices of these precious metals. The same effect can result from innovations that use resources more efficiently. If a new invention doubles the number of miles one can travel on a gallon of gasoline, that is tantamount to doubling the supply of petroleum that still remains in the ground. 2. The invention of new methods of mining or refining that may significantly reduce extraction costs. This development can also lead to a rightward shift in the supply curve, as suppliers become able to deliver a larger quantity at any given price. The situation is therefore again represented by a diagram like Figure 5—only now a reduction in cost, not a new discovery of reserves, shifts the supply curve to the right. (See “Necessity Is FIGURE 6 the Mother of Invention: Innovation Can Increase Controls on the Price of a Resource Resources” below for a real-world example.) 3. Price controls that hold prices down or decrease them. A legislature can pass a law prohibiting the sale of the resource at D a price higher than P* (see Figure 6). Often this strategy doesn’t work; in many cases an illegal black market emerges, where suppliers charge very high prices more or less secretly. But when price controls do work, shortages P usually follow. Because the objective is to make the legal A B P* ceiling price, P*, lower than the market equilibrium price, P, then at price P* quantity demanded (5 million tons in S the figure) will be higher than the free-market level (4 million tons). Similarly, we may expect quantity supplied (2 million tons in the figure) to be less than its free-market level (again, 4 million tons). Thus, as always happens in 0 2 4 5 these cases, quantity supplied is less than quantity deQuantity in Millions of Tons manded, and a shortage results (measured in Figure 6 by the length of AB, or 3 million tons).

373

D

Necessity Is the Mother of Invention: Innovation Can Increase Resources

The U.S. petroleum industry faced a squeeze between competition from low-cost foreign producers and the upward pressure exerted on costs by the depletion of easily accessible domestic reserves. Under these conditions, it was imperative to develop techniques that would allow exploitation of known reserves at competitive costs. Initial extraction had removed as little as 30 percent of the oil in some abandoned reservoirs. This was largely because traditional vertical drilling methods limited the amount of oil that could be economically removed from reserves with complex structures. With the development of horizontal drilling, it became possible to approach a reservoir from any angle and thus to drain it more thoroughly.

SOURCE: © AP Images

One study of technological innovation in natural resource industries describes how economic necessity compels firms to search hard for ways to extract resources more efficiently, thereby increasing the available supply:

SOURCE: R. David Simpson, ed., Productivity in Natural Resource Industries: Improvement Through Innovation, Washington, D.C.: Resources for the Future, 1999, pp. 17–18.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

374

Part 4

The Virtues and Limitations of Markets

Many economists believe that this is exactly what happened after 1971 when President Nixon decided to experiment with price controls. It was then that the economy experienced a plague of shortages, and we seemed to be “running out of nearly everything.” After price controls ended in 1974, most of the shortages disappeared. We can explain each of our examples of minerals whose price did not rise by one or more of these influences. For example, copper and zinc have benefited from technological changes that lowered their extraction costs. In addition, the development of direct electroplating techniques has made copper production much more efficient. In the case of lead, new mines in Missouri held abundant quantities of ore that were much easier to extract and much cheaper to refine than what had been available before. Obviously, real events are more complex than a naïve reading of theoretical models might lead us to believe.

Is Price Interference Justified? Despite these influences, if a resource does become scarce and costly to obtain, its price must ultimately rise unless government interferes. Moreover: In a free market, quantity demanded can never exceed quantity supplied, even if a finite resource is undergoing rapid depletion. The reason is simple: In any free market, price will automatically adjust to eliminate any difference between quantity supplied and quantity demanded. In theory, any shortage—any excess of quantity demanded over quantity supplied— must be artificial, ascribable to a decision to prevent the price mechanism from doing its job.

To say that the cause is artificial, of course, does not settle the basic issue—whether freedom of price adjustments is desirable when resources are scarce, or whether interference with the pricing process is justified. Many economists believe that this is a case in which the disease—shortages and their resulting economic problems—is far worse than the cure—deregulation of prices. They hold that the general public is misguided in regarding these price rises as the problem, when in fact they are part of the (admittedly rather painful) cure. It is, of course, easy to understand why no consumer loves a price rise. It is also easy to understand why many consumers attribute any such price increase to a conspiracy by greedy suppliers who somehow deliberately arrange for shortages to force prices upward. Sometimes, this view is even correct. For example, the members of the Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC) have openly and frankly tried to influence the flow of oil in order to increase its price—and have often succeeded. But it is important to recognize from the principles of supply and demand that when a resource grows scarce, its price will tend to rise automatically, even without any conspiracies or plots.

On the Virtues of Rising Prices Rising prices help to control resource depletion in three basic ways: • They discourage consumption and waste and provide an inducement for conservation. • They stimulate more efficient resource use by industry, providing incentives for employment of processes that are more sparing in their use of the resource or that use substitute resources. • They encourage innovation—the discovery of other, more abundant resources that can serve the same role and of new techniques that permit these other resources to be used economically.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Externalities, the Environment, and Natural Resources

Chapter 17

PUZZLE REVISITED:

375

GROWING RESERVES OF EXHAUSTIBLE NATURAL RESOURCES

Earlier we saw, strangely enough, that reserves of many mineral resources have actually been increasing, despite growing world production that uses these resources. This paradox has a straightforward economic explanation: Rising mineral reserves are a tribute to the success of pricing and exploration activity. Minerals are not discovered by accident. Rather, exploration and discovery entail costly work requiring geologists, engineers, and expensive machinery. Industry does not consider this money worth spending when reserves are high and mineral prices are low. In the twentieth century, every time some mineral’s known reserves fell and its price tended to rise, exploration increased until the decline was offset. The law of supply and demand worked. In the 1970s, for example, the rising price of oil led to very substantial increases in oil exploration, which helped to build up reserves. Although, to protect ourselves from OPEC, it may not be wise for us to consume more oil from American sources, it certainly does seem prudent for us to increase our reserves through exploration. Increased profitability of exploration is perhaps the most effective way to achieve that goal.

| SUMMARY | 1. Pollution is as old as human history. Contrary to popular notions, some forms of pollution were actually decreasing even before government programs were initiated to protect the environment. 2. Both planned and market economies suffer from substantial environmental problems. 3. The production of commodities must cause waste disposal problems unless everything is recycled, but even recycling processes cause pollution (and use up energy). 4. Industrial activity causes environmental damage, but so does the activity of private individuals (as when people drive cars that emit pollutants). Government agencies also damage the environment (as when military airplanes emit noise and exhaust fumes or a hydroelectric project floods large areas). 5. Pollution is an externality—when a factory emits smoke, it dirties the air in nearby neighborhoods and may damage the health of persons who neither work for the factory nor buy its products. Hence, the public interest in pollution control is not best served by the free market. This conclusion is another of our Ideas for Beyond the Final Exam. 6. Pollution can be controlled by voluntary programs, direct controls, pollution charges (taxes on emissions), or other monetary incentives for emissions reduction.

7. Most economists believe that the monetary incentives approach is the most efficient and effective way to control damaging externalities. 8. The quantity demanded of a scarce resource can exceed the quantity supplied only if something prevents the market mechanism from operating freely. 9. As a resource grows scarce on a free market, its price will rise, inducing increased conservation by consumers, increased exploration for new reserves, and increased substitution of other items that can serve the same purpose. 10. In the twentieth century, the relative prices of many resources remained roughly constant, largely because of the discovery of new reserves and cost-saving innovations. 11. In the 1970s, OPEC succeeded in raising petroleum’s relative price, but the price increase led to a substantial decline in world demand as well as to an increase in production in countries outside OPEC. 12. Known reserves of depletable scarce resources have not tended to fall with time, because as the price of the resource rises with increasing scarcity, increased exploration for new reserves becomes profitable.

| KEY TERMS | direct controls

364

emissions permits

366

externality

356

pollution charges (taxes on emissions) 364

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

376

Part 4

The Virtues and Limitations of Markets

| TEST YOURSELF | 1. Production of Commodity X creates 10 pounds of emissions for every unit of X produced. The demand and supply curves for X are described by the following table:

Price $10 9 8 7 6 5

Quantity Demanded 80 85 90 95 100 105

Quantity Supplied 100 95 90 85 80 75

2. Using the data in Test Yourself Question 1, if the price of X to consumers is $9, and the government imposes a tax of $2 per unit, show that because suppliers get only $7, they will produce only 85 units of output, not the 95 units of output they would produce if they received the full $9 per unit. 3. With the tax described in Test Yourself Question 2, how much pollution will be emitted? 4. Compare your answers to Test Yourself Questions 1 and 3 and show how large a reduction in pollution emissions occurs because of the $2 tax on the polluting output.

What is the equilibrium price and quantity, and how much pollution will be emitted?

| DISCUSSION QUESTIONS | 1. What sorts of pollution problems would you expect in a small African village? In a city in India? In the People’s Republic of China? In New York City?

What information will you need to collect before determining what you would do about each of the preceding provisions?

2. Suppose you are assigned the task of drafting a law to impose a tax on smoke emissions. What provisions would you put into the law?

3. Discuss some valid and some invalid objections to letting rising prices eliminate shortages of supplies of scarce resources.

a. How would you decide the size of the tax? b. What would you do about smoke emitted by a municipal electricity plant? c. Would you use the same tax rate in densely and sparsely settled areas?

4. Why may an increase in fuel prices lead to more conservation after several years have passed than it does in the months following the price increase? What does your answer imply about the relative sizes of the long-run and short-run elasticity of demand for fuel?

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Taxation and Resource Allocation The taxing power of the government must be used to provide revenues for legitimate government purposes. It must not be used to regulate the economy or bring about social change. RONAL D RE AGA N

N



othing is certain but death and taxes,” proclaims an old adage. In recent decades, American politics seems to have turned this aphorism on its head. It seems that the surest route to political death is to raise taxes—and the surest route to winning elections is to cut them. Tax-cutting fever first swept the nation during the presidency of Ronald Reagan, who won two landslide elections. After pledging not to raise taxes, President George Bush (the first) agreed to some small tax increases in 1990—a decision that some think cost him the 1992 election. Next came President Bill Clinton, who made income-tax increases for upper-income taxpayers a major component of his deficit-reduction plan in 1993. The next year, the Democrats were annihilated at the polls by a Republican party pledging to cut taxes. Clinton won reelection in 1996 anyway. But President George Bush (the second) defeated Al Gore in 2000 partly on the basis of his promise to cut taxes, and then won reelection in 2004 partly because John Kerry, like Clinton, proposed to repeal part of the Bush tax cuts. During the 2008 campaign, whether or not to extend the Bush tax cuts was a hot political issue once again. The Democratic candidate, Barack Obama, pledged to roll back some of the tax cuts, but Republican John McCain campaigned not only on extending the Bush tax cuts, but on adding still more. As this book goes to press, it appears that President Obama and the Democratically-controlled congress will let many of the Bush tax cuts expire at the end of 2010, but no one knows for sure. Antitax sentiment is nothing new in the United States, a country that was born partly out of a tax revolt. But taxes are inevitable in any modern, mixed economy. Although the vast majority of economic activities in the United States are left to the private sector, some—such as provision of national defense and highways—are reserved for the government. And any such government spending requires tax revenues to pay the bills. So do transfer programs such as Social Security and unemployment insurance. In addition, the government sometimes uses the tax system to promote some social goal. For example, we learned in the previous chapter that policy makers can use taxes to correct misallocations of resources caused by externalities, including those that contribute to global climate change.

C O N T E N T S ISSUE: SHOULD THE BUSH TAX CUTS BE (PARTLY)

THE STATE AND LOCAL TAX SYSTEM

THE LEVEL AND TYPES OF TAXATION

Sales and Excise Taxes Property Taxes Fiscal Federalism

REPEALED?

Progressive, Proportional, and Regressive Taxes Direct versus Indirect Taxes

THE FEDERAL TAX SYSTEM The Federal Personal Income Tax The Payroll Tax The Corporate Income Tax Excise Taxes The Payroll Tax and the Social Security System

THE CONCEPT OF EQUITY IN TAXATION Horizontal Equity Vertical Equity The Benefits Principle

THE CONCEPT OF EFFICIENCY IN TAXATION

SHIFTING THE TAX BURDEN: TAX INCIDENCE The Incidence of Excise Taxes The Incidence of the Payroll Tax

WHEN TAXATION CAN IMPROVE EFFICIENCY EQUITY, EFFICIENCY, AND THE OPTIMAL TAX ISSUE REVISITED: THE PROS AND CONS OF

REPEALING THE BUSH TAX CUTS

Tax Loopholes and Excess Burden

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

378

Part 4

The Virtues and Limitations of Markets

This chapter discusses the types of taxes that are used to raise what President Reagan called “revenues for legitimate government purposes,” the effects of taxes on resource allocation and income distribution, and the principles that distinguish “good” taxes from “bad” ones.

ISSUE:

SHOULD THE BUSH TAX CUTS BE (PARTLY) REPEALED?

President George W. Bush was one of the biggest tax cutters in U.S. history. He proposed, and Congress passed, tax cuts in 2001, 2002, and 2003. These bills reduced personal income-tax rates substantially, phased out the estate tax, and created a preferentially low tax rate on dividends—among other things. However, the legislation made most of the tax cuts temporary (with different “sunset” years), so they will expire in 2010 unless Congress explicitly reenacts them. Probably for that reason, repeal or extension of the Bush tax cuts became an issue in the 2008 presidential campaign and still is. The Bush tax cuts have been controversial since their inception. Supporters, including most Republicans, credit them with the economy’s rapid growth in 2003 and 2004 and argue that they should be made permanent. Critics, including most Democrats, blame the tax cuts for ballooning the federal budget deficit and suggest that the tax cuts for upper-income households should be repealed because the nation cannot afford them. In this chapter, you will learn the principles by which tax systems are judged. Then we will apply those principles to appraising the Bush tax cuts.

THE LEVEL AND TYPES OF TAXATION Many Americans believe that taxes have been gobbling up an ever-increasing share of the U.S. economy. Figure 1, however, shows that this supposition is not true. By charting the behavior of both federal and state and local taxes as a percentage of gross domestic product (GDP) since 1929, we see that the share of federal taxes in GDP was rather steady from the early 1950s until around 2000. It climbed from less than 4 percent in 1929 to 20 percent during World War II, fell back to 15 percent in the immediate postwar period, and fluctuated mainly in the 18 to 21 percent range until the Bush tax cuts pushed it down below 17 percent. More recently, it has rebounded back into the 18–19 percent range. The share of GDP taken by state and local taxes climbed substantially from World War II until the early 1970s. But since then it, too, has remained remarkably stable—at about 10 to 11 percent. Whether these shares are too high or too low is a matter of some debate. In any event, The shares of GDP taken in taxes by the federal, state, and local governments have been approximately constant for about 40 years.

Americans have always felt that taxes are both too many and too high. Sometimes it seems that the tax collector is everywhere. We have income and payroll taxes deducted from our paychecks, sales taxes added to our purchases, and property taxes levied on our homes. We pay gasoline taxes, liquor taxes, cigarette taxes, and telephone taxes. Not surprisingly, tax cuts are more popular politically than are tax increases. Yet, as we noted in Chapter 2, by international standards Americans are among the most lightly taxed people in the world. (See Figure 13 of Chapter 2, on page 35.)

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

379

Taxation and Resource Allocation

Chapter 18

FIGURE 1

22 20 18 Percentage of GDP

SOURCE: Economic Report of the President, 2008 (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office; 2008).

Taxes as a Percentage of Gross Domestic Product

Federal government

16 14 12 10

State and local government

8 6 4 2 0

1930 1935 1940 1945 1950 1955 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2008

Progressive, Proportional, and Regressive Taxes Economists classify taxes as progressive, proportional, or regressive. Under a progressive tax like the personal income tax, the fraction of income paid in taxes rises as a person’s income increases. Under a proportional tax like the payroll tax, this fraction is constant. Under a regressive tax like the notorious head tax, which charges every person the same amount, the fraction of income paid to the tax collector declines as income rises.1 Because the fraction of income paid in taxes is called the average tax rate, we can reformulate these definitions as they appear in the margin. Often, however, the average tax rate is less interesting than the marginal tax rate, which is the fraction of each additional dollar that is paid to the tax collector. The reason, as we will see, is that the marginal tax rate, not the average tax rate, most directly affects economic incentives. Those who advocate tax cuts emphasize the virtues of low marginal rates.

Direct versus Indirect Taxes Another way to classify taxes is to categorize them as either direct taxes or indirect taxes. Direct taxes are levied directly on people; primary examples are income taxes and estate taxes. In contrast, indirect taxes are levied on particular activities, such as buying cigarettes, gasoline, or using the telephone. But, of course, people ultimately pay them—hence the name, “indirect” taxes. The federal government raises revenues mainly by direct taxes, whereas states and localities rely more heavily on indirect taxes. Sales taxes and property taxes are the most important indirect taxes in the United States, although many other countries, including the members of the European Union (EU), rely heavily on the value-added tax (VAT)—a tax that has often been discussed, but never adopted, in the United States.

A progressive tax is one in which the average tax rate paid by an individual rises as income rises. A proportional tax is one in which the average tax rate is the same at all income levels. A regressive tax is one in which the average tax rate falls as income rises. The average tax rate is the ratio of taxes to income. The marginal tax rate is the fraction of each additional dollar of income that is paid in taxes. Direct taxes are taxes levied directly on people. Indirect taxes are taxes levied on specific economic activities.

THE FEDERAL TAX SYSTEM The personal income tax is the biggest source of revenue to the federal government. Few people realize that the payroll tax—a tax levied on wages and salaries up to a certain limit 1

In 1990, Prime Minister Margaret Thatcher caused riots in the United Kingdom by instituting a head tax.

The personal income tax is a tax levied on the income of an individual or a family, typically with a progressive rate structure.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

380

Part 4

The Virtues and Limitations of Markets

Payroll taxes (Social Security contributions) 41.7%

Excise taxes 3.1% Corporate income taxes 6.8%

Individual income taxes 44.2%

SOURCE: Office of Management and Budget. Summary Tables http://www.whitehouse.gov/omb/budget/overview/

All other 4.2%

and paid by employers and employees—is the next biggest source. Furthermore, payroll taxes have been growing more rapidly than income taxes for decades. In 1960, payroll tax collections were just 36 percent as large as personal income-tax collections; in the recessionary economy of 2009, this figure reached almost 95 percent. In fact, most Americans today pay more in payroll taxes than they do in income taxes. The rest of the federal government’s revenues come mostly from the corporate income tax and from various excise (sales) taxes. Figure 2 shows the breakdown of federal revenues for the fiscal year 2009 budget. Let us now look at these taxes in more detail.

The Federal Personal Income Tax

The tax on individual incomes traces its origins to the Sixteenth Amendment to the U.S. Constitution in 1913, but it remained inconsequential until Sources of Federal the beginning of World War II. Washington then raised the tax substantially to Revenue finance the war, and it has been the major source of federal revenue ever since. Many taxpayers have little or no additional tax to pay when the April 15 day of reckoning comes around, because employers withhold income taxes from payrolls and forward those funds to the U.S. Treasury. In fact, many taxpayers are “overwithheld” during the year and receive refund checks from Uncle Sam. Nevertheless, most taxpayers (including the authors of this book!) dread the arrival of their Form 1040 because of its legendary complexity. The personal income tax is progressive. That fact is evident in Table 1, which shows that average tax rates rise as income rises. Ignoring a few complications, the current tax law has six basic marginal rates, each of which applies within a specific tax bracket. As income rises above certain points, the marginal tax rate increases from 10 percent to 15 percent, then to 25 percent, 28 percent, and then finally to 33 percent and 35 percent on very high incomes (more than TAB LE 1 about $370,000 of taxable income for a married couple). Federal Personal Income Tax Rates in 2008 Actually, the income tax is less progressive than it seems because for a Married Couple Filing Jointly of a variety of tax loopholes. Let us examine a few major ones. SOURCE: © The New Yorker Collection 1986, Mick Stevens From cartoonbank.com. All Rights Reserved.

F I GURE 2

Taxable Income $ 10,000 25,000 50,000 100,000 150,000 250,000 1,000,000

Tax $ 1,000 2,919 6,669 17,375 30,264 60,322 320,363

A tax loophole is a special provision in the tax code that reduces taxation below normal rates (perhaps to zero) if certain conditions are met. A particular source of income is tax exempt if income from that source is not taxable. A tax deduction is a sum of money that may be subtracted before the taxpayer computes taxable income.

Average Tax Rate

Marginal Tax Rate

10.0% 11.7 13.3 17.4 20.2 24.1 32.0

10.0% 15.0 15.0 25.0 28.0 33.0 35.0

Tax-Exempt Status of Municipal Bond Interest To help state and local governments and certain public authorities raise funds, Congress has made interest on their bonds tax exempt under the federal income tax. Whether or not it was Congress’s intent, this provision has turned out to be one of the biggest loopholes for the very rich, who invest much of their wealth in tax-free municipal bonds. Such tax-conscious investing has long been the principal reason why some multimillionaires pay so little income tax.

Tax Benefits for Homeowners Among the sacred cows of the U.S. income-tax system is the deductibility of payments that homeowners make for mortgage interest and property taxes. These tax deductions substantially reduce homeowners’ tax bills and give them preferential treatment compared to renters. Clearly, Congress’s intent is to encourage home ownership. However, because homeowners are, on the average, richer than renters, this loophole also erodes the progressivity of the income tax. Why call this a “loophole,” when other interest expenses and taxes (such as those paid by shopkeepers, for example) are considered legitimate deductions? The answer is that, unlike shopkeepers, homeowners do not pay taxes on the income they earn by incurring these expenses. The reason is that the “income” from owning a home accrues not in cash, but in the form of living rent-free. An example will illustrate the point. Jack and Jill are neighbors. Each earns $60,000 per year and lives in a $200,000 house. The difference is that Jack owns his home, whereas Jill rents. Most observers would agree that Jack and Jill should pay the same income tax. Will they? Suppose Jack pays $4,000 per year in local property taxes and has a $160,000

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 18

381

Taxation and Resource Allocation

mortgage at an 8 percent interest rate, which costs him $12,800 per year in interest. Both property taxes and mortgage interest are tax deductible, so he gets to deduct $16,800 in housing expenses, but Jill, who may pay $16,800 per year in rent, does not. Thus, Jill’s tax burden is higher than Jack’s. We could go on listing more tax loopholes, but enough has been said to illustrate the main point: Every tax loophole encourages particular patterns of behavior and favors particular types of people. Furthermore, because most loopholes mainly benefit the rich, they erode the progressivity of the income tax.

The Payroll Tax The second most important tax in the United States is the payroll tax, the proceeds of which are earmarked to be paid into various “trust funds.” These funds, in turn, are used mainly to pay for Social Security, Medicare, and unemployment benefits. The payroll tax is levied at a fixed percentage rate (now about 16 percent), shared about equally between employees and employers. For example, a firm paying an employee a gross monthly wage of $5,000 will deduct $400 (8 percent of $5,000) from that worker’s check, add an additional $400 of its own funds, and send the $800 to the government. On the surface, this tax seems to be proportional, but it is actually highly regressive, for two reasons. First, only wages and salaries are subject to the tax; interest and dividends are not. Second, because Social Security benefits are subject to upper limits, earnings above a certain level (which changes each year) are exempt from the Social Security tax. In 2009, this level was $106,800 per year. Above this limit, the marginal payroll tax rate is zero.2

The payroll tax is a tax levied on the earnings from work. In the United States, the tax starts at the first dollar earned and ends at an upper limit that increases each year.

The Corporate Income Tax

The corporate income tax is a tax levied on the profits of corporations, after all expenditures on wages, interest, rent, and purchases of other inputs are deducted.

The tax on corporate profits is also considered a “direct” tax, because corporations are fictitious “people” in the eyes of the law. All large corporations currently pay a basic marginal tax rate of 35 percent. (Firms with smaller profits pay a lower rate.) Because the tax applies only to profits—not to income—all wages, rents, and interest paid by corporations are deducted before the tax is applied. Since World War II, corporate income-tax collections have accounted for a declining share of federal revenue. But the low corporate profits of recent years shrank this share to under 7 percent in 2009.

Excise Taxes An excise tax is a sales tax on the purchase of a particular good or service. Although sales taxes are mainly reserved for state and local governments in the United States, the federal government does levy excise taxes on a hodgepodge of miscellaneous goods and services, including cigarettes, alcoholic beverages, gasoline, and tires. Although these taxes constitute a minor source of federal government revenue, raising revenue is not their only goal. Some taxes seek to discourage consumption of a good by raising its price. For example, there are steep excise taxes on cigarettes and alcoholic beverages, but their main purpose is not to raise revenue. The clear intent is to discourage smoking and drinking.

An excise tax is a tax levied on the purchase of some specific good or service.

The Payroll Tax and the Social Security System In government statistical documents, payroll taxes are euphemistically called “contributions for social insurance,” although these “contributions” are far from voluntary. The term signifies the fact that, unlike other taxes, the proceeds from this particular tax are set aside in “trust funds” to pay benefits to Social Security recipients and others.

2

The Social Security System raises funds from the payroll tax and pays Social Security benefits to retirees.

However, the portion of the payroll tax that pays for Medicare is applied to all earnings, without limit.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

382

Part 4

The Virtues and Limitations of Markets

P O L I C Y DEB AT E According to the government’s long-range projections, Social Security benefits that have already been promised exceed expected future payroll tax receipts by a wide margin. Thus, although Social Security faces no immediate financial problem, something must be done eventually to put the system on a sound financial footing. You don’t have to be an actuary to see that some combination of higher payroll taxes (or some other revenue source) and lower Social Security benefits will be needed to do the job. But both alternatives are politically unpalatable. This dilemma led President Bush to suggest another way out: privatizing part of the Social Security System. What does that mean? Simply that some portion of current payroll taxes would be diverted away from the Social Security trust fund and directed into private investment

SOURCE: © AP Images

Privatizing Social Security accounts, owned and controlled by individual workers. The idea is that these private accounts would earn higher returns than the Social Security trust fund, which invests all of its money in U.S. government bonds. If so, the private accounts would grow rapidly, relieving the trust fund of some of the burden of paying future benefits. But critics worry that many individuals would not be wise investors. After his reelection in 2004, President Bush presented his own specific privatization plan and began to press for it. But Congress would have none of it, even though it was then dominated by Republicans. In the 2008 campaign, most Democrats made a point of opposing privatization, and few Republicans supported it with any vigor. It looks like Social Security privatization is dead for now.

The standard notion of a trust fund does not apply. Some private pension plans are trust funds. You pay money into them while you are working, the trustees invest those savings for you, and you withdraw it bit by bit in your retirement years. The Social Security system does not function that way. For most of its history, the system has simply taken the payroll tax payments of current workers and handed them over to current retirees. The benefit checks that your grandparents receive each month are not, in any real sense, dividends on the investments they made while they worked. Instead, these checks are paid out of the payroll taxes that your parents (or you) pay each month. For many years, this “pay-as-you-go” system managed to give every generation of retirees more in benefits than it had contributed in payroll taxes. Social Security “contributions” were, indeed, a good investment. How was this miracle achieved? It relied heavily on growth—both population growth and wage growth. As long as the population grows, there are more and more young people to tax. Similarly, as long as real wages keep rising, the same payroll tax rates permit the government to pay benefits to each generation in excess of that generation’s contributions. Ten percent of today’s average real wage, after all, is a good deal more than 10 percent of the real wages your grandfather earned 50 years ago. Unfortunately, the growth magic stopped working in the 1970s, for several reasons. First, growth in real wages slowed dramatically, while Social Security benefits continued to grow rapidly. As a result, the burden of financing Social Security grew more onerous. Second, population growth slowed significantly in the United States. Birthrates in this country were very high from the close of World War II until about 1960 (the postwar baby boom) and fell thereafter. As a result, the fraction of the U.S. population that is older than age 65 has climbed from only 7.5 percent in 1945 to over 12.5 percent today, and it is certain to go much higher in the coming decades as baby boomers retire. Thus, there are fewer working people available to support each retired person. Third, life expectancy keeps rising while the average retirement age keeps falling. These facts are undoubtedly good news for Americans, but they are bad news for the financial health of the Social Security system. The reason is simple: As people live longer

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 18

383

Taxation and Resource Allocation

and retire younger, they spend more and more years in retirement. When Congress set the normal Social Security retirement age at 65, many Americans did not live that long. Nowadays most do, and many live 20 years or more beyond retirement. With the growth magic over and the long-run funding of Social Security clearly at risk in 1983, Congress trimmed Social Security benefits (mainly by raising the normal retirement age to 67 in stages) and increased payroll taxes to shore up the system’s finances. Furthermore, Social Security abandoned its tradition of pay-as-you-go financing. Congress decided instead to start accumulating funds in advance so that the Social Security Administration would be able to pay the baby boomers’ retirement benefits. Since then, the trust fund has taken in more money than it has paid out. The Social Security surplus is now running at about $180 billion per year. If current projections of population, real wages, and retirement behavior prove reasonably accurate, these annual surpluses will accumulate into a huge trust fund balance in a few more years and then start to be drawn down. Unfortunately, the long-run funding problem has not been solved, for those same projections show the trust fund running out of money by about 2037. It is therefore clear that some combination of lower Social Security benefits and higher payroll taxes looms on the long-run horizon, unless some way is found to inject more money into the system. (See the box “Privatizing Social Security” on the previous page.)

THE STATE AND LOCAL TAX SYSTEM

Sales and Excise Taxes These days, all but five states, many large cities, and a few counties levy broad-based sales taxes on purchases of goods and services, with certain specific exemptions. For example, food is exempted from sales tax in many states. Overall sales tax rates typically run in the 5 to 8 percent range. In addition, most states impose special excise taxes on such things as tobacco products, liquor, gasoline, and luxury items.

Property Taxes

SOURCE: Economic Report of the President, 2008 (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office; 2008).

Indirect taxes are the backbone of state and local government revenues, although most states also levy income taxes. Sales taxes are the principal source of revenue to the states, whereas cities and towns rely heavily on property taxes. Figure 3 shows the breakdown of state and local government receipts by source.

FI GURE 3 Sources of State and Local Revenue From federal government 22.5% Income taxes (personal and corporate) 13.2%

All other 28.4%

Property taxes 16.8%

Municipalities raise revenue by taxing properties, such as houses and office buildings. Educational and religious institutions are normally exempt from these property tax levies. The usual procedure is to assess each taxable property based on its market value and then to place a tax rate on the community’s total assessed value that yields enough revenue to cover expenditures on local services. Property taxes generally run between 1 and 3 percent of true market value. Considerable political controversy has surrounded the property tax for years. Because local property taxes provide the main source of financing for public schools, wealthy communities with expensive real estate are able to afford higher-quality schools than poor communities. A simple arithmetical example will clarify why. Suppose real estate holdings in Richtown average $300,000 per family, whereas real estate holdings in Poortown average only $100,000 per family. If both towns levy a 2 percent property tax to pay for their schools, Richtown will generate $6,000 per family in tax receipts, but Poortown will generate only $2,000. Glaring inequalities like this have led courts in many states to declare unconstitutional the financing of public schools by local property taxes, because doing so deprives children in poorer districts of an equal opportunity to receive high-quality education. These legal

Sales and gross receipts taxes 19.1%

The property tax is levied on the assessed values of taxable properties, such as houses and office buildings.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

384

Part 4

The Virtues and Limitations of Markets

decisions, in turn, have created considerable political turmoil as state legislatures scrambled to find ways to fund their schools while complying with court rulings. Many states have been grappling with this problem for years.

Fiscal Federalism

Fiscal federalism refers to the system of grants from one level of government to the next.

Figure 3 points out an interesting fact: Grants from the federal government are a major source of revenue to state and local governments. In addition, grants from the states are vital to local governments. This system of transfers from one level of government to the next, which has a long history, is referred to as fiscal federalism. Aid from this source has come traditionally in the form of restricted grants—that is, money given from one level of government to the next on the condition that it be spent for a specific purpose. For example, the U.S. government may grant funds to a state if that state promises to use the money to build highways. Alternatively a state government may give money to a school district to spend on a specific educational program. The system of grants from the federal government to the states has often been the subject of political controversy. Supporters of large grants see state governments as more flexible and closer to the people. They also view the states as “laboratories of democracy,” where creative solutions to make government more efficient can be developed. Critics of grant programs argue that the history of state governments gives little reason to see them as efficient providers of public services. These people worry that minimum national standards in welfare and health care might be sacrificed as states husband their limited financial resources.

THE CONCEPT OF EQUITY IN TAXATION Taxes are judged on two criteria: equity (Is the tax fair?) and efficiency (Does the tax interfere with the workings of the market economy?). Although economists are mostly concerned with the second criterion, public discussions about tax proposals focus almost exclusively on the first. Let us, therefore, begin our discussion by investigating the concept of equitable taxation.

Horizontal Equity Horizontal equity is the notion that equally situated individuals should be taxed equally.

Vertical equity refers to the notion that differently situated individuals should be taxed differently in a way that society deems to be fair. The ability-to-pay principle of taxation refers to the idea that people with greater ability to pay taxes should pay higher taxes.

There are three distinct concepts of tax equity. The first, horizontal equity, simply asserts that equally situated individuals should be taxed equally. Few would quarrel with this principle. Because it is often difficult to apply in practice, violations of horizontal equity can be found throughout the tax code. Consider, for example, the personal income tax. Horizontal equity calls for two families with the same income to pay the same tax. But what if one family has eight children and the other has none? Well, you answer, we must define “equally situated” to include equal family sizes, so only families with the same number of children can be compared on grounds of horizontal equity. But what if one family has unusually high medical expenses and the other has none? Are they still “equally situated”? By now, the point should be clear: Determining when two families are equally situated is no simple task. In fact, the U.S. tax code contains literally scores of requirements that must be met before two families are construed as equal.

Vertical Equity The second concept of fair taxation seems to flow naturally from the first. If equals are to be treated equally, it appears that unequals should be treated unequally. This precept is known as vertical equity. Just saying this does not get us very far, however, because vertical equity is a slippery concept. Often it is translated into the ability-to-pay principle, which states that those

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 18

385

Taxation and Resource Allocation

most able to pay should pay the highest taxes. Unfortunately, this principle still leaves a definitional problem similar to the problem of defining “equally situated”: How do we measure ability to pay? The nature of each tax often provides a straightforward answer. In income taxation, we measure ability to pay by income; in property taxation, we measure it by property value; and so on. But an even thornier problem arises TABLE 2 when we try to translate this concept into Three Alternative Income-Tax Plans concrete terms. Consider the three alternaPlan 1 Plan 2 tive income-tax plans listed in Table 2. Average Average Families with higher incomes pay higher Income Tax Tax Rate Tax Tax Rate taxes under all three plans, so each plan can claim to follow the ability-to-pay prin$10,000 $ 300 3% $1,000 10% 50,000 8,000 16 5,000 10 ciple. Yet the three have radically different 250,000 70,000 28 25,000 10 distributive consequences. Plan 1 is a progressive tax, like the individual income tax in the United States: The average tax rate is higher for richer families. Plan 2 is a proportional tax: Every family pays 10 percent of its income. Plan 3 is regressive: Because tax payments rise more slowly than income, the average tax rate for richer families is lower than that for poorer families. Which plan comes closest to the ideal notion of vertical equity? Many people find that Plan 3, the regressive tax, offends their sense of fairness. People agree much less over the relative merits of progressive versus proportional taxes. Some people take the notion of vertical equity to be synonymous with progressivity. Other things being equal, progressive taxes are seen as “good” taxes in some ethical sense, whereas regressive taxes are seen as “bad.” On these grounds, advocates of greater equality support progressive income taxes and oppose regressive sales taxes. But other people disagree and find proportional taxes to be “fair.”

Plan 3 Tax

Average Tax Rate

$1,000 3,000 7,500

10% 6 3

The Benefits Principle Whereas the principles of horizontal and vertical equity, for all their ambiguities and practical problems, at least do not conflict with one another, the final principle of fair taxation often violates commonly accepted notions of vertical equity. According to the benefits principle of taxation, those who reap the benefits from government services should pay the taxes. The benefits principle is often used to justify earmarking the proceeds from certain taxes for specific public services. For example, receipts from gasoline taxes typically go to finance construction and maintenance of roads. Thus, those who use the roads pay the taxes—and roughly in proportion to their usage. Most people seem to find this system fair. But in other contexts—such as public schools and hospitals—the body politic has been loath to apply the benefits principle because it clashes so dramatically with common notions of fairness. (Should sick people pay for public hospitals?) So most public services are financed out of general tax revenues rather than by direct charges for their use.

The benefits principle of taxation holds that people who derive benefits from a service should pay the taxes that finance it.

THE CONCEPT OF EFFICIENCY IN TAXATION Economic efficiency is among the most central concepts of economics. The economy is said to be efficient if it has used every available opportunity to make someone better off without making anyone else worse off. In this sense, taxes almost always introduce inefficiencies. That is, if the tax were removed, some people could be made better off without anyone being harmed. However, that is not a terribly pertinent comparison. The government does, after all, need revenue to pay for the services it provides. So, when economists discuss the notion of “efficient” taxation, they are usually seeking taxes that cause the least amount of inefficiency for a given amount of tax revenue. Or, in the more colorful words of Jean-Baptiste Colbert, treasurer to King Louis IV of France, “The art of taxation consists in so plucking the goose to obtain the largest amount of feathers, with the least possible amount of hissing.”

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

386

Part 4

The Virtues and Limitations of Markets

The burden of a tax to an individual is the amount one would have to be given to be just as well off with the tax as without it.

To explain the concept of efficient taxation, we need to introduce a new term. Economists define the burden of a tax as the amount the taxpayer would have to be given to be just as well off in the presence of the tax as in its absence. An example will clarify this notion and also make clear why: The burden of a tax normally exceeds the revenue raised by the tax.

Suppose the government, in the interest of energy conservation, levies a high tax on the biggest gas-guzzling cars, with progressively lower taxes on smaller cars.3 For example, a simple tax schedule might be the following: Car Type Hummer Chrysler 300 Toyota Prius

Tax $1,000 500 0

Harry has a taste for big SUVs and has recently been buying Hummers. Once the new tax takes effect, he has three options: He can still buy a Hummer and pay $1,000 in tax; he can switch to a Chrysler 300 and avoid half the tax; or he can switch to the hybrid Toyota Prius and avoid the entire tax. If Harry sticks with the Hummer, we have a case in which the burden of the tax is exactly equal to the tax he pays. Why? Because if someone gave Harry $1,000, he would be in exactly the same position as he was before the tax was enacted. In general: When a tax induces no change in economic behavior, the burden of the tax is measured accurately by the revenue collected.

The excess burden of a tax to an individual is the amount by which the burden of the tax exceeds the tax that is paid.

However, this result is not what we normally expect to happen, and it is certainly not what the government intends by levying a tax on gas-guzzling vehicles. Normally, we expect taxes to induce some people to alter their behavior in ways that reduce or avoid tax payments. So let us look into Harry’s other two options. If Harry decides to purchase a Chrysler, he pays only $500 in tax, but that $500 understates his burden. If we give Harry $500, his tax bill will be covered, but he will still be chagrined by the fact that he no longer drives a Hummer. How much money would it take to make Harry just as well off as he was before the tax? Only Harry knows for sure, but we do know that it is more than the $500 tax that he pays. Whatever that (unknown) amount is, the amount by which it exceeds the $500 tax bill is called the excess burden of the tax. Harry’s final option makes the importance of understanding excess burden even more clear. If he switches to a Prius, Harry will pay no tax. Are we therefore to say he has suffered no burden? Clearly not, for he longs for the Hummer that he no longer drives. The general principle is Whenever a tax induces people to change their behavior—that is, whenever it “distorts” their choices—the tax has an excess burden. In such a case, the revenue collected systematically understates the true burden of the tax.

The excess burdens that arise from tax-induced changes in economic behavior are precisely the inefficiencies we noted at the outset of this section. The basic precept of efficient taxation is to try to devise a tax system that minimizes these inefficiencies. In particular: In comparing two taxes that raise the same total revenue, the one that produces less excess burden is the more efficient.

Notice the proviso that the two taxes being compared must yield the same revenue. We are really interested in the total burden of each tax. Because Total burden 5 Tax collections 1 Excess burden

3

A tax like the one described here has been in effect since 1984.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 18

387

Taxation and Resource Allocation

we can unambiguously state that the tax with less excess burden is more efficient only when tax collections are equal. Excess burdens arise when consumers and firms alter their behavior on account of taxation. This precept of sound tax policy can be restated in a way that is reminiscent of President Reagan’s statement at the beginning of this chapter: In designing a tax system to raise revenue, the government should try to raise any given amount of revenue through taxes that induce the smallest changes in behavior.

Sometimes, however, a tax is levied not primarily as a revenue raiser, but as a way to induce individuals or firms to alter their behavior—in contrast to President Reagan’s dictum. For example, proposals for taxes on carbon-based fuels like coal and gasoline are designed to induce people to use fewer of them. The possibility of using taxes to change consumer behavior will be discussed later in this chapter.

Tax Loopholes and Excess Burden We noted earlier that loopholes make the income tax less progressive than it appears to be on paper. Now that we have learned that tax-induced changes in behavior lead to excess burdens, we can understand the second reason why tax specialists condemn tax loopholes: Loopholes make the income tax less efficient than it could be. Why? Because most loopholes involve imposing different tax rates on different types of income. Given a choice between paying, say, a 35 percent marginal tax rate on one type of income and a 15 percent rate on another, most rational taxpayers will favor the latter. Thus: When different income-earning activities are taxed at different marginal rates, economic choices are distorted by tax considerations, which in turn impairs economic efficiency.

Our example is hardly hypothetical. Upper-bracket taxpayers in the United States now pay a 35 percent tax on income that comes in the form of wages or interest but only 15 percent on income that comes in the form of capital gains or dividends. It is no wonder, then, that such people shun interest and seek capital gains—often in the stock market. One major objective shared by tax reformers is to enhance both the equity and efficiency of the personal income tax by closing loopholes and lowering tax rates. The Tax Reform Act of 1986—the pride and joy of tax reformers—did exactly that, but by now that law is ancient history. Since 1986, Congress has allowed a number of tax loopholes to reappear and keeps creating new ones. Critics on both sides of the aisle have long bemoaned the tax system’s legendary complexity and yearned for a simpler tax code with fewer loopholes. But so far, those pleas have gone unheeded.

SHIFTING THE TAX BURDEN: TAX INCIDENCE When economists speak of the incidence of a tax, they are referring to who actually bears the burden of the tax. In discussing the tax on gas-guzzling autos, we adhered to what has been called the flypaper theory of tax incidence: the burden of any tax sticks where the government puts it. In this case, the burden stays on Harry, our SUV fan, but often things do not work out this way. Consider, for example, what will happen if the government levies a $1,000 tax on SUVs like Hummers. We learned how to deal with such a tax in a supply-and-demand diagram back in Chapter 4: The supply curve shifts up by the amount of the tax—in this case, $1,000. Figure 4 shows such a shift by the movement from S0S0 to S1S1. If the demand curve DD does not shift, the market equilibrium moves from point A to point B. The quantity of SUVs declines as Harrys all over America react to the higher price by buying fewer SUVs. Notice that the price rises from $40,000 to $40,600, an increase of $600. People who continue buying these vehicles therefore bear a burden of only $600—less than the tax that they pay!

The incidence of a tax is an allocation of the burden of the tax to specific individuals or groups.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

388

Part 4

The Virtues and Limitations of Markets

F I GURE 4 S1

The Incidence of an Excise Tax Price of an SUV, Including Tax

D

Tax = $1,000 S0

$40,600

B Rise in price = $600 A

$40,000

D S1 S0 Number of SUVs

The American Way of Tax

New York—The Tax Man was very cross about Figg. Figg’s way of life did not conform to the way of life several governments wanted Figg to pursue. “What’s the idea of living in a rental apartment over a delicatessen in the city, Figg?” he inquired. Figg explained that he liked urban life. In that case, said the Tax Man, he was raising Figg’s city sales and income taxes. “If you want them cut, you’ll have to move out to the suburbs,” he said. Figg gave up the city and rented a suburban house but the Tax Man was not satisfied. He squeezed Figg until beads of blood popped out along the seams of Figg’s wallet. “Mercy, good Tax Man,” Figg gasped. “Tell me how to live so that I may please my government, and I shall obey.” The Tax Man told Figg to quit renting and buy a house. The government wanted everyone to accept large mortgage loans from bankers. If Figg complied, it would cut his taxes. Figg bought a house, which he did not want, in a suburb where he did not want to live, and he invited his friends and relatives to attend a party celebrating his surrender to a way of life that pleased his governments. “I have had enough of this, Figg,” the Tax Man declared. “Your government doesn’t want you entertaining friends and relatives. This will cost you plenty.” Figg immediately threw out all of his friends and relatives, then asked the Tax Man what sort of people his government wished him to entertain. “Business associates,” said the Tax Man. “Entertain plenty of business associates, and I shall cut your taxes.” To make the Tax Man and his government happy, Figg began entertaining people he didn’t like in the house he didn’t want in the suburb where he didn’t want to live.

Then was the Tax Man enraged indeed. “Figg!” he thundered, “I will not cut your taxes for entertaining straw bosses, truck drivers and pothole fixers.” “Why not?” said Figg. “These are the people I associate with in my business.” “Which is what?” asked the Tax Man. “Earning my pay by the sweat of my brow,” said Figg. “Your government is not going to bribe you for performing salaried labor,” said the Tax Man. “Don’t you know, you imbecile, that tax rates on salaried income are higher than on any other kind?” And he taxed the sweat of Figg’s brow at a ferocious rate. “Get into business, or minerals, or international oil,” warned the Tax Man, “or I shall make your taxes as the taxes of 10.” Figg went into business, which he hated, and entertained people he didn’t like in the house he didn’t want in the suburb where he did not want to live, and the Tax Man and all the governments and the nation were happy. Figg began to make a profit. The Tax Man was outraged. “What’s the idea of making a profit, Figg?” he demanded, placing his iron grip on Figg’s bank account. “Spare me,” Figg pleaded. “Only if you sell your business!” roared the Tax Man. “After forcing me to get into business, the Government now wants me to get out of business?” asked Figg. “Exactly” said the Tax Man. “Sell, and I’ll tax the profit from the sale at a delightfully low capital-gain rate of only 25 percent. Otherwise, I’ll take the meat ax to those profits.” SOURCE: © CORBIS

The humorist Russell Baker discussed the problem of excess burden in this classic newspaper column. It seems that every time his mythical Mr. Figg took a step to avoid paying taxes and to satisfy the tax man, he became less and less happy.

SOURCE: From Russell Baker, “The American Way of Tax”, ‘The New York Times’, April 12, 1977, p. 27. Copyright © 1977 The New York Times Company. All rights reserved. Used by permission and protected by the Copyright Laws of the United States. The printing, copying, redistribution, or retransmission of the Material without express written permission is prohibited.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 18

389

Taxation and Resource Allocation

Does this mean that the tax imposes a negative excess burden? Certainly not. What it means is that consumers who refrain from buying the taxed commodity manage to shift part of the tax burden away from consumers as a whole, including those who continue to buy SUVs. Who are the victims of this tax shifting? There are two main candidates. First are the automakers or, more precisely, their stockholders. To the extent that the tax reduces auto sales and profits, stockholders bear the burden. The other principal candidates are autoworkers. To the extent that reduced production leads to layoffs or lower wages, these workers bear part of the tax burden. People who have never studied economics almost always believe in the flypaper theory of incidence, which holds that sales taxes are borne by consumers, property taxes are borne by homeowners, and taxes on corporations are borne by stockholders. Perhaps the most important lesson of this chapter is that

Tax shifting occurs when the economic reactions to a tax cause prices and outputs in the economy to change, thereby shifting part of the burden of the tax onto others.

The flypaper theory of incidence is typically wrong.

Failure to grasp this basic point has led to all sorts of misguided tax legislation in which members of Congress or state legislatures, thinking they were placing a tax burden on one group of people, inadvertently placed it squarely on another. Of course, in some cases the flypaper theory of incidence is roughly correct. So let us consider some specific examples of tax incidence.

The Incidence of Excise Taxes Excise taxes have already been covered by our SUV example, because Figure 4 could represent any commodity that is taxed. Our basic finding is that part of the burden will fall on consumers of the taxed commodity (including those who stop buying it because of the tax), and part will be borne by the firms and workers who produce the commodity. How is the burden shared between buyers and sellers? It all depends on the slopes of the demand and supply curves. Intuitively speaking, if consumers are very loyal to the taxed commodity, they will continue to buy almost the same amount regardless of price. In that case, they will get stuck with most of the tax bill because they have left themselves vulnerable to it. Thus: The more inelastic the demand for the product, the larger the share of the tax that consumers will pay.

Similarly, if suppliers are determined to offer the same amount of the product no matter how low the price, then they will wind up paying most of the tax. That is: The more inelastic the supply curve, the larger the share of the tax that suppliers will pay.

An Extreme Case of Tax Incidence D Price of an SUV, Including Tax

One extreme case arises when no one stops buying SUVs when their prices rise. The demand curve becomes vertical, like the demand curve DD in Figure 5. Then no tax shifting can take place. When the supply curve shifts upward by the amount of the tax ($1,000), the price of an SUV (inclusive of tax) rises by the full $1,000—from $40,000 to $41,000. So consumers bear the entire burden. The other extreme case arises when the supply curve is totally inelastic, as depicted by the vertical line SS in Figure 6. Because the number of SUVs supplied is the same at any price, the supply curve will not shift when a tax is imposed. Consequently, automakers must bear the full burden of any tax that is placed on their product. Figure 6 shows that the tax does not change the market price (including tax), which, of course, means that the price received by sellers must fall by the full amount of the tax. Demand and supply schedules for most goods and services are not as extreme as those depicted in Figures 5

FI GURE 5

S1 S0

$41,000 Rise in price = $1,000 $40,000 Tax = $1,000

S1

S0

D Number of SUVs

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

390

Part 4

The Virtues and Limitations of Markets

and 6, so buyers and sellers normally share the burden. Precisely how it is shared depends on the elasticities of the supply and demand curves.4

Price of an SUV, Including Tax

S D

The Incidence of the Payroll Tax $40,000

D S

Economists view the payroll tax as an excise tax on the employment of labor. As mentioned earlier, the U.S. payroll tax comes in two parts: Half is levied on employees (via payroll deductions) and half on employers. A fundamental point, which people who have never studied economics often fail to grasp, is that The ultimate incidence of a payroll tax is the same whether it is levied on employers or on employees.

Number of SUVs

F I GURE 6 Another Extreme Case of Tax Incidence

A simple numerical example will illustrate why this must be so. Consider an employee earning $100 per day with a 16 percent payroll tax that is shared equally between the employer and the employee, as under present U.S. law. To hire this worker, a firm must pay $100 in wages to the worker plus $8 in taxes to the government—for a total daily cost of $108. But how much does the worker receive? He gets $100 in wages paid by the employer less $8 deducted and sent to the government, or $92 per day. The difference between wages paid and wages received is $108 2 $92 5 $16, the amount of the tax. Now suppose Congress tries to “shift” the burden of the tax entirely onto firms by raising the employer’s tax to $16 while lowering the employee’s tax to zero. At first, with the daily wage fixed at $100, the firm’s total labor costs (including tax) rise to $116 per day, and workers’ net income rises to $100 per day. Congress seems to have achieved its goal. This achievement is fleeting, however, for what we have just described is not an equilibrium situation. With the daily cost of labor at $116 for firms, the quantity of labor demanded will be less than it was when labor cost only $108 per day. Similarly, with takehome pay up to $100 for workers, the quantity of labor supplied will be more than it was when the after-tax wage was only $92. Therefore, a surplus of labor on the market will develop (an excess of quantity supplied over quantity demanded), and this surplus will place downward pressure on wages. How far will wages have to fall? We can easily see that an after-tax wage of $92 will restore equilibrium. If daily take-home pay is $92, the same as it was before the tax change, quantity supplied will be the same. From the firm’s perspective, labor now costs $108 per day ($92 in wages plus $16 in taxes), just as it did before the tax change. Firms will, therefore, demand the same quantity of labor as they did when the payroll tax was shared. Thus, in the end, the market will completely frustrate the intent of Congress. The payroll tax is an excellent example of a case in which Congress, misled by the flypaper theory of incidence, thinks it is “taxing firms” when it raises the employer’s share and “taxing workers” when it raises the employee’s share. In truth, who really pays the tax in the long run depends on the incidence of the payroll tax. But no lasting difference results from a change in the employee’s and the employer’s shares. So who, in fact, bears the burden? Like any excise tax, the incidence of the payroll tax depends on the elasticities of the supply and demand schedules. In the case of labor, a large body of empirical evidence points to the conclusion that the quantity of labor supplied is not very responsive to price for most population groups. The supply curve is almost vertical, like that shown in Figure 6. The result: Workers as a group can shift little of the burden of the payroll tax to employers. Employers can shift it in most cases. To firms, their share of the payroll tax is an additional cost of using labor. When payroll taxes go up, firms try to substitute cheaper

4

For concrete examples, see Test Yourself Questions 3 and 4 at the end of this chapter.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 18

Taxation and Resource Allocation

factors of production (such as capital) for labor wherever they can. This effort reduces the quantity of labor demanded, lowering the wage received by workers. Thus market forces shift part of the tax burden from firms to workers. To the extent that the supply curve of labor has some positive slope, the quantity of labor supplied will fall when the wage goes down, allowing workers to shift some of the burden back onto firms, but firms, in turn, can shift that burden onto consumers by raising their prices. As we know from Part 3, prices in competitive markets generally rise when costs (such as labor costs) increase. It is doubtful, therefore, that firms bear much of the payroll tax burden. The flypaper theory of incidence could not be farther from the truth. Even though the tax is collected by the firm, it is really borne by workers and consumers.

WHEN TAXATION CAN IMPROVE EFFICIENCY We have spent much of this chapter discussing the inefficiencies and excess burdens that arise from taxation. Before we finish this discussion, we must point out two things. First, economic efficiency is not society’s only goal. For example, a tax on energy causes “inefficiencies” if it changes people’s behavior patterns. These changes may be just what the government intends. The government wants people to conserve energy and is willing to tolerate some economic inefficiency to accomplish this goal. We can, of course, argue whether the conservation achieved is worth the efficiency loss. The general point is that Some taxes that introduce economic inefficiencies may nonetheless be good social policy if they help to achieve some other goal.

We have already mentioned the excise tax on cigarettes, which aims to change behavior. Another important example is the high tax on alcoholic beverages. A second, and more fundamental, point is that Some taxes that change economic behavior may lead to efficiency gains, rather than to efficiency losses.

As you might suspect, this favorable outcome is possible only when the system has an inefficiency prior to the tax. In such a case, an appropriate tax may help set things right. One important example of this phenomenon was discussed at length in the previous chapter. Because firms and individuals who despoil clean air and water often do so without paying any price, these precious resources are used inefficiently. A corrective tax on pollution can remedy this problem.

EQUITY, EFFICIENCY, AND THE OPTIMAL TAX In a perfect world, the ideal tax would raise the revenues the government needs, reflect society’s views on equity in taxation, and induce no changes in economic behavior—and so have no excess burden. Unfortunately, there is no such tax. Sometimes, in fact, the taxes with the smallest excess burdens are the most regressive. For instance, a head tax, which charges every person the same number of dollars, is incredibly regressive. It is also perfectly efficient. Because no change in economic behavior will enable anyone to avoid it, no one has any reason to change behavior. As we have noted, the regressive payroll tax also seems to have small excess burdens. Fortunately, however, there is a tax that, although not ideal, still scores highly on both the equity and efficiency criteria: a comprehensive personal income tax with few loopholes. Although it is true that income taxes can be avoided by earning less income, we have already observed that in reality the supply of labor responds little to tax policy. People also can reduce their tax bills by investing in relatively safe assets (such as government bonds) rather than riskier ones (such as common stocks), because safer assets pay lower rates of return. But it is not clear that the income tax actually induces such behavior. Why?

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

391

392

Part 4

The Virtues and Limitations of Markets

Because although the government shares in the profits when investments turn out well, it also shares in the losses when investments turn sour. Finally, because an income tax reduces the return on saving, many economists have worried that it would discourage saving and thus retard economic growth.5 Empirical evidence, however, does not suggest that such reactions happen to any great extent. On balance, then, although unresolved questions remain and research is continuing, Most of the research to date suggests that a comprehensive personal income tax with no loopholes would induce few of the behavioral reactions that cause inefficiencies and thus would have a rather small excess burden.

On the equity criterion, we know that personal income taxes can be made as progressive as society deems desirable, though if marginal tax rates on rich people get extremely high, some of the potential efficiency losses might become more serious than they are now. On both grounds, then, many economists—including both liberals and conservatives—view a comprehensive personal income tax as one of the best ways for a government to raise revenue. They differ, however, over how progressive the income tax should be, with some conservatives favoring a proportional tax.

ISSUE REVISITED:

THE PROS AND CONS OF REPEALING THE BUSH TAX CUTS

How do the tax cuts enacted in 2001 and 2003 stack up against these criteria? Should these tax cuts be maintained or repealed? First, the Bush tax cuts concentrated on reducing marginal tax rates. They therefore can be expected to improve economic efficiency, at least modestly. That effect is a clear plus, which—not surprisingly—is touted by supporters. Second, however, the tax cuts were skewed toward upper-bracket taxpayers, thereby reducing the progressivity of the tax system. Whether that change is a plus or a minus depends on your attitude toward inequality. Some Americans wondered why the very rich should get such large tax breaks. Others pointed out that the people who received the biggest tax cuts in 2001–2003 were the people who paid the highest taxes. Naturally, this aspect of the tax cuts has been a bone of contention between Democrats and Republicans since 2001—and remains so today. Third, a number of critics of the tax cuts worried about their large magnitude. Can we really afford such generosity, they asked, or does the government need the money for what President Reagan called “legitimate government purposes”? In answering this question back in 2001, when large budget surpluses were looming, President Bush argued that the government should return some of the money to the people who paid the (unneeded) taxes, but the surpluses evaporated quickly after September 11, 2001, and the federal government began running sizable deficits—which ballooned during the recent recession. Democrats see repeal of the Bush tax cuts as an appealing way to raise revenue, whereas Republicans insist that deficits be attacked only on the spending side. So where does this partial accounting of the pros and cons of repealing the Bush tax cuts leave us? As usual in a serious public policy debate, with plenty of room for reasonable people to disagree! As we said back in Chapter 1, economics is not supposed to give you all the answers. It is supposed to teach you how to ask the right questions. Now you know what they are.

5

For this reason, some economists prefer a tax on consumption to a tax on income.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

393

Taxation and Resource Allocation

Chapter 18

| SUMMARY | 8. The burden of a tax is the amount of money an individual would have to be given to be as well off with the tax as without it. This burden normally exceeds the taxes that are paid, and the difference between the two amounts is called the excess burden of the tax.

1. Taxes in the United States have been quite constant as a percentage of gross domestic product since the early 1970s. The federal tax share fell sharply after 2001, but it has risen since. 2. The U.S. government raises most of its revenue by direct taxes, such as the personal and corporate income taxes and the payroll tax. Of these taxes, the payroll tax is increasing most rapidly.

9. Excess burden arises whenever a tax induces some people or firms to change their behavior. Because excess burdens signal economic inefficiencies, the basic principle of efficient taxation is to utilize taxes that have small excess burdens.

3. For decades, the Social Security System relied successfully on pay-as-you-go financing. In recent years, however, it has been accumulating a large trust fund to be used to pay benefits to future retirees. But experts do not think that trust fund will be large enough.

10. When people change their behavior on account of a tax, they often shift the burden of the tax onto someone else. For this reason, the “flypaper theory of tax incidence”— the belief that the burden of any tax sticks where Congress puts it—is often incorrect.

4. State and local governments raise most of their tax revenues by indirect taxes. States rely mainly on sales taxes, whereas localities depend on property taxes.

11. The burden of a sales or excise tax normally is shared between suppliers and consumers. The manner in which it is shared depends on the elasticities of supply and demand.

5. Controversy has arisen over whether local property taxes are an equitable way to finance public education. 6. In our multilevel system of government, the federal government makes a variety of grants to state and local governments, and states in turn make grants to municipalities and school districts. This system of intergovernmental transfers is called fiscal federalism.

12. The payroll tax works like an excise tax on labor services. Because the supply of labor is much less elastic than the demand for labor, workers bear most of the burden of the payroll tax—including both the employer’s and the employee’s shares.

7. The three concepts of fair, or “equitable,” taxation occasionally conflict. Horizontal equity simply calls for equals to be treated equally. Vertical equity, which calls for unequals to be treated unequally, has often been translated into the ability-to-pay principle—namely, that people who are better able to pay taxes should be taxed more heavily. The benefits principle of tax equity ignores ability to pay and seeks to tax people according to the benefits they receive.

13. Sometimes “inefficient” taxes—that is, taxes that cause a good deal of excess burden—are nonetheless desirable because the changes in behavior they induce further some other social goal. 14. When there are inefficiencies in the system for reasons other than the tax system (for example, externalities), taxation can conceivably improve efficiency.

| KEY TERMS | ability-to-pay principle average tax rate

384

379

excise tax

381

fiscal federalism

property tax 384

383

proportional taxes 379

benefits principle of taxation 385

horizontal equity

384

regressive taxes 379

incidence of a tax

387

Social Security System

burden of a tax

indirect taxes

386

corporate income tax direct taxes

381

379

economic efficiency excess burden

386

marginal tax rate payroll tax

385

379 379

381

tax exempt 380 tax loopholes 380

personal income tax progressive taxes

381

tax deductions 380

379

379

tax shifting

389

vertical equity

384

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

394

Part 4

The Virtues and Limitations of Markets

| TEST YOURSELF | 1. Using the following hypothetical income-tax table, compute the marginal and average tax rates. Is the tax progressive, proportional, or regressive? Income $20,000 30,000 40,000 50,000

d. Suppose the tax is levied on the producers. How much of the tax are producers able to shift onto consumers? Explain how they manage to do so. e. Will there be any excess burden from this tax? Why? Who bears this excess burden?

Income Tax $2,000 2,700 3,200 3,500

f. By how much has cigarette consumption declined on account of the tax? Why might the government be happy about this outcome, despite the excess burden? 4. Now suppose the supply schedule is instead as follows:

2. Which concept of tax equity, if any, seems to be served by each of the following? a. The progressive income tax b. The excise tax on cigarettes c. The gasoline tax 3. Suppose the supply-and-demand schedules for cigarettes are as follows: Price per Carton $3.00 3.25 3.50 3.75 4.00 4.25 4.50 4.75 5.00

Quantity Demanded Quantity Supplied 360 160 330 180 300 200 270 220 240 240 210 260 180 280 150 300 120 320

NOTE: Quantity is in millions of cartons per year.

a. What are the equilibrium price and equilibrium quantity? b. Now the government levies a $1.25 per carton excise tax on cigarettes. What are the new equilibrium price paid by consumers, the price received by producers, and the quantity? c. Explain why it makes no difference whether Congress levies the $1.25 tax on the consumer or the producer. (Relate your answer to the discussion of the payroll tax in the text.)

Price per Carton $3.00 3.25 3.50 3.75 4.00 4.25 4.50 4.75 5.00

Quantity Supplied 60 105 150 195 240 285 330 375 420

NOTE: Quantity is in millions of cartons per year.

a. What are the equilibrium price and equilibrium quantity in the absence of a tax? b. What are the equilibrium price and equilibrium quantity in the presence of a $1.25 per carton excise tax? c. Explain why your answer to part b differs from your answer to part b of the previous question, and relate this difference to the discussion of the incidence of an excise tax in this chapter. 5. The country of Taxmania produces only two commodities: rice and caviar. The poor spend all their income on rice, whereas the rich purchase both goods. Both demand for and supply of rice are quite inelastic. In the caviar market, both supply and demand are quite elastic. Which good would be heavily taxed if Taxmanians cared mostly about efficiency? What if they cared mostly about vertical equity?

| DISCUSSION QUESTIONS | 1. “Americans are overtaxed. The federal government should continue cutting taxes.” Comment. 2. Soon after taking office in 2001, President Bush proposed a series of large tax cuts, including lower bracket rates and repeal of the estate tax. Critics argued that these tax cuts were excessive in magnitude and regressive in their distributional impact. Why did they say that? Do you agree? 3. Use the example of Mr. Figg (see the box, “The American Way of Tax” on page 388) to explain the concepts of efficient taxes and excess burden.

4. Think of some tax that you personally pay. What steps have you taken or could you take to reduce your tax payments? Is there an excess burden on you? Why or why not? 5. Discuss President Reagan’s statement on taxes quoted on the first page of this chapter. Do you agree with him? 6. Use the criteria of equity and efficiency in taxation to evaluate the idea of taxing capital gains at a lower rate than other sources of income.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Part

The Distribution of Income

I

n Part 5, we examine how a market economy distributes its income, using the price mechanism, with the prices of the inputs to the production process determined by supply and demand; that is, we investigate what determines the share of total output that goes to workers, to landowners, to investors, etc. We will see that the market assigns a central role to the marginal productivity of each of these recipients—how much of a marginal contribution each makes to the economy’s total output. In Chapter 19, we will study the payments made for the use of capital (interest), land (rent), and the reward to entrepreneurs (profits). Because most people earn their incomes primarily from wages and salaries, and because these payments constitute nearly threequarters of U.S. national income, our analysis of the payments to labor (wages) merits a separate chapter (Chapter 20). In Chapter 21, we turn to some important problems in the distribution of income—poverty, inequality, and discrimination.

C H A P T E R S 19 | Pricing the Factors of Production

21 | Poverty, Inequality,

and Discrimination

20 | Labor and Entrepreneurship: The Human Inputs

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Pricing the Factors of Production Rent is that portion of the produce of the earth which is paid to the landlord for use of the original and indestructible powers of the soil. DAVI D RI CARD O ( 1772– 1823)

I

n Chapter 15, we noted that the market mechanism cannot be counted on to distribute income in accord with ethical notions of fairness, and we listed this as one of the market’s shortcomings. But there is much more to say about how income is distributed in a market economy. The market mechanism distributes income through its payments to the factors of production. Everyone owns some potentially usable factors of production—the inputs used in the production process. Many of us have only our own labor; but some of us also have funds that we can lend, land that we can rent, or natural resources that we can sell at prices determined by supply and demand. The distribution of income in a market economy is determined by the prices of the factors of production and by the amounts that are employed. For example, if wages are low and unequal and unemployment is high, obviously many people will be poor.

Factors of production are the broad categories— land, labor, capital, exhaustible natural resources, and entrepreneurship—into which we classify the economy’s different productive inputs.

C O N T E N T S PUZZLE: WHY DOES A HIGHER RETURN TO SAVINGS

REDUCE THE AMOUNTS SOME PEOPLE SAVE?

THE PRINCIPLE OF MARGINAL PRODUCTIVITY INPUTS AND THEIR DERIVED DEMAND CURVES INVESTMENT, CAPITAL, AND INTEREST The Demand for Funds The Downward-Sloping Demand Curve for Funds

PUZZLE RESOLVED: THE SUPPLY OF FUNDS The Issue of Usury Laws: Are Interest Rates Too High?

THE DETERMINATION OF RENT Land Rents: Further Analysis Generalization: Economic Rent Seeking Rent as a Component of an Input’s Compensation An Application of Rent Theory: Salaries of Professional Athletes Rent Controls: The Misplaced Analogy

PAYMENTS TO BUSINESS OWNERS: ARE PROFITS TOO HIGH OR TOO LOW? What Accounts for Profits? Taxing Profits

CRITICISMS OF MARGINAL PRODUCTIVITY THEORY | APPENDIX | Discounting and Present Value

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

398

Part 5

The Distribution of Income

PUZZLE:

Entrepreneurship is the act of starting new firms, introducing new products and technological innovations, and, in general, taking the risks that are necessary to seek out business opportunities.

WHY DOES A HIGHER RETURN TO SAVINGS REDUCE THE AMOUNTS SOME PEOPLE SAVE?

The rate of interest is the price one obtains by saving some money and lending it to others—for example, lending the money to a bank (by depositing the money into a bank account) or lending the money to a corporation (by buying its bonds). We normally expect that a rise in the price of a loan (like the price of anything else) will reduce the quantity demanded and increase the quantity supplied. In fact, many people who save their money and lend it to others do the opposite—they reduce the amount they lend when the rate of interest goes up. How can that make sense? The same puzzle affects other factors of production. For example, when wages, the price of labor, rise, workers often decide to work less, perhaps taking longer vacations. Why don’t they work more when pay is better? The explanation will be discussed later in the chapter. It is useful to group the factors of production into five broad categories: land, labor, capital, exhaustible natural resources, and a rather mysterious input called entrepreneurship. In this chapter, we will look at two of them—the interest paid to capital and the rent of land. But first, because there is a great deal of misperception about the distribution of income among workers, suppliers of capital, and landlords, let’s see how much these three groups actually earn. Of all the payments made to factors of production in the United States in 2006, interest payments accounted for about 4.5 percent; land rents were minuscule, making up only 0.7 percent; corporate profits accounted for 15 percent; and income of other business proprietors made up 9.4 percent. In total, the payments to all the factors of production that we deal with in this chapter amounted to about 30 percent of national factor income. Where did the rest of it go? The answer is that 70 percent of 2006 national factor income consisted of employee compensation—that is, wages and salaries.1 There are many other serious misunderstandings about the nature of income distribution and about what government can do to influence it, and discussions of the subject are often emotional. That’s because the distribution of income is the one area in economics in which any one individual’s interests almost inevitably conflict with the interests of someone else. By definition, if I get a larger slice of the total income pie, then you end up with a smaller slice. Still, as we will see in the next chapter, it is possible to get more for oneself by increasing the size of the pie, and then everyone can benefit.

THE PRINCIPLE OF MARGINAL PRODUCTIVITY The marginal physical product (MPP) of an input is the increase in output that results from a one-unit increase in the use of the input, holding the amounts of all other inputs constant. The marginal revenue product (MRP) of an input is the money value of the additional sales that a firm obtains by selling the marginal physical product of that input.

By now it should not surprise you that supply and demand determine the prices of inputs as well as the prices of goods and services. The supply sides of the markets for the various factors differ enormously, so we must discuss each factor market separately. We can use one basic principle, the principle of marginal productivity, to explain how much of any input a profit-maximizing firm will demand, given the price of that input. To review the principle, we must first recall two concepts from Chapter 7: marginal physical product (MPP) and marginal revenue product (MRP). Table 1 helps us review these two concepts in terms of Naomi’s Natural Farm, which has to decide how much organic corn, priced at $10 per bag, to feed its chickens. The marginal

National Income and Product Accounts, U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis, available at http://www.bea.gov. (Note: This calculation consists of the Bureau of Economic Analysis categories, Compensation of Employees, Proprietors’ Income with IVA and CCAdj., Rental Income of Persons with CCAdj., Corporate Profits with IVA and CCAdj., and Net Interest and Miscellaneous Payments, all as a percentage of Net National Factor Income.) 1

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 19

physical product (MPP) column tells us how many additional pounds of chicken each additional bag of corn will yield. For example, according to the table, the fourth bag increases output by 34 pounds. The marginal revenue product (MRP) column tells us how many dollars this marginal physical product is worth. In Table 1, we assume Naomi’s prized, natural chickens sell at $0.75 per pound, so the MRP of the fourth bag of corn is $0.75 per pound times 34 pounds, or $25.50 (last column of the table). The marginal productivity principle states that in competitive factor markets, the profit-maximizing firm will hire or buy the quantity of any input at which the marginal revenue product equals the price of the input.

399

Pricing the Factors of Production

TABLE 1 Naomi’s Natural Farm Schedules for TPP, MPP, APP, and MRP of Corn

(1)

(2)

(3)

Corn Input (Bags)

TPP: Total Physical Product (chicken, lbs)

MPP: Marginal Physical Product per Bag

0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12

0.0 lbs 14.0 36.0 66.0 100.0 130.0 156.0 175.0 184.0 185.4 180.0 165.0 144.0

14.0 lbs 22.0 30.0 34.0 30.0 26.0 19.0 9.0 1.4 25.4 215.0 221.0

The basic logic behind this principle is simple, as we saw before. We know that the firm’s profit from acquiring an additional unit of an input is the input’s marginal revenue product minus its marginal cost (which is the price of the additional unit of input). If the input’s marginal revenue product is greater than its price, it will pay the profit-seeking firm to acquire more of that input because an additional unit of input brings the firm revenue that exceeds its cost. The firm should purchase that input up to the amount at which diminishing returns reduce the MRP to the level of the input’s price, so that further expansion yields zero further addition to profit. By similar reasoning, if MRP is less than price, then the firm is using too much of the input. We see in Table 1 that about seven bags is the optimal amount of corn for Naomi to use each week, because an eighth bag brings in a marginal revenue product of only $6.75, which is less than the $10 cost of buying the bag. One corollary of the principle of marginal productivity is obvious: The quantity of any input demanded depends on its price. The lower the price of corn, the more it pays the farm to buy. In our example, it pays Naomi to use between seven and eight bags when the price per bag is $10. But if corn were more expensive—say, $20 per bag—that high price would exceed the value of the marginal product of either the sixth or seventh bag. It would, therefore, pay the firm to stop at five bags of corn. Thus, marginal productivity analysis shows that the quantity demanded of an input normally declines as the input price rises. The “law” of demand applies to inputs just as it applies to consumer goods.

(4) APP: Average Physical Product per Bag

(5) MRP: Marginal Revenue Product per Bag

0.0 lbs $10.50 14.0 16.50 18.0 22.50 22.0 25.50 25.0 22.50 26.0 19.50 26.0 14.25 25.0 6.75 23.0 1.05 20.6 24.05 18.0 211.25 15.0 215.75 12.0

INPUTS AND THEIR DERIVED DEMAND CURVES We can, in fact, be much more specific about how much of each input a profit-maximizing firm will demand. That’s because the marginal productivity principle tells us precisely how to derive the demand curve for any input from its marginal revenue product (MRP) curve. Figure 1 graphs the MRP schedule from Table 1, showing the marginal revenue product for corn (MRPc) rising and then declining as Naomi feeds more and more corn to her chickens. In the figure, we focus on three possible prices for a bag of corn: $20, $15, and $10. As we have just seen, the optimal purchase rule requires Naomi to keep increasing her use of corn until her MRP begins to fall and eventually is reduced to the price of corn. At a price of $20 per bag, we see that the quantity demanded is about 5.6 bags of corn per week (point A); at that point, MRP equals price. Similarly, if the price of corn is $15 per bag, quantity demanded is about 6.8 bags per week (point B). Finally, at a price of $10 per bag, the quantity demanded would be about 7.7 bags per week (point C). Points A, B, and C are therefore three points on the demand curve for corn. By repeating this exercise for any other price, we learn that because the

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

MRP per Bag of Corn per Week

400

The Distribution of Income

Part 5

$26 24 22 20 18 16 14 12 10 8 6 4 2 0 –2 –4 –6 –8 –10 –12 –14 –16

profit-maximizing purchase of an input occurs at the point where the MRP has fallen down to the level of the input price, A D

The demand curve for any input is the downward-sloping portion of its marginal revenue product curve.2

B C

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

Bags of Corn per Week

F I GURE 1 Marginal Revenue Product Graph for Naomi’s Natural Farm

MRP per Bag of Corn

The derived demand for an input is the demand for the input by producers as determined by the demand for the final product that the input is used to produce.

$50 40 30 20 10 0

1

2

9

10

11

12

The demand for corn or labor (or for any other input) is called a derived demand because it is derived from the underlying demand for the final product (poultry in this case). For example, suppose that a surge in demand drives organic chicken prices to $1.50 per pound. Then, at each level of corn usage, the marginal revenue product will be twice as large as when poultry brought $0.75 per pound. This effect appears in Figure 2 as an upward shift of the (derived) demand curve for corn, from D0D0 to D1D1, even though the marginal physical product curves have not changed. Thus, an outward shift in demand for poultry leads to an outward shift in the demand for corn.3 We conclude that, in general:

An outward shift in the demand curve for any commodity causes an outward shift of the derived demand curve for all factors utilized in the production of that commodity.

Similarly, an inward shift in the demand curve for a commodity leads to inward shifts in the demand curves for factors used in producing that commodity. This completes our discussion of the demand side of the analysis of input pricing. The most noteworthy feature of the discussion is the fact that the same marginal productivity principle serves as the foundation for the demand schedule for each and every type of input. In particular, as we will see in Chapter 20, the marginal productivity principle serves as the basis for the deD1 termination of the demand for labor—that crucial input whose financial reward plays so important a role in an economy’s standard of living. On the demand side, one analysis fits almost all. D0 The supply side for each input, however, entails a very different story. Here we must deal with each of the main production factors individually. We must do D0 D1 so because, as we will see, the supply relationships of 3 5 6 7 8 9 10 4 the different inputs vary considerably. We begin with interest payments, or the return on capital. First, we Bags of Corn per Week must define a few key terms.

F I GURE 2 A Shift in the Demand Curve for Corn

Why is the demand curve restricted to only the downward-sloping portion of the MRP curve? The logic of the marginal productivity principle dictates this constraint. For example, if the price of corn were $15.00 per bag, Figure 1 shows that MRP 5 P at two input quantities: (approximately) 1.75 bags (point D) and 6.8 bags (point B). Point D cannot be the optimal stopping point, however, because the MRP of a second bag ($16.50) is greater than the cost of the third bag ($15.00); that is, the firm makes more money by expanding its input use beyond 1.5 bags per week. A similar profitable opportunity for expansion occurs anytime P 5 MRP and the MRP curve slopes upward at the current price. This must be so, because then an increase in the quantity of input used by the firm will raise MRP above the input’s price. It follows that a profit-maximizing firm will always demand an input quantity that is in the range where MRP is diminishing. 3 To make Figure 2 easier to read, the (irrelevant) upward-sloping portion and the negative portion of each curve have been omitted. 2

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 19

401

Pricing the Factors of Production

INVESTMENT, CAPITAL, AND INTEREST Although people sometimes use the words investment and capital as if they were interchangeable, it is important to distinguish between them. Economists define capital as the inventory (or stock) of plant, equipment, and other productive resources owned by a business firm, an individual, or some other organization. Investment is the amount by which capital grows. A warehouse owned by a firm is part of its capital. Expansion of the warehouse by adding a new area to the building is an investment. So, when economists use the word investment, they do not mean just the transfer of money. The higher the level of investment, the faster the amount of capital that the investor possesses grows. The relation between investment and capital is often explained by the analogy of filling a bathtub: The accumulated water in the tub is analogous to the stock of capital, whereas the flow of water from the faucet (which adds to the tub’s water) is like the flow of investment. Just as the faucet must be turned on for more water to accumulate, the capital stock increases only when investment continues. If investment ceases, the capital stock stops growing (but does not disappear). In other words, if investment is zero, the capital stock does not fall to zero but remains constant (just as when you turn off the faucet the tub doesn’t suddenly empty, but rather the level of the water stays the same). The process of building up capital by investing and then using this capital in production can be divided into five steps, listed below and summarized in Figure 3:

Investment is the flow of resources into the production of new capital. It is the labor, steel, and other inputs devoted to the construction of factories, warehouses, railroads, and other pieces of capital during some period of time.

SOURCE: © The New Yorker Collection 1995, Robert Mankoff from cartoonbank.com. All Rights Reserved.

Step 1. The firm decides to enlarge its stock of capital. Step 2. The firm raises the funds to finance its expansion, either by tapping outside sources such as banks or by holding onto some of its own earnings rather than paying them out to company owners. Step 3. The firm uses these funds to hire the inputs needed to build factories, warehouses, and the like. This step is the act of investment. Step 4. After the investment is completed, the firm ends up with a larger stock of capital. Step 5. The firm uses the capital (along with other inputs) either to expand production or to reduce costs. At this point, the firm starts earning returns on its investment.

Capital refers to an inventory (stock) of plant, equipment, and other (generally durable) productive resources held by a business firm, an individual, or some other organization.

“I can’t sleep. I just got this incredible craving for capital.”

Notice that investors put money into the investment process—either their own or funds borrowed from others. Then, through a series of steps, firms transform the funds into physical inputs suitable for production use. If investors borrow the funds, they must

FIGU R E 3 The Investment Production Process

1 Decide to increase the capital stock

2 Raise funds

3 Investment flow: Buy inputs, use them to build up capital stock

4 Added capital stock

Other inputs

5

Production

Initial capital stock

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

402

Part 5

The Distribution of Income

Interest is the payment for the use of funds employed in the production of capital; it is measured as the percent per year of the value of the funds tied up in the capital.

someday return those amounts to the lender with some payment for their use. This payment is called interest, and it is calculated as an annual percentage of the amount borrowed. For example, if an investor borrows $1,000 at an interest rate of 12 percent per year, the annual interest payment is $120.

The Demand for Funds The rate of interest is the price at which funds can be rented (borrowed). Just like other factor prices, interest rates are determined by supply and demand. On the demand side of the market for loans are borrowers—people or institutions that, for one reason or another, wish to spend more than they currently have. Individuals or families borrow to buy homes or automobiles or other expensive products. Sometimes, as we know, they borrow because they want to consume more than they can afford, which can get them into financial trouble. But often, borrowing makes good sense as a way to manage their finances when they experience a temporary drop in income. It also makes sense to borrow money to buy an item such as a home that will be used for many years. This long product life makes it appropriate for people to pay for the item as it is used, rather than all at once when it is purchased. Businesses use loans primarily to finance investment. To the business executive who borrows funds to finance an investment and pays interest in return, the funds really represent an intermediate step toward the acquisition of the machines, buildings, inventories, and other forms of physical capital that the firm will purchase. The marginal productivity principle governs the quantity of funds demanded, just as it governs the quantity of corn demanded for chicken feed. Specifically: Firms will demand the quantity of borrowed funds that makes the marginal revenue product of the investment financed by the funds just equal to the interest payment charged for borrowing.

One noteworthy feature of capital distinguishes it from other inputs, such as corn. When Naomi feeds corn to her chickens, the input is used once and then it is gone. But a blast furnace, which is part of a steel company’s capital, normally lasts many years. The furnace is a durable good; because it is durable, it contributes not only to today’s production but also to future production. This fact makes calculation of the marginal revenue product more complex for a capital good than for other inputs. To determine whether the MRP of a capital good is greater than the cost of financing it (that is, to decide whether an investment is profitable), we need a way to compare money values received at different times. For, other things being equal, a dollar to be received in 2011 is worth less than a dollar in 2010 because the recipient of the 2010 dollar has an additional year in which to use it to earn more money; for example, he can lend it out for an additional year and earn the additional interest. To make such comparisons between money obtained at different dates, economists and businesspeople use a calculation procedure called discounting. We will explain discounting in detail in the appendix to this chapter, but it is not necessary to master this technique in an introductory course. There are really only two important attributes of discounting to learn here: • A sum of money received at a future date is worth less than the same sum of money

received today. • This difference in values between money today and money in the future is greater

when the rate of interest is higher.

We can easily understand why this is so. To illustrate our first point, consider what you could do with a dollar that you received today rather than a year from today. If the annual rate of interest were 10 percent, you could lend it out (for example, by putting it in a savings account) and receive $1.10 in a year’s time—your original $1.00 plus $0.10 interest. For this reason, money received today is worth more than the same number of dollars received later. Now for our second point. Suppose the annual rate of interest is 15 percent rather than the 10 percent in the previous example. In this case, $1.00 invested today would grow to

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 19

403

Pricing the Factors of Production

$1.15 (rather than $1.10) in a year’s time, which means that $1.15 received a year from today would be equivalent to $1.00 received today, and so, when the interest rate is 15 percent, $1.10 a year in the future must now be worth less than $1.00 today. In contrast, when the interest rate is only 10 percent per year, $1.10 to be received a year from today is equivalent to $1 of today’s money, as we have seen. This illustrates the second of our two points. The rate of interest is a crucial determinant of the economy’s level of investment. It strongly influences the amount of current consumption that consumers will choose to forgo in order to use the resources to build machines and factories that can increase the output of consumers’ goods in the future. The interest rate is crucial in determining the allocation of society’s resources between present and future—an issue that we discussed in Chapter 15 (pages 318–319). Let us see, then, how the market sets interest rates.

The Downward-Sloping Demand Curve for Funds A rise in the price of borrowed funds, like a rise in the price of any item, usually decreases quantity demanded. But when the money is used for investment by the firm the situation is a little more complicated than the relation between price and a consumers’ good. The two attributes of discounting discussed above help to explain the special reasons why the demand curve for funds has a negative slope. Recall that the demand for borrowed funds, like the demand for all inputs, is a derived demand, derived from the desire to invest in capital goods. But firms will receive part— perhaps all—of a machine or factory’s marginal revenue product in the future. Hence, the value of the MRP in terms of today’s money shrinks as the interest rate rises. Why? Because a given future return on investment in a machine or factory becomes worth less (it must be discounted more) when the rate of interest rises, as our illustration of the second point about discounting showed. As a consequence of this shrinkage, a machine that appears to be a good investment when the interest rate is 10 percent may look like a terrible investment if interest rates rise to 15 percent; that is, the higher the interest rate, the fewer machines a firm will demand. That is so because investing in the machines would use up money that could earn more interest in a savings account. Thus, the demand curve for machines and other forms of capital will have a negative slope—the higher the interest rate, the smaller the quantity that firms will demand. As the interest rate on borrowing rises, more and more investments that previously looked profitable start to look unprofitable. The demand for borrowing for investment purposes, therefore, is lower at higher rates of interest.

The higher the interest rate, the less people and firms will want to borrow to finance their investments.

The Derived Demand Curve for Loans

D Rate of Interest in Percent per Year

Note that, although this analysis clearly applies to a firm’s purchase of capital goods such as plant and equipment, it may also apply to the company’s land and labor purchases. Firms often finance both of these expenditures via borrowed funds, and these inputs’ marginal revenue products may accrue only months or even years after the inputs have been bought and put to work. (For example, it may take quite some time before newly acquired agricultural land will yield a marketable crop.) Thus, just as in the case of capital investments, a rise in the interest rate will reduce the quantity demanded of investment goods such as land and labor, just as it cuts the derived demand for investment in plant and equipment. Figure 4 depicts a derived demand schedule for loans, with the interest rate on the vertical axis as the loan’s cost to a borrower. Its negative slope illustrates the conclusion we have just stated:

FI GURE 4

D

0 Dollars Demanded per Year

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

404

Part 5

The Distribution of Income

PUZZLE RESOLVED:

F I GURE 5 Equilibrium in the Market for Loans

Rate of Interest in Percent per Year

D

7.5%

A

5.5

S

0

THE SUPPLY OF FUNDS

Somewhat different relationships arise on the supply side of the market for funds—where the suppliers or lenders are consumers, banks, and other business firms. Funds lent out are usually returned to the owner (with interest) only over a period of time. Loans will look better to lenders when they bear higher interest rates, so the supply schedule for loans rather naturally may be expected to slope upward—at higher rates of interest, lenders supply more funds. Such a supply schedule appears as the curve SS in Figure 5, where we also reproduce the demand curve, DD, from Figure 4. Here, the free-market interest rate is 7.5 percent. However, not all supply curves for funds slope uphill to the right like curve SS. As we stated in the puzzle at the beginning of the chapter, sometimes a rise in the interest rate (the price of loans that is the financial reward for saving) will lead people to save less, rather than more. An example will help to explain the reason for this apparently curious behavior, which, as we will see, can sometimes be sensible behavior. Say Jim is saving to buy a $10,000 used tractor in three years. If he lends money out at interest in the interim, suppose Jim must save $3,100 per year to reach his goal. If interest rates were higher, he could get away with saving less than $3,100 per year and still reach his $10,000 goal because every year, with the higher interest, he would get larger interest payments on his savings. Thus, Jim’s saving S (and lending) may decline as a result of the rise in interest rate. This argument applies fully only to savers, like Jim, with a fixed accumulation goal, but similar considE erations affect the calculations of other savers. So when the rate of interest rises, some people save more but some save less. B Generally, we expect the quantity of loans supplied to rise at least somewhat when the interest reward rises, so the supply curve will have a positive slope, like SS in Figure 5. However, for reasons similar to those indicated in Jim’s example, the increase in the economy’s D saving that results from a rise in the interest rate is usually quite small. That is why we have drawn the supply curve to be so steep. The rise in the amount supplied by some lenders is partially offset by a decline in the amounts lent by savers with fixed goals (like Jim, who is putting money away to buy a tractor, or Jasmine, who Dollars Lent per Year is saving for an expensive camera). Having examined the relevant demand and supply curves, we are now in a position to discuss the determination of the equilibrium rate of interest. This is summed up in Figure 5, in which the equilibrium is, as always, at point E, where quantity supplied equals quantity demanded. We conclude, again, that the equilibrium interest rate on loans is 7.5 percent in the example in the graph.

The Issue of Usury Laws: Are Interest Rates Too High? People have often been dissatisfied with the market mechanism’s determination of interest rates. Fears that interest rates, if left unregulated, would climb to exorbitant levels have made usury laws (which place upper limits on money-lending rates) quite popular in many times and places. Attempts to control interest payments date back to biblical days, and in the Middle Ages the influence of the church even led to total prohibition of interest payments in much of Europe. The same is true today in Moslem countries. In the United Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 19

405

Pricing the Factors of Production

States, the patchwork of state usury laws was mostly dismantled during the 1980s when the banking industry was deregulated. Unscrupulous lenders often manage to evade usury laws, charging interest rates even higher than the free-market equilibrium rate. Even when usury laws are effective, they interfere with the operation of supply and demand and, as we will demonstrate, they may harm economic efficiency. Look at Figure 5 again but, this time, assume it depicts the supply of bank loans to consumers. Consider what happens if a usury law prohibits interest rates higher than 5.5 percent per year on consumer loans. At 5.5 percent, the quantity supplied (point A in Figure 5) falls short of the quantity demanded (point B). This means that many applicants for consumer loans are being turned down even though banks consider them to be creditworthy. Who gains and who loses from this usury law? The gainers are the lucky consumers who get loans at 5.5 percent even though they would have been willing to pay 7.5 percent. The losers are found on both the supply side and the demand side: the consumers who would have been willing and able to get credit at 7.5 percent but who are turned down at 5.5 percent, and the banks that could have made profitable loans at rates of up to 7.5 percent if there were no interest-rate ceiling. This analysis explains why usury laws can be politically popular. Few people sympathize with bank stockholders, and the consumers who get loans at lower rates are, naturally, pleased with the result of usury laws. Other consumers, who would like to borrow at 5.5 percent but cannot because quantity supplied is less than quantity demanded, are likely to blame the bank for refusing to lend, rather than blaming the government for outlawing mutually beneficial transactions. Concern over high interest rates can be rational. It may, for example, be appropriate to combat homelessness by making financing of housing cheaper for poor people. Of course, it may be much more rational for the government to subsidize the interest on housing for the poor rather than to declare high interest rates illegal, in effect pretending that those costs can simply be legislated away, as a usury ceiling tries to do.4

THE DETERMINATION OF RENT

Annual Rent per Acre

The factor of production we will discuss next is land. Rent, the payment for the use of land, is another price that, when left to the market, often seems to settle at politically unpopular levels. Rent controls are a frequent solution. We discussed the effects of rent controls in Chapter 4 (pages 72–73), and we will say a bit more about them later in this chapter. Our main focus here is the determination of rents by free markets. S D The market for land is characterized by a special feature on the supply side. Land is a factor of production whose total quantity supplied is (roughly) unchanging and virtually unchangeable: The same quantity is available at every possible price. Indeed, classical economists used this notion as E $2,000 the working definition of land, and the definition seems to fit, at least approximately. Although people may drain swamps, clear forests, fertilize fields, build skyscrapers, or convert land from one use (a farm) to another (a housing development), human effort cannot change the total supply S of land by very much. 1,000 What does this fact tell us about how the market determines land rents? Figure 6 helps to provide an answer. Acres of Land The vertical supply curve SS means that no matter what

D

FI GURE 6 The law also sometimes concerns itself with discrimination in lending against women or members of ethnic minority groups. Strong evidence suggests the existence of sex and race discrimination in lending. For example, as late as the nineteenth century, married women were often denied loans without the explicit permission of their husbands, even when the women had substantial independent incomes. 4

Determination of Land Rent in Littleville

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

406

The Distribution of Income

Part 5

D1

Annual Rent per Acre

D0

$2,500 2,000

F I GURE 7 A Shift in Demand with a Vertical Supply Curve

Economic rent is the portion of the earnings of a factor of production that exceeds the minimum amount necessary to induce that factor to be supplied.

the level of rents, there are only 1,000 acres of land in a small hamlet called Littleville. The demand curve, DD, S slopes downward and is a typical marginal revenue product curve, predicated on the notion that the use of land, like everything else, is subject to diminishing reA turns. The free-market price is determined, as usual, by the intersection of the supply and demand curves at E point E. In this example, each acre of land in Littleville rents for $2,000 per year. The first interesting feature of this diagram is that, because quantity supplied is rigidly fixed at 1,000 acres whatever the price, the market level D1 of rent is entirely determined by the market’s demand D0 S side. This leads to the second special feature: Any shift 1,000 in the demand curve that raises (or lowers) it by X dollars will raise (or lower) the equilibrium price of land by Acres of Land precisely the same amount—X dollars. If, for example, a major university relocates to Littleville, attracting more people who want to live there, the DD curve will shift outward, as depicted in Figure 7. Equilibrium in the market will shift from point E to point A. The same 1,000 acres of land will be available, but now each acre will command a rent of $2,500 per acre. The landlords will collect more rent, even though society gets no more of the input—land—from the landlords in return for its additional payment. The same process also works in reverse, however. If the university shuts its doors and the demand for land declines as a result, the landlords will suffer even though they did not contribute to the decline in the demand for land. (To see this, simply reverse the logic of Figure 7. The demand curve begins at D1D1 and shifts to D0D0.) This discussion shows the special feature of rent that leads economists to distinguish it from payments to other factors of production. An economic rent is an “extra” payment for a factor of production (such as land) that does not change the amount of the factor that is supplied. Society is not compensated for a rise in its rent payments by any increase in the quantity of land it obtains. Economic rent is thus the portion of the factor payment that exceeds the minimum payment necessary to induce that factor to be supplied. As late as the end of the nineteenth century, the idea of economic rent exerted a powerful influence far beyond technical economic writings. American journalist Henry George was nearly elected mayor of New York in 1886, running on the platform that all government should be financed by a “single tax” levied on landlords, who, he said, are the only ones who earn incomes without contributing to the productive process. George said that landlords reap the fruits of economic growth without contributing to economic progress. He based his logic on the notion that landowners do not increase the supply of their factor of production—the quantity of land—when rents increase.

Land Rents: Further Analysis If all plots of land were identical, our previous discussion would be virtually all there is to the theory of land rent. But plots of land do differ—in geographical location, topography, nearness to marketplaces, soil quality, and so on. The early economists, notably David Ricardo, took this disparity into account in their analysis of rent determination—a remarkable nineteenth-century piece of economic logic still considered valid today. The basic notion is that capital invested in any piece of land must yield the same rate of return per dollar invested as capital invested in any other piece that is actually in use. Why? If it were not so, capitalist renters would bid against one another for the more profitable pieces of land. This competition would go on until the rents they would have to pay for these parcels were driven up to a point that eliminated their advantages over other parcels. Suppose that a farmer produces a crop on one piece of land for $160,000 per year in labor, fertilizer, fuel, and other nonland costs, whereas a neighbor who is no more efficient

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Pricing the Factors of Production

407

produces the same crop for $120,000 on a second piece of land. The rent on the second parcel must be exactly $40,000 per year higher than the rent on the first, because otherwise production on one plot would be cheaper than on the other. If, for example, the rent difference were only $30,000 per year, it would be $10,000 cheaper to produce on the second plot of land. No one would want to rent the first plot and every grower would instead bid for the second plot. Rent on the first plot would be forced down by the lack of customers, and rent on the second plot would be driven up by eager bidders. These pressures would come to an end only when the rent difference reached $40,000, so that both plots became equally profitable. At any given time, some low-quality pieces of land are so inferior that it does not pay to use them at all—remote deserts are a prime example. Any land that is exactly on the borderline between being used and not being used is called marginal land. By this definition, marginal land earns no rent because if its owner charged any for it, no one would willingly pay to use it. We combine these two observations—that the difference between the costs of producing on any two pieces of land must equal the difference between their rents and that zero rent is charged on marginal land—to conclude that

Marginal land is land that is just on the borderline of being used—that is, any land the use of which would be unprofitable if the farmer had to pay even a penny of rent.

Chapter 19

Rent on any piece of land will equal the difference between the cost of producing the output on that land and the cost of producing it on marginal land.

That is, competition for the superior plots of land will permit the landowners to charge prices that capture the full advantages of their superior parcels. This analysis helps us to understand more completely the effects of an outward shift in the demand curve for land. Suppose population growth raises demand for land. Naturally, rents will rise. But we can be more specific than this statement. In response to an outward shift in the demand curve, two things will happen: • It will now pay to employ some land whose use was formerly unprofitable. The land that was previously on the zero-rent margin will no longer be on the borderline, and some land that is so poor that it was formerly not even worth considering will now just reach the borderline of profitability. The settling of the American West illustrates this process strikingly. Land that once could not be given away is often now very valuable. • People will begin to exploit already-used land more intensively. Farmers will use more labor and fertilizer to squeeze larger amounts of crops out of their acreage, as has happened in recent decades. Urban real estate that previously held two-story houses will now be used for high-rise buildings. These two events will increase rents in a predictable fashion. Because the land that is considered marginal after the change must be inferior to the land that was considered marginal previously, rents must rise by the difference in yields between the old and new marginal lands. Table 2 illustrates this point. In the table, we deal with three pieces of land: A, a very productive piece; B, a piece that was initially considered only marginal; and C, a piece that is inferior to B but nevertheless becomes marginal when the demand curve for land shifts TABLE 2 upward and to the right. Nonrent Costs and Rent on Three Pieces of Land The crop costs $80,000 more when produced on B Total than on A, and $12,000 more when produced on C Nonland Cost Rent Type of of Producing than on B. Suppose, initially, that demand for the crop Land a Given Crop Before After is so low that Farmer Jones does not plant crops in field C. Farmer Jones is on the fence about whether to A. A tract that was better than $120,000 $80,000 $92,000 plant crops in field B. Because field B is marginal, it is marginal before and after B. A tract that was marginal 200,000 0 12,000 just on the margin between being used and being left before but is attractive now idle—it will command no rent. We know that the rent C. A tract that was previously 212,000 0 0 on field A will be equal to the $80,000 cost advantage not worth using but is now of A over B. Now suppose demand for the crop inmarginal creases enough so that plot C becomes marginal land.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

408

Part 5

The Distribution of Income

Then field B commands a rent of $12,000, the cost advantage of B over C. Plot A’s rent now must rise from $80,000 to $92,000, the size of its cost advantage over C, the newly marginal land. In addition to the quality differences among pieces of land, a second influence pushes land rents up: increased intensity of use of land that is already under cultivation. As farmers apply more fertilizer and labor to their land, the marginal productivity of the land increases, just as factory workers become more productive when more is invested in their equipment. Once again, the landowner can capture this productivity increase in the form of higher rents. (If you do not understand why, refer back to Figure 7 and recall that the demand curves are marginal revenue product curves—that is, they indicate the amount that capitalists are willing to pay landlords to use their land.) Thus, we can summarize the theory of rent as follows: As the use of land increases, landlords receive higher payments from two sources: • Increased demand leads the community to employ land previously not good enough

to use; the advantage of previously used land over the new marginal land increases, and rents go up correspondingly. • Land is used more intensively; the marginal revenue product of land rises, thereby in-

creasing the ability of the producer who uses the land to pay rent.

Generalization: Economic Rent Seeking Economists refer to the payments for land as “rents,” but land is not the only scarce input with a fixed supply, at least in the short run. Toward the beginning of the twentieth century, some economists realized that the economic analysis of rent can be applied to inputs other than land. As we will see, this extension yielded some noteworthy insights. The concept of rent can be used to analyze such common phenomena as lobbying in the U.S. Congress (attempts to influence the votes of members of Congress) by industrial groups, lawsuits between rival firms, and battles over exclusive licenses (as for a television station). Such interfirm battles can waste very valuable economic resources—for

Supply and demand do not equalize prices for identical commodities offered by different sellers when the commodity, such as land, cannot be transferred from one geographic market to another. In 2008, for example, retailers on the Avenue des Champs-Elysees in Paris paid an average of $1,134 per square foot, per year. In comparison, shop space on Milan’s Via Montenapoleone cost $983 per square foot each year, and retail real estate on New Bond Street in London cost $810 per square foot per year. A fifteen-block stretch of 5th Avenue, between Central Park and 42nd Street in New York City, ranked as the most expensive retail real estate in the world, at $1,850 per square foot in 2008.

SOURCE: Matt Woolsey, “World’s Most Valuable Addresses,” Forbes, December 22, 2008, http://www.forbes.com/2008/12/22/most-valuable-addresses-forbeslife-cx_ mw_1222realestate.html.

SOURCE: © Adina Tovy/Robert Harding/Jupiterimages

Land Prices Around the World

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 19

Pricing the Factors of Production

example, the time that executives, bureaucrats, judges, lawyers, and economists spend preparing and battling court trials. Because this valuable time could have been used in production, such activities entail large opportunity costs. Rent analysis offers insights into the reasons for these battles and provides a way to assess what quantity of resources people waste as they seek economic rents for scarce resources. How is economic rent—which is a payment to a factor of production above and beyond the amount necessary to get the factor to make its contribution to production—relevant in such cases? Gordon Tullock, an economist also trained in legal matters, first identified the phenomenon of rent seeking as the search and battle for opportunities to charge or collect those payments above and beyond the amount necessary to create the source of the income. An obvious source of such rents is a monopoly license. For example, a license to operate the only television station in town will yield enormous advertising profits, far above the amount needed for the station to operate. That’s why rent seekers swoop down when such licenses become available. Similarly, the powerful lobby for U.S. sweetener producers, including corn and beet growers as well as cane sugar farmers, pressures Congress to impede cane sugar imports, because free importation would cut prices (and rents) substantially. Such activities need not increase the quantities of product supplied, just as higher rents do not increase the supply of land. That is why any resulting earnings are called “rent” and why the effort to obtain such earnings that contribute nothing to output is called “rent seeking.” How much of society’s resources will be wasted in such a process? Rent-seeking theory can give us some idea. Consider a race for a monopoly cable TV license that, once awarded, will keep competing stations from operating. Nothing prevents anyone from entering the race to grab the license. Anyone can hire the lobbyists and lawyers or offer the bribes needed in the battle for such a lucrative license. Thus, although the cable business itself may not be competitive, the process of fighting for the license can be very competitive. Of course, we know from the analysis of long-run equilibrium under perfect competition (Chapter 10, pages 206–209) that in such markets, economic profits approximate zero—in other words, revenues just cover costs. If owners expect a cable license to yield, say, $900 million over its life in rent, then rent seekers (that is, the companies competing to gain the license in the first place) are likely to waste something close to that amount as they fight for the license. Why? Suppose each of 10 bidders has an equal chance at winning the license. To each bidder, that chance should be worth about $90 million—1 chance in 10 of getting $900 million. If the average bidder spends only $70 million on the battle, each firm will still value the battle for the license at $90 million minus $70 million. This fact will tempt an eleventh bidder to enter and raise the ante to, say, $80 million in lobbying fees, hoping to grab the rent. This process of attraction of additional bidders stops only when all of the excess rent available has been wasted on the rent-seeking process, so there is no further motivation for still more people to bid.

Rent as a Component of an Input’s Compensation We can use the concept of economic rent to divide the payment for any input into two parts. The first part is simply the minimum payment needed to acquire the input—for example, the cost of producing a ball bearing or the compensation people require in exchange for the unpleasantness, hard work, and loss of leisure involved in performing labor. The owners of the input must be offered this first part of the factor payment if they are to supply the input willingly. If workers do not receive at least this first part, they will not supply their labor. The second part of the payment is a bonus that does not go to every input, but only to inputs of particularly high quality, like the payment to the owner of higher-quality land in our earlier example. Payments to workers with exceptional natural skills are a good illustration of the generalized rent concept. Because these bonuses are like the extra payment for a better piece of land, they are called economic rents. Indeed, like the rent of land, an increase in the amount of economic rent paid to an input may not increase the quantity of

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

409

410

Part 5

The Distribution of Income

that input supplied. This second part of the payment—the economic rent—is pure gravy. The skillful worker is happy to have it as an extra, but it is not a deciding consideration in the choice of whether or not to work.

An Application of Rent Theory: Salaries of Professional Athletes Professional athletes may seem to have little in common with plots of farmland. Yet to an economist, the same analysis—the theory of economic rent—explains how the market arrives at the amounts paid to each of these “factors of production.” To understand why, let’s look at a hypothetical basketball team, the Lost Lakers, and its seven-foot star center, Dapper Dan. First, we must note that there is only one Dapper Dan. That is, he is a scarce input whose supply is fixed just like the supply of land. Because he is in fixed supply, the price of his services is determined in a way similar to that of land rents. A moment’s thought shows how the general notion of economic rent applies both to land and to Dapper Dan. The total quantity of land available for use is the same whether rent is high, low, or zero; only limited payments to landlords are necessary to induce them to supply land to the market. By definition, then, a considerable proportion of the payments to landholders for their land is economic rent—payments above and beyond those necessary for landlords to provide land to the economy. Dapper Dan is (almost) similar to land in this respect. His athletic talents are unique and cannot be reproduced. What determines the payment to such a factor? Because the quantity supplied of such a unique, nonreproducible factor is absolutely fixed (there’s only one Dapper Dan), and therefore unresponsive to price, the analysis of rent that we summarized in Figure 6 applies, and the position of the demand curve for Dapper Dan’s services is determined by the superiority of his services over those of other players. Suppose the Lost Lakers team also includes a marginal player, Weary Willy, winner of last year’s Least Valuable Player award. Willy earns the $50,000 per year necessary to obtain his services. Suppose also that if no other option were available, Dapper Dan would be willing to play basketball for $50,000 per year, rather than working as a hamburger flipper, the only other job for which he is qualified. But Dan knows he can do better than that. He estimates, quite accurately, that his presence on the team brings in $10 million of added revenue over and above what the team would obtain if Dan were replaced by a player of Willy’s caliber. In that case, Dan and his agent ought to be able to obtain $10 million more per year than is paid to Willy. As a result, Dan obtains a salary of $10,050,000, of which $10 million is economic rent—exactly analogous to the previous rent example involving different pieces of land of unequal quality. Note that the team gets no more of Dapper Dan’s working time in return for the rent payment. (See “A-Rod: Earning Lots of Economic Rent” on the facing page for a real-world example.) Almost all inputs, including employees, earn some economic rent. What sorts of inputs earn no rent? Only those inputs that can be provided by a number of suppliers at equal and constant cost and with identical quality earn no rents. For instance, no ball-bearing supplier will ever receive any rent on a ball bearing, at least in the long run, because any desired number of them, of equal quality, can be produced by any of the competing suppliers at (roughly) constant costs and can contribute equal amounts to the profits of those who use them. If one ball-bearing supplier tried to charge a price above their x-cent cost, another manufacturer would undercut the first supplier and take its customers away. Hence, the competitive price includes no economic rent.

Rent Controls: The Misplaced Analogy Why is the analysis of economic rent important? Because only economic rent can be taxed away without reducing the quantity of the input supplied. Here common English gets in the way of sound reasoning. Many people feel, in effect, that the rent they pay to their landlord is economic rent. After all, their apartments will still be there if they pay $1,500 per month, or $500, or $100. This view, although true in the short run, is quite shortsighted.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 19

Pricing the Factors of Production

411

In case you think that our discussion of economic rent is mere academic theorizing, check out these numbers: In 2000, in a deal that sent shock waves through the baseball establishment, shortstop Alex Rodriguez signed a 10-year, $252-million contract with the Texas Rangers. His salary of more than $25 million per year makes him one of the highest-paid professional athletes in sports history. It is safe to assume that most of his salary is economic rent—in other words, he would still be willing to play baseball if no team offered him much more than a far smaller amount. Less than four years later, the Rangers, finding themselves unable to afford A-Rod’s huge salary, traded their superstar shortstop to the New York Yankees—who can afford him. In fact, however, the Rangers will still pay part of Rodriguez’s salary through the year 2010. But the saga continued: In October 2007, after the Yankees failed to reach the playoffs, A-Rod opted out of his contract and became a free agent. Six weeks later, he signed a new $275 million 10-year contract with the Yankees organization. That move paid off for the Yankees—in 2009 they defeated the Philadelphia Phillies to win the World Series.

Like the ball-bearing producer, the owner of a building cannot expect to earn economic rent because too many other potential owners whose costs of construction are roughly the same will also offer apartments if rents are high. If the market price temporarily included some economic rent—that is, if price exceeded production costs plus the opportunity cost of the required capital—other builders would start new construction that would drive the price down. Far from being in perfectly inelastic (vertical) supply, like raw land, buildings come rather close to being in perfectly elastic (horizontal) supply, like ball bearings. As we have learned from the theory of rent, this means that builders and owners of buildings cannot collect economic rent in the long run. Because apartment owners collect very little economic rent, payments by tenants in a free market must be just enough to keep those apartments on the market (the very definition of zero economic rent). If rent controls push these prices down, the apartments will start disappearing from the market.5 Among other unfortunate results, we can therefore expect rent controls to contribute to homelessness—though it is, of course, not the only influence behind this distressing phenomenon.

PAYMENTS TO BUSINESS OWNERS: ARE PROFITS TOO HIGH OR TOO LOW? We turn next to business profits, the discussion of which often seems to elicit more passion than logic. With the exception of some economists, almost no one thinks that profit rates are at the right level. Critics point accusingly to some giant corporations’ billion-dollar profits and argue that they are unconscionably high; they then call for much stiffer taxes on profits. On the other hand, the Chambers of Commerce, National Association of Manufacturers, and other business groups complain that regulations None of this is meant to imply that temporary rent controls in certain locations cannot have desirable effects in the short run. In the short run, the supply of apartments and houses really is fixed, and large shifts in demand can hand windfall gains to landlords—gains that are true, if temporary, economic rents. Controls that eliminate such windfalls should not cause serious problems. But knowing when the “short run” fades into the “long run” can be tricky. “Temporary” rent control laws have a way of becoming rather permanent.

5

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

SOURCE: © Jason Szenes/EPA/Landov

“A-Rod”: Earning Lots of Economic Rent

412

Part 5

The Distribution of Income

and “ruinous” competition keep profits too low, and they constantly petition Congress for tax relief. The public has many misconceptions about the nature of the U.S. economy, but probably none is farther from reality than popular perceptions of what American corporations earn in profits. Try the following experiment. Ask five of your friends who have never had an economics course what fraction of the nation’s income they imagine is pure profit to companies. Although the correct answer varies from year to year, business profits in 2006 made up 12.4 percent of gross domestic product (GDP) (before taxes).6 A comparable percentage of the prices you pay represents before-tax profit. Most people think this figure is much, much higher (see “Public Opinion on Profits” on page 31 in Chapter 2). As you can see, economists are reluctant to brand factor prices as “too low” or “too high” in some moral or ethical sense. Rather, they are likely to ask first: What is the market equilibrium price? Then they will ask whether there are any good reasons to interfere with the market solution. This analysis, however, is not so easily applied to the case of profits, because it is difficult to use supply-and-demand analysis when you do not know which factor of production earns profit. In both a bookkeeping sense and an economic sense, profits are the residual. They are what remains from the selling price after all other factors have been paid.

But which production factor earns this reward? Which factor’s marginal productivity constitutes the profit rate?

What Accounts for Profits? Economic profit is the total revenue of a firm minus all of its costs, including the interest payments and opportunity costs of the capital it obtains from its investors.

Economic profit, as we learned in Chapter 10, is the amount a firm earns over and above the payments for all inputs, including the interest payments for the capital it uses and the opportunity cost of any capital provided by the owners of the firm. The payment that firm owners receive to compensate them for the opportunity cost of their capital (and that in common parlance is considered profit) is closely related to interest rates but is not part of economic profit. In an imaginary (and dull) world in which everything was certain and unchanging, capitalists who invested money in firms would simply earn the market rate of interest on their funds. Profits beyond this level would be competed away. Payment for capital below this level could not persist, because capitalists would withdraw their funds from firms and deposit them in banks. Capitalists in such a world would be mere moneylenders. But the real world is not at all like this. Some capitalists are much more than moneylenders, and the amounts they earn often exceed current interest rates by a huge margin. This substantial earning can be a rent, of the sort we have just been considering. But now we are discussing other sources of profit, which are obtained in return for some productive service by the recipient (see “Nimble Entrepreneurship: Snatching Victory from the Jaws of Defeat” for an example). However, we can list three primary ways in which profits above “normal” interest rate levels can be earned.

1. Monopoly Power If a firm can establish a monopoly with some or all of its products, even for a short while, it can use that monopoly power to earn monopoly profits. We analyzed the nature of these monopoly earnings in Chapter 11.

2. Risk Bearing Firms often engage in financially risky activities, subjecting the capitalist investors in the firm (as well as its employees) to some financial peril. For example, when a firm prospects for oil, it must drill exploratory wells hoping to find petroleum at

6 SOURCE: National Income and Product Accounts, U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis, available at http://www.bea.gov.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 19

413

Pricing the Factors of Production

“The path to entrepreneurial success is not always obvious. In fact, in the case of Scale Computing of Indianapolis, failure was the springboard. Jeff Ready, the chief executive of Scale Computing, and his business partners said they originally thought they would use the artificial-intelligence technology they had developed at a previous start-up company to recast stock prices and make a fortune as hedge fund gurus. But by the time they had built their ‘magic box,’ the economy had turned grim and they were unable to raise the $100 million they thought they needed. It was only after potential customers rejected other software technology ideas that they realized their device could be marketed as a more practical product: a data storage system. Two years later, the orders are pouring in. Andrew Zacharakis, a professor of entrepreneurship at Babson College outside Boston, said Scale Computing’s owners followed a classic entrepreneurial path of shifting gears as necessary to seize real, as opposed to perceived, opportunities.”

SOURCE: Image copyright Tatuasha, 2009. Used under license from Shutterstock.com

Nimble Entrepreneurship: Snatching Victory from the Jaws of Defeat

SOURCE: Excerpted from Brent Bowers, “Finding the Path to Success by Changing Directions,” The New York Times, September 9, 2009, accessed online at http://www.nytimes.com.

the bottom. Of course, many such exploratory wells end up as dry holes, and the costs then bring no return. Lucky investors, on the other hand, do find oil and are rewarded handsomely—more than the competitive return on the firm’s capital. The extra income pays the firm for bearing risk. A few lucky individuals make out well in this process, but many suffer heavy losses. How well can we expect risk takers to do, on the average? If 1 exploratory drilling out of 10 typically pays off, do we expect its return to be exactly 10 times as high as the interest rate, so that the average firm will earn exactly the normal rate of interest? The answer is that the payoff will be more than 10 times the interest rate if investors dislike gambling— that is, if they prefer to avoid risk. Why? Because investors who are risk averse will not be willing to put their money into a business that faces such long odds—10 to 1—unless the market provides compensation for the financial peril. In reality, nothing guarantees that things will always work out this way. Some people love to gamble and tend to be overly optimistic. They may plunge into projects to a degree unjustified by the odds. Average payoffs to such gamblers in risky undertakings may end up below the interest rate. The successful investor will still make a good profit, just like the lucky winner in Las Vegas. The average participant, however, will have to pay for the privilege of bearing risk.

3. Returns to Innovation The third major source of profits is perhaps the most important of all for social welfare. People who introduce new outputs or new production methods or find new markets for the commodities that the firm sells are called innovative entrepreneurs. The first entrepreneur able to innovate and market a desirable new product or employ a new cost-saving machine will garner a higher profit than what an uninnovative (but otherwise similar) business manager would earn. Innovation differs from invention. Whereas invention generates new ideas, innovation takes the next step by putting the new idea into practical use. Businesspeople are rarely inventors, but they are often innovators. When an entrepreneur innovates, even if the new product or new process is not protected by patents, the entrepreneur will be one step ahead of competitors. If the market

Invention is the act of generating an idea for a new product or a new method for making an old product. Innovation also includes the next step, the act of putting the new idea into practical use.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

414

Part 5

The Distribution of Income

likes the innovation, the entrepreneur will be able to capture most of the sales, either by offering customers a better product or by supplying the product more cheaply. In either case, the entrepreneur will temporarily have some monopoly power as the competitors weaken and will receive monopoly profit for the initiative. And the benefit to the community can be substantial. Innovative entrepreneurs have played a crucial role in recognizing promising inventions and ensuring that they are put to productive use. They have contributed enormously to the rapid growth of per-capita income and the flood of new products that have emerged in the past several centuries. The crucial role of the entrepreneur will be discussed more fully in the following chapter, which will complete the elements of the story of economic growth that was begun in Chapter 16.

Taxing Profits Thus, we can consider profits in excess of market interest rates to be the return on entrepreneurial talent. But this definition is not really very helpful, because no one can say exactly what entrepreneurial talent is. Certainly we cannot measure it; nor can we teach it in a college course, although business schools may try. We do not know whether the observed profit rate provides more than the minimum reward necessary to attract entrepreneurial talent into the market. This relationship between observed profit rates and minimum necessary rewards is crucial when we start to consider the policy ramifications of taxes on profits—a contentious issue, indeed. Consider a profits tax levied on oil companies. If oil companies earn profits well above the minimum required to attract entrepreneurial talent, those profits contain a large element of economic rent. In that case, we could tax away these excess profits (rents) without fear of reducing oil production. In contrast, if oil company profits do not include economic rents, then a windfall profits tax can seriously curtail oil exploration and, hence, production. This example illustrates the general problem of deciding how heavily governments should tax profits. Critics of big business who call for high, if not confiscatory, profits taxes seem to believe that profits are mostly economic rent. If they are wrong—if, in fact, most of the observed profits are necessary to attract people into entrepreneurial roles— then a high profits tax can be dangerous. Such a tax would threaten the very lifeblood of the capitalist system. Business lobbying groups claim, predictably enough, that current tax policy creates precisely this threat. Unfortunately, neither group has offered much evidence to support its conclusion.

CRITICISMS OF MARGINAL PRODUCTIVITY THEORY The theory of factor pricing described in this chapter once again uses supply-demand analysis. Factor pricing theory also relies heavily on the principle of marginal productivity to derive the shape and position of the demand curve for various inputs. Indeed, some economists refer to the analysis (rather misleadingly) as the marginal productivity theory of distribution, when it is, at best, only a theory of the demand side of the pertinent market. Over the years, factor pricing analysis has been subject to attack on many grounds. One frequent accusation, which is largely (but not entirely) groundless, is the assertion that marginal productivity theory merely attempts to justify the income distribution that the capitalist system yields—in other words, that it is a piece of pro-capitalist propaganda. According to this argument, when marginal productivity theory claims that each factor is paid exactly its marginal revenue product, it is only a sneaky way of saying that each factor is paid exactly what it deserves. These critics claim that the theory legitimizes the gross inequities of the system—the poverty of many and the great wealth of a few. This argument is straightforward but wrong. First, payments are made not to factors of production, but rather to the people who happen to own them. If an acre of land earns

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 19

Pricing the Factors of Production

415

$2,000 because that is its marginal revenue product, it does not mean, nor is it meant to imply, that the landlord deserves any particular payment, because he may even have acquired the land by fraud. Second, an input’s MRP does not depend only on “how hard it works” but also on how much of it happens to be employed—because, according to the “law” of diminishing returns, beyond some level of employment, the more of an input that is employed, the lower its MRP. Thus, a factor’s MRP is not and cannot legitimately be interpreted as a measure of the intensity of its “productive effort.” In any event, what an input “deserves,” in some moral sense, may depend on more than what it does in the factory. For example, workers who are sick or have many children may be considered more deserving, even if they are no more productive than their healthy or childless counterparts. On these and other grounds, no economist today claims that marginal productivity analysis shows that distribution under capitalism is either just or unjust. It is simply wrong to claim that marginal productivity theory is pro-capitalist propaganda. The marginal productivity principle is just as relevant to organizing production in a socialist society as it is in a capitalist one. Other critics have attacked marginal productivity theory for using rather complicated reasoning to tell us very little about the really urgent problems of income distribution. In this view, it is all very well to say that everything depends on supply and demand and to express this idea in terms of many complicated equations (many of which appear in more advanced books and articles). But these equations do not tell us what to do about such serious distribution problems as malnutrition among the indigenous populations in Latin America or poverty among minority groups in the United States. Although it does exaggerate the situation somewhat, there is some truth to this criticism. We have seen in this chapter that the theory provides some insights into real policy matters, though not as many as we would like. Later in the book, we will see that economists do have useful things to say about the problems of poverty and underdevelopment, but very little of what we can say about these issues arises out of marginal productivity analysis. Perhaps, in the end, what should be said for marginal productivity theory is this: As the best model we have at the moment, marginal productivity theory offers us some valuable insights into the way the economy works, and until we find a more powerful model, we are better off using the tools that we do have.

| SUMMARY | 1. A profit-maximizing firm purchases the quantity of any input at which the price of the input equals its marginal revenue product (MRP). Consequently, the firm’s demand curve for an input is (the downward-sloping portion of) that input’s MRP curve. 2. Investment in a firm is the amount that is added to the firm’s capital, which is its plant, equipment, inventory, and other productive inputs that tie up the company’s money. 3. Interest rates are determined by the supply of and demand for funds. The demand for funds is a derived demand, because these funds are used to finance business investment whose profitability depends on the demand for the final products turned out with the aid of such investment. In this way, the demand for funds depends on the marginal revenue productivity of capital. 4. A dollar obtainable sooner is worth more than a dollar obtainable later because of the interest that can be earned on that dollar in the interim.

5. Increased demand for a good that needs land to produce it will drive up the price of land either because inferior land will be brought into use or because land will be used more intensively. 6. Rent controls do not significantly affect the supply of land, but they do tend to reduce the supply of buildings. 7. Economic rent is any payment to the supplier of a factor of production that is greater than the minimum amount needed to induce the factor to be supplied. 8. Factors of production that are unique in quality and difficult or impossible to reproduce will tend to be paid relatively high economic rents because of their scarcity. 9. Factors of production that are easy to produce at a constant cost and that are provided by many suppliers will earn little or no economic rent. 10. Economic profits over and above the cost of capital are earned (a) by exercise of monopoly power, (b) as payments for bearing risk, and (c) as the earnings of successful innovation.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

416

Part 5

The Distribution of Income

11. The desirability of increased taxation of profits depends on the taxes’ effects on the supply of managerial talent. If most profits are economic rents, then higher profits taxes will have few undesirable effects. If most profits

are necessary to attract good managers or entrepreneurs into the market, then higher profits taxes can weaken the capitalist economy.

| KEY TERMS | capital

401

derived demand

factors of production 400

innovation

economic profit 412

interest

economic rent 406

invention

entrepreneurship

investment

398

397

413

marginal land

407

marginal physical product (MPP) 398

402

marginal revenue product (MRP) 398

413 401

| TEST YOURSELF | 1. Which of the following inputs do you think include relatively large economic rents in their earnings? a. Nuts and bolts b. Petroleum c. A champion racehorse Use supply-demand analysis to explain your answer. 2. Three machines are employed in an isolated area. They each produce 2,000 units of output per month, the first requiring $20,000 in raw materials, the second $25,000, and the third $28,000. What would you expect to be the monthly charge for the first and second machines if the services of the third machine can be hired at a price of $9,000 per month? Which parts of the charges for the first two machines are economic rent? 3. Economists conclude that a tax on the revenues of firms will be shifted in part to consumers of the products of those firms in the form of higher prices. However, they

believe that a tax on the rent of land usually cannot be shifted and must be paid entirely by the landlord. What explains the difference? (Hint: draw the supply-demand graphs.) 4. Many economists argue that a tax on apartment buildings is likely to reduce the supply of apartments, but that a tax on all land, including the land on which apartment buildings stand, will not reduce the supply of apartments. Can you explain the difference? How is this answer related to the answer to Test Yourself Question 3? 5. Distinguish between investment and capital. 6. Explain the difference between an invention and an innovation. Give an example of each. 7. What is the difference between interest and profit? Who earns interest, in return for what contribution to production? Who earns economic profit, in return for what contribution to production?

| DISCUSSION QUESTIONS | 1. A profit-maximizing firm expands its purchase of any input up to the point where diminishing returns have reduced the marginal revenue product so that it equals the input price. Why does it not pay the firm to “quit while it is ahead,” buying so small a quantity of the input that the input’s MRP remains greater than its price? 2. If you have a contract under which you will be paid $10,000 two years from now, why do you become richer if the rate of interest falls? 3. Do you know any entrepreneurs? How do they earn a living? How do they differ from managers? 4. “Marginal productivity does not determine how much a worker will earn—it determines only how many workers will be hired at a given wage. Therefore, marginal productivity analysis is a theory of demand for labor, not a theory of distribution.” What, then, do you think

determines wages? Does marginal productivity affect their level? If so, how? 5. (More difficult) American savings rates are among the lowest of any industrial country. This has caused concern about our ability to finance new plants and equipment for U.S. industry. Some politicians and others have advocated lower taxes on saving as a remedy. Do you expect such a program to be very effective? Why? 6. If rent constitutes only 2 percent of the incomes of Americans, why may the concept nevertheless be significant? 7. Litigation in which one company sues another often involves costs for lawyers and other court costs literally amounting to hundreds of millions of dollars per case. What does rent have to do with the matter?

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 19

417

Pricing the Factors of Production

| APPENDIX | Discounting and Present Value Frequently in business and economic problems it is necessary to compare sums of money received (or paid) at different dates. Consider, for example, the purchase of a machine that costs $11,000 and will yield a marginal revenue product of $14,520 two years from today. If the machine can be financed by a two-year loan bearing 10 percent interest, it will cost the firm $1,100 in interest at the end of each year, plus $11,000 in repayment of the principal (the amount originally borrowed) at the end of the second year. (See the table that follows.) Is the machine a good investment? Costs and Benefits of Investing in a Machine

End of Year 1 Benefits Marginal revenue product of the machine Costs Interest Repayment of principal on loan Total Cost

End of Year 2

$1.00 $1.00 5 82.64 cents 2 5 11 1 i2 1.21 A similar analysis applies to money received three years from today, four years from today, and so on.

1,100 0 1,100

1,100 11,000 12,100

The general formula for the present value of $1.00 to be received N years from today when the rate of interest is i is

To illustrate the concept of present value, let us ask how much $1 received a year from today is worth in terms of today’s money. If the rate of interest is 10 percent, the answer is about 91 cents. Why? Because if we invest 91 cents today at 10 percent interest, it will grow to 91 cents plus 9.1 cents in interest 5 100.1 cents in a year. That is, at the end of a year a payment of $100 will leave the recipient about as well off as he would have been if he had instead received $91 now. Similar considerations apply to any rate of interest. In general: If the rate of interest is i, the present value of $1 to be received in a year is

$1.00 11 1 i2

What about money to be received two years from today? Using the same reasoning, and supposing the interest rate is 10 percent so that 11i 5 1.1, $1.00 invested today will grow to $1.00 times (1.1) 5 $1.10 after one year and will grow to $1.00 times (1.1) times (1.1) 5 $1.00 times (1.1)2 5 $1.21 after two years. Consequently, the present value of $1.00 to be received two years from today is

$14,520

The process that has been invented for making the magnitudes of payments at different dates comparable to one another is called discounting, or computing the present value.

This is so, because in a year

$1.00 $1.00 $1.00 1 3i5 3 1 1 1 i 2 5 $1 11 1 i2 11 1 i2 11 1 i2

$0

The total costs of owning the machine over the twoyear period ($1,100 1 $12,100 5 $13,200) are less than the total benefits ($14,520). But this is clearly an invalid comparison, because the $14,520 in future benefits is not worth $14,520 in terms of today’s money. Adding up dollars received (or paid) at different dates is a bit like adding apples and oranges.

$1.00 11 1 i2

will grow to the original amount plus the interest payment; that is,

$1.00 11 1 i2 N

The present value formula is based on the two variables that determine the present value of any future flow of money: the rate of interest (i) and the amount of time you have to wait before you get it (N). Let us now apply this analysis to our example. The present value of the $14,520 revenue is easy to calculate because it all comes two years from today. Because the rate of interest is assumed to be 10 percent (i 5 0.1), we have:

$14,520 1 1.1 2 2 $14,520 5 1.21 5 $12,000

Present value of revenues 5

The present value of the costs is a bit trickier in this example because costs occur at two different dates. The present value of the first interest payment is

$1,100 $1,100 5 5 $1,000 11 1 i2 1.1 The present value of the final payment of interest plus principal is

$12,100 $12,100 5 $10,000 2 5 11 1 i2 1 1.1 2 2

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

418

Part 5

The Distribution of Income

Now that we have expressed each sum in terms of its present value, it is permissible to add them up. So the present value of all costs is

Present value of costs 5 $1,000 1 $10,000

Comparing this figure to the $12,000 present value of the revenues clearly shows that the machine really is a good investment. We can use the same calculation procedure for all investment decisions.

5 $11,000

| SUMMARY | 1. To determine whether a loss or a gain will result from a decision whose costs and returns will come at several different periods of time, we must discount all the figures represented by these gains and losses to obtain their present value.

3. We then combine the present values of all the returns and all the costs. If the sum of the present values of the returns is greater than the sum of the present values of the costs, then the decision to invest will promise a net gain.

2. For discounting purposes, we use the present value formula for X dollars receivable N years from now with an interest rate i:

Present value 5

X 11 1 i2 N

| KEY TERM | discounting, or computing the present value 417

| TEST YOURSELF | 1. Compute the present value of $1,000 to be received in three years if the rate of interest is 11 percent. 2. A government bond pays $100 in interest each year for three years and also returns the principal of $1,000 in the

third year. How much is it worth in terms of today’s money if the rate of interest is 8 percent? If the rate of interest is 12 percent?

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Labor and Entrepreneurship: The Human Inputs Octavius (a wealthy young Englishman): “I believe most intensely in the dignity of labor.” The chauffeur: “That’s because you never done any.” GEORGE BERNARD SHAW, MA N A ND SUPER MA N , ACT I I

“O for a muse of fire that would ascend/ The brightest heaven of invention” WI L L I AM SHAKE SP EARE, HENRY V, ACT I , S CE N E I

T

wo human factors of production can be credited with major contributions to a nation’s production and economic growth—the labor force and the entrepreneurs. The former contribute the physical and mental effort required for production. The latter organize the workers’ efforts and ensure that they are provided with the capital and the raw materials their activities require. They also find new ways to carry out these processes, invent new products, and find new markets in which to sell them. We begin this chapter with a discussion of the economics of labor activity, and then we will turn to the entrepreneurs.

C O N T E N T S PART 1: THE MARKETS FOR LABOR PUZZLE: ENTREPRENEURS EARN LESS THAN MOST PEOPLE THINK—WHY SO LITTLE?

WAGE DETERMINATION IN COMPETITIVE MARKETS The Demand for Labor and the Determination of Wages Influences on MRPL: Shifts in the Demand for Labor Technical Change, Productivity Growth, and the Demand for Labor The Service Economy and the Demand for Labor

THE SUPPLY OF LABOR Rising Labor-Force Participation An Important Labor Supply Conundrum The Labor Supply Conundrum Resolved

WHY DO WAGES DIFFER? Labor Demand in General Labor Supply in General Investment in Human Capital Teenagers: a Disadvantaged Group in the Labor Market

UNIONS AND COLLECTIVE BARGAINING Unions as Labor Monopolies Monopsony and Bilateral Monopoly Collective Bargaining and Strikes

PART 2: THE ENTREPRENEUR: THE OTHER HUMAN INPUT

Fixed Costs and Public Good Attributes in Invention and Entrepreneurship Discriminatory Pricing of an Innovative Product over Its Life Cycle Negative Financial Rewards for Entrepreneurial Activity?

PUZZLE RESOLVED: WHY ARE

ENTREPRENEURIAL EARNINGS SURPRISINGLY LOW?

INSTITUTIONS AND THE SUPPLY OF INNOVATIVE ENTREPRENEURSHIP

ENTREPRENEURSHIP AND GROWTH The Entrepreneur’s Prices and Profits

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

420

Part 5

The Distribution of Income

PART 1: THE MARKETS FOR LABOR

160

Index 1959 = 100

140 120 100 80 60 40 20 0 1909 1919 1929

F I GURE 1 Index of Trends in Wages, Compensation, and Work Hours, 1909–2005 (in Real, Inflation-Adjusted Terms)

PUZZLE:

ENTREPRENEURS EARN LESS THAN MOST PEOPLE THINK—WHY SO LITTLE?

The most obvious incentive for innovative entrepreneurs to devote the time, effort, and investment to innovative activity is the great wealth and enormous prestige that success in their undertaking appears to promise, as in the case of superstar inventors such as Eli Whitney, James Watt, Elias Singer, Thomas Edison, the Wright Brothers, etc. But a healthy dose of reality may be in order. Thomas Astebro* reports on the basis of a sample of 1,091 inventions that, “only between 7–9 percent reach the market. Of the 75 inventions that did, six received returns above 1400 percent, 60 percent obtained negative returns and the median was negative” (p. 226).

SOURCE: © Library of Congress - digital version copyright Science Faction / Getty Images

180

SOURCES: Constructed by the authors from data in U.S. Census Bureau, Historical Statistics of the United States, Colonial Times to 1970 (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office; 1975); Economic Report of the President (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office; various years); and U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics, http://www.bls.gov.

200

Labor costs account for by far the largest share of gross domestic product (GDP). As noted in Chapter 19, the earnings of labor amount to almost three-quarters of national income. Wages also represent the primary source of personal income for the vast majority of Americans. For more than a century, wages were the centerpiece of the American dream. In almost every decade, the purchasing power of a typical worker’s earnings grew substantially, and the U.S. working class evolved into a comfortable middle class—the envy of the world and an irresistible lure for millions of immigrants. Then, something changed fundamentally in ways economists do not yet fully understand. Figure 1 shows that average real wages (wages adjusted for changes in the purchasing power of the dollar) stopped their upward march around 1973 and, by Hourly compensation (wages plus benefits) some (disputed) calculations, even declined. In contrast, hourly Hourly wages compensation (wages plus fringe benefits) did not fall. Fringe benefits include things like health insurance, retirement payments, and education subsidies that emHours worked ployers provide to their employper week ees. But compensation growth did slow markedly.1 The graph also shows that average hours worked per week have declined by almost 35 percent since the early 1900s, 1939 1949 1959 1969 1979 1989 2005 even when wages and compensation were increasing. (The big drop in hours worked during the 1930s was a consequence of the Great Depression, and the sharp rise in hours worked during the 1940s was attributable to World War II.) During most of the 1990s, average hours worked per week remained virtually constant, then, after 2000, started to drop slowly once again.

The sharp increases in compensation over the years reflect, at least in part, the rising cost of services such as health care, rather than an increase in the quantity and quality of benefits provided to workers. We explored the reasons for the rising costs of services in Chapter 15.

1

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 20

Labor and Entrepreneurship: The Human Inputs

Perhaps even more striking is the recent work of economist William Nordhaus.** “Using data from the U.S. non-farm business section, I estimate that innovators are able to capture about 2.2 percent of the total [benefits of] innovation . . . the rate of profit on [their investments] over the 1948–2001 period is estimated to be 0.19 percent per year” (p. 34). So we see that the innovative entrepreneur’s activities are a lottery that offers just a few mega-prizes, like so many of the lotteries that capture the headlines. An innovator’s activity is much like a mega-lottery, or like the pursuit of an occupation that offers a limited number of superstar positions. A very well-recognized attribute of lotteries is their built-in unfairness. The average payout is sure to be less than the per-ticket-holder take of the lottery operator—that is why he is in the business. The evidence does indeed support the hypothesis that the inventors and the entrepreneurs are characterized by a degree of optimism well above the norm. Research shows that they are inclined to believe, much more than other people do, that they really are likely to win the grand prize of the lottery. But that is hardly the end of the story. Each of these activities—innovative entrepreneurship and the purchase of lottery tickets—also provides an important payoff of a second sort. Both activities offer distinct psychological rewards in contemplating the prospects of glory, of wealth and fame, yielding the pleasure and excitement of anticipation, even if the winnings never materialize. They are, indeed, the stuff that dreams are made of. * Astebro, Thomas, “The Return to Independent Invention: Evidence of Unrealistic Optimism, Risk Seeking or Skewness Loving,” The Economic Journal, January 2003, pp. 226–238. ** Nordhaus, William D., “Schumpeterian Profits in the American Economy: Theory and Measurement,” Working Paper 10433, Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research, 2004.

Slowing wage growth has been accompanied by an expanding income gap between the rich and the poor, as will be discussed in Chapter 21. In 2008, the income share of the poorest fifth of households was about 3.4 percent of the U.S. total, whereas the richest fifth’s income share had reached about 50 percent.2 As of 2005, more than one in five American children lives in poverty, a rate about twice as high as in the big economies of Western Europe.3 Along with this, the prospective gap between your income as a future college graduate and the incomes of your contemporaries who have not attended college has widened sharply. For instance, in 1973 male college graduates earned about 38 percent more than their high school–educated counterparts, and female college graduates earned about 50 percent more than their high school–educated counterparts. By 2005, college-educated men and women were earning about 80 percent more and 72 percent more, respectively, than men and women with only high school educations.4 As of 2007, median annual income for high school graduates in the United States was $27,000. In comparison, college graduates earned $47,000 and those with advanced degrees earned $61,000. These developments have profound and distressing implications for the future of our society as a whole. We will discuss some of the possible causes later in the chapter.

WAGE DETERMINATION IN COMPETITIVE MARKETS To understand such labor issues, we must first investigate how wages are determined. In a completely free labor market, wages (the price of labor) would be determined by supply and demand, just like any other price. On the demand side, we would find that the demand curve for labor is derived like the demand curve for any other input—by labor’s marginal revenue product, in the manner described in Chapter 19. However, the labor market has a number of distinctive features on the supply side. U.S. Census Bureau, “Income, Poverty, and Health Insurance Coverage in the United States: 2008,” September 2009, accessed online at: http://www.census.gov. 3 United Nations Children’s Fund, “Child Poverty in Rich Countries 2005,” Innocenti Report Card, no. 6 (2005), Florence, Italy: Innocenti Research Center, accessed online at: http://www.unicef.org. 4 Lawrence Mishel, Jared Bernstein, and Sylvia Allegretto, The State of Working America, 2006/2007 (Ithaca, N.Y: ILR Press, Cornell University Press, 2007), http://www.epi.org; and U.S. Census Bureau, “Educational Attainment in the United States: 2007,” January 2009, accessed online at: http://www.census.gov. 2

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

421

422

The Distribution of Income

Part 5

Though the labor market is generally far from perfectly competitive, we start our investigation by describing the theory of competitive labor markets in which the buyers are large numbers of tiny firms and the sellers are individual workers who act independently of one another. In this model, both buyers and sellers are too small to have any choice but to accept the wage rate determined by the impersonal forces of supply and demand.

The Demand for Labor and the Determination of Wages Much of what we can say about the demand for labor was already said about the demand for inputs in general in earlier chapters. Workers are hired (primarily) by profit-maximizing firms, which hire an input quantity at which the input’s price (the market wage) equals its marginal revenue product (MRP). In this chapter, MRPL is the abbreviation we will use for the marginal revenue product of labor. Recall that MRPL is the addition to the firm’s revenue that it obtains by hiring one additional worker. It is equal to the additional amount that worker produces (the worker’s marginal physical product, or MPP) multiplied by the price of that product. In other words, to determine how much additional money that S worker brings in, we multiply the amount she produces by the price of the commodity she produces.5 If the MRPL exceeds the price of labor (the wage), by the usual reasoning of marginal analysis the firm can increase its profit by hiring at least one more worker either to produce more output or to substitute for some other input. The E reverse is true when the MRPL is less than its wage. Thus, the derived demand and, consequently, the demand curve for labor are determined by labor’s marginal revenue product. Such a demand curve is shown as the blue curve DD in Figure 2. The figure also includes a brick-colored supply D curve, labeled SS. Since in a competitive labor market equilibrium will be at the wage that equates the quantity sup500,000 plied with the quantity demanded, equilibrium occurs at point E, where demand curve DD crosses supply curve SS. Number of Workers The equilibrium wage is $300 per week and equilibrium employment is 500,000 workers. Here because 500,000 workers will be employed at a wage of $300 per week, the total income of the workers will be $300 3 0.5 million 5 $150 million.

The marginal revenue product of labor (MRPL) is the increase in the employer’s total revenue that results when it hires an additional unit of labor.

Weekly Wage

D

$300

S

F I GURE 2 Equilibrium in a Competitive Labor Market

Influences on MRPL: Shifts in the Demand for Labor

Investment in human capital is any expenditure on an individual that increases that person’s future earning power or productivity.

What determines MRPL ? The answer offers some important insights about the labor market. Some obvious influences can change labor’s MRP. For example, increased education can improve the ability of the labor force to master difficult technology, raising MRP. Economists use the phrase investment in human capital to refer to spending on education and other means to increase labor’s knowledge and skills. Such spending is analogous to investment in the firm’s plant and equipment because both are outlays today that increase production both now and in the future. Workers can also improve their skills through experience, called on-the-job training, and in a variety of ways that give them added information and increase their mental and physical dexterity. Because the demand for labor is a derived demand, anything that enhances the demand for the goods and services that labor produces can shift the labor demand curve upward. So in a period of economic prosperity when consumers will have more to spend, their demand for products will shift upward, which in turn will raise the price of the worker’s 5

To review, see Chapter 7, pages 130–131.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 20

423

Labor and Entrepreneurship: The Human Inputs

product, thereby shifting upward the MRP curve—the demand for labor. That, of course, is why unemployment is always low during a period of prosperity.

Technical Change, Productivity Growth, and the Demand for Labor Another critical influence on the MRPL is the quality and quantity of the other inputs used by workers. Especially important is innovation that improves machinery, power sources, and other productive instruments that adds to what can be produced by a given amount of labor, and so crucially affects the levels of wages and employment. Technical change that increases the worker’s productivity has two effects that work in opposite directions. First, increased productivity clearly implies an increase in the worker’s marginal physical product—the quantity of widgets that an additional worker can produce will rise. Second, because of the resulting reduction in labor cost and the increased output of widgets, we can expect that when productivity rises, widget prices will fall. Now recall that Marginal revenue product of labor in widget production 5 5 price of widgets multiplied by the worker’s marginal widget output: MRP 5 P (of widgets) 3 MPP

Because an increase in productivity raises MPP but reduces P, we cannot be sure of the net effect on MRP—that is, the net effect on the demand curve for labor.6 PRODUCTIVITY GROWTH: Productivity Growth Is (Almost) Everything in the Long Run In the long run, rising productivity has always improved the standard of living for both workers and the owners of other factors of production. As we indicated in one of our Ideas for Beyond the Final Exam, in the long run nothing contributes more to the economic wellbeing of the nation than rising productivity. Today workers enjoy far longer lives, better health, more education, and more luxury goods than they did a century ago or in any previous period in history. The fact that an hour of labor today can produce a large multiple of what our ancestors could create in an hour can increase everyone’s average income. In the short run, labor-saving technological change sometimes cuts employment and holds down wages. Historically, however, in the long run it has not reduced employment. It has raised workers’ incomes and increased real wages. In the United States, in the last century, productivity per hour of labor grew about eightfold, and the purchasing power of the wage a worker earns in an hour was multiplied nearly fivefold.

IDEAS FOR BEYOND THE FINAL EXAM

The Service Economy and the Demand for Labor Although productivity growth has not led to any long-term upward trend in unemployment, it has cut jobs drastically in some parts of the economy, sending the labor force to other economic sectors for employment. Agriculture is the prime example. It has been estimated that at the time of the American Revolution, nearly 90 percent of the U.S. labor force had agricultural jobs and eked out what today would be considered a meager standard of living. Yet today, with just 0.32 percent of the nation’s labor working on farms, the United States produces such a surplus of products that it sometimes seems unmanageable. At first, after the huge drop in farm jobs was under way, the farm workers shifted to manufacturing, as growing U.S. incomes raised demand for industrial products sharply. Then productivity in manufacturing took off, and workers again had to move elsewhere into the service sector of the economy. Indeed, it has transformed the United States into a “service economy,” with more than three-quarters of the labor force employed in services such as telecommunications, software design, health care, teaching, and restaurants.

However, experience shows that, in the very short run, an increase in labor productivity (that is, of labor-saving technology) often causes a downward shift in the demand for labor, which holds down wages. If firms can meet the current demand for their products with 10 percent fewer workers than they needed last year, they will be tempted to “downsize,” which is a polite way of saying that they will fire some workers. This does sometimes occur, so workers’ widespread fear of labor-saving technology is, to some degree, justified.

6

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

424

Part 5

The Distribution of Income

F I GURE 3 90 Service-Sector Jobs as a Percentage of the Total Labor Force

The Growing Share of Service-Sector Jobs in Nine Countries, 1967 and 2003

1967 80

78.3

2003 73.0

74.7

75.2

75.2

70 65.6 62.9

66.6

63.6

60

58.9

58.7 50.8

50

48.8 45.1

44.8

42.8

40

38.3 36.2

30

20 10 0 Italy

Spain

Germany

Japan

France

Canada

U.K.

Sweden

U.S.

SOURCES: Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, Quarterly Labor Force Statistics, various issues; and OECD in Figures, various years, http://www.sourceoecd.org.

It has been argued that this has occurred because other countries are stealing away the U.S. manufacturing business base, but this is simply untrue. As Figure 3 reports, the service sector has become dominant in all the major industrial economies. No industrial economy has been able to avoid it by stealing manufacturing markets away from the others. More relevant to our concerns here is another worry: that the workers driven from manufacturing into the service sector of the economy have predominantly become low-paid dishwashers and hamburger flippers. That is true in some cases, but the majority of new service jobs created in the past half-century are in the information sector of the economy, including computation, research, and teaching, all occupations requiring both education and specialized skills.

THE SUPPLY OF LABOR We turn next to labor supply, which has undergone several significant labor supply trends in recent decades. First, the expansion of the total labor force has continued, much of it ascribable to sheer growth of the nation’s population. From this, the number of jobholders has grown—from about 60 million jobholders right after World War II to about 145 million in 2008. Second, the proportion of the population with jobs has also grown, from about 58 percent after World War II to 65.2 percent in 2009. This is called a rise in labor force participation. Third, there are new groups of workers, notably women, who today hold proportionately more jobs (46 percent of the workforce) than before (except in wartime). Finally, the labor supply conditions have been affected by a continued and large relative decline in union membership. There has been a significant fall in the share of American workers who belong to unions, whose stated purpose is to protect their interests. Unions seek to bargain for all the workers in a firm or an industry, thus eliminating competition among workers over jobs and wages, and we will consider them later in this chapter. First, we discuss some other supply-side influences.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 20

Labor and Entrepreneurship: The Human Inputs

Rising Labor-Force Participation One significant development in labor supply in the industrial countries is the increase in the number of family members who hold jobs. In 2008, 66 percent of the 59 million American married-couple families had two wage earners, compared with only 40 percent in 1970.7 It used to be that the “head of the household” (usually the husband) was ordinarily the only breadwinner. Today, however, married women also hold jobs. This is in part attributable to lagging wages, forcing both heads of the family into gainful employment. Rapidly rising medical costs and costs of education add to these financial pressures. Participation in the labor force has increased for other reasons as well: liberation of women from their traditional role in the family, and progress in education of minorities that increased their job opportunities. Not so long ago, an African-American executive in a major business firm was unheard of, and an employed wife was considered disgraceful because it implied that her husband could not support her properly. Today this has changed drastically, although discrimination is by no means over. These changes have affected the labor market. For a while the increase in supply may have held back wages. This is, of course, what the usual supply-demand graph for a labor market tells us—when the supply curve of labor shifts to the right, the price of labor (that is, the wage) can be expected to fall. Second, it has been argued that a combination of discrimination and the initial lack of experience of these new entrants into the labor market (which temporarily reduced their MRPL) had a similar effect. Discrimination against women or African-American or Hispanic workers in the labor market can force them to accept wages lower than those paid to white male employees with comparable ability (as will be discussed more fully in the appendix to the next chapter, Chapter 21). Lack of experience can have a similar effect, but for a reason that is less objectionable: If workers acquire skill through experience on the job (on-the-job training), then, on the average, inexperienced workers can be expected to have lower MRPL, so the demand curve for the inexperienced workers will also be low, and lower wages will follow.

An Important Labor Supply Conundrum For most commodities, an increase in their prices leads to an increase in the quantities supplied, whereas a price decline reduces the amounts supplied; that is, supply curves slope upward. But the striking historical trends in labor supply tell a very different story. Supply has tended to fall when wages rose and to rise when wages fell. Throughout the first three-quarters of the twentieth century, real wages rose, as Figure 1 clearly showed. Yet labor asked for and received reductions in the length of the workday and workweek. At the beginning of the century, the standard workweek was 50 to 60 hours (with virtually no vacations). Since then, labor hours have generally declined to an average workweek of about 34 hours. In the last two decades, as the rise in real wages has ceased or at least slowed markedly, people have increased the quantity of labor they supply. Where has the common-sense view of this matter gone wrong? Why, as hourly wages rose for 75 years, did workers not sell more of the hours they had available instead of pressing for a shorter and shorter workweek? And why, in recent years, have they sold more of their labor time as real wage rates stopped rising? A simple observation helps us to answer these questions: Given the fixed amount of time in a week, a person’s decision to supply more labor to firms is simultaneously a decision to demand less leisure time for himself. The leisure time can be interpreted simply as what is left over after the time spent at work. Assuming that, deducting the necessary time for eating and sleeping, a worker has 90 usable hours in a week, then a decision to spend 40 of those hours working is simultaneously a decision to demand 50 of them for other purposes. 7

U.S. Census Bureau, Current Population Survey, http://www.census.gov.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

425

426

Part 5

The Distribution of Income

This offers us a substantial insight into the relationship between wages and labor supply. Economists say that a rise in wages has two effects on the worker’s demand for leisure—the substitution effect and the income effect, that tell us a good deal about the labor market. The substitution effect of a wage increase is the resulting incentive to work more because of the higher relative reward to labor.

1. Substitution Effect The substitution effect of an increase in the price of any good is the resulting switch of customers to a substitute product whose price has not risen. An increase in the price of fish, for example, can lead consumers to buy more meat. The same is true of wages and the demand for leisure. For instance, if you decide not to work overtime this weekend, the price you pay for that increase in leisure (the opportunity cost) is the amount of wage you have to give up as a result. An increase in wages makes leisure more expensive. So a wage increase can induce workers to buy less leisure time (and more of other things). Thus: The substitution effect of higher wages leads most workers to want to work more.

2. Income Effect An increase in the price of any good, other things equal, clearly inThe income effect of a rise in wages is the resulting rise of workers’ purchasing power that enables them to afford more leisure.

creases the real incomes of sellers of the good. That rise in income affects the amount of the good (as well as the amounts of other items) that the individual demands. This indirect effect of a price change on demand, called the income effect of the price change, is especially important in the case of wages. Higher wages make consumers richer. We expect this increased wealth to raise the demand for most goods, including leisure. So: The income effect of higher wages leads most workers to want to work less (that is, demand more leisure), whereas the income effect of lower wages makes them want to work more.

Putting these two effects together, we conclude that some workers may react to an increase in their wage rate by wanting to work more, whereas others may react by wanting to working less. For the market as a whole, therefore, higher wages can lead to either a larger or a smaller quantity of labor supplied. Statistical studies of this issue in the United States have arrived at the following conclusions: F I GURE 4 A Typical Labor Supply Schedule

Income effects outweigh substitution effects

Wage Rate (in dollars)

B

Income effects balance substitution effects A

Substitution effects outweigh income effects

Quantity of Labor Supplied (in hours)

• The response of labor supply to wage changes is not very strong for most workers. • For low-wage workers, the substitution effect seems clearly dominant, so they work more when wages rise. • For high-wage workers, the income effect just about offsets the substitution effect, so they do not work more when wages rise. Figure 4 depicts these approximate “facts.” It shows labor supply rising (slightly) as wages rise up to point A, as substitution effects outweigh income effects. Thereafter, labor supply is roughly constant as wages rise and income effects become just as important as substitution effects up to point B. At still higher wages, above point B, income effects may overwhelm substitution effects, so that rising wages can even cut the quantity of labor supplied. Thus, it is even possible that when wages are raised high enough, further wage increases will lead workers to purchase more leisure and therefore to work less (see “The Income Effect: Is Time More Valuable Than Money?” on the next page). The supply curve of labor is

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 20

427

Labor and Entrepreneurship: The Human Inputs

“Time is now more valuable than money wherever you stand on the career ladder, according to a survey of more than 1,000 junior and senior professionals. The survey, by Universum, found that 40 per cent of junior employees—those with one to eight years’ work experience—and 50 per cent of senior professionals—with more than eight years’ experience—ranked flexible working hours as the most attractive perk that an employer could offer. This compares with 31 per cent of junior staff and 36 per cent of senior staff who put competitive compensation first. Workers are placing increasing importance on their personal lives and are not afraid to make demands of their employers, the survey shows. Work-life balance is No. 1 on the list of short-term career goals for 43 per cent of junior staff and 60 per cent of more senior staff. . . . Employers are aware that workers’ demands are changing. ‘Money is no longer what drives people,’ says Sasha Hardman, the HR associate director of Allen & Overy, a law firm. ‘They want interesting work, the opportunity to progress, to work with interesting people and a good work-life balance. . . .’”

SOURCE: © 2010 Pixland/Jupiterimages

The Income Effect: Is Time More Valuable Than Money?

SOURCE: Excerpted from Clare Dight, “It’s No Longer Just About the Money, You Know,” The Times (of London), January 17, 2008, p. 8.

then said to be backward-bending, as illustrated by the broken portion of the curve above point B in Figure 4. Does this theory of labor supply apply to college students? A study of the hours worked by students at Princeton University found that it does.8 Estimated substitution effects of higher wages on the labor supply of Princeton students were positive and income effects were negative, just as the theory predicts. Apparently, substitution effects outweighed income effects by a slim margin, so that higher wages attracted a somewhat greater supply of labor. Specifically, a 10 percent rise in wages increased the hours of work of the Princeton student body by about 3 percent.

A supply curve of labor is backward-bending when a rise in an initially low wage leads to a rise in quantity of labor supplied, but a rise in a wage that was already high reduces the amount supplied.

The Labor Supply Conundrum Resolved We can now answer our earlier question: Why is it that, historically, rising wages have reduced labor supply and falling wages have increased it? Rising wages enable the worker to provide for her family with fewer hours of work. As a result, the worker can afford to purchase more leisure without a cut in living standards. Thus, the income effect of increasing wages induces workers to work fewer hours. Similarly, falling wages reduce the worker’s income. To preserve the family’s living standard, she must seek additional hours of work; and the worker’s spouse may have to leave their children in day care and take a job. Thus, it is the strong income effect of rising wages that apparently accounts for the fact that labor supply has responded in the “wrong” direction, with workers working evershorter hours as real wages rose and longer hours as wages fell.

Mary P. Hurley, “An Investigation of Employment among Princeton Undergraduates during the Academic Year,” senior thesis, Department of Economics, Princeton University, May 1975. 8

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

428

Part 5

The Distribution of Income

WHY DO WAGES DIFFER? Earlier in the chapter, we saw how wages are determined in a free-market economy: In a competitive labor market, the equilibrium wage occurs where quantity supplied equals quantity demanded (refer back to Figure 3). In reality, of course, no single wage level applies to all workers. Some workers are paid very well, whereas others are forced to accept meager earnings. We all know that certain groups in our society (the young, the disadvantaged, the uneducated) earn relatively low wages and that some of our most severe social ills (poverty, crime, drug addiction) are related to this fact. But why are some wages so low while others are so high? The explanation is important, because it can help us determine what to do to help poorly paid workers increase their earnings and move up toward the income levels of the more fortunate suppliers of labor. In the most general terms, the explanation of wage differences is the fact that there is not one labor market but many—each with its own supply and demand curves and its own equilibrium wage. Supply-demand analysis implies that wages are relatively high in markets where demand is high relative to supply, as in Figure 5(a). This, however, doesn’t tell us what we need to know about wage differentials. To make the analysis useful, we still must breathe some life into the supply-and-demand curves.

FIGURE 5 Wage Differentials

D1

S1 D2

S2

Wage

Wage

w1

w2 D1

S1

D2

S2 Number of Workers (a)

Number of Workers (b)

Labor Demand in General We start with demand. The demand for labor is greater in some markets than in others because it is guided by workers’ marginal physical product (MPP), and that depends, of course, on the worker’s abilities and degree of effort on the job. But, there is also the influence of the other factors of production that workers use to produce output. Workers in U.S. industry are more productive than workers in many other countries at least partly because they have generous supplies of machinery, natural resources, and technical knowhow, and so they earn high wages. The marginal product of some workers can also be increased relative to that of others by superior education, training, and experience. Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 20

429

Labor and Entrepreneurship: The Human Inputs

Labor Supply in General Turning next to the supply of labor, it is clear that the size of the available working population relative to the magnitude of industrial activity in a given area is important. It helps explain why construction wages soared in New Orleans as a result of the rebuilding efforts after Hurricane Katrina: Demand rose while supply was reduced by the loss of a working population. The nonmonetary attractiveness of any job will also clearly influence the supply of workers to it. Jobs that people find pleasant and satisfying—such as teaching in suburban schools—will attract a large supply of labor and will consequently pay a relatively low wage. In contrast, a premium will have to be paid to attract workers to jobs that are onerous, disagreeable, or dangerous—such as washing the windows of skyscrapers. Finally, the amount of ability and training needed to enter a particular job or profession is relevant to its supply of labor. Brain surgeons and professional ice skaters earn generous incomes because there are few people as highly skilled as they and because it is timeconsuming and expensive to acquire these skills even for those who have the ability.

Investment in Human Capital The idea that education is an investment is likely to be familiar even to students who have never thought explicitly about it. You made a conscious decision to go to college rather than to enter the labor market, and you are probably acutely aware that this decision is now costing you money—lots of money. Think of a high school friend who chose not to go to college and is now working. You are deliberately giving up a chance at a similar income in order to acquire more education. In this sense, your education is an investment in yourself—a human investment. Like a firm that devotes some of its money to build a plant that will yield profits at some future date, you are investing in your own future, hoping that your college education will help you earn more than your high school–educated friend or enable you to find a more pleasant or prestigious job when you graduate. Economists call activities such as going to college investments in human capital because such activities give the person many of the attributes of a capital investment. One implication of human capital theory is that college graduates should earn substantially more than high school graduates to compensate them for their extra investments in schooling. Do they? Your college investment will probably pay off. Indeed, as already noted, college graduates now earn nearly twice as much as their high school-educated peers, and the gap is rising.9 The large income differentials earned by college graduates provide an excellent “return” on the tuition payments and sacrificed earnings that they “invested” while in school.

But what is it about more educated people that makes firms willing to pay them higher wages? Most human capital theorists assume that students in high schools and colleges acquire skills that are productive in the marketplace, thereby raising their marginal revenue products. In this view, educational institutions are factories that take less productive workers as their raw materials, apply doses of training, and create more productive workers as outputs.

Human capital theory focuses on the expenditures that have been made to increase the productive capacity of workers via education or other means. It is analogous to investment in better machines as a way to increase their productivity.

Teenagers: a Disadvantaged Group in the Labor Market As we have observed, the “labor market” is really composed of many submarkets for labor of different types, each with its own supply-and-demand curves. One particular labor market always seems to have higher unemployment than the labor force as a whole: the job market for teenagers. Figure 6 shows that teenage unemployment rates have consistently been much higher than the overall unemployment rate, and black teenagers have fared worse than white 9 U.S. Census Bureau, “Educational Attainment in the United States: 2007,” January 2009, accessed online at: http://www.census.gov.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

430

Part 5

The Distribution of Income

FIGURE 6

50 45 Black male teenagers

40

Unemployment Rate (Percent)

SOURCES: Economic Report of the President (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office; various years); and U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics, http://www.bls.gov.

The Teenage Unemployment Problem

35

30 25

20

White male teenagers

15 10

5 0 1972

All workers

1977

1982

1987

1992

1997

2002 2005

Year

teenagers. For the most part, however, the three unemployment rates have moved up and down together, as the figure shows. The graph indicates that whenever the unemployment rate for all workers goes up or down, the teenage (defined here as a person aged 16 to 19 years) unemployment rate almost always moves in the same direction, but more dramatically. Thus, when things are generally bad, things are much, much worse for teenage workers, and especially for black teenage workers. Despite social and legislative pressures against race discrimination, efforts to improve the quality of education available to children in the inner cities, and many related programs, there has been no relative improvement in black teenage unemployment in recent years. One reason is that teenagers generally have not completed their educations and have little job experience, so their marginal revenue products tend to be relatively low. Until recently, many economists argued that this fact, together with minimum wage laws that prevent teenagers from accepting wages commensurate with their low marginal revenue products, is the main cause of high teenage unemployment. The reasoning is that legally imposed high wages make it too expensive to hire teenagers. Recent studies suggest, however, that a rise in minimum wage produces little, if any, cut in demand for teen labor.

UNIONS AND COLLECTIVE BARGAINING Our analysis of competitive labor markets has so far not dealt with one rather distinctive feature of the markets for labor: The supply of labor is not at all competitive in many labor markets; instead, it is controlled by a labor monopoly, a labor union. Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Labor and Entrepreneurship: The Human Inputs

431

Although they are significant, unions in the United States are not nearly as important as is popularly supposed. For example, most people who are unfamiliar with the data are astonished to learn that less than 13 percent of American workers belong to unions. This percentage is about half of what it was in the heyday of unionism in the mid-1950s. Figure 7 shows that in 1930, unions had enrolled slightly less than 7 percent of the U.S. labor force, and by 1933 this figure had slipped to barely more than 5 percent. Since the 1950s, the unionization rate has fallen with few interruptions. One reason unionization in the United States has been declining is the shift of the U.S. labor force (like that experienced in every other industrial country) into service industries and out of manufacturing, where unions traditionally had their base. In addition, American workers’ preferences seem to have shifted away from unions. The increasing share of women in the labor force may have contributed to this trend, because women have tradi30 tionally been less prone than men to join unions. 25 Finally, American unions came under increasing pres20 sure in the 1990s and early 2000s because of stronger 15 competition both at home and abroad. In response, firm after firm has closed 10 plants and eliminated jobs. This “downsizing” trend 5 has made it even more difficult for unions to win con0 cessions that improve the 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 economic positions of their members. That, in turn, has reduced the attractiveness of union membership. In the United States, union membership levels are much lower than in most other industrialized countries. For example, as of 2007, about 25 percent of German workers and 75 percent of Danish workers belonged to unions.10 The differences are striking and doubtless have something to do with the American tradition of “rugged individualism.” But there are also other influences involved. In the United States, growing conservatism has apparently led to growing hostility toward unions.

A labor union is an organization made up of a group of workers (usually with the same specialization, such as plumbing or costume design, or in the same industry). The unions represent the workers in negotiations with employers over issues such as wages, vacations, and sick leave.

Union Membership as a Percentage of Wage and Salary Workers

SOURCES: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, Employment and Earnings (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office; January issues, various years); and “Union Affiliation” data, Current Population Survey, 2006–2008, http://data.bls.gov.

Chapter 20

1990

2000

2010

FI GURE 7 Unionization in the United States

Unions as Labor Monopolies Unions require that we alter our economic analysis of the labor market in much the same way that monopolies required us to alter our analysis of the goods market (see Chapter 11). Recall that a monopoly seller of goods selects the point on its demand curve that maximizes its profits. Much the same idea applies to a union, which is, after all, a monopoly seller of labor. It too faces a demand curve—derived this time from the marginal revenue product schedules of firms—and can choose the point on that curve that suits it best. The problem for the economist trying to analyze union behavior—and perhaps also for the union leader trying to select a course of action—is how to decide which point on the demand curve is “best” for the union and its members. There is no obvious single goal analogous to profit maximization that clearly determines what a union should do. Instead, there are a number of alternative goals that sound plausible. Small or declining membership may not necessarily be the same thing as declining influence. For example, union membership in France (8 percent of French workers, as of 2007) is lower than in the United States, but unions are much more powerful because of their formal role the French welfare system (Sources: “Déjà vu?: Special Report, Trade Unions,” The Economist magazine, June 7, 2003, http://www.economist.com; and OECD, “Union Members and Employees” data, 2007, accessed online at: http://stats.oecd.org.).

10

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

432

Part 5

The Distribution of Income

The Way It Was The calamitous Triangle Shirtwaist Factory fire of 1911, in which 146 women and girls lost their lives, was a landmark in American labor history. It galvanized public opinion behind the movement to improve conditions, hours, and wages in the sweatshops. Pauline Newman went to work in the factory, located on what is now New York University’s campus, at the age of eight. Many of her friends lost their lives in the fire. She went on to become an organizer and executive of the newly formed International Ladies Garment Workers’ Union. In her words:

One hundred and forty-six people sacrificed, and the judge fined Blank and Harris seventy-five dollars!

The Problem Persists The following newspaper excerpts show that unsafe working conditions continue to produce tragedies, even in this day and age: China Daily (Beijing), February 25, 2006: “At least 65 people were killed and more than 100 hurt when a fire swept through a locked textile factory crowded with night-shift workers in southern Bangladesh. Up to 500 people, mainly women, were believed to be working in the KTS Composite Textile factory in the southern city of Chittagong when the fire broke out on Thursday night, local fire chief Rashedul Islam said. Firefighters had found the main entrance to the factory locked, he said, and were forced to rescue trapped workers by breaking open windows and using ropes. . . . The toll might have been higher, but people working in neighboring factories brought in bamboo ladders and ropes to rescue those trapped on the upper floors, factory security guard Ful Mia said.” SOURCE: © AP Images

We started work at seven-thirty in the morning, and during the busy season we worked until nine in the evening. They didn’t pay you any overtime and they didn’t give you anything for supper money. . . . The employers didn’t recognize anyone working for them as a human being. You were not allowed to sing. . . . We weren’t allowed to talk to each other. . . . If you went to the toilet and you were there longer than the floor lady thought you should be, you would be laid off for half a day and sent home. And, of course, that meant no pay. You were not allowed to have your lunch on the fire escape in the summertime. The door was locked to keep us in. The Daily Record (Scotland), July 9, 2006: That’s why so many people were trapped “Nine people were killed in a chemical when the fire broke out. . . . You were exfactory explosion yesterday—after bosses pected to work every day if they needed locked workers inside. . . . The Triangle Factory, now part of you and the pay was the same whether you The death toll at the factory in Kenya’s New York University worked extra or not. capital Nairobi could rise because police Conditions were dreadful in those days. have not been able to account for all of the 36 people who We didn’t have anything. . . . There was no welfare, no pension, were in the building at the time of the explosion. no unemployment insurance. There was nothing. . . . There was Most of the victims died because the factory owners locked so much feeling against unions then. The judges, when one of them inside the building after the blast, claiming that they our girls came before him, said to her: “You’re not striking wanted to prevent people from stealing valuables. against your employer, you know, young lady. You’re striking Mutinda Nzuki, who was waiting outside to be hired as a against God,” and sentenced her to two weeks. casual worker when the tragedy occurred, said: ‘The doors were all I wasn’t at the Triangle Shirtwaist Factory when the fire broke locked. It was horrific. The screams from inside were horrendous.’” out, but a lot of my friends were. . . . The thing that bothered me was the employers got a lawyer. How anyone could have deSOURCES: Excerpted from Joan Morrison and Charlotte Fox Zabusky (1980), American Mosaic: The Immigrant Experience in the Words of Those Who Lived It (New York: fended them! Because I’m quite sure that the fire was planned E. P. Dutton), reprinted by permission of the publisher, E. P. Dutton, Inc.; from “At for insurance purposes. And no one is going to convince me othLeast 65 Die in Textile Factory Fire,” China Daily, February 25, 2006, accessed online erwise. And when they testified that the door to the fire escape at http://www.chinadaily.com.cn; and from “Nine Dead in Factory Explosion,” The was open, it was a lie! It was never open. Locked all the time. Daily Record (of Scotland), July 9, 2006, p. 23.

The union leadership may, for example, decide that the size of the union is more or less fixed and try to force employers to pay the highest wage they will pay without firing any of the union members. But this tactic is a high-risk strategy for a union. Firms forced to pay such high wages will be at a competitive disadvantage compared with firms that have nonunion labor, and they may even be forced to shut down. Alternatively, union leaders may assign priority to increasing the size of their union. They may even try to make employment as large as possible by accepting a wage just above the competitive level. One way, but certainly not the only way, to strike a balance between the conflicting goals of Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 20

433

Labor and Entrepreneurship: The Human Inputs

maximizing wages and maximizing employment is to maximize the total earnings of all workers taken together.

Monopsony and Bilateral Monopoly Our analysis thus far oversimplifies matters in several important respects. For one thing, it envisions a market situation in which one powerful union is dealing with many powerless employers: We have assumed that the labor market is monopolized on the selling side but is competitive on the buying side. Some industries more or less fit this model. The giant Teamsters’ union negotiates with a trucking industry consisting of thousands of firms, most of them quite small and powerless, and most unions in the construction industry are much larger than the firms. But many cases simply do not fit the model. The huge auto manufacturing corporations do not stand idly by while the United Automobile Workers (UAW) union picks its favorite point on the demand curve for autoworkers. Nor does the steelworkers’ union sit across the bargaining table from representatives of a perfectly competitive industry. In these and other industries, although the union certainly has a good deal of monopoly power over labor supply, the firms also have some monopsony power over labor demand. (A monopsony is a buyer’s monopoly—a case where sellers have only one purchaser for their products.) As a result, the firms may deliberately reduce the quantity of labor they demand as a way to force down the equilibrium level of wages. We can calculate the profit-maximizing restriction of the quantity of labor in the same way that we determined a monopolist’s profitmaximizing restriction of output in Chapter 11. It is difficult to predict the wage and employment decisions that will emerge when both the buying and selling sides of a market are monopolized—a situation called bilateral monopoly. The difficulties here are similar to those we encountered in considering the behavior of oligopolistic industries in Chapter 12. Just as one oligopolist is acutely aware that its rivals are likely to react to anything the oligopolistic employer does, so either side in a bilateral monopoly knows that any move it makes will elicit a countermove by the other. This knowledge makes the first decision that much more complicated. In practice, the outcome of bilateral monopoly depends on economic logic, on the relative power of the union and management, on the skill and preparation of the negotiators, and partly on luck. Still, we can be a bit more concrete about the outcome of the wage determination process under bilateral monopoly. A monopsonist employer unrestrained by a union will use its market power to force wages down below the competitive level, just as a monopoly seller uses its market power to force prices higher. It accomplishes this by reducing its demand for labor below what would otherwise be the profit-maximizing amount, thereby cutting both wages and the number of workers employed. However, a union may be in a position to prevent this decline from happening. It can deliberately set a floor on wages, pledging its members not to work at all at any wage level below this floor, forcing the monopsony employer to pay higher wages and yet hire more workers than the employer otherwise would. In reality, large, oligopolistic firms do often engage in similar one-on-one wage bargaining with the unions of their employees, and the resulting bargaining process closely resembles that of the bilateral monopoly model.

A monopsony is a market situation in which there is only one buyer.

A bilateral monopoly is a market situation in which there is both a monopoly on the selling side and a monopsony on the buying side.

Collective Bargaining and Strikes The process by which unions and management settle on a labor contract is called collective bargaining. Unfortunately, nothing as simple as a supply-demand diagram can tell us what wage level will emerge from a collective bargaining session. Furthermore, actual collective bargaining sessions range over many more issues than just wages. Pensions, health and life insurance, overtime pay, seniority privileges, and work conditions are often crucial issues. Many labor contracts specify in great detail the rights of labor and management to set work conditions—and also provide elaborate procedures for resolving grievances and disputes. The final contract that emerges from collective bargaining may well run to many pages of fine print.

Collective bargaining is the process of negotiation of wages and working conditions between a union and the firms in the industry.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Part 5

The Distribution of Income

F I GURE 8 0.50

Work Time Lost in the United States Because of Strikes, 1948–2004 Percentage of Work Time Lost

0.45 0.40 0.35 0.30 0.25 0.20 0.15 0.10 0.05 0 1948 1953 1958 1963

1968 1973 1978 1983 1988 1993 1998

2004

SOURCES: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, Monthly Labor Review, various issues; and http://www.bls.gov.

434

To force management to accept its demands, unions generally threaten strikes or work slowdowns. Firms may even threaten to close the plant to prevent a strike (called a lockout). Fortunately, strikes are not nearly so common as many people believe. Figure 8 reports the percentage of work time lost as a result of strikes in the United States from 1948 to 2004. This fraction has varied greatly from year to year but has never been very large. The fraction of total work time lost has been under one-tenth of 1 percent since 1979 and has dwindled to insignificance at less than five-hundredths of 1 percent since 2001. Despite the headline-grabbing nature of major national strikes, the total amount of work time lost to strikes is truly trivial—far less, for example, than the time lost to coffee breaks! Compared with other nations, the United States suffers more from strikes than, say, Japan, but it has many fewer strikes than Canada (see Figure 9).

200 190.8 180 160 140 120 100 80 60

55.6

53.1

40 22.7 20

18.7 8.3

0 Canada

United States

Italy

France

1.4 1.3 United Sweden Germany Japan Kingdom

SOURCE: International Labour Office, Yearbook of Labour Statistics, various years, Geneva, Switzerland.

Incidence of Strikes in Eight Industrial Countries, 1996–2000

Days Lost to Strikes per Thousand Workers per Year (5-year average)

F I GURE 9

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 20

Labor and Entrepreneurship: The Human Inputs

PART 2: THE ENTREPRENEUR: THE OTHER HUMAN INPUT We think of the market mechanism as totally unguided—no one designed it and no one controls its operations. That is somewhat misleading, because there is an important category of individuals, the entrepreneurs, who contribute guidance to some critical market activities. Specifically, it is they who organize and establish new firms. Moreover, not only do they design new enterprises but they often use these new firms to introduce innovations that play such a critical part in the economic growth important to living standards described in Chapter 16. Thus, the entrepreneur may be thought of as the secret behind the market’s greatest achievement—unprecedented rates of economic growth. Anyone who creates a new business firm is usually called an “entrepreneur.” Most such new firms are merely repeats of companies that already exist: a new dress manufacturer or a new grocery. But a small proportion of the entrepreneurs are special. They start a business that sells a new product or uses a new production method or opens up in a new market; in short, they innovate. The distinction is critical, because it is only the innovating entrepreneur that we can associate unreservedly with growth of the economy. Generally, they are not inventors themselves, but their prime capability is alertness in recognizing the promising inventions of others and in finding how those inventions have to be adjusted to make them attractive to buyers and to ensure that they are put to effective use.

ENTREPRENEURSHIP AND GROWTH Some historical examples will bring out the importance of innovating entrepreneurs’ contributions. The steam engine is a prime illustration. Many people have the mistaken idea that James Watt invented the steam engine, but there were many steam engines in operation in England decades before Watt’s improvement, which increased the effectiveness and efficiency of a steam engine substantially. Moreover, a working steam engine had long before been constructed by Heron of Alexandria, probably in the first century A.D. But that engine was never put to practical use. Abraham Lincoln tells us that:

SOURCE: © Birmingham Museums and Art Gallery

. . . as much as two thousand years ago the power of steam was not only observed, but an ingenious toy was actually made and put in motion by it, at Alexandria. . . . What appears strange is, that neither the inventor of the toy, nor anyone else, for so long a time afterwards, should perceive that steam would move useful machinery as well as a toy. (Abraham Lincoln, “Lecture on Discoveries and Inventions,” 1858). Why was this machine not put to productive use in Rome? A plausible answer is that there were no innovative entrepreneurs in Rome such as appeared during the Industrial Revolution. Later we will discuss why. Heron, having no entrepreneur partner available to him, evidently sold this and his many other inventions to Roman priests who used these then-astonishing devices to demonstrate the priest’s magical powers to the members of his cult. Contrast this with the case of James Watt, who did have an entrepreneur partner, Matthew Boulton. Boulton went about England selling Watt’s engine to the owners of mines, where they were used to pump out water, their only use at that time. On one sales trip, Boulton discovered, however, that the market for such pumps was saturated—every mine he visited

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

435

436

Part 5

The Distribution of Income

already had a Boulton-Watt pump. Then it came to him that the engine could also do other things, such as running cloth-making machinery and locomotives. He talked Watt into designing the necessary adaptation for these new purposes and, as they say, the rest is history. This is not the only example where entrepreneurship made the difference between productive and nonproductive use of an invention. It is well known that the Chinese many centuries ago produced a flood of great inventions, not only gunpowder but also the wheelbarrow, printing with movable type, the spinning wheel, playing cards, and elaborate clocks, among others. But these inventions, too, escaped widespread and productive use. And there is every reason to conclude that this failure, too, was caused by the absence of interested entrepreneurs like Matthew Boulton.

The Entrepreneur’s Prices and Profits An innovative entrepreneur is someone who introduces into the economy a new product or a new process for producing goods or finds a new market for the sale of commodities or a new way of conducting business.

Just as we did with capital, land, and labor, to understand the economics of innovative entrepreneurship we must investigate its financial arrangements. Since entrepreneurs are generally self-employed, there is no such thing as the “price” of entrepreneurship corresponding to the price of land or the wage of labor, because the services of the entrepreneur are not sold directly to anyone. There are, however, two things that are close to such a concept. First, there is the amount the entrepreneurs earn from their activity and, second, there is the price of the products that they supply and that are affected by their innovations. The following widely cited story explaining the economics of innovative entrepreneurship was originally contributed by the late Harvard economist Joseph Schumpeter. It begins when the alert innovative entrepreneur either creates or recognizes a new and better product, acquires it, and brings it to market, where it makes older substitutes obsolete, in a process described as “creative destruction,” as when the automobile drove the buggy manufacturers out of business. As the first provider of the improved product, the entrepreneur initially faces little or no competition, and the resulting monopoly power enables the entrepreneur to sell the new product at a price that is high relative to its costs and yields abundant profit. This generous profit gets the attention of other individuals with entrepreneurial ambitions, who seek to enter the market with competitive and imitative products. Those imitative products, incidentally, may differ somewhat from our entrepreneur’s to avoid patent problems but are close enough to the original to attract customers. This competitive entry first reduces and finally brings to an end the temporary excess of price over the competitive level that was initially enjoyed by the entrepreneur. Now, with only zero economic profits available from his first innovation, the entrepreneur is forced to look for other inventive products to bring to market, in hopes of continuing to earn more than zero economic profits. Thus, there is no rest for the innovators. They can never afford to be satisfied with their past achievements if they want their stream of temporary high profits to continue. Yesterday’s invention soon is ancient history, and unless successor inventions are introduced soon enough by the inventor-entrepreneur partners, rivals will indeed succeed in entering and even taking over the market and will dry up the initial entrepreneur’s stream of profits. So the entrepreneurs have no choice. They must seek to generate a stream of innovations, and that is one key part of the free-market’s success story—the market provides a mechanism designed to change innovation from an occasional happening with a large element of accident into a systematic process that ensures, so far as ingenuity and current knowledge permit, the injection of a stream of inventions into the economy, one after another.11

This scenario seems to tell us that the entrepreneur’s activity offers him a stream of profits above the competitive level. But we will see that the real story is considerably different. It will be shown that, in equilibrium, the high initial earnings that inventors and innovative entrepreneurs obtain (if they are lucky) will often just enable them to recoup the R&D expenses they underwent in creating the product and the amounts they had to spend in bringing the novel product to market.

11

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 20

Labor and Entrepreneurship: The Human Inputs

Fixed Costs and Public Good Attributes in Invention and Entrepreneurship There are two special features of invention that are essential for full understanding of its economics: first, the fixed-cost characteristic of the required R&D expenditures and many of the other costs entailed in bringing an invention to market successfully and, second, the public good attribute of invention. The first of these refers to the fact that once the entrepreneur has spent the R&D funding necessary to create an invention and to improve it sufficiently to make it a market success and the amount needed to bring the novelty to the attention of consumers, these amounts of money will be fixed—this quantity of money will be the same whether the product has 500 purchasers or 5 million. The amount of metal the new product uses will clearly have a positive marginal cost—the greater the number of buyers who purchase it, the more metal the manufacturer of the item will require. But the added sales will not require any additional R&D expenditures. The marginal R&D costs will be zero. The total cost of acquiring the information is the same, whether the idea is used by 100 people or a million. Second, and related to this, the information that underlies the invention is what economists call “a public good.” It will be recalled from the discussion in Chapter 15 (pages 316–318) that this kind of good is one such that none of it is used up (depleted) when an additional person uses it. Unlike the nation’s wheat inventory, which goes down every time some bread is eaten, another reading of the specifications of an invention does not reduce the amount of information it contains. In this sense, all information is a public good—its supply is not depleted by an increase in the number of people who use it. Now, both of these attributes mean that there is a significant portion of the cost of an invention that is totally absent from marginal cost. If more people buy the new product or more people use its specifications, that does not increase the firm’s R&D cost or any other similar cost elements, and since marginal cost is by definition that addition to cost that results from an increase of the output of a product, there is no portion of R&D, or the other similar costs, that is included in the firm’s MC figure. This has several implications. First, invention cannot be successful financially if the price is set equal to marginal cost, as must happen in a perfectly competitive market (see Chapter 10, pages 200–201 to review this). Such a price would not cover any of the R&D cost and the related outlays, which, as we have just seen, are entirely absent from the marginal cost of an innovation. So for innovative products, P 5 MC is a recipe for financial loss and disaster in an innovative firm established by an innovative entrepreneur. Second, this means that what appear to be initial monopoly profits in Schumpeter’s scenario may only be the amount of revenue needed to cover those fixed R&D costs and any similar outlays. Indeed, in a perfectly competitive market in which there is innovation, that is precisely what we must expect. Assuming that just about anyone can start an invention project in her garage or basement, we would expect, for the usual reason, that entry by inventors and entrepreneurs competing for market share will continue so long as there are economic profits to be earned. This entry, as in the usual story, will drive prices down to the point where the expected revenues will just cover all the costs, including the fixed R&D costs and no more. That, theoretically, will be the long-run equilibrium of the market, and Schumpeter’s initial “monopoly earnings” will just be the form taken by recovery of the R&D costs, and zero economic profits to inventors as a group is exactly what they can expect to earn on average. For good reason, this is now the story generally accepted by economic theorists. And, as we will see next, it can lead us to even further insights than have so far been described.

Discriminatory Pricing of an Innovative Product over Its Life Cycle There are, of course, also reasons other than growing competition by imitators of a successful new product that account for its typically declining cost and falling price. Obviously, experience will teach its suppliers how to produce the novel item more efficiently so that its cost will often be lowered by ever-improved technology. Moreover, if the

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

437

438

Part 5

The Distribution of Income

product turns out to please or even excite consumers (see the story of the iPhone on page 339 in Chapter 16), costs may also be reduced by economies of scale offered by machinery with larger capacity and other cost-saving attributes. The other accepted scenario, the one that we have just gone over, tells us that the price of an innovative product will initially be high and then will gradually be driven down by competition until there comes a point in its lifetime when it brings in no further profits. But that is only a vague description of these prices. Can we provide an analysis that provides a more specific formula to determine those magnitudes at the times that intervene between these two dates? The answer is that if the market is competitive, standard economic analysis does, indeed, enable us to do so to the extent that we could explain the other price decisions of the firm in earlier chapters. To understand this we must first recall the concept of discriminatory prices and the way in which such prices are determined by a profit-maximizing firm. It will be recalled that when the firm sells the same product to one group of customers at a lower price than it sells it to another, even though it costs exactly the same to serve the two groups, the prices that are charged are called “discriminatory.” Now firms can and do discriminate in price between groups on the basis of some of their attributes, for example, using senior-citizen discounts. They also sometimes discriminate between locations, charging lower prices in cities where they face more competition. Finally, they can discriminate between customers who buy at different times, as when they charge more for a necklace the day before Christmas than the day after the holiday. A moment’s thought shows that this last story involves discrimination between different dates: high prices before competition for a new product arrives in the market and everlower prices at later dates as more and more competitors enter. We see that the logic is the same as the discrimination between cities with different numbers of competitors. Moreover, we saw earlier in the book that there is a formula that gives us the profitmaximizing prices when those prices are discriminatory. That formula was straightforward: If the firm is charging different prices to two groups of customers, it should supply to each group that quantity, Q, at which marginal revenue from these sales is equal to marginal cost. Then, to determine the profit-maximizing price for each of the two customer groups, just examine each group’s demand curve for the product and select the price that will just induce the customers in each group to purchase the quantity of the product at which its MC 5 MR and is therefore profit maximizing. The logic is exactly the same as we have already used many times before. If for either group its own MR is not equal to MC, it will raise the firm’s profit to ship (at least) a little more or a little less to those customers, depending on whether MR or MC is the larger.12

There is more that we can learn about those prices, which fit right in with the less analytical story that was told in the previous section. Here, we start off by recalling two other conclusions we have encountered before: (1) Other things being equal, the less competition there is in a market, the less elastic the firm’s demand curve will be, for reasons that will soon be recalled; and (2) other things being equal, as will be shown again, the less elastic the demand of a group of customers, the higher the profit-maximizing price will be. What these two observations lead us to conclude is fully consistent with the story, but with the difference that we have just obtained a formula to derive those profit-maximizing prices. What these two conclusions show, as Schumpeter argued, is that when an innovation is first brought to market, because competition is sparse or nonexistent at first, the demand for the new product can be expected to be (significantly) less elastic than it becomes later, when more competition appears. Then, from the other of the two preceding conclusions, this tells us that in the early days, just after the new product comes to market the profit-maximizing MC 5 MR price will be higher than that price will become later. To complete this analysis, we need only two observations about competition, elasticity and prices that underlie the story. The logic of these observations is simple and easy to explain intuitively. First, when there are few or no competitors the firm can raise its price without driving many customers into the arms of rivals. But this is just another way of saying that when competition is more limited demand will be more inelastic; that is, a given price rise will drive away a relatively small share of the firm’s customers. That is exactly how we define an inelastic demand. Second, when demand is more inelastic, as we have just recalled, a rise in price will be more profitable because it will drive away few customers, thereby raising revenues more, while at the same time cutting the firm’s input expenditure, because total sales will have been decreased somewhat by the higher prices. These paragraphs may be considered as a review of some of our earlier analysis of business decisions, but we also see now how rich that analysis can be, throwing light on the analysis of innovation and the pricing policies that the market leads innovators to adopt.

12

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 20

Labor and Entrepreneurship: The Human Inputs

Negative Financial Rewards for Entrepreneurial Activity?

SOURCE: © Jeff J Mitchell/Getty Images

This takes us through the pricing story except for one thing—the earlier assertion that if there is freedom of entry into the entrepreneurial activities, this will tend to drive the average economic profits of entrepreneurs and inventors to zero. That may seem like an implausible conclusion. After all, we are talking about the activities that raised Bill Gates to the position of richest man in the world. Indeed, we will show next that, in reality, the zero economic profit conclusion is wrong. But the surprising evidence is the opposite of what one might expect—the actual economic profits, on average, are lower, not higher, than zero! Clearly, if this is true, more explanation of what goes on is required. In much of the next few paragraphs it will be convenient to think of entrepreneurs simply as self-employed people who prefer to be their own bosses rather than hiring themselves out to an ongoing enterprise. There are several studies of relevant data that show the self-employed have earnings significantly lower than those of employees with similar education and experience. All of this implies that when individuals decide to become an entrepreneur or an inventor, they must expect to earn profits so low that they entail some financial sacrifice, rather than the reverse. That is, they must expect to suffer a substantial opportunity cost relative to what they could have earned by working in a business firm owned by others. How can that possibly be true? Why, with such a low payoff to be expected, would they do such work voluntarily?

PUZZLE RESOLVED:

WHY ARE ENTREPRENEURIAL EARNINGS SURPRISINGLY LOW?

We can now seek to provide the answer to the puzzle presented earlier in this chapter. We are not sure why entrepreneurs on average earn so little—but here are some possibilities. Strange as this may seem, there are grounds to conclude that in a competitive market this is not an abnormality. There are two reasons. The first is the very high rewards generated by the relatively few outstanding successes provide an incentive found in many other activities, such as investment in lotteries with multi-million-dollar payoffs or in occupations such as acting, in both of which actual average earnings are very low indeed. The willingness of entrepreneurs to invest their lives and fortunes in such risky activity implies that they are either highly overoptimistic or that they enjoy such gambles. There is strong evidence that over optimism is characteristic of entrepreneurs. “The available evidence certainly supports the notion that entrepreneurs are unrealistically optimistic. 68% of respondents to [one] survey of American entrepreneurs thought the odds of their business succeeding were better than for others in the same sector while only 5% thought that they were worse. . . . [Another survey found that] all respondents over-optimistically expect to live longer than the life tables suggest, but that entrepreneurs are substantially more likely to think they will live longer. These authors also establish that optimism is significantly positively associated with the propensity to be an entrepreneur.” * Thus, undervaluation of risk and very large rewards to the few blockbuster innovations can indeed lead the average reward of the entrepreneur to be lower than that of others in the economy with comparable ability and performance. There is a second reason for such low financial rewards, for the entrepreneur also receives a second payment in a form that can be considered to be a different currency. In the case of the entrepreneur, the second currency is the psychological reward of independence, that is, the absence of subservience to a directing superior and the

*

Simon C. Parker (2005), The Economics of Entrepreneurship: What We Know and What We Don’t, Hanover, Mass.: now Publishers Inc..

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

439

440

Part 5

The Distribution of Income

excitement of participation in the innovation process (which is readily observed in the biographies of innovative entrepreneurs). In a competitive equilibrium, if entrepreneurship is far more pleasant than working for others, the financial rewards to entrepreneurship must normally be below the earnings of equally capable individuals who take more “boring” jobs in established business firms. For if the wages in the two jobs, one very pleasant and one highly unpleasant, were the same, qualified individuals would be unwilling to accept the far less enjoyable of the two positions. The resulting scarcity of job takers would drive up the wages in the unpleasant position and the abundance of job seekers for the other position would drive those wages down. In the end, the difference in payoffs in the two jobs must make up for the difference in their attractiveness. Thus, we must conclude that the role of entrepreneur must offer satisfaction considerably greater than that provided by working for others and so, makes entrepreneurs willing to undertake this activity even though it is, on average, so much less rewarding financially.

INSTITUTIONS AND THE SUPPLY OF INNOVATIVE ENTREPRENEURSHIP What is there about the modern free-market economy that allows this innovation process to flourish and make its fundamental contribution to rates of economic growth that have never previously been experienced in human history? The answer is primarily found in the new institutions that grew up along with the capitalist economy, perhaps partly as a historical accident. Before the Industrial Revolution there were societies that also had their share of enterprising individuals who profited by doing things in a way that was different from that of their ancestors. The type of invention that was profitable and honorific was likely to be military or could be used to promote religious practices or even entailed outright corruption. We have already noted how Heron of Alexandria used his steam engine and his other inventions to promote the powers of the Roman priesthood and was very likely well compensated by them for his efforts. Use of the fantastically varied and potentially valuable inventions of medieval China was impeded by the fact that the incentives provided to the most enterprising individuals did not encourage them to take steps to introduce those inventions to productive activity. Rather they strove, often for years, to become part of the mandarin officialdom, where they expected to acquire wealth through the resultant power to profit through corruption. And all through history the most honored avenue to wealth and power was the military, through essentially private armies, often using innovative military equipment and tactics to acquire wealth through booty, ransom, land grabbing, enslavement of captives, and other associated means. By the eighteenth century in England and in the former American colonies, government had become sufficiently powerful to prevent the exercise of military entrepreneurship via the organization of private armies. Other unproductive forms of enterprise had also become more difficult to carry out as a result of laws and customs that prohibited or at least handicapped them. And, at the same time, new institutions were adopted that made innovative entrepreneurship safer, easier, and more profitable. For example, the patent system, unknown in ancient societies, was created directly for the United States in the Constitution. The basic point is that enterprising individuals are neither more nor less moral than those who are engaged in any other career. The entrepreneur’s special talent, as one noted student of the subject has observed, is the ability to spot new and so-far-unused profitmaking opportunities. But which activities promise to be profitable depends on current government rules and the nature of the pressures that stem from various influential sources. Today, the entrepreneurs, in their search for profits, are encouraged to innovate by a variety of rules that provide protection for such activity when it contributes to production and to the choices available to consumers. Now we have legal institutions, such as sanctity of property, that prohibits arbitrary expropriation by the king and his nobles,

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Labor and Entrepreneurship: The Human Inputs

Chapter 20

441

the patent system that helps the inventor and the innovative entrepreneur to reap rewards from their efforts, as well as enforceability of contracts by the courts, bankruptcy protection permitting those who have made unfortunate business decisions to try again, and many more. But this was not always so. These rules were quite new at the time of the Industrial Revolution, and for the first time they assured entrepreneurs and innovators that they could keep the wealth generated by their efforts. This assurance not only provided the incentives that attracted individuals into the struggle for innovation, it also served as an irresistible lure for the entry of competitors. The appearance of the early innovating entrepreneurs and their success brought in more entrepreneurs, but it also gave rise to ever-fiercer competition, using innovation as a weapon. And this provided the driving force for innovation that is present and fully effective only in the market economies. Today, entrepreneurs continue to be an indispensable ingredient in the unprecedented growth performance of the market. By ensuring that inventions are put to use quickly and effectively, they ensure that our ability to produce and to improve quality will continue to grow. But in order to keep this process going, we must be careful to prevent the adoption of rules that undercut these activities and remove the incentives for entrepreneurs to keep up their productivity-enhancing efforts. That is one of the key morals that emerges from the experience of economic history since the Industrial Revolution.

| SUMMARY | Compared with many other industrialized countries, unions in the United States have as members a smaller share of the labor force and are less radical politically.

1. In a free market, the wage rate and the level of employment are determined by the interaction of supply and demand. Workers in great demand or short supply command high wages. Similarly, low wages go to workers who are in abundant supply or who have skills that are not in great demand.

9. Unions probably succeed in forcing wages to be higher and employment to be lower than they would be in a perfectly competitive labor market.

2. The demand curve for labor, like the demand curve for any factor of production, is derived from the marginal revenue product curve. It slopes downward because of the “law” of diminishing marginal returns.

10. Strikes play an important role in collective bargaining as a way of dividing the fruits of economic activity between big business and big labor. But strikes are not nearly so common as is often supposed.

3. The demand curve for labor can be shifted upward by an increase in education or on-the-job training that raises the workers’ marginal physical products or by an increase in demand for those products that raises product price and therefore also increases labor’s MRP.

11. For about two decades Americans have experienced three noteworthy trends: (a) a decline in union membership of more than 30 percent, (b) a steady fall in real wages partly offset by rising fringe benefits, and (c) a rise in the income gap between well-paid and poorly paid workers.

4. Labor-saving innovations may either raise or lower workers’ wages and available jobs in the short run. Because they are tantamount to increased productivity, in the long run they generally raise the incomes of workers along with those of other members of the community. 5. Because of conflicting income and substitution effects, the quantity of labor supplied may rise or fall as a result of an increase in wages. Historical data show that hours of work per week have fallen as wages have risen, suggesting that income effects may be dominant in the long run. 6. Most skills can be acquired by means of investment in human capital, such as education. 7. Human capital theory assumes that people make educational decisions in much the same way as businesses make investment decisions, and it tacitly assumes that people learn things in school that increase their productivity in jobs. 8. Less than 13 percent of all U.S. workers belong to unions, which we can think of as monopoly sellers of labor.

12. Innovative entrepreneurs look for new products or new productive processes or new markets and try to have them put to profitable use. 13. In a widely recognized model of this process, just after entrepreneurs bring new products to market they face no competition and earn monopoly profits, but then competitors enter with imitations of any successful new product and gradually drive the prices down to competitive levels. So, to continue to earn profits the entrepreneur must soon find another innovation to bring to market. 14. The R&D spending on a new product and on breaking into the market is a fixed cost with public good properties, so the amount it adds to marginal cost is zero. 15. Therefore, to cover those fixed costs and earn at least zero economic profit overall, price must exceed marginal cost, unlike a perfectly competitive market where P 5 MC. 16. To cover the fixed cost of R&D, etc., and with the threat of growing competition by imitators, the entrepreneur

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

442

Part 5

The Distribution of Income

will, in effect, charge discriminatory prices, that is, different prices for the same product on sales to early buyers than they will charge to later buyers. 17. The profit-maximizing rule for the discriminatory price variation at different dates will be the same as always applies under price discrimination; that is, if the marginal cost of supplying earlier customers is the same as doing so for later customers, then the quantities supplied at the two dates must be such that the marginal revenues at the two dates are equal.

18. Entrepreneurs will do what it takes to achieve wealth, power, and prestige by innovation. So before there were laws protecting private property, enforcing contracts, and offering patent protection to innovators, they would often organize private armies, take bribes, and find new ways to get special favors from people in power, rather than promoting productive innovation. Since about the time of the Industrial Revolution the laws have changed, and it has become more profitable for entrepreneurs to undertake productive innovations.

| KEY TERMS | backward-bending 427

income effect 426

bilateral monopoly

innovative entrepreneurship

436

marginal revenue product of labor (MRPL) 422

investment in human capital

422

monopsony

433

collective bargaining human capital theory

433 429

labor union

433

substitution effect

431

426

| TEST YOURSELF | 1. The following table shows the number of pizzas that can be produced by a large pizza parlor employing various numbers of pizza chefs.

Number of Chefs 1 2 3 4 5 6

Number of Pizzas per Day 40 64 82 92 100 92

competition? The model of pure monopoly? The model of bilateral monopoly? a. Odd-job repairs in private homes b. Manufacture of low-priced clothing for children c. Auto manufacturing 4. Can you think of some types of workers whose marginal products probably were raised by computerization? Are there any whose marginal products were probably reduced? Can you characterize the difference between the two types of jobs in general terms?

b. Assuming a price of $9 per pizza, find the marginal revenue product schedule.

5. Suppose you are the sole producer of commodity X, which was just invented to clean the snow from sidewalks more efficiently, and you have produced enough to sell for two winters. If the quantity you expect to sell in 2011 would yield MR 5 $400 and in 2012 it will be $300, what can you do to try to increase your total profit?

c. If chefs are paid $100 per day, how many chefs will this pizza parlor employ? How would your answer change if chefs’ wages rose to $125 per day?

6. Explain what a doubling of the number of customers for your snow cleaner will do to the R&D component of your marginal costs.

d. Suppose the price of pizza increases from $9 to $12. Show what happens to the derived demand curve for chefs.

7. If two jobs are available, one of which is fun and very respectable and the other unpleasant and dangerous, where would you expect wages to be higher? Is that really so in practice?

a. Find the marginal physical product schedule of the pizza chefs.

2. Discuss the concept of the financial rate of return on a college education. If this return is less than the return on a bank account, does that mean you should quit college? Why might you want to stay in school anyway? Are there circumstances under which it might be rational not to go to college, even when the financial returns to college are very high? 3. In which of the following industries is wage determination most plausibly explained by the model of perfect

8. Assume the inventor of the snow cleaner gets only 3 percent of the benefits, the remainder consisting of reduced medical bills for back pain. In the general public, explain why this is an externality. How large is it? Is it a beneficial externality? How will it affect the number of snow cleaners it is most profitable to manufacture, as compared to the number that best contributes to the general welfare?

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 20

Labor and Entrepreneurship: The Human Inputs

443

| DISCUSSION QUESTIONS | 1. Colleges are known to pay rather low wages for student labor. Can this trend be explained by the operation of supply and demand in the local labor markets? Is the concept of monopsony of any use? How might things differ if students formed a union?

8. Since about 1980, GDP per capita (that is, the average real income per person) in the United States has risen fairly substantially. Yet real wages have failed to rise. What do you think may explain this phenomenon?

2. College professors are highly skilled (or at least highly educated!) laborers, yet their wages are not very high. Is this a refutation of the marginal productivity theory?

9. If you were the youngest son of an English nobleman in the Middle Ages, what could you do to make your fortune? What kinds of innovation would be appreciated by people in power?

3. It seems to be a well-established fact that workers with more years of education typically receive higher wages. What are some possible reasons for this trend?

10. How did Julius Caesar attain his position in Rome and in history? In what sense can his activities be said to have been entrepreneurial?

4. Approximately what fraction of the U.S. labor force belongs to unions? (Try asking this question of a person who has never studied economics.) Why do you think this fraction is so low?

11. Why do you think China, with all its incredible inventions, fell behind economically?

5. What are some reasonable goals for a union? Use the tools of supply and demand to explain how a union might pursue its goals, whatever they are. Consider a union that has been in the news recently. What was it trying to accomplish? 6. “Strikes are simply intolerable and should be outlawed.” Comment on this statement. 7. In a bitter strike battle between Eastern Airlines and several of its unions, it was clear from the beginning that the airline was in serious financial trouble. The airline was, indeed, eventually forced to close down, costing many jobs. Discuss what might nevertheless have led the unions to hold out so tenaciously.

12. What are some of the U.S. laws and other rules that played a critical role in the attainment of leadership in per-capita income and innovation? 13. What steps should the United States consider undertaking to protect itself from the fate of other countries that once were economic leaders of the world and then fell far behind? 14. Why do you think even though high school education in other countries is widely considered to be better than that in the United States every country sends its best and brightest to the United States to get their Doctorate degrees?

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Poverty, Inequality, and Discrimination The white man knows how to make everything, but he does not know how to distribute it. SI TTI NG BU LL

T

he last two chapters analyzed how factor prices—wages, rents, and interest rates—are determined in a market economy. One reason for concern about this issue is that these payments determine the incomes of the people who own the factors. The study of factor pricing, therefore, is an indirect way to learn about how the market distributes income among individuals. In this chapter, we turn directly to the problem of income distribution. Specifically, we seek answers to the following questions: How unequal are incomes in the United States, and why? How can society decide rationally on how much equality it wants? And, once this decision is made, what policies are available to pursue this goal?

C O N T E N T S ISSUE: WERE THE BUSH TAX CUTS UNFAIR?

THE FACTS: POVERTY Counting the Poor: The Poverty Line Absolute versus Relative Poverty

THE FACTS: INEQUALITY SOME REASONS FOR UNEQUAL INCOMES THE FACTS: DISCRIMINATION

THE TRADE-OFF BETWEEN EQUALITY AND EFFICIENCY POLICIES TO COMBAT POVERTY Education as a Way Out The Welfare Debate and the Trade-Off The Negative Income Tax

OTHER POLICIES TO COMBAT INEQUALITY The Personal Income Tax Death Duties and Other Taxes

POLICIES TO COMBAT DISCRIMINATION A LOOK BACK | APPENDIX | The Economic Theory of Discrimination Discrimination by Employers Discrimination by Fellow Workers Statistical Discrimination The Roles of the Market and the Government

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

446

Part 5

The Distribution of Income

ISSUE:

WERE THE BUSH TAX CUTS UNFAIR?

Reducing taxes was the major thrust of President George W. Bush’s economic policy. Tax cuts were passed in 2001, 2002, 2003, and 2004, amounting in total to a substantial reduction in the federal tax burden—or, as some critics put it, a large reduction in the tax burdens of the rich. And that is precisely the fairness issue. One of the chief criticisms of the Bush tax cuts was that they were distributively unfair, that wealthy Americans were the chief beneficiaries while people of modest means received little. According to one estimate, the lower 60 percent of income earners—a majority of the population—received just 13.7 percent of the tax cuts while the top 1 percent received 24.2 percent.1 To people concerned with income inequality, that was prima facie evidence that the tax cuts were unfair. And, for this reason, every Democratic candidate for the 2008 presidential nomination, including Barack Obama, pledged to roll back some of the tax cuts for the rich—which President Obama subsequently proposed. President Bush and his supporters responded to these criticisms in a variety of ways. One was to deny the unfairness. It is natural, they said, for upper-bracket taxpayers to get a disproportionate share of the tax cuts for a simple reason: They pay a disproportionate share of the taxes. But a second retort pointed out that lower tax rates improve incentives and enhance economic efficiency—topics that we addressed in Chapter 18. Fairness is in the eye of the beholder, they maintained, but one thing we do know is that lower tax rates improve economic performance. Largely for this reason, Senator John McCain, during the 2008 campaign, pledged to continue the Bush tax cuts. Which side of this 2008 debate—which lingers on—had it right? Should we worry more about the distributive consequences of the Bush tax cuts or welcome their efficiency effects? It’s a good question, but one, as we shall see, without a clear answer.

IDEAS FOR BEYOND THE FINAL EXAM

As we will show in this chapter, the debate over the Bush tax cuts provides a classic example of the trade-off between equality and efficiency that we introduced in Chapter 1. Some conservatives seem so enamored of the efficiency gains from lower tax rates that they ignore, or even deny, the distributive consequences. Some liberals, by contrast, argue that tax cuts that are so “unfair” should be rejected regardless of their potential efficiency benefits. Economists prefer to avoid such absolutes and to think in terms of trade-offs instead. To reap gains on one front, society often must make sacrifices on another. A policy is not necessarily ill-conceived simply because it has an undesirable effect on income inequality, provided it makes a sufficiently important contribution to efficiency. But policies with very adverse distributive consequences may deserve to be rejected, even if they would raise the nation’s total output. Admitting that there is a trade-off between equality and efficiency—namely, that tax cuts that favor the rich may nonetheless enhance economic efficiency—may not be the best way to win votes. But it does face up to reality. And in that way, it helps us to think through the inherently political decisions about what should be done.

If we are to understand these complex issues, a good place to start is, as always, with the facts.

THE FACTS: POVERTY In 1962, social critic Michael Harrington published a little book called The Other America, which turned out to have a profound effect on American society. Harrington’s “other Americans” were the poor who lived in the land of plenty. Ill-clothed in the richest country 1 Isaac Shapiro and Joel Friedman, “Tax Returns: A Comprehensive Assessment of the Bush Administration Tax Cuts,” Center on Budget and Policy Priorities, April 2004, p. 19.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

447

Poverty, Inequality, and Discrimination

Chapter 21

Pine Ridge [South Dakota] lies in the poorest county in America, with 75 percent unemployment and an average family income of $3,700 per year. The life expectancy for men is 48 years, 25 years below the national average. The infant mortality rate is the highest in the country. Bad health, disease, drugs, and alcohol have ravaged the Oglala Sioux. Their culture has been diluted by television and their language is gradually dying out. . . . [P]eople on the reservation . . . agree that the tribe’s funds are chronically mismanaged, that nepotism rules job placement and that a handful of people are getting rich while the rest of the tribe struggles to survive. . . . But . . . hardly anyone outside the reservation knows what’s going on at Pine Ridge. SOURCE: Julie Winokur, “Bury the News at Wounded Knee,” at http://www.archive .salon.com/news/feature/2000/03/13/pine_ridge/index.html.

SOURCE: © Bob Rowan; Progressive Image/CORBIS

The Poorest Place in America?

on earth, inadequately nourished in a nation where obesity was a problem, infirm in a country with some of the world’s highest health standards, these people lived an almost unknown existence in their dilapidated hovels, according to Harrington. To make matters worse, this deprivation often condemned the children of the “other Americans” to repeat the lives of their parents. There was, Harrington argued, a “cycle of poverty” that could be broken only by government action. The work of Harrington and others touched the hearts of many Americans who, it seemed, really had no idea of the abominable living conditions of some other people in the country. Within a few years, the growing outrage over the plight of the poor had crystallized into a “War on Poverty,” which President Lyndon Johnson declared in 1964.

Counting the Poor: The Poverty Line As part of this program, the government adopted an official definition of poverty: The poor were those families with incomes less than $3,000 in 1964. This dividing line between the poor and nonpoor was called the poverty line, and a goal was established: to get all Americans above the poverty line by the nation’s bicentennial in 1976. (The goal was not met.) The poverty line was subsequently modified to account for differences in family size and other considerations, and it is now also adjusted each year to reflect changes in the cost of living. In 2009, the poverty line for a family of four was just over $25,300 and 13.2 percent of all Americans remained in poverty by official definitions. Who are the poor? Relative to their proportions in the overall population, they are more likely to be black than white and more likely to be female than male. They are less educated and in poorer health than the population as a whole. About 35 percent of the poor are children. America made substantial progress toward eliminating poverty in the decade from 1963 to 1973; the percentage of people living below the poverty line dropped from 20 percent to 11 percent (see Figure 1). But thereafter, slower economic growth and cutbacks in social welfare programs reversed the trend. By 1983, the poverty rate was back to what it had been in the 1960s. After that, the poverty rate increased and decreased with no clear trend until the great economic boom of the 1990s restored it almost to its 1970s low. Poverty rose again when the economy slumped early in this decade, but then recovered a bit of the lost ground in 2005 and 2006, before increasing again during the 2008–2009 recession. High poverty rates worry many people, especially because poverty seems often to be associated with homelessness, illegitimacy, drug dependency, and ill-health. However, some critics argue that the official data badly overstate the number of poor persons. Some

The poverty line is an amount of income below which a family is considered “poor.”

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

448

Part 5

The Distribution of Income

F I GURE 1

26

Percentage of Persons Who Are Poor

24

22 Declaration of the War on Poverty

20

1990–1991 recession

1981–1982 recession

18 Percentage of persons who are poor

16

2001 recession

1969–1970 recession 1974–1975 recession

14 12

Including in-kind transfers

10 8

1955

1959

1963

1967

1971

1975

1979

1983

1987

1991

1995

1999

2003

2007

SOURCE: For 1959–2008, U.S. Bureau of the Census. For 1955–1958, estimates kindly provided by Gordon M. Fisher.

Progress in the War on Poverty

even go so far as to claim that poverty would be considered a thing of the past if the official definition (based on cash income) were amended to include the many goods that the poor receive in kind: public education, public housing, health care, food, and the like. These criticisms prompted the Census Bureau to develop several experimental measures of poverty that account for the value of goods given in kind. If these new measures are accepted as valid, fewer people are classified as poor, but the basic patterns remain the same: Poverty went up and down from the late 1970s until about 1993 with no clear trend and then declined until 2000, when it started heading up again.

Absolute versus Relative Poverty This debate raises a fundamental question: How do we define “the poor”? Continuing economic growth will eventually pull almost everyone above any arbitrarily established poverty line. Would that mark the end of poverty? Some would say yes, but would insist that the biblical injunction is right: “The poor ye have always with you.” We can define poverty two ways. The more optimistic definition uses an absolute concept of poverty: If you fall short of a certain minimum standard of living, you are poor; once you pass this standard, you are no longer poor. The more pessimistic definition relies on a relative concept of poverty: The poor are those who fall too far behind the average income.

Each definition has advantages and disadvantages. The basic problem with the absolute poverty concept is that it is arbitrary. Who sets the line? Most of the people of Bangladesh would consider themselves quite prosperous if they lived a bit below the U.S. poverty line. Similarly, the standard of living that we now call “poor” would not have been considered so in America in 1900, and certainly not in Europe during the Middle Ages. Different times and different places apparently call for different poverty lines. Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 21

Poverty, Inequality, and Discrimination

449

Because the concept of poverty seems to be culturally—not physiologically—determined, it must be a relative concept. For example, the European Union (EU) places the poverty line at half the national average income—which means that the poverty line automatically rises as the EU grows richer. Once we move from an absolute to a relative concept of poverty, any sharp distinction between the poor and the nonpoor starts to blur. At least in part, the poor are so poor because the rich are so rich. If we follow this line of thought far enough, we are led away from the narrow problem of poverty and toward the broader problem of income inequality.

THE FACTS: INEQUALITY

SOURCE: U.S. Bureau of the Census.

Nothing in the market mechanism guarantees equality of incomes. On the contrary, the market system tends to allow or even foster inequality because the basic source of its great efficiency is its system of rewards and penalties. The market is generous to those who succeed in operating efficient enterprises that respond to consumer demands, but it ruthlessly penalizes those who are unable or unwilling to satisfy consumer demands efficiently. Recent developments in the United States have demonstrated these tendencies dramatically, as inequalities have risen notably. The market’s financial punishment of those who try and fail can be severe. At times the market even brings down the great and powerful. Robert Morris, once perhaps the wealthiest resident of the American colonies, ended up in debtors’ prison. Some of the greatest American fortunes in the late nineteenth century were made in the railroads, most of which subsequently went bankrupt. When the Internet euphoria ended in 2000, many former multimillionaires (and a few former billionaires) found themselves jobless and nearly destitute. Most recently, the financial crisis of 2007–2009 humbled some of America’s greatest financial institutions. Most people have a good idea that the gulf between the rich and the poor is wide, but few have any concept of where they stand in the income distribution. For example, during a 1995 congressional debate over tax cuts for “the middle class,” one member of Congress with an annual income in excess of $150,000 declared himself a member of the “middle class,” if not indeed of the “lower-middle class”! Table 1 offers some statistics on the income distribution among U.S. households in 2008. But before looking at them, try the following experiment. First, write down what you think your household’s before-tax income was in 2008. (If you do not know, take a guess.) Next, try to guess what TABLE 1 percentage of American households had incomes lower Distribution of Household Income in the United States than this amount. Finally, if we divide America into three in 2008 broad income classes—rich, middle class, and poor—to Households which group do you think your household belongs? Households in This and Now that you have written down answers to these three Income in This Lower questions, look at the income distribution data for 2008 in Range Range Ranges Table 1. If you are like most college students, these figures Less than $5,000 3.0% 3.0% may surprise you. First, if we adopt the tentative definition $5,000 to $9,999 4.1 7.1 that the lowest 20 percent are the “poor,” the highest $10,000 to $14,999 5.8 12.9 $15,000 to $24,999 11.8 24.7 20 percent are the “rich,” and the middle 60 percent are the $25,000 to $34,999 10.9 35.6 “middle class,” many fewer of you belong to the celebrated $35,000 to $49,000 14.0 49.6 “middle class” than you thought. In fact, the cutoff point $50,000 to $74,999 17.9 67.5 that defined membership in the “rich” class in 2008 was $75,000 to $99,999 11.9 79.4 only about $100,000 before taxes, an income level exceeded $100,000 or more 20.5 100.0 by the parents of many college students. (Your parents may NOTE: If your household income falls close to one of the endpoints of the ranges indicated here, you can approximate the fraction of households with income be shocked to learn that they are rich!) lower than yours by just looking at the last column. If your household’s income Next, use Table 1 to estimate the fraction of U.S. housefalls within one of the ranges, you can interpolate the answer. Example: Your household’s income was $80,000. This is 20 percent of the way from $75,000 holds that have incomes lower than yours. (The table to $100,000, so your household was richer than roughly 0.20 3 11.9 percent 5 2.4 percent of the households in this class. Adding this to the caption has instructions to help you make this estimate.) percentage of households in lower classes (67.5 percent in this case) gives the Many students who come from households of moderate answer—about 70 percent of all households earned less than yours. Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

450

Part 5

The Distribution of Income

prosperity feel instinctively that they stand perhaps a bit above the middle of the income distribution. So they estimate that a Income Shares in Selected Years little more than half of all families have lower incomes. In fact, Income the median income among American households in 2008 was Group 2008 1990 1980 1970 only $50,300. Lowest fifth 3.4 3.9 4.3 4.1 This exercise has perhaps brought us down to earth. America Second fifth 8.6 9.6 10.3 10.8 is not nearly as rich as Madison Avenue would like us to beMiddle fifth 14.7 15.9 16.9 17.4 lieve. Let us now look past the average level of income and see Fourth fifth 23.3 24.0 24.9 24.5 Highest fifth 50.0 46.6 43.7 43.3 how the pie is divided. Table 2 shows the shares of income accruing to each fifth of the population in 2008 and several earlier years. In a perfectly equal society, all the numbers in this table would be “20 percent,” because each fifth of the population would receive one-fifth of the income. In fact, as the table shows, reality is far from this perfect equality. In 2008, for example, the poorest fifth of all households had just 3.4 percent of the total income, whereas the richest fifth had 50.0 percent, almost 15 times as much. These data for 2008 give us a snapshot of the U.S. income distribution. But to interpret them, we must know what the distribution looked like in earlier years or what it looks like in other countries. The historical data in Table 2 shows that SOURCE: U.S. Bureau of the Census.

TAB LE 2

The distribution of income in the United States has grown substantially more unequal since about 1980.

SOURCE: © The New Yorker Collection, 1988, Joseph Mirachi from cartoonbank.com. All Rights Reserved.

Specifically, the share of the poorest fifth is now the lowest, and the share of the richest fifth is almost the highest since the government began collecting data in 1947. America is not a very class-conscious society, and for years only specialists paid much attention to data like those in Table 2. But income inequality has captured increasing public attention of late as more and more American families sense that they are losing ground to the people at the top. There is particular, and well-justified, concern that the real earnings of wage earners below the middle have fallen further and further behind the wages at the top. These trends toward widening income and wage disparities have been going on for almost three decades now, which is a long time. Comparing the United States with other countries is much more difficult because no two nations use precisely the same definition of income distribution. The Luxembourg Income Study is the leading international effort to produce comparable data for many countries. In its latest comparison of the income distributions of 20 high-income (mostly European) countries, Sweden and Finland had the most equal income distributions, with Norway, The Netherlands, and Belgium close behind. The United States stood “The poor are getting poorer, but with the rich getting richer it all averages out in the long run.” out as having the most inequality. Thus, it appears that The United States has more income inequality than most other industrialized countries.

SOME REASONS FOR UNEQUAL INCOMES Let us now begin to formulate a list of the causes of income inequality. Here are some that come to mind.

Differences in Ability Everyone knows that people have different capabilities. Some can run faster, ski better, do calculations more quickly, type more accurately, and so on. Hence, it should not be surprising that some people are more adept at earning income. Precisely what sort of ability is relevant to earning income has been a matter of intense debate among economists, sociologists, and psychologists for decades. The talents that

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 21

Poverty, Inequality, and Discrimination

451

How Important Is the Bell Curve? important than genetics in determining intelligence and that “true” intelligence may differ from measured IQ. Furthermore, few, if any, economists believe that cognitive ability is the main ingredient in economic success. The bottom line, according to most scholars, is that the black–white IQ gap does not go very far in explaining racial income inequalities. Nor can we be certain that much of the measured IQ gap is biologically, rather than culturally, determined.

Frequency

Over a decade ago, social critic Charles Murray and psychologist Richard Herrnstein created a furor with a book claiming that genetically inherited intelligence is overwhelmingly important to economic success. The book’s title, The Bell Curve, referred to the shape of the distribution of scores on conventional IQ tests (see chart), which shows most people clustered near the middle, with small minorities on either end. Critics of government antipoverty efforts were attracted to the book’s central message: that the poor are poor in large measure because they are not very smart. Among the most stunning claims made by Herrnstein and Murray was that much of the observed economic gap between blacks and whites could be attributed to the fact that blacks’ IQ scores were, on average, lower than those of whites. Although The Bell Curve received a blitz of media attention, social scientists generally gave the analysis low marks. No one doubts that intelligence contributes to economic success, nor that genetics has some bearing on intelligence. But the scientific evidence on the strength of each link is in great dispute. Many experts on IQ, for example, argue that environmental factors may be more

100 IQ

make for success in school have some effect, but hardly an overwhelming one. The same is true of innate intelligence—“IQ” (see the box, “How Important Is the Bell Curve?”). It is clear that some types of inventiveness are richly rewarded by the market, as is that elusive characteristic we have discussed in earlier chapters: entrepreneurial ability. Also, it is obvious that poor health often impairs earning ability.

Differences in Intensity of Work Some people work longer hours than others or labor more intensely when they are on the job. These disparities lead to income differences that are largely voluntary.

Risk Taking Most people who acquire large sums of money do so by taking risks—by investing their money in the stock market, in a small start-up company, or in some other uncertain venture. Those who gamble and succeed become wealthy. Perhaps the most spectacular example is Bill Gates, believed to be the richest person in the world, who dropped out of Harvard to start a small company that we now know as Microsoft. Of course, those who try and fail often go broke. Most people prefer not to take such chances and end up somewhere in between. This is another way in which income differences arise voluntarily.

Compensating Wage Differentials Some jobs are more arduous than others, or more dangerous, or more unpleasant for other reasons. To induce people to take these jobs, some sort of financial incentive normally must be offered. For example, factory workers who work the night shift normally receive higher wages than those who work during the day. Schooling and Other Types of Training Chapter 20 analyzed schooling and other types of training as “investments in human capital.” As explained there, this phrase refers to the idea that people sacrifice current income to improve their skills so that their future incomes will be higher. When this is done, income differentials naturally rise. Although it is generally agreed that differences in schooling are an important cause of income differentials, this particular cause has both voluntary and involuntary aspects. Young men or women who choose not to go to college have made voluntary decisions that affect their incomes. Many never get the choice: Their parents simply cannot afford to send them. For them, the resulting income differential is not voluntary.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

452

Part 5

The Distribution of Income

Work Experience It is well-known to most people and well documented by scholarly research that more experienced workers earn higher wages. Inherited Wealth Not all income is derived from work. Some represents the return on invested wealth, and part of this wealth is inherited. Although this cause of inequality applies to few people, many of America’s superrich got that way through inheritance. Think of the Rockefellers or, more recently, the Waltons (of Wal-Mart fame). Financial wealth is not the only type of capital that can be inherited—so can human capital. In part, this inheritance happens naturally through genetics: High-ability parents tend to have highability children, although the link is an imperfect one. But it also happens partly for economic reasons: Well-to-do parents send their children to the best schools, thereby transforming their own financial wealth into human wealth for their children. This type of inheritance affects many more people than the financial type.

Luck No observer of our society can fail to notice the role that chance plays in income inequalities. Some of the rich and some of the poor got there largely by good or bad fortune. Two Internet entrepreneurs work equally hard, but only one develops the hot web site that makes him rich. A farmer digs for water, but strikes oil instead. A storekeeper near the World Trade Center disaster is driven out of business for lack of customers. The list could go on and on. Many large income differentials arise purely by chance.

THE FACTS: DISCRIMINATION

SOURCE: U.S. Bureau of the Census.

Some of the factors we have just listed lead to income differentials that are widely accepted as “just.” For example, most people believe it is fair for people who work harder to receive higher incomes. Other factors on our list ignite heated debates. For example, some people view income differentials that arise purely by chance as perfectly acceptable, whereas others find these same differentials intolerable. However, almost no one is willing to condone income inequalities that arise from discrimination. Economic The facts about discrimination are not easy to come by. Economic discrimination is discrimination occurs said to occur when equivalent factors of production receive different payments for equal when equivalent factors contributions to output. But this definition is difficult to apply in practice because we of production receive cannot always tell when two factors of production are “equivalent.” different payments for Few people would call it “discrimination” if a woman with only a high school equal contributions to diploma receives a lower salary than a man with a college degree. Even if a man output. and a woman have the same education, the man may have 10 more years of work experience than the woman does. If they receive different wages for this reason, is that discriminatory? In principle, we should compare men and women with equal productivities. If women receive lower wages than men who do the same work, we would attribute the difference to discrimination. But discrimination normally takes much more subtle forms than paying unequal wages for equal work. For instance, employers can simply TAB LE 3 relegate women to inferior jobs, thereby justifying their lower salaries. Median Incomes in 2008 One clearly incorrect way to measure discrimination is to compare the different groups’ typical incomes. Table 3 displays such data for Percentage white men, white women, black men, and black women in 2008. Population Median of White Group Income Male Income Virtually everyone agrees that the amount of discrimination is less than these differentials suggest, but far greater than zero. Precisely White males $35,120 100 Black males 25,118 72 how much is a topic of continuing economic research. Several studies White females 20,350 58 suggest that about half of the observed wage differential between Black females 20,203 58 black men and white men, and at least half of the differential between white women and white men, arises from discrimination in the NOTE: For persons 15 years old and older.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 21

453

Poverty, Inequality, and Discrimination

labor market (although more might be due to discrimination in education, and so on). Other studies have reached somewhat different conclusions.

THE TRADE-OFF BETWEEN EQUALITY AND EFFICIENCY We have noted that America has more income inequality than other wealthy nations, and we have observed that inequality in the United States has been on the rise for about 30 years. Should society try to reverse this trend? Here economics alone cannot provide an answer, although it can inform the discussion. Value judgments are needed to supplement the economic analysis. Some people say, “That’s the way the ball bounces.” If the market mechanism happens to produce high and rising inequality, so be it. To these conservatives, government has no business intervening to reduce income inequalities. If it does, they argue, economic efficiency will be impaired. But others beg to differ. Their vision of a “good society” does not countenance high and rising inequality, especially when those at the bottom are so poor. These liberals want the government to promulgate policies that reduce income disparities— programs such as income support for the poor, antidiscrimination statutes, and progressive income and inheritance taxes. Economic analysis cannot tell us how important it is to promote greater equality. That value-laden judgment falls more into the realm of political theory and philosophy, maybe even psychology. It is a question over which reasonable people can and do differ. But economics can tell us quite a bit about the costs, in terms of reduced efficiency, of alternative policies to promote greater equality. Specifically: THE TRADE-OFF BETWEEN EQUALITY AND EFFICIENCY Policies that redistribute income reduce the rewards of high-income earners while raising the rewards of low-income earners. Hence, such policies reduce the incentive to earn high income. Such incentive effects give rise to a trade-off that is one of the most fundamental in all of economics, and one of our Ideas for Beyond the Final Exam. Measures taken to increase the amount of economic equality normally reduce economic efficiency, that is, reduce society’s total output. So, in trying to divide the pie more equally, we may inadvertently reduce its size.

IDEAS FOR BEYOND THE FINAL EXAM

This annoying trade-off does not mean that all attempts to reduce inequality are misguided. That is where the economic analysis comes in—to temper and inform our value judgments. Basic economic principles teach us two lessons on which we will elaborate in the balance of this chapter: 1. There are better and worse ways to promote equality. In pursuing further income equality (or fighting poverty), we should seek policies that do the least possible harm to incentives and efficiency. 2. Equality is bought at a price. Thus, like any commodity, society must rationally decide how much to “purchase.” We will probably want to spend some of our potential income on equality, but certainly not all of it.

The first lesson is obvious: We should accomplish any desired redistribution by utilizing the most efficient redistributive policies. By picking these policies, rather than less efficient ones, we can “buy” whatever degree of equality we want at a lower “price” in terms of lost output. In the rest of this chapter, we will discuss alternative policies and try to indicate which ones damage incentives least. The second lesson is somewhat less obvious: Neither complete laissez-faire nor complete equality would normally be society’s optimal choice. To see why, let’s take the argument in two steps. At one extreme, it is easy to understand why we should not seek perfect equality. Ask yourself what would happen if we tried to achieve complete equality of incomes by putting a 100 percent income tax on all income and then dividing the tax receipts equally among the population. No one would have any incentive to work, to invest, to take risks,

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

454

Part 5

The Distribution of Income

SOURCE: © The New Yorker Collection, 1978, James Mulligan from cartoonbank.com. All Rights Reserved.

IDEAS FOR BEYOND THE FINAL EXAM

or to do anything else to earn money, because the rewards for all such activities would have disappeared. The nation’s total production would fall drastically. Only someone with a fanatic desire for equality would favor such an outcome. The argument at the other extreme is more subtle. Let’s assume (a) that almost everyone would favor greater equality if nothing had to be sacrificed to achieve it, and (b) that complete laissez-faire results in more inequality than society wants. There will presumably be some small redistributive policies that have essentially no adverse effects on incentives. Example: Levying a 0.1 percent tax on the incomes of billionaires and giving the proceeds to poor children. In a democracy, policies like that would presumably receive nearly unanimous approval. It follows that society should always carry out some redistribution, even if it is minor. We have therefore established our result: The socially optimal amount of equality is presumably more than the unfettered operation of free markets would produce, but less than complete equality. The government should therefore presumably undertake some redistribution of income, but not too much. It is astonishing how much confusion is caused by a failure to understand these two lessons. Proponents of greater equality often feel obliged to deny that the programs they advocate will hurt incentives at all. Sometimes these vehement denials are so patently unrealistic that they undermine the very case that the egalitarians are trying to make. Conservatives who oppose such policies also undercut the strength of their case by making outlandish claims about the efficiency losses from redistribution. Neither side, it seems, is willing to acknowledge the fundamental trade-off between equality and efficiency. As a result, the debate generates more heat than light. Because these debates will likely continue for the rest of your lives, we hope that some understanding of this trade-off stays with you well Beyond the Final Exam. The trade-off idea applies directly to the debate over extending or repealing the Bush tax cuts. The tax cuts did worsen income inequality, but they also improved incentives and therefore contributed to greater economic efficiency. Depending on your value judgments, you might therefore approve or disapprove of the policies. This case illustrates the point that merely understanding the trade-off will not tell you what to do. We know that the optimal amount of equality lies between two extremes, but we do not know what it actually is. Nor can we expect people to agree on the optimal degree of inequality, because the answer depends on value judgments: Just how much is more equality worth to you? Arthur Okun, one-time chairman of the Council of Economic Advisers, described the issue graphically. Imagine that money is liquid and that you have a bucket that can be “There is a perfect example used to move money from the rich to the poor. Unfortuof what is wrong with this nately, the bucket leaks. As you move the money, some gets country today.” lost. (These are the efficiency losses from redistribution.) Will you use the bucket if only 1 cent is lost for each $1 you move? Almost everyone would say yes. However, what if you lose 90 cents, so that each $1 taken from the rich results in only 10 cents for the poor? Only the most extreme egalitarians will still say yes. Now try the more difficult questions. What if 20 to 40 cents is lost for each $1 that you move? If you can answer questions such as these, you can decide how much equality you want, for you will have expressed your value judgments in quantitative terms.

“There is a perfect example of what is wrong with this country today.”

POLICIES TO COMBAT POVERTY Let us take it for granted that the nation wants to reduce poverty, at least somewhat. Which policies promote this goal? Which of these does the least harm to incentives and hence is most efficient?

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 21

Poverty, Inequality, and Discrimination

Education as a Way Out Education is often advertised as one of the principal ways to escape from poverty. No doubt many people have used this route successfully, and still do. And the evidence points clearly to the conclusion that more education boosts earnings. However, delivering quality education to poor children is no simple matter. Many of them, especially in the inner cities, are ill-equipped to learn and attend schools that are illequipped to teach. Despite some gratifying progress in recent years, dropout rates remain dismayingly high. An astonishing number of youths leave the public school system without even acquiring basic literacy. All of these problems are familiar; none is easy to solve. In truth, our educational system must serve many goals, and the alleviation of poverty is not the major one. If it were, we would certainly spend more money on preschool and innercity children and less on college education than we do today. Furthermore, education is not an effective way to lift adults out of poverty. Its effects are delayed for a generation or more.

The Welfare Debate and the Trade-Off By contrast, a variety of programs collectively known as “welfare” are specifically designed to alleviate poverty, meant to help adults as well as children, and intended to have quick effects. The best known and most heavily criticized of these programs used to be Aid to Families with Dependent Children (AFDC). AFDC provided direct cash grants to families that had children but no breadwinner, generally because the father was absent or unknown and the mother could not or did not work. When Bill Clinton campaigned in 1992 on a promise to “end welfare as we know it,” many Americans shared his dissatisfaction with the system. Why? Because AFDC was a classic example of an inefficient redistributive program. One major reason was that it provided no incentive for welfare mothers to earn income. Once monthly earnings passed a few hundred dollars, AFDC payments were reduced by $1 for each $1 that the family earned as wages. Thus, if a member of the family got a job, the family was subjected to a 100 percent marginal tax rate! Little wonder, then, that many welfare recipients did not look very hard for work. In addition, critics argued that “the welfare mess” was too bureaucratic, too expensive, and might even be hurting the very people it was designed to help—by, for example, encouraging out-of-wedlock births and fostering a culture of dependence on the state. In 1996, Congress redeemed President Clinton’s campaign pledge by replacing AFDC with a new welfare program: Temporary Assistance to Needy Families (TANF). Notice the word temporary. TANF limits eligibility for welfare checks to two years at a time and five years over a person’s lifetime. Before recipients reach these time limits, they are supposed to have found jobs. The new law also gave states much greater latitude to design their own welfare systems, thereby greatly reducing federal influence over welfare. And, indeed, the generosity of TANF now varies tremendously across the 50 states. The new welfare law was highly controversial when it was enacted. Critics argued that it would throw many needy families to the wolves when their benefits ran out. Supporters argued that it would give them “a hand up, instead of a handout”—and would save the taxpayers money to boot. This debate offered another illustration of the trade-off between equality and efficiency and how poorly understood it is. Critics of TANF argued that the new law was mean-spirited because it reduced the amount of income support that poor mothers could receive. Supporters argued that TANF provided better work incentives than AFDC. From 1996 to 2000, the economy boomed, jobs were plentiful, and the welfare rolls shrank dramatically. So the new system was not put to the test until the economy slowed in 2000 and 2001 and jobs became scarcer. When the welfare rolls did not soar in the weak job market of 2001–2003, TANF passed its first test with flying colors. This success, supporters claimed, proved that the new system worked well. However, studies of the welfare population found very high poverty rates among those who had exited the TANF program. They also found that roughly half of the people eligible for TANF benefits were

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

455

456

Part 5

The Distribution of Income

not receiving them. Furthermore, because many poor women cycle in and out of welfare, few had yet reached the five-year lifetime limit. For all of these reasons, the debate over welfare reform goes on. Studies of TANF during the 2008–2009 recession have yet to be completed.

Food Stamps A second prominent welfare program is Food Stamps, which burgeoned in the 1970s and was cut back several times in the 1980s and 1990s. Under this program, poor families receive “stamps”—which nowadays are actually delivered via an electronic benefits card—that they can use to purchase food. The size of each family’s Food Stamp benefit depends on its income: The poorer the family, the greater the benefit.

Transfers in Kind In addition to TANF and Food Stamps, the government provides many poor people with a number of important goods and services, either at no charge or at prices that are well below market levels. Medical care under the Medicaid program and subsidized public housing are two notable examples.2 These programs significantly enhance the living standards of the poor. However, most of them offer benefits that decline as family income rises. Taken as a whole, all of the antipoverty programs together put some poor families in a position where they are taxed extremely heavily if their earnings rise. When this situation occurs, the incentive to work becomes quite weak.

The Negative Income Tax

The negative income tax (NIT) is a program where people below a certain income range would receive a payment from the government.

How can we do the job better? Can we design a simple structure that gets income into the hands of the poor without destroying their incentives to work? The solution suggested most frequently by economists is called the negative income tax (NIT). Table 4 illustrates how a NIT works. A particular NIT plan is defined by picking two numbers: a minimum income level below which no family is allowed to fall (the “guarantee”) and a rate at which benefits are “taxed TABLE 4 away” as income rises. The table considers a Illustration of a Negative Income Tax Plan plan with a $12,000 guaranteed income and a Benefits Total 50 percent tax rate. Thus, a family with no Earnings Paid Income earnings (top row) would receive a $12,000 $ 0 $12,000 $12,000 payment (a “negative tax”) from the govern4,000 10,000 14,000 ment. A family earning $4,000 (second row) 8,000 8,000 16,000 would have the basic benefit reduced by 12,000 6,000 18,000 50 percent of its earnings, or $2,000. Thus, it 16,000 4,000 20,000 20,000 2,000 22,000 would receive $10,000 from the government 24,000 0 24,000 plus the $4,000 earned income for a total income of $14,000. Notice in Table 4 that, with a 50 percent tax rate, the increase in total income as earnings rise is always half of the increase in earnings. Thus, recipients always have some incentive to work. Notice also that there is a level of income at which benefits cease—$24,000 in this example. This “break-even” level is not a third number that policy makers can select freely. Rather, it is dictated by the choices of the guarantee and the tax rate. In our example, $12,000 is the maximum possible benefit, and benefits are reduced by 50 cents for each $1 of earnings. Hence, benefits will be reduced to zero when 50 percent of earnings is equal to $12,000—which occurs when earnings are $24,000. The general relation is Guarantee 5 Tax rate 3 Break-even level

The fact that the break-even level is completely determined by the guarantee and the tax rate creates a vexing problem. To make a real dent in the poverty problem, the guarantee must be placed fairly close to the poverty line. But then any moderate tax rate will push the break-even level far above the poverty line. As a result, families who are not considered “poor” (although they are certainly not rich) will also receive benefits. For example, a low tax rate of 331⁄3 percent means that some benefits are paid to families whose income is as high as three times the guarantee level. Medicaid programs pay for the health care of low-income people; Medicare is available to all seniors, regardless of income. 2

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 21

457

Poverty, Inequality, and Discrimination

The solution seems obvious: raise the tax rate to bring the guarantee and the break-even level closer together. Then the incentive to work shrinks, and with it the principal rationale for the NIT in the first place. So the NIT is no panacea for the ills of the welfare system. Difficult choices must still be made.

The Negative Income Tax and Work Incentives The NIT should increase work incentives for welfare recipients. However, we have just seen that a number of families who are now too well off to collect welfare inevitably would become eligible for NIT payments. For these people, the NIT imposes work disincentives by subjecting them to the relatively high NIT tax rate. Government-sponsored experiments back in the 1960s found that recipients of NIT benefits did in fact work less than nonrecipients, but only by a slight amount. Largely because of its superior work incentives, economists believe that a NIT is a more efficient way to redistribute income than the existing multifaceted welfare system. If this view is correct, then replacing the current welfare system with a NIT would lead to both more equality and more efficiency. But this does not mean that equalization would become costfree. There is still a trade-off: By increasing equality, we still diminish the nation’s output. The Negative Income Tax and Reality The NIT is often mistakenly viewed as an “academic” idea that does not exist in practice. But, in fact, America has two important programs that strongly resemble a NIT. One is the Food Stamps program already mentioned. Food Stamp benefits decline as earnings rise, and Food Stamps are used like cash in many poor neighborhoods. Hence, Food Stamp benefits look very much like the NIT plan illustrated in Table 4. The second program is an important feature of the income tax code, called the Earned Income Tax Credit (EITC). It works as follows. As earnings rise from zero to some threshold (which was about $12,500 in 2009 for a worker with two children), the federal government supplements the earnings of the working poor by giving them what amounts to a grant that is proportional to their earnings. Once earnings pass a second threshold (about $16,500 in 2009), the government starts taking this grant back, just as a NIT would. The EITC dates back to 1975 but was made substantially more generous in 1993. It is now America’s biggest income-support program, reaching over 25 million families.

The Earned Income Tax Credit (EITC) is a program in which the federal government gives out grants to certain families proportional to their earnings.

OTHER POLICIES TO COMBAT INEQUALITY If we take the broader view that society’s objective is not just to eliminate poverty, but to reduce income disparities, then the fact that many nonpoor families would receive benefits under a NIT is perhaps not a serious drawback. After all, unless the plan is outlandishly generous, these families’ incomes will still fall well below the average. Even so, the NIT is largely thought of as an antipoverty program, not as a tool for general income equalization.

The Personal Income Tax By contrast, the federal personal income tax is thought of as a way to promote greater equality. Indeed, it is probably given far more credit in this regard than it actually deserves. Because the income tax is progressive, it takes a larger share of income from the rich than from the poor.3 Thus, incomes after tax are distributed more equally than incomes before tax. The actual amount of redistribution achieved by the personal income tax is quite small—and even that was reduced by the tax cuts of 2001–2003.

Death Duties and Other Taxes Taxes on inheritances and estates levied by both states and the federal government also equalize incomes. In this case, they seem clearly aimed at limiting the incomes of the rich, 3

For definitions of progressive, proportional, and regressive taxes, see Chapter 18.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

458

Part 5

The Distribution of Income

or at least at limiting their ability to transfer this largesse from one generation to the next. But the amount of money involved is too small to make much difference to the overall income distribution. Total receipts from estate and gift taxes by all levels of government provide less than 1 percent of total tax revenues. Nonetheless, the federal estate tax has been a hot political issue since 2001 when Congress voted to eliminate it, but in a rather unusual way. Under current law, the estate tax was phased out in January 2010, but then it will miraculously reappear in 2011 unless Congress acts! So it is a good bet that the estate tax law will be changed again in the coming years. Exactly how is not so clear. Most experts agree that the many other taxes in the U.S. system—including sales taxes, payroll taxes, and property taxes—are decidedly regressive as a group. On balance, the evidence seems to suggest that The U.S. tax system as a whole is only slightly progressive.

POLICIES TO COMBAT DISCRIMINATION

Affirmative action refers to active efforts to locate and hire members of underrepresented groups.

The policies we have just considered are all based on taxes and transfer payments—on moving dollars from one set of hands to another. A quite different approach has been used to fight discrimination: Governments have made it illegal to discriminate. Perhaps the major milestone in the war against discrimination was the Civil Rights Act of 1964, which outlawed many forms of discrimination and established the Equal Employment Opportunity Commission (EEOC). When you read in a want ad that the company is “an equal opportunity employer,” the firm is proclaiming its compliance with this and related legislation. Originally, policy makers sought to attack the problem by outlawing discrimination in rates of pay and in hiring standards—and by devoting resources to enforcing these provisions. Some progress in reducing discrimination by race and sex undoubtedly was made between 1964 and the early 1970s. However, many people felt the pace was too slow. One reason was that discrimination in the labor market proved to be more subtle than was first thought. Only rarely could officials find definitive proof that unequal pay was being given for equal work, because determining when work was “equal” turned out to be a formidable task. To combat this problem, a new and controversial approach was added to the antidiscrimination arsenal. Firms and other organizations with suspiciously small representations of minorities or women in their workforces were required not just to end discriminatory practices but also to demonstrate that they were taking affirmative action to remedy this imbalance. That is, they had to document the fact that they were making efforts to locate members of minority groups and females and then to hire them if they were qualified. This approach to fighting discrimination remains controversial to this day. Critics, including many Republicans in Congress, claim that affirmative action amounts to numerical quotas and compulsory hiring of unqualified workers simply because they are black or female. If this allegation is true, it exacts a toll on economic efficiency. Proponents of affirmative action, including many Democrats, argue that affirmative action is needed to redress past wrongs and to prevent discriminatory employers from claiming that they are unable to find qualified minority or female employees. (See the box “Should Affirmative Action Be Abolished?” on the next page.) The difficulty revolves around the impossibility of deciding who is “qualified” and who is not based on purely objective criteria. What one person sees as government coercion to hire an unqualified applicant to fill a quota, another sees as a discriminatory employer being forced to mend his or her ways. Nothing in this book, or anywhere else, will teach you which view is correct in any particular instance. The controversy over affirmative action once again illustrates the trade-off between equality and efficiency. Putting more women and members of minority groups into high-paying jobs would certainly make the income distribution more equal. Supporters of affirmative action seek that result. But if affirmative action disrupts industry and requires firms to replace

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 21

Poverty, Inequality, and Discrimination

459

P OLICY D E B AT E

Should Affirmative Action Be Abolished? state universities. (In California, this action followed a contentious statewide referendum on the matter.) When they did, minority enrollments plummeted so dramatically that a few opponents of affirmative action had well-publicized second thoughts. The issue remains open. Few people actually like affirmative action—it offends many people’s sense of fairness, and even many supporters view it as a necessary evil. New appointments to the Supreme Court have made the Court less and less sympathetic to affirmative action over the years.

SOURCE: © Paul J. Richards/AFP/Getty Images

Affirmative action was controversial from the start. It became a particularly hot political issue in the 1990s and 2000s, as conservative politicians reacted to what they perceived to be one of the chief grievances of the “angry white male.” A number of critics believe that affirmative action has outlived its usefulness. It is time, they say, to rely on “race-blind” standards that judge each person on his or her individual merits. Any other system of selection is unfair, they insist, especially when affirmative action programs devolve into rigid quotas by race or sex—as they frequently do. Although no federal laws were changed, an important 1995 Supreme Court ruling in Adarand v. Pena set new and tougher standards for federal affirmative action programs. This ruling prompted President Clinton to order a comprehensive review of federal programs that favored minorities in such matters as hiring and awarding contracts. Although a few programs were cut back or eliminated, the review generally concluded that the United States was still so far from being a “color-blind” society that affirmative action was still needed, and the president continued to defend affirmative action against Republican efforts to eliminate it. Some state governments, however, went much farther than the federal government. California and Texas, for example, abolished several affirmative action programs at their

“qualified” white males with other, “less qualified” workers, the nation’s productivity will suffer. Opponents of affirmative action are disturbed by these potential efficiency losses. How far should these programs be pushed? A good question, but one without a good answer.

A LOOK BACK We have now completed three chapters on the distribution of income. So this may be an opportune moment to pause and see how this analysis relates to our central theme: What does the market do well, and what does it do poorly? We have learned that a market economy relies on the marginal productivity principle to assign an income to each individual. In so doing, the market attaches high prices to scarce factors and low prices to abundant ones and therefore guides firms to use society’s resources efficiently. This ability is one of the market’s great strengths. However, by attaching high prices to some factors and low prices to others, the market mechanism may create a distribution of income that is quite unequal. Some people wind up fabulously rich, whereas others wind up miserably poor. For this reason, the market has been widely criticized for centuries for doing a rather poor job of distributing income in accord with commonly held notions of fairness and equity. On balance, most observers feel that both the praise and the criticism are well justified: The market mechanism is extraordinarily good at promoting efficiency but not very good at promoting equality. As we said at the outset, the market has both virtues and vices.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

460

Part 5

The Distribution of Income

| SUMMARY | 1. The United States declared a “War on Poverty” in 1964, and within a decade the fraction of families below the official poverty line had dropped substantially. Today, the poverty rate is higher than it was in the 1970s. 2. In the United States today, the richest 20 percent of households receive about 50 percent of the income, whereas the poorest 20 percent of households receive less than 31⁄2 percent. These numbers reflect a considerable increase in inequality since about 1980. The U.S. income distribution also appears to be more unequal than those of most other industrial nations. 3. Individual incomes differ for many reasons. Differences in natural abilities, in the desire to work hard and to take risks, in schooling and experience, and in inherited wealth all account for income disparities. Economic discrimination also plays a role. All of these factors, however, explain only part of the inequality that we observe. A portion of the rest is due simply to good or bad luck, and the balance is unexplained. 4. There is a trade-off between the goals of reducing inequality and enhancing economic efficiency. Namely, policies that help on the equality front normally harm efficiency, and vice versa. 5. Because of this trade-off, there is in principle an optimal degree of inequality for any society. Society finds this optimum in the same way that a consumer decides how much to buy of different commodities: The trade-off tells us how costly it is to “purchase” more equality, and preferences then determine how much should be

“bought.” However, because people have different value judgments about the importance of equality, they disagree over the ideal amount of equality. 6. Whatever goal for equality is selected, society can gain by using more efficient redistributive policies because such policies let us “buy” any given amount of equality at a lower price in terms of lost output. Economists claim, for example, that a negative income tax is an efficient redistributive tool. 7. But the negative income tax is no panacea for all inequality-related problems. Its primary virtue is the way it preserves incentives to work. But if this goal is accomplished by keeping the tax rate low, then either the minimum guaranteed level of income will have to be low or many nonpoor families will become eligible to receive benefits. 8. The goal of income equality is also pursued through the tax system, especially through the progressive federal income tax and death duties. But other taxes are typically regressive, so the tax system as a whole is only slightly progressive. 9. Discrimination has been attacked by making it illegal, rather than through the tax and transfer system. But simply declaring discrimination to be illegal is much easier than actually ending discrimination. The tradeoff between equality and efficiency applies once again: Strict enforcement of affirmative action will certainly reduce discrimination and increase income equality, but it may do so at a cost in terms of economic efficiency.

| KEY TERMS | absolute concept of poverty affirmative action

448

458

456

relative concept of poverty

negative income tax (NIT)

Earned Income Tax Credit (EITC) 457 economic discrimination

Food Stamps poverty line

456

447

448

Temporary Assistance to Needy Families (TANF) 455

452

| TEST YOURSELF | 1. Define the poverty rate. Does it rise or fall during recessions? 2. Since the official poverty line was set at $3,000 in 1964, prices have risen by about a factor of 7. If the poverty

line was adjusted only for inflation, what would it be now? How does that compare with the actual poverty line?

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 21

Poverty, Inequality, and Discrimination

461

| DISCUSSION QUESTIONS | 1. Discuss the “leaky bucket” analogy (page 454) with your classmates. What maximum amount of income would you personally allow to leak from the bucket in transferring money from the rich to the poor? Explain why people differ in their answers to this question. 2. Suppose you were to design a negative income tax system for the United States. Pick a guaranteed income level and a tax rate that seem reasonable to you. What break-even level of income is implied by these choices? Construct a version of Table 4 for the plan you have just devised. 3. Suppose the War on Poverty were starting anew and you were part of a presidential commission assigned the task of defining the poor. Would you choose an absolute

or a relative concept of poverty? Why? What would be your specific definition of poverty? 4. Discuss the concept of the “optimal amount of inequality.” What are some of the practical problems in determining how much inequality really is optimal? 5. A number of conservative politicians and economists advocate replacing the progressive income tax with a “flat tax” that would apply the same, low tax rate to all income above a certain exempt amount. One argument against making this change is that the distribution of income has grown much more unequal since the 1970s. Does the evidence support that view? Is it a decisive argument against a flat tax? How is the trade-off between equality and efficiency involved here?

| APPENDIX | The Economic Theory of Discrimination Although discrimination is often thought of as a noneconomic topic, economic analysis can actually tell us quite a bit about its economic effects. This appendix uses some of the analysis we have provided in previous chapters to shed light on two specific questions: 1. Must prejudice, which we define as arising when one group dislikes associating with another group, lead to economic discrimination as defined in the chapter (unequal pay for equal work)? 2. Do “natural” economic forces tend either to erode or to exacerbate discrimination over time? Exactly who is prejudiced or discriminatory turns out to be critical to the answers, as we will now see.

DISCRIMINATION BY EMPLOYERS Most attention seems to focus on discrimination by employers, so let us start there. What happens if, for example, some firms refuse to hire blacks? Figure 2 will help us find the answer. Panel (a) pertains to firms that discriminate; Panel (b) pertains to firms that do not. Supply and demand curves for labor in each market are shown in the figure, based on the analysis of Chapter 20. We suppose that the two demand curves are identical. However, the supply curve in market (b) must be farther to the right than the supply curve in market (a) because both whites and blacks can work in market (b), whereas only whites can work in market (a). The result is that wages will be lower in market (b) than they are in market (a). Because all the blacks are forced

into market (b), we conclude that employers discriminate against them in the economic sense of that word. Now consider the situation from the employers’ point of view. Firms in market (a) pay more for labor (W a is greater than W b), so the nondiscriminatory firms in market (b) have a cost advantage. As we learned in earlier chapters, the forces of competition will shift more and more of the total market to the low-cost (nondiscriminatory) producers, eventually driving the discriminators out of business. Of course, this only happens if there is effective competition. If the discriminating firm in market (a) has a protected monopoly, it will be able to stay in business. But it will still pay for the privilege of discriminating by earning lower monopoly profits than it otherwise would (because it will pay higher wages than necessary).

DISCRIMINATION BY FELLOW WORKERS So, if employers are the source of discrimination, competitive forces tend to reduce discrimination over time. Such optimistic conclusions do not follow, however, if it is fellow workers who are prejudiced. Consider what happens, for example, if men object to having women as their supervisors. If male workers will not give their full cooperation, female supervisors will be less effective than male supervisors and hence will earn lower wages. Here prejudice does lead to discrimination. Furthermore, in this case, firms that put women into supervisory positions will be at a competitive disadvantage relative to firms that do not. So market forces will not erode discrimination.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

462

Part 5

The Distribution of Income

FIGURE 2 Wage Discrimination Sa

Wa

D

Sa

Sb

D

Wage Rate

Wage Rate

D

Number of Workers (a) Discriminators

STATISTICAL DISCRIMINATION A final type of discrimination, called statistical discrimination, may be the most stubborn of all. And it can exist even when there is no prejudice. Statistical discrimination is said to occur when the productivity of a particular worker is estimated to be low just because that worker belongs to a particular group (such as women).

Let us look at an important example. It is, of course, a biological fact that only women give birth. It is also a fact that most working women who have babies leave their jobs for a while to care for their newborns. Employers recognize both facts. What they cannot know, however, is which women of child-bearing age will leave the labor force for this reason. Suppose three candidates apply for a job that requires a long-term commitment. Susan plans to quit after a few years to raise a family. Jane does not plan to have any children. Jack is a man. If he knew all the facts, the employer might not want Susan, but would be equally happy with either Jane or Jack. But the employer cannot differentiate between Susan and Jane. He therefore presumes that either one, being a young woman, is more likely than Jack to quit to raise a family. So he hires Jack, even though Jane is just as good a prospect. Thus Jane is a victim of statistical discrimination.

Wb

Sb

D

Number of Workers (b) Nondiscriminators

Lest it be thought that this example actually justifies discrimination against women on economic grounds, it should be noted that most women return to work within six months after childbirth. Furthermore, women typically have less absenteeism and job turnover for nonpregnancy health reasons than men do. The box “Are Women Better Workers?” argues that employers often fail to take these other sex-related differences into account and thus mistakenly favor men.

THE ROLES OF THE MARKET AND THE GOVERNMENT In terms of the two questions with which we began this appendix, we conclude that different types of discrimination lead to different answers. Prejudice will often, but not always, lead to economic discrimination, and discrimination may occur even in the absence of prejudice. Finally, the forces of competition tend to erode some, but not all, of the inequities produced by discrimination. However, the victims of discrimination are not the only losers when discrimination occurs. Society also loses whenever discriminatory practices impair economic efficiency. Thus reasonable antidiscrimination policies should be able to enhance both equality and efficiency. For this reason, most observers believe that we should not rely on market forces alone to combat discrimination. The government has a clear role to play.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 21

Poverty, Inequality, and Discrimination

463

Are Women Better Workers? In the piece excerpted here, economist Audrey Freedman argues that a female employee can be a better bargain than a male, even though only women request pregnancy leaves and it is mainly women who miss workdays for child-care reasons. It is undeniable . . . that women, not men, take pregnancy leaves. It is also undeniable that women are the primary nurturers in a family. They are the most likely to be responsible for the care and support of children, as well as their elderly parents. If we stop there . . . women in business are more costly than men. But the built-in bias of that analysis is the failure to account for far more costly drains on corporate productivity from behavior that is more characteristic of men than of women. For example, men are more likely to be heavy users of alcohol. This gender-related habit causes businesses to suffer excessive medical costs, serious performance losses, and productivity drains. Yet, the male-dominated corporate hierarchy most often chooses to ignore these “good old boy” habits. Drug abuse among the fast-movers of Wall Street seems to be understood as a normal response to the pressures of taking risks with other people’s money. The consequences in loss of judgment are tolerated. They are not calculated as a malerelated cost of business. . . . In addition, in our culture, lawlessness and violence are found far more often among men than women. The statistics on criminals and prison population are obvious, yet we seem to be unable to recognize these as primarily male behaviors.

A top executive of a major airline once commented to me that his company’s greatest problem is machismo in the cockpit— pilots and copilots fighting over the controls. There is an obvious solution: Hire pilots from that half of the population that is less susceptible to the attacks of rage that afflict macho males.

Image not available due to copyright restrictions

SOURCE: Audrey Freedman, “Those Costly ‘Good Old Boys,’” The New York Times, July 12, 1989, p. A23. Copyright 1989 by the New York Times Company. Reprinted by permission.

| SUMMARY | 1. Prejudice by employers will result in discrimination in rates of pay and in partial segregation of the workplace. However, the forces of competition should erode this type of discrimination.

places. But competition will not erode this type of discrimination. 3. Discrimination may also arise even when there is no prejudice. This is called statistical discrimination.

2. Prejudice by fellow workers will result in wage discrimination, and perhaps even in segregated work-

| KEY TERM | statistical discrimination

462

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Part

The Macroeconomy: Aggregate Supply and Demand

M

acroeconomics is the headline-grabbing part of economics. When economic news appears on the front page of your daily newspaper or is reported on the nightly television news, you are most likely reading or hearing about some macroeconomic development in the national or world economy. The Federal Reserve has just cut interest rates. Inflation remains low. Jobs remain scarce. The federal government’s budget shows a large deficit. The euro is rising in value. These developments are all macroeconomic news. But what do they mean? Part 6 begins your study of macroeconomics. It will first acquaint you with some of the major concepts of macroeconomics—things that you hear about every day, such as gross domestic product (GDP), inflation, unemployment, and economic growth (Chapters 22 and 23). Then it will introduce the basic theory that we use to interpret and understand macroeconomic events (Chapters 24 through 27). By the time you finish Chapter 27— which is only six chapters away—those newspaper articles will make a lot more sense.

C H A P T E R S 22 | An Introduction

25 | Aggregate Demand and

23 | The Goals of

26 | Demand-Side Equilibrium:

24 | Economic Growth: Theory

27 | Bringing in the Supply Side:

to Macroeconomics Macroeconomic Policy and Policy

the Powerful Consumer

Unemployment or Inflation? Unemployment and Inflation?

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

An Introduction to Macroeconomics Where the telescope ends, the microscope begins. Which of the two has the grander view? VICTOR HUGO

B

y time-honored tradition, economics is divided into two fields: microeconomics and macroeconomics. These inelegant words are derived from the Greek, where micro means something small and macro means something large. Chapters 3 and 4 introduced you to microeconomics. This chapter does the same for macroeconomics. How do the two branches of the discipline differ? It is not a matter of using different tools. As we shall see in this chapter, supply and demand provide the basic organizing framework for constructing macroeconomic models, just as they do for microeconomic models. Rather, the distinction is based on the issues addressed. For an example of a macroeconomic question, turn the page.

C O N T E N T S ISSUE: HOW DID THE HOUSING BUST

Recession and Unemployment Economic Growth

DRAWING A LINE BETWEEN MACROECONOMICS AND MICROECONOMICS

GROSS DOMESTIC PRODUCT

LEAD TO THE GREAT RECESSION?

Aggregation and Macroeconomics The Foundations of Aggregation The Line of Demarcation Revisited

SUPPLY AND DEMAND IN MACROECONOMICS A Quick Review Moving to Macroeconomic Aggregates Inflation

Money as the Measuring Rod: Real versus Nominal GDP What Gets Counted in GDP? Limitations of the GDP: What GDP Is Not

THE ECONOMY ON A ROLLER COASTER Growth, but with Fluctuations Inflation and Deflation The Great Depression From World War II to 1973 The Great Stagflation, 1973–1980

Reaganomics and Its Aftermath Clintonomics: Deficit Reduction and the “New Economy” Tax Cuts and the Bush Economy

ISSUE REVISITED: HOW DID THE HOUSING

BUST LEAD TO THE GREAT RECESSION?

THE PROBLEM OF MACROECONOMIC STABILIZATION: A SNEAK PREVIEW Combating Unemployment Combating Inflation Does It Really Work?

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

468

Part 6

The Macroeconomy: Aggregate Supply and Demand

ISSUE:

HOW DID THE HOUSING BUST LEAD TO THE GREAT RECESSION?

The U.S. economy expanded, albeit at highly variables rates, for 25 consecutive quarters starting in the fourth quarter of 2001 and continuing through the fourth quarter of 2007. Then the economy hit a wall, declining in five of the next six quarters before finally righting itself in 2009. What went wrong? Part of the answer is well-known. An exceptional boom in homebuilding came to an abrupt end early in 2006, and then turned into a severe housing bust that did not hit bottom until the middle of 2009. Although housing was not the only factor at work, it was certainly a major contributor to the Great Recession. But how? How does a housing bust lead an entire economy downhill? There is, of course, no simple answer to questions like these. But beginning in this chapter and continuing through Parts 6 and 7, we will learn a great deal about the factors that determine whether an economy grows or declines—and how fast. Among those factors, we will see, are a number of government policy decisions.

DRAWING A LINE BETWEEN MACROECONOMICS AND MICROECONOMICS In microeconomics, the spotlight is on how individual decision-making units behave. For example, the dairy farmers of Chapter 4 are individual decision makers; so are the consumers who purchase the milk. How do they decide which actions are in their own best interests? How are these millions of decisions coordinated by the market mechanism, and with what consequences? Questions such as these lie at the heart of microeconomics. Although Plato and Aristotle might wince at the abuse of their language, microeconomics applies to the decisions of some astonishingly large units. The annual sales of General Electric and Wal-Mart, for example, exceed the total production of many nations. Yet someone who studies GE’s pricing policies is a microeconomist, whereas someone who studies inflation in a small country like Monaco is a macroeconomist. The micro-macro distinction in economics is certainly not based solely on size. What, then, is the basis for this long-standing distinction? The answer is that, whereas microeconomics focuses on the decisions of individual units, no matter how large, macroeconomics concentrates on the behavior of entire economies, no matter how small. Microeconomists might look at a single company’s pricing and output decisions. Macroeconomists study the overall price level, unemployment rate, and other things that we call economic aggregates.

Aggregation and Macroeconomics

Aggregation means combining many individual markets into one overall market.

An “economic aggregate” is simply an abstraction that people use to describe some salient feature of economic life. For example, although we observe the prices of gasoline, telephone calls, and movie tickets every day, we never actually see “the price level.” Yet many people—not just economists—find it meaningful to speak of “the cost of living.” In fact, the government’s attempts to measure it are widely publicized by the news media each month. Among the most important of these abstract notions is the concept of domestic product, which represents the total production of a nation’s economy. The process by which real objects such as software, baseballs, and theater tickets are combined into an abstraction called total domestic product is aggregation, and it is one of the foundations of macroeconomics. We can illustrate it by a simple example. An imaginary nation called Agraria produces nothing but foodstuffs to sell to consumers. Rather than deal separately with the many markets for pizzas, candy bars, hamburgers, and so on, macroeconomists group them all into a single abstract “market for output.” Thus, when macroeconomists announce that output in Agraria grew 10 percent last year, are they referring to more potatoes or hot dogs, more soybeans or

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 22

An Introduction to Macroeconomics

green peppers? The answer is: They do not care. In the aggregate measures of macroeconomics, output is output, no matter what form it takes.

The Foundations of Aggregation Amalgamating many markets into one means ignoring distinctions among different products. Can we really believe that no one cares whether the national output of Agraria consists of $800,000 worth of pickles and $200,000 worth of ravioli rather than $500,000 each of lettuce and tomatoes? Surely this is too much to swallow. Macroeconomists certainly do not believe that no one cares; instead, they rest the case for aggregation on two foundations: 1. Although the composition of demand and supply in the various markets may be terribly important for some purposes (such as how income is distributed and the diets people enjoy), it may be of little consequence for the economy-wide issues of growth, inflation, and unemployment—the issues that concern macroeconomists. 2. During economic fluctuations, markets tend to move up or down together. When demand in the economy rises, there is more demand for potatoes and tomatoes, more demand for artichokes and pickles, more demand for ravioli and hot dogs.

Although there are exceptions to these two principles, both are serviceable enough as approximations. In fact, if they were not, there would be no discipline called macroeconomics, and a full-year course in economics could be reduced to a half-year. Lest this cause you a twinge of regret, bear in mind that many people believe that unemployment and inflation would be far more difficult to control without macroeconomics—which would be a lot worse.

The Line of Demarcation Revisited These two principles—that the composition of demand and supply may not matter for some purposes, and that markets normally move together—enable us to draw a different kind of dividing line between microeconomics and macroeconomics. In macroeconomics, we typically assume that most details of resource allocation and income distribution are relatively unimportant to the study of the overall rates of inflation and unemployment. In microeconomics, we generally ignore inflation, unemployment, and growth, focusing instead on how individual markets allocate resources and distribute income.

To use a well-worn metaphor, a macroeconomist analyzes the size of the proverbial economic “pie,” paying scant attention to what is inside it or to how it gets divided among the dinner guests. A microeconomist, by contrast, assumes that the pie is of the right size and shape, and frets over its ingredients and who gets to eat it. If you have ever baked or eaten a pie, you will realize that either approach alone is a trifle myopic. Economics is divided into macroeconomics and microeconomics largely for the sake of pedagogical clarity: We can’t teach you everything at once. In reality, the crucial interconnection between macroeconomics and microeconomics is with us all the time. There is, after all, only one economy.

SUPPLY AND DEMAND IN MACROECONOMICS Whether you are taking a course that concentrates on macroeconomics or one that focuses on microeconomics, the discussion of supply and demand in Chapter 4 served as an invaluable introduction. Supply and demand analysis is just as fundamental to macroeconomics as it is to microeconomics.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

469

470

The Macroeconomy: Aggregate Supply and Demand

Part 6

A Quick Review Figure 1 shows two diagrams that should look familiar from Chapter 4. In Figure 1(a), we find a downward-sloping demand curve, labeled DD, and an upward-sloping supply curve, labeled SS. Because the figure is a multipurpose diagram, the “Price” and “Quantity” axes do not specify any particular commodity. To start on familiar terrain, first imagine that this graph depicts the market for milk, so the vertical axis measures the price of milk and the horizontal axis measures the quantity of milk demanded and supplied. As we know, if nothing interferes with the operation of a free market, equilibrium will be at point E with a price P0 and a quantity of output Q0. Next, suppose something happens to shift the demand curve outward. For example, we learned in Chapter 4 that an increase in consumer incomes might do that. Figure 1(b) shows this shift as a rightward movement of the demand curve from D0D0 to D1D1. Equilibrium shifts from point E to point A, so both price and output rise.

Moving to Macroeconomic Aggregates The aggregate demand curve shows the quantity of domestic product that is demanded at each possible value of the price level. The aggregate supply curve shows the quantity of domestic product that is supplied at each possible value of the price level.

Now let’s switch from microeconomics to macroeconomics. To do so, we reinterpret Figure 1 as representing the market for an abstract object called “domestic product”—one of those economic aggregates that we described earlier. No one has ever seen, touched, or eaten a unit of domestic product, but these are the kinds of abstractions we use in macroeconomic analysis. Consistent with this reinterpretation, think of the price measured on the vertical axis as being another abstraction—the overall price index, or “cost of living.”1 Then the curve DD in Figure 1(a) is called an aggregate demand curve, and the curve SS is called an aggregate supply curve. We will develop an economic theory to derive these curves explicitly in Chapters 24 through 27. As we will see there, the curves have rather different origins from the microeconomic counterparts we encountered in Chapter 4.

F I GURE 1 Two Interpretations of a Shift in the Demand Curve

D1 S

S D0

D

A

E

Price

Price

P1

P0

E P0

D1 S

D

Q0 Quantity (a)

1

S

D0

Quantity (b)

Chapter 23’s appendix explains how such price indexes are calculated.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

471

An Introduction to Macroeconomics

Chapter 22

Inflation With this macroeconomic reinterpretation, Figure 1(b) depicts the problem of inflation. We see from the figure that the outward shift of the aggregate demand curve, whatever its cause, pushes the price level up. If aggregate demand keeps shifting out month after month, the economy will suffer from inflation—meaning a sustained increase in the general price level.

Inflation refers to a sustained increase in the general price level.

Recession and Unemployment The second principal issue of macroeconomics, recession and unemployment, also can be illustrated on a supply-demand diagram, this time by shifting the demand curve in the opposite direction. Figure 2 repeats the supply and demand curves of Figure 1(a) and in addition depicts a leftward shift of the aggregate demand curve from D0D0 to D2D2. Equilibrium now moves from point E to point B so that domestic product (total output) declines. This is what we normally mean by a recession—a period of time during which production falls and people lose jobs.

Economic Growth

A recession is a period of time during which the total output of the economy declines.

Figure 3 illustrates macroeconomists’ third area of concern: the process of economic growth. Here the original aggregate demand and supply curves are, once again, D0D0 and S0S0, which intersect at point E. But now we consider the possibility that both curves shift to the right over time, moving to D1D1 and S1S1, respectively. The new intersection point is C, and the brick-colored arrow running from point E to point C shows the economy’s growth path. Over this period of time, domestic product grows from Q0 to Q1. FIGU R E 2

FIGURE 3

An Economy Slipping into a Recession

Economic Growth

S

D0

S0

D1

S1 D0

D2

C Price Level

Price Level

E

B

E

S0 D0

D1 S1

S D2 Q2

D0

Q0

Domestic Product

Q0

Q1 Domestic Product

GROSS DOMESTIC PRODUCT Up to now, we have been somewhat cavalier in using the phrase “domestic product.” Let’s now get more specific. Of the various ways to measure an economy’s total output,

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

472

Part 6

The Macroeconomy: Aggregate Supply and Demand

Gross domestic product (GDP) is the sum of the money values of all final goods and services produced in the domestic economy and sold on organized markets during a specified period of time, usually a year.

the most popular choice by far is the gross domestic product, or GDP for short—a term you have probably encountered in the news media. GDP is the most comprehensive measure of the output of all the factories, offices, and shops in the United States. Specifically, it is the sum of the money values of all final goods and services produced in the domestic economy within the year. Several features of this definition need to be underscored.2 First, you will notice that We add up the money values of things.

Money as the Measuring Rod: Real versus Nominal GDP

Nominal GDP is calculated by valuing all outputs at current prices.

Real GDP is calculated by valuing outputs of different years at common prices. Therefore, real GDP is a far better measure than nominal GDP of changes in total production.

The GDP consists of a bewildering variety of goods and services: computer chips and potato chips, tanks and textbooks, ballet performances and rock concerts. How can we combine all of these into a single number? To an economist, there is a natural way to do so: First, convert every good and service into money terms, and then add all the money up. Thus, contrary to the cliché, we can add apples and oranges. To add 10 apples and 20 oranges, first ask: How much money does each cost? If apples cost 20 cents and oranges cost 25 cents, then the apples count for $2 and the oranges for $5, so the sum is $7 worth of “output.” The market price of each good or service is used as an indicator of its value to society for a simple reason: Someone is willing to pay that much money for it. This decision raises the question of what prices to use in valuing different outputs. The official data offer two choices. Most obviously, we can value each good and service at the price at which it was actually sold. If we take this approach, the resulting measure is called nominal GDP, or GDP in current dollars. This seems like a perfectly sensible choice, but it has one serious drawback as a measure of output: Nominal GDP rises when prices rise, even if there is no increase in actual production. For example, if hamburgers cost $2.00 this year but cost only $1.50 last year, then 100 hamburgers will contribute $200 to this year’s nominal GDP, whereas they contributed only $150 to last year’s nominal GDP. But one hundred hamburgers are still 100 hamburgers—output has not grown. For this reason, government statisticians have devised alternative measures that correct for inflation by valuing goods and services produced in different years at the same set of prices. For example, if the hamburgers were valued at $1.50 each in both years, $150 worth of hamburger output would be included in GDP in each year. In practice, such calculations can be quite complicated, but the details need not worry us in an introductory course. Suffice it to say that, when the calculations are done, we obtain real GDP or GDP in constant dollars. The news media often refer to this measure as “GDP corrected for inflation.” Throughout most of this book, and certainly whenever we are discussing the nation’s output, we will be concerned with real GDP. The distinction between nominal and real GDP leads us to a working definition of a recession as a period in which real GDP declines. For example, between the fourth quarter of 2007 and the second quarter of 2009, the recent recession, real GDP fell from $13,391 billion to $12,902 billion. In fact, it has become conventional to say that a recession occurs when real GDP declines for two or more consecutive quarters. In this mega-recession, real GDP declined for four consecutive quarters.

What Gets Counted in GDP? The next important aspect of the definition of GDP is that The GDP for a particular year includes only goods and services produced within the year. Sales of items produced in previous years are explicitly excluded.

2 Certain exceptions to the definition are dealt with in Chapter 25’s appendix. Some instructors may prefer to take up that material here.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 22

473

An Introduction to Macroeconomics

For example, suppose you buy a perfectly beautiful 1985 Thunderbird from a friend next week and are overjoyed by your purchase. The national income statistician will not share your glee. She counted that car in the GDP of 1985, when it was first produced and sold, and will never count it again. The same is true of houses. The resale values of houses do not count in GDP because they were counted in the years they were built. Next, you will note from the definition of gross domestic product that Only final goods and services count in the GDP.

The adjective final is the key word here. For example, when Dell buys computer chips from Intel, the transaction is not included in the GDP because Dell does not want the chips for itself. It buys them only to manufacture computers, which it sells to consumers. Only the computers are considered a final product. When Dell buys chips from Intel, economists consider the chips to be intermediate goods. The GDP excludes sales of intermediate goods and services because, if they were included, we would wind up counting the same outputs several times.3 For example, if chips sold to computer manufacturers were included in GDP, we would count the same chip when it was sold to the computer maker and then again as a component of the computer when it was sold to a consumer. Next, note that

Final goods and services are those that are purchased by their ultimate users.

An intermediate good is a good purchased for resale or for use in producing another good.

The adjective domestic in the definition of GDP denotes production within the geographic boundaries of the United States.

For the most part, only goods and services that pass through organized markets count in the GDP.

SOURCE: From The Wall Street Journal— Permission, Cartoon Features Syndicate.

Some Americans work abroad, and many American companies have offices or factories in foreign countries. For example, roughly half of IBM’s employees work outside the United States. Although all of these foreign employees of American firms produce valuable outputs, none of it counts in the GDP of the United States. (It counts, instead, in the GDPs of the other countries.) On the other hand, quite a few foreign companies produce goods and services in the United States. For example, if your family owns a Toyota or a Honda, it was most likely assembled in a factory here. All that activity of foreign firms on our soil does count in our GDP.4 Finally, the definition of GDP notes that

This restriction, of course, excludes many economic activities. For example, illegal activities are not included in the GDP. Thus, gambling services in Atlantic City are part of GDP, but gambling services in Chicago are not. Garage sales, although sometimes lucrative, are not included either. The definition reflects the statisticians’ inability to measure the value of many of the “More and more, I ask myself what’s economy’s most important activities, such as housework, do-it-yourself rethe point of pursuing the meaning pairs, and leisure time. These activities certainly result in currently produced of the universe if you can’t have a rising GNP.” goods or services, but they all lack that important measuring rod—a market price. This omission results in certain oddities. For example, suppose that each of two neighboring families hires the other to clean house, generously paying $1,000 per week for the services. Each family can easily afford such generosity because it collects an identical salary from its neighbor. Nothing real has changed, but GDP goes up by $104,000 per year. If this example seems trivial, you may be interested to know that,

Actually, there is another way to add up the GDP by counting a portion of each intermediate transaction. This is explained in Chapter 25’s appendix. 4 There is another concept, called gross national product, which counts the goods and services produced by all Americans, regardless of where they work. For consistency, the outputs produced by foreigners working in the United States are not included in GNP. In practice, the two measures—GDP and GNP—are very close. 3

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

474

Part 6

The Macroeconomy: Aggregate Supply and Demand

according to one estimate made some years ago, America’s GDP might be a stunning 44 percent higher if unpaid housework were valued at market prices and counted in GDP.5

Limitations of the GDP: What GDP Is Not Now that we have seen in some detail what the GDP is, let’s examine what it is not. In particular: Gross domestic product is not a measure of the nation’s economic well-being.

The GDP is not intended to measure economic well-being and does not do so for several reasons.

Only Market Activity Is Included in GDP As we have just seen, a great deal of work done in the home contributes to the nation’s well-being but is not counted in GDP because it has no price tag. One important implication of this exclusion arises when we try to compare the GDPs of developed and less developed countries. Americans are always amazed to hear that the per capita GDPs of the poorest African countries are less than $250 per year. Surely, no one could survive in America on $5 per week. How can Africans do it? Part of the answer, of course, is that these people are terribly poor. But another part of the answer is that International GDP comparisons are vastly misleading when the two countries differ greatly in the fraction of economic activity that each conducts in organized markets.

This fraction is relatively large in the United States and relatively small in the poorest countries. So when we compare their respective measured GDPs, we are not comparing the same economic activities. Many things that get counted in the U.S. GDP are not counted in the GDPs of very poor nations because they do not pass through markets. It is ludicrous to think that these people, impoverished as they are, survive on what an American thinks of as $5 per week. A second implication is that GDP statistics take no account of the so-called underground economy—a term that includes not just criminal activities, but also a great deal of legitimate business that is conducted in cash or by barter to escape the tax collector. Naturally, we have no good data on the size of the underground economy. Some observers, however, think that it may amount to 10 percent or more of U.S. GDP—and much more in some foreign countries.

GDP Places No Value on Leisure As a country gets richer, its citizens normally take more and more leisure time. If that is true, a better measure of national well-being that includes the value of leisure would display faster growth than conventionally measured GDP. For example, the length of the typical workweek in the United States fell steadily for many decades, which meant that growth in GDP systematically underestimated the growth in national well-being. But then this trend stopped and may even have reversed. (See “Are Americans Working More?” on the next page.)

“Bads” as Well as “Goods” Get Counted in GDP There are also reasons why the GDP overstates how well-off we are. Here is a tragic example. Disaster struck the United States on September 11, 2001. No one doubts that this made the nation worse off. Thousands of people were killed. Buildings and businesses were destroyed. Yet the disaster almost certainly raised GDP. The government spent more for disaster relief and cleanup, and later for reconstruction. Businesses spent more to rebuild and repair damaged buildings and replace lost items. Even consumers spent more on cleanup and replacing lost possessions. No one imagines that America was better off after 9/11, despite all this additional GDP. 5 Ann Chadeau, “What Is Households’ Non-Market Production Worth?” OECD Economic Studies, 18 (1992), pp. 85–103.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

An Introduction to Macroeconomics

Chapter 22

475

Are Americans Working More? According to conventional wisdom, the workweek in the United States is steadily shrinking, leaving Americans with more and more leisure time to enjoy. But a 1991 book by economist Juliet Schor pointed out that this view was wrong: Americans were really working longer and longer hours. Her findings were both provocative and controversial at the time. But since then, the gap between the typical American and European workweeks has widened.

SOURCE: © Comstock Images/Getty Images

In the last twenty years the amount of time Americans have spent at their jobs has risen steadily. . . . Americans report that they have only sixteen and a half hours of leisure a week, after the obligations of job and household are taken care of. . . . If present trends continue, by the end of the century Americans will be spending as much time at their jobs as they did back in the nineteen twenties. The rise in worktime was unexpected. For nearly a hundred years, hours had been declining. . . . Equally surprising, but also hardly recognized, has been the deviation from Western Europe. After progressing in tandem for nearly a century, the United States veered off into a trajectory of declining leisure, while in Europe work has been disappearing. . . . U.S. manufacturing employees currently work 320 more hours [per year]—the equivalent of over two months—than their counterparts in West Germany or France. . . . We have paid a price for prosperity. . . .

We are eating more, but we are burning up those calories at work. We have color televisions and compact disc players, but we need them to unwind after a stressful day at the office. We take vacations, but we work so hard throughout the year that they become indispensable to our sanity.

SOURCE: Juliet B. Schor, The Overworked American (New York: Basic Books; 1991), pp. 1–2, 10–11.

Wars represent an extreme example. Mobilization for a war fought on some other nation’s soil normally causes a country’s GDP to rise rapidly. But men and women serving in the military could be producing civilian output instead. Factories assigned to produce armaments could instead be making cars, washing machines, and televisions. A country at war is surely worse off than a country at peace, but this fact will not be reflected in its GDP.

Ecological Costs Are Not Netted Out of the GDP Many productive activities of a modern industrial economy have undesirable side effects on the environment. Automobiles provide an essential means of transportation, but they also despoil the atmosphere. Factories pollute rivers and lakes while manufacturing valuable commodities. Almost everything seems to produce garbage, which creates serious disposal problems. None of these ecological costs are deducted from the GDP in an effort to give us a truer measure of the net increase in economic welfare that our economy produces. Is this omission foolish? Not if we remember that national income statisticians are trying to measure economic activity conducted through organized markets, not national welfare. Now that we have defined several of the basic concepts of macroeconomics, let us breathe some life into them by perusing the economic history of the United States.

THE ECONOMY ON A ROLLER COASTER Growth, but with Fluctuations The most salient fact about the U.S. economy has been its seemingly limitless growth; it gets bigger almost every year. Nominal gross domestic product in 2009 was around $14.3 trillion, more than 28 times as much as in 1959. The black curve in Figure 4 shows

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

476

Part 6

The Macroeconomy: Aggregate Supply and Demand

F I GURE 4 Nominal GDP, Real GDP, and Real GDP per Capita since 1959 $50,000

$15,000 $14,000 $13,000

$40,000

$12,000 $11,000 $10,000

Dollars per Year

30,000

Real GDP per Capita (left scale)

$9,000 8,000

25,000 7,000 6,000

20,000

5,000 15,000

Real GDP (right scale)

4,000 3,000

10,000 Nominal GDP (right scale)

2,000

5,000 1,000 0 0 1955 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 Year

Billions of Dollars per Year

35,000

SOURCE: Economic Report of the President (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, various years).

$45,000

NOTE: Real GDP figures are in 2005 dollars.

Real GDP per capita is the ratio of real GDP divided by population.

that extraordinary upward march. But, as the discussion of nominal versus real GDP suggests, a large part of this apparent growth was simply inflation. Because of higher prices, the purchasing power of each 2009 dollar was about one-sixth of each 1959 dollar. Corrected for inflation, we see that real GDP (the blue curve in the figure) was only about 4 3⁄4 times greater in 2009 than in 1959. Another reason for the growth of GDP is population growth. A nation becomes richer only if its GDP grows faster than its population. To see how much richer the United States has actually become since 1959, we must divide real GDP by the size of the population to obtain real GDP per capita—which is the brick-colored line in Figure 4. It turns out that real output per person in 2009 was roughly 2.7 times as much as in 1959. That is still not a bad performance. If aggregate supply and demand grew smoothly from one year to the next, as was depicted in Figure 3, the economy would expand at a steady rate. But U.S. economic history displays a far less regular pattern—one of alternating periods of rapid and slow growth that are called macroeconomic fluctuations, or sometimes just business cycles. In some years— six since 1959, to be exact—real GDP actually declined. Such recessions, and their attendant problem of rising unemployment, have been a persistent feature of American economic performance—one to which we will pay much attention in the coming chapters. The bumps encountered along the American economy’s historic growth path stand out more clearly in Figure 5, which displays the same data in a different way and extends the time period back to 1870. Here we plot not the level of real GDP each year, but, rather, its growth rate—the percentage change from one year to the next. Now the booms and busts that delight and distress people—and swing elections—stand out clearly. For example, the

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

477

An Introduction to Macroeconomics

Chapter 22

FIGURE 5

Percentage Growth Rate of Real GDP

SOURCE: Constructed by the authors from Commerce Department data since 1929. Data for 1869–1928 are based on research by Professor Christina Romer.

The Growth Rate of U.S. Real Gross Domestic Product since 1870

Rapid industrialization 20

Pre-1940

15

Railroad prosperity

World War II

Roaring Twenties

Korean War Expansion of 1960s

World War I

10

Boom of 1990s

Expansion of 1980s

5

2007–09 Recession

0 1974–75 Recession

–5 Depression of 1890s

–10 –15

–20 1870 1880 1890 1900

Postwar depression Panic of 1907 Great Depression

Postwar recession

1990–91 1982–83 Recession Recession Post-1950

1910 1920 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990

2000 2009

Year

fact that real GDP grew by over 7 percent from 1983 to 1984 helped ensure Ronald Reagan’s landslide reelection. Then, from 1990 to 1991, real GDP actually fell by 1 percent, which helped Bill Clinton defeat George H. W. Bush. The recent recession stands out for its severity.

Inflation and Deflation The history of the inflation rate depicted in Figure 6 also shows more positive numbers than negative ones—more inflation than deflation. Although the price level has risen roughly 16-fold since 1869, the upward trend is of rather recent vintage. Prior to World

Deflation refers to a sustained decrease in the general price level.

FIGURE 6

World War I

25 Percentage Inflation Rate

SOURCE: Constructed by the authors from Commerce Department data since 1929. Data for 1869–1928 are based on research by Professor Christina Romer.

The Inflation Rate in the United States since 1870

World War II Postwar adjustment

20 Pre-1940

Inflation of the 1970s

15

Disinflation of the 1980s

10 5 0

Vietnam War inflation Post-1950

–5 –10

Post–Civil War deflation

Postwar deflation

Great Depression

–15 1870 1880 1890 1900 1910 1920 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 Year

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

2000 2009

478

Part 6

The Macroeconomy: Aggregate Supply and Demand

War II, Figure 6 shows periods of inflation and deflation, with little or no tendency for one to be more common than the other. Indeed, prices in 1940 were barely higher than those at the close of the Civil War. However, the figure does show some large gyrations in the inflation rate, including sharp bursts of inflation during and immediately after the two world wars and dramatic deflations in the 1870s, the 1880s, 1921–1922, and 1929–1933. Recently, as you can see, inflation has been both low and stable. In sum, although both real GDP, which measures the economy’s output, and the price level have grown a great deal over the past 140 years, neither has grown smoothly. The ups and downs of both real growth and inflation are important economic events that need to be explained. The remainder of Part 6, which develops a model of aggregate supply and demand, and Part 7, which explains the tools the government uses to try to manage aggregate demand, will build a macroeconomic theory designed to do precisely that.

The Great Depression As you look at these graphs, the Great Depression of the 1930s is bound to catch your eye. The decline in economic activity from 1929 to 1933 indicated in Figure 5 was the most severe in our nation’s history, and the rapid deflation in Figure 6 was extremely unusual. The Depression is but a dim memory now, but those who lived through it—including some of your grandparents—will never forget it.

Human Consequences Statistics often conceal the human consequences and drama of economic events. But in the case of the Great Depression, they stand as bitter testimony to its severity. The production of goods and services dropped an astonishing 30 percent, business investment almost dried up entirely, and the unemployment rate rose ominously from about 3 percent in 1929 to 25 percent in 1933—one person in four was jobless! From the data alone, you can conjure up pictures of soup lines, beggars on street corners, closed factories, and homeless families. (See “Life in ‘Hooverville.’”)

During the worst years of the Great Depression, unemployed workers congregated in shantytowns on the outskirts of many major cities. With a heavy dose of irony, these communities were known as “Hoovervilles,” in honor of the then–president of the United States, Herbert Hoover. A contemporary observer described a Hooverville in New York City as follows: It was a fairly popular “development” made up of a hundred or so dwellings, each the size of a dog house or chickencoop, often constructed with much ingenuity out of wooden boxes, metal cans, strips of cardboard or old tar paper. Here human beings lived on the margin of civilization by foraging for garbage, junk, and waste lumber. I found some . . . picking through heaps of rubbish they had gathered before their doorways or cooking over open fires or battered oilstoves. Still others spent their days improving their rent-free homes . . . Most of them, according to the police, lived by begging or trading in junk; when all else failed they ate at the soup kitchens or public canteens. . . . They lived in fear of being forcibly removed by the authorities, though the neighborhood people in many cases helped them and the police tolerated them for the time being.

SOURCE: © American Stock/Hulton Archive/Getty Images

Life in “Hooverville”

SOURCE: Mathew Josephson, Infidel in the Temple (New York: Knopf, 1967), pp. 82–83.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 22

479

An Introduction to Macroeconomics

The Great Depression was a worldwide event; no country was spared its ravages. It literally changed the histories of many nations. In Germany, it facilitated the ascendancy of Nazism. In the United States, it enabled Franklin Roosevelt to engineer one of the most dramatic political realignments in our history and to push through a host of political and economic reforms.

A Revolution in Economic Thought The worldwide depression also caused a

SOURCE: © Pictorial Press Ltd/Alamy

much-needed revolution in economic thinking. Until the 1930s, the prevailing economic theory held that a capitalist economy occasionally misbehaved but had a natural tendency to cure recessions or inflations by itself. The roller coaster bounced around but did not run off the tracks. But the stubbornness of the Great Depression shook almost everyone’s faith in the ability of the economy to correct itself. In England, this questioning attitude led John Maynard Keynes, one of the world’s most renowned economists, to write The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money (1936). Probably the most important economics book of the twentieth century, it carried a message that was considered revolutionary at the time. Keynes rejected the idea that the economy naturally gravitated toward smooth growth and high levels of employment, asserting instead that if pessimism led businesses and consumers to curtail their spending, the economy might be condemned to years of stagnation. In terms of our simple aggregate demand–aggregate supply framework, Keynes was suggesting that there were times when the aggregate demand curve shifted inward—as depicted in Figure 2. As that figure showed, the consequence would be declining output and deflation. This doleful prognosis sounded all too realistic at the time. But Keynes closed his book on a hopeful note by showing how certain government actions—the things we now call monetary and fiscal policy—might prod the economy out of a depressed state. The lessons he taught the world then are among the lessons we will be learning in the rest of Part 6 and in Part 7—along with many qualifications that economists have learned since 1936. These lessons show how governments can manage their economies so that recessions will not turn into depressions and depressions will not last as long as the Great Depression, but they also show why this is not an easy task. While Keynes was working on The General Theory, he wrote his friend John Maynard Keynes George Bernard Shaw that “I believe myself to be writing a book on economic theory which will largely revolutionize . . . the way the world thinks about economic problems.” In many ways, he was right.

From World War II to 1973 The Great Depression finally ended when the United States mobilized for war in the early 1940s. As government spending rose to extraordinarily high levels, it gave aggregate demand a big boost. Thus, fiscal policy was (accidentally) being used in a big way. The economy boomed, and the unemployment rate fell as low as 1.2 percent during the war. Figure 1(b) suggested that spending spurts such as this one should lead to inflation, but much of the potential inflation during World War II was contained by price controls. With prices held below the levels at which quantity supplied equaled quantity demanded, shortages of consumer goods were common. Sugar, butter, gasoline, cloth, and a host of other goods were strictly rationed. When controls were lifted after the war, prices shot up. A period of strong growth marred by several recessions after the war then gave way to the fabulous 1960s, a period of unprecedented—and noninflationary—growth that was credited to the success of the economic policies that Keynes had prescribed in the 1930s. For a while, it looked as if we could avoid both unemployment and inflation, as aggregate demand and aggregate supply expanded in approximate balance. The optimistic verdicts proved premature on both counts.

The government’s fiscal policy is its plan for spending and taxation. It can be used to steer aggregate demand in the desired direction.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

480

Part 6

The Macroeconomy: Aggregate Supply and Demand

Inflation came first, beginning about 1966. Its major cause, as it had been so many times in the past, was high levels of wartime spending. The Vietnam War pushed aggregate demand up too fast. Later, unemployment also rose when the economy ground to a halt in 1969. Despite a short and mild recession, inflation continued at 5 to 6 percent per year. Faced with persistent inflation, President Richard Nixon stunned the nation by instituting wage and price controls in 1971, the first time this tactic had ever been employed in peacetime. The controls program held inflation in check for a while, but inflation worsened dramatically in 1973, mainly because of an explosion in food prices caused by poor harvests around the world.

The Great Stagflation, 1973–1980

Stagflation is inflation that occurs while the economy is growing slowly (“stagnating”) or in a recession.

In 1973 things began to get much worse, not only for the United States but for all oilimporting nations. A war between Israel and the Arab nations precipitated a quadrupling of oil prices by the Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC). At the same time, continued poor harvests in many parts of the globe pushed world food prices higher. Prices of other raw materials also skyrocketed. By unhappy coincidence, these events came just as the Nixon administration was lifting wage and price controls. Just as had happened after World War II, the elimination of controls led to a temporary acceleration of inflation as prices that had been held artificially low were allowed to rise. For all these reasons, the inflation rate in the United States soared above 12 percent during 1974. Meanwhile, the U.S. economy was slipping into what was, up to then, its longest and most severe recession since the 1930s. Real GDP fell between late 1973 and early 1975, and the unemployment rate rose to nearly 9 percent. With both inflation and unemployment unusually virulent in 1974 and 1975, the press coined a new term—stagflation—to refer to the simultaneous occurrence of economic stagnation and rapid inflation. Conceptually, what was happening in this episode is that the economy’s aggregate supply curve, which normally moves outward from one year to the next, shifted inward instead. When this happens, the economy moves from a point like E to a point like A in Figure 7. Real GDP declines as the price level rises. Thanks to a combination of government actions and natural economic forces, the economy recovered. Unfortunately, stagflation came roaring back in 1979 when the price of oil soared again. This time, inflation hit the astonishing rate of 16 percent in the first half of 1980, and the economy sagged.

F I GURE 7 The Effects of an Adverse Supply Shift

S1 D S0

Price Level

A E

S1

D S0

Real GDP

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 22

481

An Introduction to Macroeconomics

Reaganomics and Its Aftermath Recovery was under way when President Ronald Reagan assumed office in January 1981, but high inflation seemed deeply ingrained. The new president promised to change things with a package of policies—mainly large tax cuts—that, he claimed, would both boost growth and reduce inflation. However, the Federal Reserve under Paul Volcker was already deploying monetary policy to fight inflation—which meant using excruciatingly high interest rates to deter spending. So while inflation did fall, the economy also slumped—into its worst recession since the Great Depression. When the 1981–1982 recession hit bottom, the unemployment rate was approaching 11 percent, the financial markets were in disarray, and the word depression had reentered the American vocabulary. The U.S. government also acquired chronically large budget deficits, far larger than anyone had dreamed possible only a few years before. This problem remained with us for about 15 years. The recovery that began in the winter of 1982–1983 proved to be vigorous and long lasting. Unemployment fell more or less steadily for about six years, eventually dropping below 5.5 percent. Meanwhile, inflation remained tame. These developments provided an ideal economic platform on which George H. W. Bush ran to succeed Reagan—and to continue his policies. But, unfortunately for the first President Bush, the good times did not keep rolling. Shortly after he took office, inflation began to accelerate a bit, and Congress enacted a deficit-reduction package (including a tax increase) not entirely to the president’s liking. Then, in mid-1990, the U.S. economy slumped into another recession—precipitated by yet another spike in oil prices before the Persian Gulf War. When the recovery from the 1990–1991 recession proved to be sluggish, candidate Bill Clinton hammered away at the lackluster economic performance of the Bush years. His message apparently resonated with American voters.

Monetary policy refers to actions taken by the Federal Reserve to influence aggregate demand by changing interest rates.

Clintonomics: Deficit Reduction and the “New Economy”6 Although candidate Clinton ran on a platform that concentrated on spurring economic growth, the yawning budget deficit forced President Clinton to concentrate on deficit reduction instead. A politically contentious package of tax increases and spending cuts barely squeaked through Congress in August 1993, and a second deficit-reduction package passed in 1997. Transforming the huge federal budget deficit into a large surplus turned out to be the crowning achievement of Clinton’s economic policy. Whether by cause or coincidence, the national economy boomed during President Clinton’s eight years in office. Business spending perked up, the stock market soared, unemployment fell rapidly, and even inflation drifted lower. Why did all these wonderful things happen at once? Some optimists heralded the arrival of an exciting “New Economy”—a product of globalization and computerization—that naturally performs better than the economy of the past. The new economy was certainly an alluring vision. But was it real? Most mainstream economists would answer yes and no. On the one hand, advances in computer and information technology did seem to lead to faster growth in the second half of the 1990s. In that respect, we did get a “New Economy.” But something more mundane also happened: A variety of transitory factors pushed the economy’s aggregate supply curve outward at an unusually rapid pace between 1996 and 1998. When this happens, the expected result is faster economic growth and lower inflation, as Figure 8 shows.

6

One of the authors of this book was a member of President Clinton’s original Council of Economic Advisers.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

482

Part 6

The Macroeconomy: Aggregate Supply and Demand

F I GURE 8

S0

D1

The Effects of a Favorable Supply Shift

S1 D0 S2

Price Level

C B

E

S0 D1 S1 D0

S2

Real GDP

Figure 8 takes the graphical analysis of economic growth from Figure 3 and adds a new aggregate supply curve, S2S2, which lies to the right of S1S1. With supply curve S2S2 instead of S1S1, the economy moves from point E not just to point C, as in the earlier figure, but all the way to point B. Comparing B to C, we see that the economy winds up both farther to the right (that is, it grows faster) and lower (that is, it experiences less inflation). That, in a nutshell, is how our simple aggregate demand–aggregate supply framework explains this episode of recent U.S. economic history.

Tax Cuts and the Bush Economy The Clinton boom ended around the middle of 2000—just before the election of President George W. Bush. Real GDP grew very slowly in the second half of 2000 and then actually declined in two quarters of 2001, marking the first recession in the United States in 10 years. But it was a very minor one. The tax cut of 2001 turned out to be remarkably well timed, and the war on terrorism led to a burst of government spending. Both of these components of fiscal policy helped shift the aggregate demand curve outward, thereby mitigating the recession. (Refer back to Figure 1(b).) The Federal Reserve also lowered interest rates to encourage more spending. The recession ended late in 2001, but the recovery was extremely weak until the spring of 2003, when growth finally picked up—remaining strong through 2006 before slowing a bit late in 2007. The tax cuts of 2001–2003, while giving the economy a boost, also brought back large budget deficits. One sector of the U.S. economy that really boomed during the Bush years was housing. Both housing prices and new construction soared, especially during the years 2002–2006. Then the so-called housing “bubble” burst, and the economy started to slow down. At the end of 2007 the Great Recession began in earnest, with real GDP falling in five of the next six quarters despite more (small) tax cuts under both Presidents Bush and Obama and several bursts of federal government spending. When President Obama took office in January 2009, the jobs were disappearing rapidly and the economy looked grim indeed.7

ISSUE REVISITED:

HOW DID THE HOUSING BUST LEAD TO THE GREAT RECESSION?

At the start of this chapter, we asked why and how the end of the housing boom ushered in such a severe recession. Much of the answer is complex, involving close study of the financial system. So we will revisit it in Chapter 20. But part of the answer is simple enough.

7

For much more detail on the causes of the recession and the government’s attempt to cure it, see Chapter 20.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

483

An Introduction to Macroeconomics

Chapter 22

As we will see in the next chapter, spending on new home construction is one component of aggregate demand. When the housing boom ended, that component naturally started to decline as people built fewer houses. So the aggregate demand curve began to shift inward. In addition, as the financial system deteriorated—partly in response to the disaster in housing—consumers and investors lost confidence and started to spend less. This further pullback shifted the aggregate demand curve inward even more. As we have learned in this chapter, and will learn in greater depth later, insufficient aggregate demand is the typical cause of recessions. (See Figure 2.) This recession, the biggest since the 1930s by some measures, was no exception.

THE PROBLEM OF MACROECONOMIC STABILIZATION: A SNEAK PREVIEW This brief look at the historical record shows that our economy has not generally produced steady growth without inflation. Rather, it has been buffeted by periodic bouts of unemployment or inflation, and sometimes it has been plagued by both. We have also hinted that government policies may have had something to do with this performance. Let us now expand upon and systematize this hint. To provide a preliminary analysis of stabilization policy, the name given to government programs designed to shorten recessions and to counteract inflation, we can once again use the basic tools of aggregate supply and demand analysis. To facilitate this discussion, we have reproduced as Figures 9 and 10 two diagrams found earlier in this chapter, but we now give them slightly different interpretations.

Combating Unemployment

Stabilization policy is the name given to government programs designed to prevent or shorten recessions and to counteract inflation (that is, to stabilize prices).

Figure 9 offers a simplified view of government policy to fight unemployment. Suppose that in the absence of government intervention, the economy would reach an equilibrium at point E, where the aggregate demand curve D0D0 crosses the aggregate supply curve SS. Now if the output corresponding to point E is too low, leaving many workers unemployed, the government can reduce unemployment by increasing aggregate demand. The year 2009 was a dramatic example. Subsequent chapters will consider in detail how this is done. Our brief historical review has already mentioned three methods: Congress can spend more or reduce taxes (“fiscal

FIGURE 9

D1

Stabilization Policy to Fight Unemployment

S D0

Price Level

A

E

D1 D0

S

Increase in output Real GDP

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

484

The Macroeconomy: Aggregate Supply and Demand

Part 6

policy”), as it recently did with the 2009 “stimulus” bill; or the Federal Reserve can lower interest rates (“monetary policy”), as it also did in late 2007 and throughout 2008. In the diagram, any of these actions would shift the demand curve outward to D1D1, causing equilibrium to move to point A. In general: Recessions and unemployment are often caused by insufficient aggregate demand. When such situations occur, fiscal or monetary policies that successfully augment demand can be effective ways to increase output and reduce unemployment. They also normally raise prices.

Combating Inflation The opposite type of demand management is called for when inflation is the main macroeconomic problem. Figure 10 illustrates this case. Here again, point E, the intersection of aggregate demand curve D0D0 and aggregate supply curve SS, is the equilibrium the economy would reach in the absence of government policy. But now suppose the price level corresponding to point E is considered “too high,” meaning that the price level would be rising too rapidly if the economy were to move to point E. Government policies that reduce demand from D0D0 to D2D2 can keep prices down and thereby reduce inflation. Some examples are reducing government spending or raising taxes, as done by the Clinton administration in the 1990s, or raising interest rates, which the Federal Reserve last did in 2005–2006. Thus:

FIGURE 10 Stabilization Policy to Fight Inflation

S

D0

Price Level

D2

Inflation is frequently caused by aggregate demand racing ahead too fast. When this is the case, fiscal or monetary policies that reduce aggregate demand can be effective anti-inflationary devices. But such policies also decrease real GDP and raise unemployment.

E Decrease in prices

B

D0 S D2

This, in brief, summarizes the intent of stabilization policy. When aggregate demand fluctuations are the source of economic instability, the government can limit both recessions and inflations by pushing aggregate demand ahead when it would otherwise lag and restraining it when it would otherwise grow too quickly.

Does It Really Work?

Can the government actually stabilize the economy, as these simple diagrams suggest? That is a matter of some debate— a debate that is important enough to constitute one of our Ideas for Beyond the Final Exam. We will deal with the pros and cons in Part 7, but a look back at Figures 5 and 6 may be instructive right now. First, cover the portions of the two figures that deal with the period after 1940, the portions from the shaded area rightward in each figure. The picture that emerges for the 1870–1940 period is that of an economy with frequent and sometimes quite pronounced fluctuations. Now do the reverse. Cover the data before 1950 and look only at the postwar period. There is indeed a difference. Instances of negative real GDP growth are less common and business fluctuations look less severe. Although government policies have not achieved perfection, things do look much better. When we turn to inflation, however, matters look rather worse. Gone are the periods of deflation and price stability that occurred before World War II. Prices now seem only to rise. This quick tour through the data suggests that something has changed. The U.S. economy behaved differently from 1950 to 2009 than it did from 1870 to 1940.

Real GDP

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 22

485

An Introduction to Macroeconomics

Although controversy over this point continues, many economists attribute this shift in the economy’s behavior to lessons the government has learned about managing the economy—lessons you will be learning in the next part of this book. When you look at the prewar data, you see the fluctuations of an unmanaged economy that went through booms and recessions for “natural” economic reasons. The government did little about either. When you examine the postwar data, on the other hand, you see an economy that has been increasingly managed by government policy— sometimes successfully and sometimes unsuccessfully. Although the recessions are less severe, this improvement has come at a cost: The economy appears to be more inflation-prone than it was in the more distant past. These two changes in our economy may be connected, but to understand why, we will have to provide some relevant economic theory.

IDEAS FOR BEYOND THE FINAL EXAM

We have, in a sense, spent much of this chapter running before we have learned to walk—that is, we have been using aggregate demand and aggregate supply curves extensively before developing the theory that underlies them. That is the task before us in the rest of Part 6.

| SUMMARY | 1. Microeconomics studies the decisions of individuals and firms, the ways in which these decisions interact, and their influence on the allocation of a nation’s resources and the distribution of income. Macroeconomics looks at how entire economies behave and studies the pressing social problems of economic growth, inflation, and unemployment. 2. Although they focus on different subjects, microeconomics and macroeconomics rely on virtually identical tools. Both use the supply-and-demand analysis introduced in Chapter 4. 3. Macroeconomic models use abstract concepts like “the price level” and “gross domestic product” that are derived by combining many different markets into one. This process is known as aggregation; it should not be taken literally but rather viewed as a useful approximation. 4. The best specific measure of the nation’s economic output is gross domestic product (GDP), which is obtained by adding up the money values of all final goods and services produced in a given year. These outputs can be evaluated at current market prices (to get nominal GDP) or at some fixed set of prices (to get real GDP). Neither intermediate goods nor transactions that take place outside organized markets are included in GDP. 5. GDP measures an economy’s production, not the increase in its well-being. For example, the GDP places no value on housework, other do-it-yourself activities, or leisure time. On the other hand, even commodities that might be considered as “bads” rather than “goods” are counted in the GDP (for example, activities that harm the environment). 6. America’s economic history shows steady growth punctuated by periodic recessions—that is, periods in which real GDP declined. Although the distant past included

some periods of falling prices (deflation), more recent history shows only rising prices (inflation). 7. The Great Depression of the 1930s was the worst in U.S. history. It profoundly affected both our nation and countries throughout the world. It also led to a revolution in economic thinking, thanks largely to the work of John Maynard Keynes. 8. From World War II to the early 1970s, the American economy exhibited steadier growth than in the past. Many observers attributed this more stable performance to the implementation of the monetary and fiscal policies (collectively called stabilization policy) that Keynes had suggested. At the same time, however, the price level seems only to rise—never to fall—in the modern economy. The economy seems to have become more “inflation-prone.” 9. Between 1973 and 1991, the U.S. economy suffered through several serious recessions. In the first part of that period, inflation was also unusually virulent. This unhappy combination of economic stagnation with rapid inflation was nicknamed “stagflation.” Since 1982, however, inflation has been low. 10. The United States enjoyed a boom in the 1990s, and unemployment fell to its lowest level in 30 years. Yet inflation also fell. One explanation for this happy combination of rapid growth and low inflation is that the aggregate supply curve shifted out unusually rapidly. 11. One major cause of inflation is that aggregate demand may grow more quickly than does aggregate supply. In such a case, a government policy that reduces aggregate demand may be able to stem the inflation. 12. Recessions often occur because aggregate demand grows too slowly. In this case, a government policy that stimulates demand may be an effective way to fight the recession.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

486

Part 6

The Macroeconomy: Aggregate Supply and Demand

| KEY TERMS | aggregate demand curve aggregate supply curve aggregation deflation

470 470

468

fiscal policy

real GDP per capita

inflation

recession

471

intermediate good

477

final goods and services

gross domestic product (GDP) 472

monetary policy 473

479

nominal GDP real GDP

473

stabilization policy

481

stagflation

476

471 483

480

472

472

| TEST YOURSELF | 1. Which of the following problems are likely to be studied by a microeconomist and which by a macroeconomist? a. The rapid growth of Google b. Why unemployment in the United States fell from 2003 to 2006 c. Why Japan’s economy grew faster than the U.S. economy in the 1980s, but slower in the 2000s d. Why college tuition costs have risen so rapidly in recent years

c. Smith goes to the woods, cuts down a tree, and uses the wood to build himself a garage that is worth $50,000. d. The Jones family sells its old house to the Reynolds family for $400,000. The Joneses then buy a newly constructed house from a builder for $500,000. e. You purchase a used computer from a friend for $200. f. Your university purchases a new mainframe computer from IBM, paying $25,000.

2. Use an aggregate supply-and-demand diagram to study what would happen to an economy in which the aggregate supply curve never moved while the aggregate demand curve shifted outward year after year.

g. You win $100 in an Atlantic City casino.

3. Which of the following transactions are included in gross domestic product, and by how much does each raise GDP?

j. You buy a new economics textbook from your college bookstore for $100.

h. You make $100 in the stock market. i. You sell a used economics textbook to your college bookstore for $60.

a. Smith pays a carpenter $50,000 to build a garage. b. Smith purchases $10,000 worth of materials and builds himself a garage, which is worth $50,000.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 22

An Introduction to Macroeconomics

487

| DISCUSSION QUESTIONS | 1. You probably use “aggregates” frequently in everyday discussions. Try to think of some examples. (Here is one: Have you ever said, “The students at this college generally think . . .”? What, precisely, did you mean?) 2. Try asking a friend who has not studied economics in which year he or she thinks prices were higher: 1870 or 1900? 1920 or 1940? (In both cases, prices were higher in

the earlier year.) Most young people think that prices have always risen. Why do you think they have this opinion? 3. Give some reasons why gross domestic product is not a suitable measure of the well-being of the nation. (Have you noticed newspaper accounts in which journalists seem to use GDP for this purpose?)

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

The Goals of Macroeconomic Policy When men are employed, they are best contented. BENJAM I N FR ANKL I N

Inflation is repudiation. CALVI N CO OL I D GE

S

omeone once quipped that you could turn a parrot into an economist by teaching him just two words: supply and demand. And now that you have been through Chapters 4 and 22, you see what he meant. Sure enough, economists think of the process of economic growth as having two essential ingredients: • The first ingredient is aggregate supply. Given the available supplies of inputs like labor and capital, and the technology at its disposal, an economy is able to produce a certain volume of outputs, measured by GDP. This capacity to produce normally increases from one year to the next as the supplies of inputs grow and the technology improves. The theory of aggregate supply will be our focus in Chapters 24 and 27. • The second ingredient is aggregate demand. How much of the capacity to produce is actually utilized depends on how many of these goods and services people and businesses want to buy. We begin building a theory of aggregate demand in Chapters 25 and 26.

Inputs are the labor, machinery, buildings, and other resources used to produce outputs. Outputs are the goods and services that the economy produces.

C O N T E N T S PART 1: THE GOAL OF ECONOMIC GROWTH

TYPES OF UNEMPLOYMENT

OTHER COSTS OF INFLATION

PRODUCTIVITY GROWTH: FROM LITTLE ACORNS . . .

HOW MUCH EMPLOYMENT IS “FULL EMPLOYMENT”?

THE COSTS OF LOW VERSUS HIGH INFLATION

ISSUE: IS FASTER GROWTH ALWAYS

UNEMPLOYMENT INSURANCE: THE INVALUABLE CUSHION

LOW INFLATION DOES NOT NECESSARILY LEAD TO HIGH INFLATION

THE CAPACITY TO PRODUCE: POTENTIAL GDP AND THE PRODUCTION FUNCTION

PART 3: THE GOAL OF LOW INFLATION

| APPENDIX | How Statisticians Measure Inflation

THE GROWTH RATE OF POTENTIAL GDP ISSUE REVISITED: IS FASTER GROWTH ALWAYS

Inflation and Real Wages The Importance of Relative Prices

PART 2: THE GOAL OF LOW UNEMPLOYMENT

INFLATION AS A REDISTRIBUTOR OF INCOME AND WEALTH

BETTER?

BETTER?

INFLATION: THE MYTH AND THE REALITY

THE HUMAN COSTS OF HIGH UNEMPLOYMENT

REAL VERSUS NOMINAL INTEREST RATES

COUNTING THE UNEMPLOYED: THE OFFICIAL STATISTICS

Confusing Real and Nominal Interest Rates The Malfunctioning Tax System

Index Numbers for Inflation The Consumer Price Index Using a Price Index to “Deflate” Monetary Figures Using a Price Index to Measure Inflation The GDP Deflator

INFLATION DISTORTS MEASUREMENTS

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

490

Part 6

The Macroeconomy: Aggregate Supply and Demand

Growth policy refers to government policies intended to make the economy grow faster in the long run.

Corresponding to these two ingredients, economists visualize a dual task for those who make macroeconomic policy. First, policy should create an environment in which the economy can expand its productive capacity rapidly, because that is the ultimate source of higher living standards. This first task is the realm of growth policy, and it is taken up in the next chapter. Second, policy makers should manage aggregate demand so that it grows in line with the economy’s capacity to produce, avoiding as much as possible the cycles of boom and bust that we saw in the last chapter. This is the realm of stabilization policy. As we noted in the last chapter, inadequate growth of aggregate demand can lead to high unemployment, whereas excessive growth of aggregate demand can lead to high inflation. Both are to be avoided. Thus, the goals of macroeconomic policy can be summarized succinctly as achieving rapid but relatively smooth economic growth with low unemployment and low inflation. Unfortunately, that turns out to be a tall order, as recent events have painfully illustrated. In chapters to come, we will explain why these goals cannot be attained with machine-like precision and why improvement on one front often spells deterioration on another. Along the way, we will pay a great deal of attention to both the causes of and cures for sluggish growth, high unemployment, and high inflation. Before getting involved in such weighty issues of theory and policy, we pause in this chapter to take a close look at the three goals themselves. How fast can—or should—the economy grow? Why does a rise in unemployment cause such social distress? Why is inflation so loudly deplored? The answers to some of these questions may seem obvious at first. But, as you will see, there is more to them than meets the eye. The chapter is divided into three main parts, corresponding to the three goals. An appendix explains how inflation is measured.

PART 1: THE GOAL OF ECONOMIC GROWTH To residents of a prosperous society like ours, economic growth—the notion that standards of living rise from one year to the next—seems like part of the natural order of things. But it is not. Historians tell us that living standards barely changed from the Roman Empire to the dawn of the Industrial Revolution—a period of some 16 centuries! Closer in time, per capita incomes have tragically declined, on net, in most of the former Soviet Union and some of the poorest countries of Africa in recent decades. Economic growth is not automatic. Growth is also a very slow, and therefore barely noticeable, process. In a typical year, the typical American consumes about 2 percent more goods and services than he or she did in the previous year. Can you perceive a difference that small? Perhaps not, but such tiny changes, when compounded for decades or even centuries, transform societies. During the twentieth century, for example, living standards in the United States increased by a factor of almost seven—which means that your ancestors in the year 1900 consumed roughly one-seventh as much food, clothing, shelter, and other amenities as you do today. Try to imagine how your family would fare on one-seventh of its current income.

PRODUCTIVITY GROWTH: FROM LITTLE ACORNS . . . Small differences in growth rates make an enormous difference—eventually. To illustrate this point, think about the relative positions of three major nations—the United States, the United Kingdom, and Japan—at two points in history: 1870 and 1979. In 1870, the United States was a young, upstart nation. Although already among the most prosperous countries on earth, the United States was in no sense yet a major power. The United Kingdom, by contrast, was the preeminent economic and military power of the world. The Victorian era was at its height, and the sun never set on the British Empire. Meanwhile, somewhere across the Pacific was an inconsequential island nation called Japan. In 1870, Japan had only recently opened up to the West and was economically backward.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 23

491

The Goals of Macroeconomic Policy

The Wonders of Compound Interest

SOURCE: © Popperfoto/Getty Images

Growth rates, like interest rates, compound so that, for example, 10 years of growth at 3 percent per year leaves the economy more than 30 percent larger. How much more? The answer is 34.4 percent. To see how we get this figure, start with the fact that $100 left in a bank account for one year at 3 percent interest grows to $103, which is 1.03 3 $100. If left for a second year, that $103 will grow another 3 percent—to 1.03 3 $103 5 $106.09, which is already more than $106. Compounding has begun. Notice that 1.03 3 $103 5 (1.03)2 3 $100. Similarly, after three years the original $100 will grow to (1.03)3 3 $100 5 $109.27. As you can see, each additional year adds another 1.03 growth factor to the multiplication. Now returning to answer our original question, after 10 years of compounding, the depositor will have (1.03)10 3 $100 5 $134.39 in the bank. Thus the balance will have grown by 34.4 percent. By identical logic, an economy growing at 3 percent per year for 10 years will expand 34.4 percent in total.

You may not be impressed by the difference between 30 percent and 34.4 percent. If so, follow the logic for longer periods. After 20 years of 3 percent growth, the economy will be 80.6 percent bigger (because (1.03)20 5 1.806), not just 60 percent bigger. After 50 years, cumulative growth will be 338 percent, not 150 percent. And after a century, it will be 1,822 percent, not just 300 percent. Now we are talking about large discrepancies! No wonder Einstein once said, presumably in jest, that compounding was the most powerful force in the universe. The arithmetic of growth leads to a convenient “doubling rule” that you can do in your head. If something (the money in a bank account, the GDP of a country, and so on) grows at an annual rate of g percent, how long will it take to double? The approximate answer is 70/g, so the rule is often called “the Rule of 70.” For example, at a 2 percent growth rate, anything doubles in about 70/2 5 35 years. At a 3 percent growth rate, doubling takes roughly 70/3 5 23.33 years. Yes, small differences in growth rates can make a large difference.

Now fast-forward more than a century. By 1979, the United States had become the world’s preeminent economic power, Japan had emerged as the clear number two, and the United Kingdom had retreated into the second rank of nations. Obviously, the Japanese economy grew faster than the U.S. economy during this century, whereas the British economy grew more slowly, or else this stunning transformation of relative positions would not have occurred. The magnitudes of the differences in growth rates may astound you. Over the 109-year period, GDP per capita in the United States grew at a 2.3 percent compound annual rate, whereas the United Kingdom’s growth rate was 1.8 percent—a difference of merely 0.5 percent per annum, but compounded for more than a century. And what of Japan? What growth rate propelled it from obscurity into the front rank of nations? The answer is just 3.0 percent, a mere 0.7 percent per year faster than the United States. These numbers show vividly what a huge difference a 0.5 or 0.7 percentage point change in the growth rate makes, if sustained for a long time. Economists define the productivity of a country’s labor force (or “labor productivity“) as the amount of output a typical worker turns out in an hour of work. For example, if output is measured by GDP, productivity would be measured by GDP divided by the total number of hours of work. It is the growth rate of productivity that determines whether living standards will rise rapidly or slowly. PRODUCTIVITY GROWTH IS (ALMOST) EVERYTHING IN THE LONG RUN As we pointed out in our list of Ideas for Beyond the Final Exam, only rising productivity can raise standards of living in the long run. Over long periods of time, small differences in rates of productivity growth compound like interest in a bank account and can make an enormous difference to a society’s prosperity. Nothing contributes more to material wellbeing, to the reduction of poverty, to increases in leisure time, and to a country’s ability to finance education, public health, environmental improvement, and the arts than its productivity growth rate.

Labor productivity is the amount of output a worker turns out in an hour (or a week, or a year) of labor. If output is measured by GDP, it is GDP per hour of work.

IDEAS FOR BEYOND THE FINAL EXAM

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

492

Part 6

The Macroeconomy: Aggregate Supply and Demand

ISSUE:

IS FASTER GROWTH ALWAYS BETTER? How fast should the U.S. economy, or any economy, grow? At first, the question may seem silly. Isn’t it obvious that we should grow as fast as possible? After all, that will make us all richer. In a broad sense, economists agree; faster growth is generally preferred to slower growth. But as we shall see in a few pages, further thought suggests that the apparently naive question is not quite as silly as it sounds. Growth comes at a cost. So more may not always be better.

THE CAPACITY TO PRODUCE: POTENTIAL GDP AND THE PRODUCTION FUNCTION Potential GDP is the real GDP that the economy would produce if its labor and other resources were fully employed. The labor force is the number of people holding or seeking jobs.

The economy’s production function shows the volume of output that can be produced from given inputs (such as labor and capital), given the available technology.

F IGURE 1

Questions like how fast our economy can or should grow require quantitative answers. Economists have invented the concept of potential GDP to measure the economy’s normal capacity to produce goods and services. Specifically, potential GDP is the real gross domestic product (GDP) an economy could produce if its labor force was fully employed. Note the use of the word normal in describing capacity. Just as it is possible to push a factory beyond its normal operating rate (by, for example, adding a night shift), it is possible to push an economy beyond its normal full-employment level by working it very hard. For example, we observed in the last chapter that the unemployment rate dropped as low as 1.2 percent under abnormal conditions during World War II. So when we talk about employing the labor force fully, we do not mean a measured unemployment rate of zero. Conceptually, we estimate potential GDP in two steps. First, we count up the available supplies of labor, capital, and other productive resources. Then we estimate how much output these inputs could produce if they were all fully utilized. This second step—the transformation of inputs into outputs—involves an assessment of the economy’s technology. The more technologically advanced an economy, the more output it will be able to produce from any given bundle of inputs—as we emphasized in Chapter 3’s discussion of the production possibilities frontier. To help us understand how technology affects the relationship between inputs and outputs, it is useful to introduce a tool called the production function—which is simply a mathematical or graphical depiction of the relationship between inputs and outputs. We will use a graph in our discussion. For a given level of technology, Figure 1 shows how output (measured by real GDP on the vertical axis) depends on labor input (measured by hours of work on the horizontal

B

Y1 A

K

Y0

0

L0

Labor Input (hours)

(a) Effect of better technology

K1

Y1 Real GDP

Real GDP

M

A Y0

0

L0

(b) Effect of more capital

K0

Labor Input (hours)

SOURCE: Bureau of Labor Statistics. Data pertain to the nonfarm business sector.

The Economy’s Production Function

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 23

The Goals of Macroeconomic Policy

axis). To read these graphs, and to relate them to the concept of potential GDP, begin with the black curve OK in Figure 1(a), which shows how GDP depends on labor input, holding both capital and technology constant. Naturally, output rises as labor inputs increase as we move outward along the curve OK, just as you would expect. If the country’s labor force can supply L0 hours of work when it is fully employed, then potential GDP is Y0 (see point A). If the technology improves, the production function will shift upward—say, to the brickcolored curve labeled OM—meaning that the same amount of labor input will now produce more output. The graph shows that potential GDP increases to Y1. Now what about capital? Figure 1(b) shows two production functions. The black curve OK0 applies when the economy has some lower capital stock, K0. The higher, brick-colored curve OK1 applies when the capital stock is some higher number, K1. Thus, the production function tells us that potential GDP will be Y0 if the capital stock is K0 (see point A) but Y1 if the capital stock is K1 instead (see point B). Once again, this relationship is just what you would expect: The economy can produce more output with the same amount of labor if workers have more capital to work with. You can hardly avoid noticing the similarities between the two panels of Figure 1: Better technology, as in Figure 1(a), or more capital, as in Figure 1(b), affect the production function in more or less the same way. In general: Either more capital or better technology will shift the production function upward and therefore raise potential GDP.

THE GROWTH RATE OF POTENTIAL GDP With this new tool, it is but a short jump to potential growth rates. If the size of potential GDP depends on the size of the economy’s labor force, the amount of capital and other resources it has, and its technology, it follows that the growth rate of potential GDP must depend on • The growth rate of the labor force • The growth rate of the nation’s capital stock • The rate of technical progress To sharpen the point, observe that real GDP is, by definition, the product of the total hours of work in the economy times the amount of output produced per hour—what we have just called labor productivity: GDP 5 Hours of work 3 Output per hour 5 Hours of work 3 Labor productivity.

For example, in the United States today, in round numbers, GDP is about $14 trillion and total hours of work per year are about 250 billion. Thus labor productivity is roughly $14 trillion/250 billion hours 5 $56 per hour. How fast can the economy increase its productive capacity? By transforming the preceding equation into growth rates, we have our answer: The growth rate of potential GDP is the sum of the growth rates of labor input (hours of work) and labor productivity:1 Growth rate of potential GDP 5 Growth rate of labor input 1 Growth rate of labor productivity

In the United States in recent years, labor input has been increasing at a rate of about 1 percent per year. But labor productivity growth, which was very slow until the mid1990s, has leaped upward since then—averaging about 2.8 percent per annum from 1995 to 2008. Together, these two figures imply an estimated growth rate of potential GDP of about 3.8 percent over these years.

1 You may be wondering about what happened to capital. The answer, as we have just seen in our discussion of the production function, is that one of the main determinants of potential GDP, and thus of labor productivity, is the amount of capital that each worker has to work with. Accordingly, the role of capital is incorporated into the productivity number; that is, the growth rate of labor productivity depends on the growth rate of capital.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

493

494

Part 6

The Macroeconomy: Aggregate Supply and Demand

TABLE 1 Recent Growth Rates of Real GDP in the United States

Years

Growth Rate per Year

1995–1997 1997–1999 1999–2001 2001–2003 2003–2005 2005–2007 1995–2008

4.1% 4.3 2.2 2.1 3.4 2.5 3.0

Do the growth rates of potential GDP and actual GDP match up? The answer is an important one to which we will return often in this book: Over long periods of time, the growth rates of actual and potential GDP are normally quite similar. However, the two often diverge sharply over short periods owing to cyclical fluctuations. The recent departure is dramatic.

Table 1 illustrates this point with some recent U.S. data. Since 1995, GDP growth rates over two-year periods have ranged from as low as 2.1 percent per annum to as high as 4.3 percent. Over the entire 13-year period, GDP growth averaged 3 percent, which is below current estimates of the growth rate of potential GDP. The next chapter is devoted to studying the determinants of economic growth and some policies that might speed it up. We already know from the production function that there are two basic ways to boost a nation’s growth rate—other than faster popSOURCE: U.S. Department of Commerce. ulation growth and simply working harder. One is accumulating more capital. Other things being equal, a nation that builds more capital for its future will grow faster. The other way is by improving technology. When technological breakthroughs are coming at a fast and furious pace, an economy will grow more rapidly. We will discuss both of these factors in detail in the next chapter. First, however, we need to address the more basic question posed earlier in this chapter.

ISSUE REVISITED:

IS FASTER GROWTH ALWAYS BETTER?

It might seem that the answer to this question is obviously yes. After all, faster growth of either labor productivity or GDP per person is the route to higher living standards, but exceptions have been noted. For openers, some social critics have questioned the desirability of faster economic growth as an end in itself, at least in the rich countries. Faster growth brings more wealth, and to most people the desirability of wealth is beyond question. “I’ve been rich and I’ve been poor. Believe me, honey, rich is better,” singer Sophie Tucker once told an interviewer. And most people seem to share her sentiment. To those who hold this belief, a healthy economy is one that produces vast quantities of jeans, pizzas, cars, and computers. Yet the desirability of further economic growth for a society that is already quite wealthy has been questioned on several grounds. Environmentalists worry that the sheer increase in the volume of goods imposes enormous costs on society in the form of crowding, pollution, global climate change, and proliferation of wastes that need disposal. It has, they argue, dotted our roadsides with junkyards, filled our air with pollution, and poisoned our food with dangerous chemicals. Some psychologists and social critics argue that the never-ending drive for more and better goods has failed to make people happier. Instead, industrial progress has transformed the satisfying and creative tasks of the artisan into the mechanical and dehumanizing routine of the assembly-line worker. In the United States, it even seems to be driving people to work longer and longer hours. The question is whether the vast outpouring of material goods is worth all the stress and environmental damage. In fact, surveys of self-reported happiness show that residents of richer countries are no happier, on average, than residents of poorer countries. But despite this, most economists continue to believe that more growth is better than less. For one thing, slower growth would make it extremely difficult to finance programs that improve the quality of life—including efforts to protect the environment. Such programs are costly, and the evidence suggests that people are willing to pay for them only after their incomes reach a certain level. Second, it would be difficult to prevent further economic growth even if we were so inclined. Mandatory controls are abhorrent to most Americans; we cannot order people to stop being inventive and hardworking. Third, slower economic growth would seriously hamper efforts to

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 23

495

The Goals of Macroeconomic Policy

eliminate poverty—both within our own country and throughout the world. Much of the earth’s population still lives in a state of extreme want. These unfortunate people are far less interested in clean air and fulfillment in the workplace than they are in more food, better clothing, and sturdier shelters. All that said, economists concede that faster growth is not always better. One important reason will occupy our attention later in Parts 6 and 7: An economy that grows too fast may generate inflation. Why? You were introduced to the answer at the end of the last chapter: Inflation rises when aggregate demand races ahead of aggregate supply. In plain English, an economy will become inflationary when people’s demands for goods and services expand faster than its capacity to produce them. So we probably do not want to grow faster than the growth rate of potential GDP, at least not for long. Should society then seek the maximum possible growth rate of potential GDP? Maybe, but maybe not. After all, more rapid growth does not come for free. We have noted that building more capital is one good way to speed the growth of potential GDP. But the resources used to manufacture jet engines and computer servers could be used to make home air conditioners and video games instead. Building more capital imposes an obvious cost on a society: The citizens must consume less today. Saying this does not argue against investing for the future. Indeed, most economists believe we need to do more of that. But we must realize that faster growth through capital formation comes at a cost—an opportunity cost. Here, as elsewhere, you don’t get something for nothing.

PART 2: THE GOAL OF LOW UNEMPLOYMENT We noted earlier that actual GDP growth can differ sharply from potential GDP growth over periods as long as several years. These macroeconomic fluctuations have major implications for employment and unemployment. In particular: When the economy grows more slowly than its potential, it fails to generate enough new jobs for its ever-growing labor force. Hence, the unemployment rate rises. Conversely, GDP growth faster than the economy’s potential leads to a falling unemployment rate.

The unemployment rate is the number of unemployed people, expressed as a percentage of the labor force.

High unemployment is socially wasteful. When the economy does not create enough jobs to employ everyone who is willing to work, a valuable resource is lost. Potential goods and services that might have been produced and enjoyed by consumers are lost forever. This lost output is the central economic cost of high unemployment, and we can measure it by comparing actual and potential GDP. That cost is considerable. Table 2 summarizes the idleness of workers and machines, and the resulting loss of national output, for some of the years of lowest economic activity in recent decades. The second column lists the civilian unemployment rate and thus measures unused labor resources. The third lists the percentage of industrial capacity that U.S. manufacturers were actually using, which indicates the extent to TABLE 2 which plant and equipment went unused. The fourth column estiThe Economic Costs of High Unemployment mates the shortfall between potential and actual real GDP. We see that unemployment has cost the people of the United States as much as an Civilian Capacity Real GDP Lost 8.1 percent reduction in their real incomes. Unemployment Utilization Due to Idle Although Table 2 shows extreme examples, our inability to utilize Year Rate Rate Resources all of the nation’s available resources was a persistent economic prob1958 6.8% 75.0% 4.8% lem for decades. The blue line in Figure 2 shows actual real GDP in the 1961 6.7 77.3 4.1 United States from 1954 to 2009, whereas the black line shows poten1975 8.5 73.4 5.4 1982 9.7 71.3 8.1 tial GDP. The graph makes it clear that actual GDP has fallen short of 1992 7.5 79.4 2.6 potential GDP more often than it has exceeded it, especially during the 2003 6.0 73.4 2.2 1973–1993 period and very recently. In fact: 2009

A conservative estimate of the cumulative gap between actual and potential GDP over the years 1974 to 1993 (all evaluated in 2000

9.3

70.0

7.6

SOURCES: Bureau of Labor Statistics, Federal Reserve System, and Congressional Budget Office.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

496

Part 6

The Macroeconomy: Aggregate Supply and Demand

F IGURE 2 Actual and Potential GDP in the United States since 1954 12,500 12,000 11,500 11,000

2008–2009 Recession

10,500 10,000 9,500

Actual GDP

9,000

8,000 7,500 7,000 6,500

Potential GDP

6,000 5,500 5,000

1982 –1983 Recession

4,500 1974 –1975 Recession

4,000 3,500 1960s Boom

3,000 2,500 2,000

1960 –1961 1957–1958 Recession Recession 1955

1959

1963

1967

2009 1971

1975

1979

1983 Year

1987

1991

1995

1999

2003

2007

SOURCE: U.S. Department of Commerce and Congressional Budget Office.

Billions of 2000 Dollars

8,500

prices) is roughly $1,750 billion. At 2009 levels, this loss in output as a result of unemployment would be over one-and-a-half months worth of production. And there is no way to redeem those losses. In 2009 alone, the output loss was over 7.5 percent. The labor wasted in 2009 cannot be utilized in 2010.

THE HUMAN COSTS OF HIGH UNEMPLOYMENT If these numbers seem a bit dry and abstract, think about the human costs of being unemployed. Years ago, job loss meant not only enforced idleness and a catastrophic drop in income, it often led to hunger, cold, ill health, even death. Here is how one unemployed worker during the Great Depression described his family’s plight in a mournful letter to the governor of Pennsylvania: I have been out of work for over a year and a half. Am back almost thirteen months and the landlord says if I don’t pay up before the 1 of 1932 out I must go, and where am I to go in the cold winter with my children? If you can help me please for God’s sake and the children’s sakes and like please do what you can and send me some help, will you, I cannot find any work. . . . Thanksgiving dinner was black coffee and bread and was very glad to get it. My wife is in the hospital now. We have no shoes to were [sic]; no clothes hardly. Oh what will I do I sure will thank you.2 From Milton Meltzer, Brother, Can You Spare a Dime? The Great Depression 1929–1933, p. 103. Copyright © 1969. Reprinted by permission of Alfred A. Knopf, Inc.

2

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

SOURCE: Bureau of Labor Statistics.

Percent

Nowadays, unemployment does not hold quite such terrors for most families, although its consequences remain dire enough. Our system of unemployment insurance (discussed later in this chapter) has taken part of the sting out of unemployment, as have other social welfare programs that support the incomes of the poor. Yet most families still suffer painful losses of income and, often, severe noneconomic consequences when a breadwinner becomes unemployed. Even families that are well protected by unemployment compensation suffer when joblessness strikes. Ours is a work-oriented society. A man’s place has always been in the office or shop, and lately this has become true for women as well. A worker forced into idleness by a recession endures a psychological cost that is no less real for our inability to measure it. Martin Luther King, Jr., put it graphically: “In our society, it is murder, psychologically, to deprive a man of a job. . . . You are in substance saying to that man that he has no right to exist.”3 High unemployment has been linked to psychological and physical disorders, divorces, suicides, and crime. It is important to realize that these costs, whether large or small in total, are distributed most unevenly across the population. In 2008, 40 for example, the unemployment rate among 35 all workers averaged just 5.8 percent. But, as Figure 3 shows, 10.1 percent of black workers 30 were unemployed. For teenagers, the situation 25 was much worse, with unemployment at 18.7 percent, and that of black male teenagers a 20 shocking 35.9 percent. Married men had the 15 lowest rate—just 3.4 percent. Overall unem10.1 10 ployment varies from year to year, but these relationships are typical: In good times and bad, married men suffer the least unemployment and teenagers suffer the most; nonwhites are unemployed much more often than whites; blue-collar workers have above-average rates of unemployment; well-educated people have belowaverage unemployment rates.4

497

The Goals of Macroeconomic Policy

Chapter 23

5 0

FI GURE 3 Unemployment Rates for Selected Groups, 2008

35.9

18.7

3.4

Married Men

Blacks

Teenagers

Black Male Teenagers

It is worth noting that unemployment in the United States has been much lower than in most other industrialized countries in recent years. For example, during 2006, when the U.S. unemployment rate averaged 4.6 percent, the comparable figures were 5.5 percent in Canada, 9.5 percent in France, 6.9 percent in Italy, and 10.4 percent in Germany.5

COUNTING THE UNEMPLOYED: THE OFFICIAL STATISTICS We have been using unemployment figures without considering where they come from or how accurate they are. The basic data come from a monthly survey of about 60,000 households conducted for the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics. The census taker asks several questions about the employment status of each member of the household and, on the basis of the answers, classifies each person as employed, unemployed, or not in the labor force.

Quoted in Coretta Scott King (ed.), The Words of Martin Luther King (New York: Newmarket Press; 1983), p. 45. Unemployment rates for men and women are about equal. 5 The numbers for foreign countries are based (approximately) on U.S. unemployment concepts. 3 4

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

498

Part 6

The Macroeconomy: Aggregate Supply and Demand

The Employed The first category is the simplest to define. It includes everyone currently at work, including part-time workers. Although some part-timers work less than a full week by choice, others do so only because they cannot find suitable full-time jobs. Nevertheless, these workers are counted as employed, even though many would consider them “underemployed.”

The Unemployed The second category is a bit trickier. For persons not currently working, the survey first determines whether they are temporarily laid off from a job to which they expect to return. If so, they are counted as unemployed. The remaining workers are asked whether they actively sought work during the previous four weeks. If they did, they are also counted as unemployed.

A discouraged worker is an unemployed person who gives up looking for work and is therefore no longer counted as part of the labor force.

Out of the Labor Force If they failed to look for a job, they are classified as out of the labor force rather than unemployed. This seems a reasonable way to draw the distinction— after all, not everyone wants to work. Yet there is a problem: Research shows that many unemployed workers give up looking for jobs after a while. These so-called discouraged workers are victims of poor job prospects, just like the officially unemployed. When they give up hope, the measured unemployment rate—which is the ratio of the number of unemployed people to the total labor force—actually declines. Involuntary part-time work, loss of overtime or shortened work hours, and discouraged workers are all examples of “hidden” or “disguised” unemployment. People concerned about such phenomena argue that we should include them in the official unemployment rate because, if we do not, the magnitude of the problem will be underestimated. Others, however, argue that measured unemployment overestimates the problem because, to count as unemployed, potential workers need only claim to be looking for jobs, even if they are not really interested in finding them.

TYPES OF UNEMPLOYMENT Frictional unemployment is unemployment that is due to normal turnover in the labor market. It includes people who are temporarily between jobs because they are moving or changing occupations, or are unemployed for similar reasons. Structural unemployment refers to workers who have lost their jobs because they have been displaced by automation, because their skills are no longer in demand, or because of similar reasons. Cyclical unemployment is the portion of unemployment that is attributable to a decline in the economy’s total production. Cyclical unemployment rises during recessions and falls as prosperity is restored.

Providing jobs for those willing to work is one principal goal of macroeconomic policy. How are we to define this goal? We have already noted that a zero measured unemployment rate would clearly be an incorrect answer. Ours is a dynamic, highly mobile economy. Households move from one state to another. Individuals quit jobs to seek better positions or retool for more attractive occupations. These and other decisions produce some minimal amount of unemployment—people who are literally between jobs. Economists call this frictional unemployment, and it is unavoidable in our market economy. The critical distinguishing feature of frictional unemployment is that it is short-lived. A frictionally unemployed person has every reason to expect to find a new job soon. A second type of unemployment can be difficult to distinguish from frictional unemployment but has very different implications. Structural unemployment arises when jobs are eliminated by changes in the economy, such as automation or permanent changes in demand. The crucial difference between frictional and structural unemployment is that, unlike frictionally unemployed workers, structurally unemployed workers cannot realistically be considered “between jobs.” Instead, their skills and experience may be unmarketable in the changing economy in which they live. They are thus faced with either prolonged periods of unemployment or the necessity of making major changes in their skills or occupations. The remaining type of unemployment, cyclical unemployment, will occupy most of our attention. Cyclical unemployment rises when the level of economic activity declines, as it does in a recession. Thus, when macroeconomists speak of maintaining “full employment,” they mean limiting unemployment to its frictional and structural components— which means, roughly, producing at potential GDP. A key question, therefore, is: How much measured unemployment constitutes full employment?

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 23

499

The Goals of Macroeconomic Policy

P OLICY D E B AT E

Does the Minimum Wage Cause Unemployment?

Hourly Wage

Elementary economic reasoning— summarized in the simple supplydemand diagram to the right—suggests that setting a minimum wage (W in D the graph) above the free-market wage (w in the graph) must cause A W unemployment. In the graph, unemployment is the horizontal gap between the quantity of labor supplied w (point B) and the quantity demanded (point A) at the minimum wage. Indeed, the conclusion seems so elementary that generations of economists took it for granted. The S argument seems compelling. Indeed, earlier editions of this book, for example, confidently told students that a higher minimum wage must lead to higher unemployment. Number But some surprising economic research published in the 1990s cast serious doubt on this conventional wisdom.* For example, economists David Card and Alan Krueger compared employment changes at fast-food restaurants in New Jersey and nearby Pennsylvania after New Jersey, but not Pennsylvania, raised its minimum wage in 1992. To their surprise, the New Jersey stores did more net hiring than their Pennsylvania counterparts. Similar results were found for fast-food stores in Texas after the federal minimum wage was raised

in 1991, and in California after the statewide minimum wage was increased in 1988. In none of these S cases did a higher minimum wage seem to reduce employment— in contrast to the implications of B simple economic theory. The research of Card and Krueger, and of others who reached similar conclusions, was controversial from the start, and remains so. Thus, a policy question that had been deemed closed now seems to be open: Does the minimum wage reD ally cause unemployment? Resolution of this debate is of more than academic interest. In 1996, President Clinton recomof Workers mended and Congress passed an increase in the federal minimum wage—justifying its action, in part, by the new research suggesting that unemployment would not rise as a result. The same research was cited in 2007, when Congress debated and then enacted a three-stage increase in the minimum wage that brought it up to $7.25 by the summer of 2009. Economic research can have consequences. *SOURCE: David Card and Alan Krueger, Myth and Measurement: The New Economics of the Minimum Wage (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press; 1995).

HOW MUCH EMPLOYMENT IS “FULL EMPLOYMENT”? John F. Kennedy was the first president to commit the federal government to a specific numerical goal for unemployment. He picked a 4 percent target, which was rejected as being unrealistically ambitious in the 1970s. But when the government abandoned the 4 percent unemployment target, no new number was put in its place. Instead, we have experienced a long-running national debate over exactly how much measured unemployment corresponds to full employment—a debate that continues to this day. In the early 1990s, many economists believed that full employment came at a measured unemployment rate as high as 6 percent. Others disputed that estimate as unduly pessimistic. Then real-world events decisively rejected the 6 percent estimate. The boom of the late 1990s pushed the unemployment rate below 5 percent by the summer of 1997, and it remained there every month until September 2001—even falling as low as 3.9 percent in 2000. All this left economists guessing where full employment might be. Official government reports issued in early 2010 estimated the full-employment unemployment rate to be around 5 percent, but no one was totally confident in such estimates.

Full employment is a situation in which everyone who is willing and able to work can find a job. At full employment, the measured unemployment rate is still positive.

UNEMPLOYMENT INSURANCE: THE INVALUABLE CUSHION One major reason why America’s unemployed workers no longer experience the complete loss of income that devastated so many during the 1930s is our system of

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

500

Part 6

The Macroeconomy: Aggregate Supply and Demand

Unemployment insurance is a government program that replaces some of the wages lost by eligible workers who lose their jobs.

unemployment insurance—one of the most valuable institutional innovations to emerge from the trauma of the Great Depression. Each of the 50 states administers an unemployment insurance program under federal guidelines. Although the precise amounts vary, the average weekly benefit check in 2008 was $292, which amounted to just under half of average weekly earnings. Although a 50 percent drop in earnings poses very serious problems, the importance of this 50 percent income cushion can scarcely be exaggerated, especially because it may be supplemented by funds from other welfare programs. Families that are covered by unemployment insurance rarely go hungry or are dispossessed from their homes when they lose their jobs. Eligibility for benefits varies by state, but some criteria apply quite generally. Only experienced workers qualify, so persons just joining the labor force (such as recent college graduates) or reentering after prolonged absences (such as women returning to the job market after years of child rearing) cannot collect benefits. Neither can those who quit their jobs, except under unusual circumstances. Also, benefits end after a stipulated period of time, normally six months. For all of these reasons, only 37 percent of the 7.1 million people who were unemployed in an average week in 2007 actually received benefits. The importance of unemployment insurance to the unemployed is obvious, but significant benefits also accrue to citizens who never become unemployed. During recessions, billions of dollars are paid out in unemployment benefits. And because recipients probably spend most of their benefits, unemployment insurance limits the severity of recessions by providing additional purchasing power when and where it is most needed. The unemployment insurance system is one of several cushions built into our economy since 1933 to prevent another Great Depression. By giving money to those who become unemployed, the system helps prop up aggregate demand during recessions.

Although the U.S. economy is now probably “depression-proof,” this should not be a cause for much rejoicing, for the many recessions we have had since the 1950s—most notably, the devastating 2007–2009 recession—amply demonstrate that we are far from “recession-proof.” The fact that unemployment insurance and other social welfare programs replace a significant fraction of lost income has led some skeptics to claim that unemployment is no longer a serious problem. But the fact is that unemployment insurance is just what the name says—an insurance program. And insurance can never prevent a catastrophe from occurring; it simply spreads the costs among many people instead of letting all of the costs fall on the shoulders of a few unfortunate souls. As we noted earlier, unemployment robs the economy of output it could have produced, and no insurance policy can insure society against such losses. Our system of payroll taxes and unemployment benefits spreads the costs of unemployment over the entire population, but it does not eliminate the basic economic cost.

In that case, you might ask, why not cushion the blow even more by making unemployment insurance much more generous, as many European countries have done? The answer is that there is also a downside to unemployment insurance. When unemployment benefits are very generous, people who lose their jobs may be less than eager to look for new jobs. The right level of unemployment insurance strikes an appropriate balance between the benefits of supporting the incomes of unemployed people and the costs of raising the unemployment rate a bit.

PART 3: THE GOAL OF LOW INFLATION Both the human and economic costs of inflation are less obvious than the costs of unemployment. But this does not make them any less real, for if one thing is crystal clear about inflation, it is that people do not like it.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 23

501

The Goals of Macroeconomic Policy

When inflation is low, as it has been in recent years, it barely registers as a problem in national public opinion polls. However, when inflation is high, it often heads the list— generally even ahead of unemployment. Surveys also show that inflation, like unemployment, makes people unhappy. Finally, studies of elections suggest that voters penalize the party that occupies the White House when inflation is high. The fact is beyond dispute: People dislike inflation. The question is, why?

INFLATION: THE MYTH AND THE REALITY At first, the question may seem ridiculous. During inflationary times, people pay higher prices for the same quantities of goods and services they had before. So more and more income is needed just to maintain the same standard of living. Is it not obvious that this erosion of purchasing power—that is, the decline in what money will buy—makes everyone worse off?

Inflation and Real Wages

The purchasing power of a given sum of money is the volume of goods and services that it will buy.

This would indeed be the case were it not for one very significant fact. The wages that people earn are also prices—prices for labor services. During a period of inflation, wages also rise. In fact, the average wage typically rises more or less in step with prices. Thus, contrary to popular myth, workers as a group are not usually victimized by inflation. The purchasing power of wages—what is called the real wage rate—is not systematically eroded by inflation. Sometimes wages rise faster than prices, and sometimes prices rise faster than wages. In the long run, wages tend to outstrip prices as new capital equipment and innovation increase output per worker.

Figure 4 illustrates this simple fact. The brick-colored line shows the rate of increase of prices in the United States for each year since 1948, and the black line shows the rate of increase of wages. The difference between the two, shaded in blue in the diagram, indicates the rate of growth of real wages. Generally, wages rise faster than prices, reflecting the

11

11

10

10

FI GURE 4 Rates of Change of Wages and Prices in the United States since 1948

9

8

8

7

7

6

6

5

5

4

4 3

3 2

Prices

Percentage Change in Prices

Percentage Change in Wages

SOURCE: Bureau of Labor Statistics. Data pertain to nonfarm business sector.

Wages 9

The real wage rate is the wage rate adjusted for inflation. Specifically, it is the nominal wage divided by the price index. The real wage thus indicates the volume of goods and services that the nominal wages will buy.

2

1

1

0

0 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 1965 1975 1955 1985 1995 2005 Year

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

502

Part 6

The Macroeconomy: Aggregate Supply and Demand

Calculating the Real Wage: A Real Example The real wage shows not how many dollars a worker is paid for an hour of work (that is called the nominal wage), but rather the purchasing power of that money. It indicates what an hour’s worth of work can buy. As noted in the definition of the real wage in the margin on the previous page, we calculate the real wage by dividing the nominal wage by the price level. The rule is6 Real wage 5

Nominal wage Price level

3 100

SOURCE: The Wall Street Journal—Permission, Cartoon Features Syndicate.

Here’s a concrete example. Between 1998 and 2007, the average hourly wage in the United States rose from $13.01 to $17.41, an increase of 34 percent over nine years. Sounds pretty good for

American workers. But over those same nine years, the Consumer Price Index (CPI), the most commonly used index of the price level, rose by 27 percent, from 163.0 to 207.3. This means that the real wages in the two years were Real wage in 1998 5

$13.01 3 100 5 $7.98 163

Real wage in 2007 5

$17.41 3 100 5 $8.40 207.3

for an increase of just 5.2 percent over the nine years, which is a small fraction of 34 percent.

steady advance of labor productivity; therefore, real wages rise. But this is not always the case; the graph shows several instances in which inflation outstripped wage increases. The feature of Figure 4 that virtually jumps off the page is the way the two lines dance together. Wages normally rise rapidly when prices rise rapidly, and they rise slowly when prices rise slowly. But you should not draw any hasty conclusions from this association. It does not, for example, imply that rising prices cause rising wages or that rising wages cause rising prices. Remember the warnings given in Chapter 1 about trying to infer causation just by looking at data. But analyzing cause and effect is not our purpose right now. We merely want to dispel the myth that inflation inevitably erodes real wages. Why is this myth so widespread? Imagine a world without inflation in which wages are rising 2 percent per year because of the increasing productivity of labor. Now imagine “Sure, you’re raising my that, all of a sudden, inflation sets in and prices start rising 3 percent per year but nothing allowance. But am I actually else changes. Figure 4 suggests that, with perhaps a small delay, wage increases will gaining any purchasing accelerate to 2 1 3 5 5 percent per year. power?“ Will workers view this change with equanimity? Probably not. To each worker, the 5 percent wage increase will be seen as something he earned by the sweat of his brow. In his view, he deserves every penny of his 5 percent raise. In a sense, he is right because “the sweat of his brow” earned him a 2 percent increment in real wages that, when the inflation rate is 3 percent, can be achieved only by increasing his money wages by 5 percent. An economist would divide the wage increase in the following way: Reason for Wages to Increase Higher productivity Compensation for higher prices Total

Amount 2% 3% 5%

But the worker will probably keep score differently. Feeling that he earned the entire 5 percent raise by his own merits, he will view inflation as having “robbed” him of threefifths of his just deserts. The higher the rate of inflation, the more of his raise the worker will feel has been stolen from him. Of course, nothing could be farther from the truth. Basically, the economic system rewards the worker with the same 2 percent real wage increment for higher productivity, regardless of the rate of inflation. The “evils of inflation” are often exaggerated because people fail to understand this point.

As explained in the appendix, it is conventional to multiply price index numbers by 100. That is the reason for the 100 in the formula. It does not alter the percentage change.

6

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

503

The Goals of Macroeconomic Policy

Chapter 23

The Importance of Relative Prices A related misperception results from failure to distinguish between a rise in the general price level and a change in relative prices, which is a rise in one price relative to another. To see the distinction most clearly, imagine first a pure inflation in which every price rises by 10 percent during the year, so that relative prices do not change. Table 3 gives an example in which the price of movie tickets increases from $6.00 to $6.60, the price of candy bars from 50 cents to 55 cents, and the price of automobiles from $9,000 to $9,900. After the inflation, just as before, it will still take 12 candy bars to buy a movie ticket, 1,500 movie tickets to buy a car, and so on. A person who manufactures candy bars in order to purchase movie tickets is neither helped nor harmed by the inflation. Neither is a car dealer with a sweet tooth.

An item’s relative price is its price in terms of some other item rather than in terms of dollars.

TABLE 3 Pure Inflation

Item Candy bar Movie ticket Automobile

Last Year’s Price $0.50 6.00 9,000

This Year’s Price $0.55 6.60 9,900

Increase 10% 10 10

But real inflations are not like this. When there is 10 percent general inflation—meaning that the “average price” rises by 10 percent—some prices may jump 20 percent or more whereas others actually fall.7 Suppose that, instead of the price increases shown in Table 3, prices rise as shown in Table 4. Movie prices go up by 25 percent, but candy prices do not change. Surely, candy manufacturers who love movies will be disgruntled because it now costs 15 candy bars instead of 12 to get into the theater. They will blame inflation for raising the price of movie tickets, even though their real problem stems from the increase in the price of movies relative to candy. (They would have been hurt as much if movie tickets had remained at $6 while the price of candy fell to 40 cents.) Because car prices have risen by only 5 percent, theater owners in need of new cars will be delighted by the fact that an automobile now costs only 1,260 movie admissions—just as they would have cheered if car prices had fallen to $7,560 while movie tickets remained at $6. However, they are unlikely to attribute their good fortune to inflation. Indeed, they should not. What has actually happened is that cars became cheaper relative to movies. TABLE 4 Real-World Inflation

Item Candy bar Movie ticket Automobile

Last Year’s Price $0.50 6.00 9,000

This Year’s Price $0.50 7.50 9,450

Increase 0% 25 5

Because real-world inflations proceed at uneven rates, relative prices are always changing. There are gainers and losers, just as some would gain and others lose if relative prices whereas to change without any general inflation. Inflation, however, gets a bad name because losers often blame inflation for their misfortune, whereas gainers rarely credit inflation for their good luck. Inflation is not usually to blame when some goods become more expensive relative to others.

7

How statisticians figure out “average” price increases is discussed in the appendix to this chapter.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

504

Part 6

The Macroeconomy: Aggregate Supply and Demand

These two kinds of misconceptions help explain why respondents to public opinion polls often cite inflation as a major national issue, why higher inflation rates depress consumers, and why voters express their ire at the polls when inflation is high. But not all of the costs of inflation are mythical. Let us now turn to some of the real costs.

INFLATION AS A REDISTRIBUTOR OF INCOME AND WEALTH We have just seen that the average person is neither helped nor harmed by inflation. But almost no one is exactly average! Some people gain from inflation and others lose. For example, senior citizens trying to scrape by on pensions or other fixed incomes suffer badly from inflation. Because they earn no wages, it is little solace to them that wages keep pace with prices. Their pension incomes do not.8 This example illustrates a general problem. Think of pensioners as people who “lend” money to an organization (the pension fund) when they are young, expecting to be paid back with interest when they are old. Because of the rise in the price level during the intervening years, the unfortunate pensioners get back dollars that are worth less in purchasing power than those they originally loaned. In general: Those who lend money are often victimized by inflation.

Although lenders may lose heavily, borrowers may do quite well. For example, homeowners who borrowed money from banks in the form of mortgages back in the 1950s, when interest rates were 3 or 4 percent, gained enormously from the surprisingly virulent inflation of the 1970s. They paid back dollars of much lower purchasing power than those that they borrowed. The same is true of other borrowers. Borrowers often gain from inflation.

Because the redistribution caused by inflation generally benefits borrowers at the expense of lenders, and because both lenders and borrowers can be found at every income level, we conclude that Inflation does not systematically steal from the rich to aid the poor, nor does it always do the reverse.

Why, then, is the redistribution caused by inflation so widely condemned? Because its victims are selected capriciously. No one legislates the redistribution. No one enters into it voluntarily. The gainers do not earn their spoils, and the losers do not deserve their fate. Moreover, inflation robs particular classes of people of purchasing power year after year—people living on private pensions, families who save money and “lend” it to banks, and workers whose wages and salaries do not adjust to higher prices. Even if the average person suffers no damage from inflation, that fact offers little consolation to those who are its victims. This is one fundamental indictment of inflation. Inflation redistributes income in an arbitrary way. Society’s income distribution should reflect the interplay of the operation of free markets and the purposeful efforts of government to alter that distribution. Inflation interferes with and distorts this process.

REAL VERSUS NOMINAL INTEREST RATES But wait. Must inflation always rob lenders to bestow gifts upon borrowers? If both parties see inflation coming, won’t lenders demand that borrowers pay a higher interest rate as compensation for the coming inflation? Indeed they will. For this reason, economists draw a sharp distinction between expected inflation and unexpected inflation. 8 The same is not true of Social Security benefits, which are automatically increased to compensate recipients for changes in the price level.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 23

505

The Goals of Macroeconomic Policy

What happens when inflation is fully expected by both parties? Suppose Diamond Jim wants to borrow $1,000 from Scrooge for one year, and both agree that, in the absence of inflation, a fair rate of interest would be 3 percent. This means that Diamond Jim would pay back $1,030 at the end of the year for the privilege of having $1,000 now. If both men expect prices to increase by 6 percent, Scrooge may reason as follows: “If Diamond Jim pays me back $1,030 one year from today, that money will buy less than what $1,000 buys today. Thus, I’ll really be paying him to borrow from me! I’m no philanthropist. Why don’t I charge him 9 percent instead? Then he’ll pay back $1,090 at the end of the year. With prices 6 percent higher, this will buy roughly what $1,030 is worth today. So I’ll get the same 3 percent increase in purchasing power that we would have agreed on in the absence of inflation and won’t be any worse off. That’s the least I’ll accept.” Diamond Jim may follow a similar chain of logic. “With no inflation, I was willing to pay $1,030 one year from now for the privilege of having $1,000 today, and Scrooge was willing to lend it. He’d be crazy to do the same with 6 percent inflation. He’ll want to charge me more. How much should I pay? If I offer him $1,090 one year from now, that will have roughly the same purchasing power as $1,030 today, so I won’t be any worse off. That’s the most I’ll pay.” This kind of thinking may lead Scrooge and Diamond Jim to write a contract with a 9 percent interest rate—3 percent as the increase in purchasing power that Diamond Jim pays to Scrooge and 6 percent as compensation for expected inflation. Then, if the expected 6 percent inflation actually materializes, neither party will be made better or worse off by inflation. This example illustrates a general principle. The 3 percent increase in purchasing power that Diamond Jim agrees to turn over to Scrooge is called the real rate of interest. The 9 percent contractual interest charge that Diamond Jim and Scrooge write into the loan agreement is called the nominal rate of interest. The nominal rate of interest is calculated by adding the expected rate of inflation to the real rate of interest. The general relationship is Nominal interest rate 5 Real interest rate 1 Expected inflation rate

Expected inflation is added to compensate the lender for the loss of purchasing power that the lender expects to suffer as a result of inflation. Because of this, Inflation that is accurately predicted need not redistribute income between borrowers and lenders. If the expected rate of inflation that is embodied in the nominal interest rate matches the actual rate of inflation, no one gains and no one loses. However, to the extent that expectations prove incorrect, inflation will still redistribute income.9

It need hardly be pointed out that errors in predicting the rate of inflation are the norm, not the exception. Published forecasts bear witness to the fact that economists have great difficulty in predicting the rate of inflation. The task is no easier for businesses, consumers, and banks. This is another reason why inflation is so widely condemned as unfair and undesirable. It sets up a guessing game that no one likes.

The real rate of interest is the percentage increase in purchasing power that the borrower pays to the lender for the privilege of borrowing. It indicates the increased ability to purchase goods and services that the lender earns. The nominal rate of interest is the percentage by which the money the borrower pays back exceeds the money that was borrowed, making no adjustment for any decline in the purchasing power of this money that results from inflation.

INFLATION DISTORTS MEASUREMENTS So inflation imposes costs on society because it is difficult to predict. But other costs arise even when inflation is predicted accurately. Many such costs stem from the fact that people are simply unaccustomed to thinking in inflation-adjusted terms and so make errors in thinking and calculation. Many laws and regulations that were designed for an inflationfree economy malfunction when inflation is high. Here are some important examples. EXERCISE: Who gains and who loses if the inflation turns out to be only 4 percent instead of the 6 percent that Scrooge and Diamond Jim expected? What if the inflation rate is 8 percent?

9

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

506

Part 6

The Macroeconomy: Aggregate Supply and Demand

Confusing Real and Nominal Interest Rates People frequently confuse real and nominal interest rates. For example, most Americans viewed the 12 percent mortgage interest rates that banks charged in 1980 as scandalously high but saw the 5 percent mortgage rates of 2009 as great bargains. In truth, with inflation around zero in 2009 and 10 percent in 1980, the real interest rate in 2009 (about 5 percent) was well above the bargain-basement real rates in 1980 (about 2 percent).

The Malfunctioning Tax System

A capital gain is the difference between the price at which an asset is sold and the price at which it was bought.

The tax system is probably the most important example of inflation illusion at work. The law does not recognize the distinction between nominal and real interest rates; it simply taxes nominal interest regardless of how much real interest it represents. Similarly, capital gains—the difference between the price at which an investor sells an asset and the price paid for it—are taxed in nominal, not real, terms. As a result, our tax system can do strange things when inflation is high. An example will show why. Between 1984 and 2008, the price level roughly doubled. Consider some stock that was purchased for $20,000 in 1984 and sold for $35,000 in 2008. The investor actually lost purchasing power while holding the stock because $20,000 of 1984 money could buy roughly what $40,000 could buy in 2008. Yet because the law levies taxes on nominal capital gains, with no correction for inflation, the investor would have been taxed on the $15,000 nominal capital gain—even though suffering a real capital loss of $5,000. Many economists have proposed that this (presumably unintended) feature of the law be changed by taxing only real capital gains; that is, capital gains in excess of inflation. To date, Congress has not agreed. This little example illustrates a pervasive and serious problem: Because it fails to recognize the distinction between nominal and real capital gains, or between nominal and real interest rates, our tax system levies high, and presumably unintended, tax rates on capital income when there is high inflation. Thus the laws that govern our financial system can become counterproductive in an inflationary environment, causing problems that were never intended by legislators. Some economists feel that the high tax rates caused by inflation discourage saving, lending, and investing— and therefore retard economic growth.

Thus, failure to understand that high nominal interest rates can still be low real interest rates has been known to make the tax code misfire, to impoverish savers, and to inhibit borrowing and lending. And it is important to note that these costs of inflation are not purely redistributive. Society as a whole loses when mutually beneficial transactions are prohibited by dysfunctional legislation. Why, then, do such harmful laws stay on the books? The main reason appears to be a lack of understanding of the difference between real and nominal interest rates. People fail to understand that it is normally the real rate of interest that matters in an economic transaction because only that rate reveals how much borrowers pay and lenders receive in terms of the goods and services that money can buy. They focus on the high nominal interest rates caused by inflation, even when these rates correspond to low real interest rates. The difference between real and nominal interest rates, and the fact that the real rate matters economically whereas the nominal rate is often politically significant, are matters that are of the utmost importance and yet are understood by very few people—including many who make public policy decisions.

OTHER COSTS OF INFLATION Another cost of inflation is that rapidly changing prices make it risky to enter into longterm contracts. In an extremely severe inflation, the “long term” may be only a few days from now, but even moderate inflations can have remarkable effects on long-term

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 23

The Goals of Macroeconomic Policy

loans. Suppose a corporation wants to borrow $1 million to finance the purchase of some new equipment and needs the loan for 20 years. If inflation averages 2 percent over this period, the $1 million it repays at the end of 20 years will be worth $672,971 in today’s purchasing power. If inflation averages 5 percent instead, it will be worth only $376,889. Lending or borrowing for this long a period is obviously a big gamble. With the stakes so high, the outcome may be that neither lenders nor borrowers want to get involved in long-term contracts. But without long-term loans, business investment may become impossible. The economy may stagnate. Inflation also makes life difficult for the shopper. You probably have a group of stores that you habitually patronize because they carry the items you want to buy at (roughly) the prices you want to pay. This knowledge saves you a great deal of time and energy. But when prices are changing rapidly, your list quickly becomes obsolete. You return to your favorite clothing store to find that the price of jeans has risen drastically. Should you buy? Should you shop around at other stores? Will they have also raised their prices? Business firms have precisely the same problem with their suppliers. Rising prices force them to shop around more, which imposes costs on the firms and, more generally, reduces the efficiency of the entire economy.

THE COSTS OF LOW VERSUS HIGH INFLATION The preceding litany of the costs of inflation alerts us to one very important fact: Predictable inflation is far less burdensome than unpredictable inflation. When is inflation most predictable? When it proceeds year after year at a modest and more or less steady rate. Thus, the variability of the inflation rate is a crucial factor. Inflation of 3 percent per year for three consecutive years will exact lower social costs than inflation that is 2 percent in the first year, zero in the second year, and 7 percent in the third year. In general: Steady inflation is more predictable than variable inflation and therefore has smaller social and economic costs.

The average level of inflation also matters. Partly because of the inflation illusions mentioned earlier and partly because of the more rapid breakdown in normal customer relationships that we have just mentioned, steady inflation of 6 percent per year is more damaging than steady inflation of 3 percent per year. Economists distinguish between low inflation, which is a modest economic problem, and high inflation, which can be a devastating one, partly on the basis of the average level of inflation and partly on its variability. If inflation remains steady and low, prices may rise for a long time, but at a moderate and fairly constant pace, allowing people to adapt. For example, inflation in the United States, as measured by the Consumer Price Index, was remarkably steady from 1991 through 2008, never dropping below 1.6 percent nor rising above 4.1 percent. Very high inflations typically last for short periods of time and are often marked by highly variable inflation rates from month to month or year to year. In recent decades, for example, countries ranging from Argentina to Russia to Zimbabwe have experienced bouts of inflation exceeding 100 percent or even 1,000 percent per year. (See “How to Make Hyperinflation Even Worse” on the next page.) Each of these episodes severely disrupted the affected country’s economy. The German hyperinflation after World War I is perhaps the most famous episode of runaway inflation. Between December 1922 and November 1923, when a hard-nosed reform program finally broke the spiral, wholesale prices in Germany increased by almost 100 million percent! Even this experience was dwarfed by the great Hungarian inflation of 1945–1946, the greatest inflation of them all. For a period of one year, the monthly rate of inflation averaged about 20,000 percent. In the final month, the price level skyrocketed 42 quadrillion percent!

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

507

508

Part 6

The Macroeconomy: Aggregate Supply and Demand

If you review the costs of inflation that have been discussed in this chapter, you will see why the distinction between low and high inflation is so fundamental. Many economists think we can live rather nicely in an environment of steady, low inflation. No one believes we can survive very well under extremely high inflation. When inflation is steady and low, the rate at which prices rise is relatively easy to predict. It can therefore be taken into account in setting interest rates. Under high inflation, especially if prices are rising at everincreasing or highly variable rates, this is extremely difficult, and perhaps impossible, to do. The potential redistributions become monumental, and lending and borrowing may cease entirely. Any inflation makes it difficult to write long-term contracts. Under low, creeping inflation, the “long term” may be 20 years, or 10 years, or 5 years. By contrast, under high, galloping inflation, the “long term” may be measured in days or weeks. Restaurant prices may change daily. Airfares may go up while you are in flight. When it is impossible to enter into contracts of any duration longer than a few days, economic activity becomes paralyzed. We conclude that The horrors of hyperinflation are very real. But they are either absent in low, steady inflations or present in such muted forms that they can scarcely be considered horrors.

How to Make Hyperinflation Even Worse A newspaper story in July 2007 reported that “buying meat in Zimbabwe these days is like buying an illegal substance.“* While the government price ceiling for beef was Z$87,000 per kilogram, the article reported one of the few shopkeepers with meat to sell asking Z$300,000 per kilo for the precious substance—while carefully watching the door for government inspectors. The local newspaper in one of Zimbabwe’s cities reported that trying to find beef for sale was “like looking for a snowflake in the Sahara desert.” Why? Because the government’s only licensed meat processor was slaughtering only 100 cattle per day—to feed a population of 12 million people! And meat was by no means a special case. Within weeks after price controls were instituted, such basics as bread, cornmeal, sugar, salt, flour, and even matches were difficult to find, thousands of shopkeepers had been arrested, and many stores were opening only at night to avoid the inspectors. Zimbabwe was barreling full-speed-ahead toward economic chaos.

SOURCE: © AP Images

For some years now, the world’s highest inflation rate has been in the impoverished African country of Zimbabwe. And recently, it escalated into the first episode of virulent hyperinflation in decades. After averaging around 20 percent per year in the mid-1990s, Zimbabwean inflation began to accelerate at the end of the 1990s and really took off starting in 2002. According to the International Monetary Fund (IMF), consumer prices in Zimbabwe rose 132 percent in 2002, 350 percent in 2004, and a stunning 1,017 percent in 2006. Then things really got out of control, with inflation rising month after month. The IMF estimates that inflation in Zimbabwe reached the astonishing rate of 16,000 percent for 2007 as a whole, and press reports state that it topped 66,000 percent at an annual rate in December! The root cause, of course, was what it always is in hyperinflations: the Zimbabwean government was printing colossal amounts of money to pay its bills. Although printing too much money was bad enough, Zimbabwe’s dictator, Robert Mugabe, decided to compound the sin by instituting price controls in July 2007. After all, if inflation is running too high, he apparently reasoned, why not just decree that it stop? Well, even an absolute dictator must contend with the laws of economics—especially if he keeps running the printing presses at full tilt. (In the summer of 2007, Zimbabwe’s central bank was forced to introduce a 200,000 Zimbabwean dollar (Z$) bill so that people could conduct business.) The result was predictable: commodities, including basic foodstuffs, quickly disappeared from the shelves. Long queues and even riots developed as Zimbabwe’s starved citizens scrambled to purchase what little there was to buy. Neighboring South Africa reported Zimbabweans pouring over the border—some to flee the chaos, but some just to shop.

SOURCE: “Zimbabwe's Shopping Nightmare,” The Scotsman, July 26, 2007.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 23

509

The Goals of Macroeconomic Policy

LOW INFLATION DOES NOT NECESSARILY LEAD TO HIGH INFLATION We noted earlier that inflation is surrounded by a mythology that bears precious little relation to reality. It seems appropriate to conclude this chapter by disposing of one particularly persistent myth: that low inflation is a slippery slope that invariably leads to high inflation.

Although creeping inflations have many causes, runaway inflations have occurred only when the government has printed incredible amounts of money, usually to finance wartime expenditures. In the German inflation of 1923, the government finally found that its printing presses could not produce enough paper money to keep pace with the exploding prices. Not that it did not try—by the end of the inflation, the daily output of currency exceeded 400 quadrillion marks! The Hungarian authorities in 1945–1946 tried even harder: The average growth rate of the money supply was more than 12,000 percent per month. Needless to say, these are not the kind of inflation problems that are likely to face industrialized countries in the foreseeable future. But that does not mean there is nothing wrong with low inflation. We have spent several pages analyzing the very real costs of even modest inflation. A case against moderate inflation can indeed be built, but it does not help this case to shout slogans like “Creeping inflation always leads to galloping inflation.” Fortunately, it is simply not true.

SOURCE: © Camera Press/Globe Photos, Inc.

There is neither statistical evidence nor theoretical support for the belief that low inflation inevitably leads to high inflation. To be sure, inflations sometimes speed up. At other times, however, they slow down.

These children in Germany during the hyperinflation of the 1920s are building a pyramid with cash, worth no more than the sand or sticks used by children elsewhere.

| SUMMARY | 1. Macroeconomic policy strives to achieve rapid and reasonably stable growth while keeping both unemployment and inflation low. 2. Only rising productivity can raise standards of living in the long run. And seemingly small differences in productivity growth rates can compound to enormous differences in living standards. This is one of our Ideas for Beyond the Final Exam. 3. The production function tells us how much output the economy can produce from the available supplies of labor and capital, given the state of technology. 4. The growth rate of potential GDP is the sum of the growth rate of the labor force plus the growth rate of labor productivity. The latter depends on, among other things, technological change and investment in new capital. 5. Over long periods of time, the growth rates of actual and potential GDP match up quite well. But, owing to macroeconomic fluctuations, the two can diverge sharply over short periods.

6. Although some psychologists, environmentalists, and social critics question the merits of faster economic growth, economists generally assume that faster growth of potential GDP is socially beneficial. 7. When GDP is below its potential, unemployment is above “full employment.” High unemployment exacts heavy financial and psychological costs from those who are its victims, costs that are borne quite unevenly by different groups in the population. 8. Frictional unemployment arises when people are between jobs for normal reasons. Thus, most frictional unemployment is desirable. 9. Structural unemployment is due to shifts in the pattern of demand or to technological change that makes certain skills obsolete. 10. Cyclical unemployment is the portion of unemployment that rises when real GDP grows more slowly than potential GDP and falls when the opposite is true. 11. Today, after some years of extremely high unemployment, economists are unsure where full employment lies.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

510

The Macroeconomy: Aggregate Supply and Demand

Part 6

Many think it may be at a measured unemployment rate around 5 percent.

16. The real rate of interest is the nominal rate of interest minus the expected rate of inflation.

12. Unemployment insurance replaces about half of the lost income of unemployed persons who are insured. Barely over one-third of the unemployed actually collect benefits, and no insurance program can bring back the lost output that could have been produced had these people been working.

17. Because the real rate of interest indicates the command over real resources that the borrower surrenders to the lender, it is of primary economic importance. Public attention often is riveted on nominal rates of interest, and this confusion can lead to costly policy mistakes. 18. Because nominal—not real—capital gains and interest are taxed, our tax system levies heavy taxes on income from capital when inflation is high.

13. People have many misconceptions about inflation. For example, many believe that inflation systematically erodes real wages and blame inflation for any unfavorable changes in relative prices. Both of these ideas are myths.

19. Low inflation that proceeds at moderate and fairly predictable rates year after year carries far lower social costs than does high or variable inflation. But even low, steady inflations entail costs.

14. Other costs of inflation are real, however. For example, inflation often redistributes income from lenders to borrowers.

20. The notion that low inflation inevitably accelerates into high inflation is a myth with no foundation in economic theory and no basis in historical fact.

15. This redistribution is ameliorated by adding the expected rate of inflation to the interest rate, but such expectations often prove to be inaccurate.

| KEY TERMS | capital gain

506

cyclical unemployment

inputs 498

489

labor force

real rate of interest 492

real wage rate

discouraged workers 498

labor productivity

economic growth 490

nominal rate of interest

expected rate of inflation

505

outputs

frictional unemployment

498

potential GDP

491

492

production function

growth policy

purchasing power

490

redistribution by inflation 505

489

full employment 499

505

501

492

relative prices

504

503

structural unemployment

498

unemployment insurance

500

unemployment rate 495

501

| TEST YOURSELF | 1. Two countries start with equal GDPs. The economy of Country A grows at an annual rate of 3 percent, whereas the economy of Country B grows at an annual rate of 4 percent. After 25 years, how much larger is Country B’s economy than Country A’s economy? Why is the answer not 25 percent? 2. If output rises by 35 percent while hours of work increase by 40 percent, has productivity increased or decreased? By how much? 3. Most economists believe that from 2003 to 2006, actual GDP in the United States grew faster than potential GDP. What, then, should have happened to the unemployment rate over those three years? Then, from 2006 to 2009, actual GDP likely grew slower than potential GDP. What should have happened to the unemployment rate over those three years? (Check the data on the inside back cover of this book to see what actually happened.) 4. Country A and Country B have identical population growth rates of 1 percent per annum, and everyone in each country always works 40 hours per week. Labor

productivity grows at a rate of 2 percent in Country A and a rate of 2.5 percent in Country B. What are the growth rates of potential GDP in the two countries? 5. What is the real interest rate paid on a credit card loan bearing 18 percent nominal interest per year, if the rate of inflation is a. zero? b. 4 percent? c. 8 percent? d. 15 percent? e. 20 percent? 6. Suppose you agree to lend money to your friend on the day you both enter college at what you both expect to be a zero real rate of interest. Payment is to be made at graduation, with interest at a fixed nominal rate. If inflation proves to be lower during your college years than what you both had expected, who will gain and who will lose?

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

The Goals of Macroeconomic Policy

Chapter 23

511

| DISCUSSION QUESTIONS | 1. If an earthquake destroys some of the factories in Poorland, what happens to Poorland’s potential GDP? What happens to Poorland’s potential GDP if it acquires some new advanced technology from Richland and starts using it?

5. Show why each of the following complaints is based on a misunderstanding about inflation: a. “Inflation must be stopped because it robs workers of their purchasing power.” b. “Inflation makes it impossible for working people to afford many of the things they were hoping to buy.”

2. Why is it not as terrible to become unemployed nowadays as it was during the Great Depression?

c. “Inflation must be stopped today, for if we do not stop it, it will surely accelerate to ruinously high rates and lead to disaster.”

3. “Unemployment is no longer a social problem because unemployed workers receive unemployment benefits and other benefits that make up for most of their lost wages.” Comment. 4. Why is it so difficult to define full employment? What unemployment rate should the government be shooting for today?

| APPENDIX | How Statisticians Measure Inflation INDEX NUMBERS FOR INFLATION Inflation is generally measured by the change in some index of the general price level. For example, between 1977 and 2008 the Consumer Price Index (CPI), the most widely used measure of the price level, rose from 60.6 to 215.3—an increase of 255 percent. The meaning of the change is clear enough. But what are the meanings of the 60.6 figure for the price level of 1977 and the 215.3 figure for 2008? Both are index numbers. A price index expresses the cost of a market basket of goods relative to its cost in some “base” period, which is simply the year used as a basis of comparison.

Because the CPI currently uses 1982–1984 as its base period, the CPI of 215.3 for 2008 means that it cost $215.30 in 2008 to purchase the same basket of several hundred goods and services that cost $100 in 1982–1984. Now in fact, the particular list of consumer goods and services under scrutiny did not actually cost $100 in 1982–1984. When constructing index numbers, by convention the index is set at 100 in the base period. This conventional figure is then used to obtain index numbers for other years in a very simple way. Suppose that the budget needed to buy the hundreds of items included in the CPI was $2,000 per month in

1982–1984 and $4,146 per month in 2008 Then the index is defined by the following rule: CPI in 2008 CPI in 1982–1984 Cost of market basket in 2008 5 Cost of market basket in 1982–1984 Because the CPI in 1982–1984 is set at 100: $4,306 CPI in 2008 5 5 2.153 100 $2,000 or

CPI in 2008 = 215.3 Exactly the same sort of equation enables us to calculate the CPI in any other year. We have the following rule: Cost of market basket in given year 3 100 CPI in given year 5 Cost of market basket in base year

Of course, not every combination of consumer goods that cost $2,000 in 1982–1984 rose to $4,306 by 2008. For example, a color TV set that cost $400 in 1983 might still have cost $400 in 2008, but a $400 hospital bill in 1983 might have ballooned to $3,000.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

512

Part 6

The Macroeconomy: Aggregate Supply and Demand

The index number problem refers to the fact that there is no perfect cost-of-living index because no two families buy precisely the same bundle of goods and services, and hence no two families suffer precisely the same increase in prices. Economists call this the index number problem: When relative prices are changing, there is no such thing as a “perfect price index” that is correct for every consumer. Any statistical index will understate the increase in the cost of living for some families and overstate it for others. At best, the index can represent the situation of an “average” family.

THE CONSUMER PRICE INDEX The Consumer Price Index (CPI), which is calculated and announced each month by the Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS), is surely the most closely watched price index. When you read in the newspaper or see on television that the “cost of living rose by 0.2 percent last month,” chances are the reporter is referring to the CPI. The Consumer Price Index (CPI) is measured by pricing the items on a list representative of a typical urban household budget.

To know which items to include and in what amounts, the BLS conducts an extensive survey of spending habits roughly once every decade. As a consequence, the same bundle of goods and services is used as a standard for 10 years or more, whether or not spending habits change.10 Of course, spending habits do change, and this variation introduces a small error into the CPI’s measurement of inflation. A simple example will help us understand how the CPI is constructed. Imagine that college students purchase only three items—hamburgers, jeans, and movie tickets—and that we want to devise a cost-ofliving index (call it SPI, or “Student Price Index”) for them. First, we would conduct a survey of spending habits in the base year. (Suppose it is 1983.) Table 5 represents the hypothetical results. You will note that the frugal students of that day spent only $100 per month: $56 on hamburgers, $24 on jeans, and $20 on movies.

10 Economists call this a base-period weight index because the relative importance it attaches to the price of each item depends on how much money consumers actually chose to spend on the item during the base period.

TABLE 5 Results of Student Expenditure Survey, 1983

Average Price

Item

Hamburger $ 0.80 Jeans 24.00 Movie ticket 5.00 Total

Average Quantity Average Purchased Expenditure per Month per Month 70 1 4

$56 24 20 $100

Table 6 presents hypothetical prices of these same three items in 2008. Each price has risen by a different amount, ranging from 25 percent for jeans up to 50 percent for hamburgers. By how much has the SPI risen? TABLE 6 Prices in 2008

Item

Price

Hamburger $1.20 Jeans 30.00 Movie ticket 7.00

Increase over 1983 50% 25 40

Pricing the 1983 student budget at 2008 prices, we find that what once cost $100 now costs $142, as the calculation in Table 7 shows. Thus, the SPI, based on 1983 5 100, is SPI 5 5

Cost of budget in 2008 Cost of budget in 1983

3 100

$142 3 100 5 142 $100

TABLE 7 Cost of 1983 Student Budget in 2008 Prices

70 hamburgers at $1.20 1 pair of jeans at $30 4 movie tickets at $7 Total

$84 30 28 $142

So, the SPI in 2008 stands at 142, meaning that students’ cost of living has increased 42 percent over the 25 years.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 23

USING A PRICE INDEX TO “DEFLATE” MONETARY FIGURES One of the most common uses of price indexes is in the comparison of monetary figures relating to two different points in time. The problem is that if there has been inflation, the dollar is not a good measuring rod because it can buy less now than it did in the past. Here is a simple example. Suppose the average student spent $100 per month in 1983 but $140 per month in 2008. If there was an outcry that students had become spendthrifts, how would you answer the charge? The obvious answer is that a dollar in 2008 does not buy what it did in 1983. Specifically, our SPI shows us that it takes $1.42 in 2008 to purchase what $1 would purchase in 1983. To compare the spending habits of students in the two years, we must divide the 2008 spending figure by 1.42. Specifically, real spending per student in 2008 (where “real” is defined by 1983 dollars) is: Nominal spending in 2008 Real spending 5 3 100 in 2008 Price index of 2008 Thus: Real spending in 2008 5

$140 3 100 5 $98.59 142

This calculation shows that, despite appearances to the contrary, the change in nominal spending from $100 to $140 actually represented a small decrease in real spending. This procedure of dividing by the price index is called deflating, and it serves to translate noncomparable monetary figures into more directly comparable real figures. Deflating is the process of finding the real value of some monetary magnitude by dividing by some appropriate price index.

A good practical illustration is the real wage, a concept we have discussed in this chapter. As we saw in the boxed insert on page 502, we obtain the real wage by dividing the nominal wage by the price level.

USING A PRICE INDEX TO MEASURE INFLATION In addition to deflating nominal magnitudes, price indexes are commonly used to measure inflation, that is, the rate of increase of the price level. The procedure is

The Goals of Macroeconomic Policy

513

straightforward. The data on the inside back cover (column 13) show that the CPI was 49.3 in 1974 and 44.4 in 1973. The ratio of these two numbers, 49.3/44.4, is 1.11, which means that the 1974 price level was 11 percent greater than the 1973 price level. Thus, the inflation rate between 1973 and 1974 was 11 percent. The same procedure holds for any two adjacent years. Most recently, the CPI rose from 207.3 in 2007 to 215.3 in 2008. The ratio of these two numbers is 215.3/207.3 5 1.039, meaning that the inflation rate from 2007 to 2008 was 3.9 percent.

THE GDP DEFLATOR In macroeconomics, one of the most important of the monetary magnitudes that we have to deflate is the nominal gross domestic product (GDP). The price index used to deflate nominal GDP is called the GDP deflator. It is a broad measure of economywide inflation that includes the prices of all goods and services in the economy.

Our general principle for deflating a nominal magnitude tells us how to go from nominal GDP to real GDP: Real GDP 5

Nominal GDP 3 100 GDP deflator

As with the CPI, the 100 simply serves to establish the base of the index as 100, rather than 1.00. Some economists consider the GDP deflator to be a better measure of overall inflation than the Consumer Price Index. The main reason is that the GDP deflator is based on a broader market basket. As mentioned earlier, the CPI is based on the budget of a typical urban family. By contrast, the GDP deflator is constructed from a market basket that includes every item in the GDP—that is, every final good and service produced by the economy. Thus, in addition to prices of consumer goods, the GDP deflator includes the prices of airplanes, lathes, and other goods purchased by businesses—especially computers, which fall in price every year. It also includes government services. For this reason, the two indexes rarely give the same measure of inflation. Usually the discrepancy is minor, but sometimes it can be noticeable, as in 2000 when the CPI recorded a 3.4 percent inflation rate over 1999 while the GDP deflator recorded an inflation rate of only 2.2 percent.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

514

Part 6

The Macroeconomy: Aggregate Supply and Demand

| SUMMARY | 1. Inflation is measured by the percentage increase in an index number of prices, which shows how the cost of some basket of goods has changed over a period of time. 2. Because relative prices are always changing, and because different families purchase different items, no price index can represent precisely the experience of every family. 3. The Consumer Price Index (CPI) tries to measure the cost of living for an average urban household by pricing a typical market basket every month.

4. Price indexes such as the CPI can be used to deflate nominal figures to make them more comparable. Deflation amounts to dividing the nominal magnitude by the appropriate price index. 5. The inflation rate between two adjacent years is computed as the percentage change in the price index between the first year and the second year. 6. The GDP deflator is a broader measure of economywide inflation than the CPI because it includes the prices of all goods and services in the economy.

| KEY TERMS | Consumer Price Index (CPI) deflating

512

513

GDP deflator

513

price index

index number problem

511

511

| TEST YOURSELF | 1. Below you will find the yearly average values of the Dow Jones Industrial Average, the most popular index of stock market prices, for four different years. The Consumer Price Index for each year (on a base of 1982–1984 5 100) can be found on the inside back cover of this book. Use these numbers to deflate all five stock market values. Do real stock prices always rise every decade? Dow Jones Industrial Average 753 891 2,679 10,735

Year 1970 1980 1990 2000

Nominal GDP Real GDP GDP deflator

2006 13,399 12,976

2007 13,254 106.2

2008 14,441 108.5

4. Use the following data to compute the College Price Index for 2008 using the base 1982 = 100.

2. Below you will find nominal GDP and the GDP deflator (based on 2000 5 100) for the years 1988, 1998, and 2008. a. Compute real GDP for each year. b. Compute the percentage change in nominal and real GDP from 1988 to 1998, and from 1998 to 2008. c. Compute the percentage change in the GDP deflator over these two periods. GDP Statistics Nominal GDP Real GDP GDP deflator

3. Fill in the blanks in the following table of GDP statistics:

1988 5,100

1998 8,794

2008 14,441

73.2

95.4

119.7

Item Button-down shirts Loafers Sneakers Textbooks Jeans Restaurant meals

Price in 1982 $10 25 10 12 12 5

Quantity per Month in 1982 1 1 3 12 3 11

Price in 2008 $25 55 35 40 30 14

5. Average hourly earnings in the U.S. economy during several past years were as follows: 1970 $3.23

1980 $6.66

1990 $10.01

2000 $13.75

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 23

Use the CPI numbers provided on the inside back cover of this book to calculate the real wage (in 1982–1984 dollars) for each of these years. Which decade had the fastest growth of money wages? Which had the fastest growth of real wages? 6. The example in the appendix showed that the Student Price Index (SPI) rose by 42 percent from 1983 to 2008. You can understand the meaning of this better if you do the following:

The Goals of Macroeconomic Policy

515

b. Compute the weighted average of the percentage increases of the three prices shown in Table 6, using the expenditure weights you just computed. You should get 42 percent as your answer. This shows that inflation, as measured by the SPI, is a weighted average of the percentage price increases of all the items that are included in the index.

a. Use Table 5 to compute the fraction of total spending accounted for by each of the three items in 1983. Call these values the “expenditure weights.”

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Economic Growth: Theory and Policy Once one starts to think about . . . [differences in growth rates among countries], it is hard to think about anything else. ROBERT E. LU CA S , J R. , 1995 NOBEL PRIZE WINNER IN ECONOMICS

W

hy do some economies grow rapidly while others grow slowly—or not at all? As the opening quotation suggests, there is probably no more important question in all of economics. From 1990 to 2005, according to the World Bank, the American economy grew at a 3.2 percent annual rate, whereas China’s grew 10.3 percent per year and Russia’s declined (on average) by 1.2 percent per year. Those are very large differences. What factors account for such disparities? The discussion in Chapter 23 of the goal of economic growth focused our attention on two crucial but distinct tasks for macroeconomic policy makers, both of which are quite difficult to achieve: • Growth policy: Ensuring that the economy sustains a high long-run growth rate of potential GDP (although not necessarily the highest possible growth rate) • Stabilization policy: Keeping actual GDP reasonably close to potential GDP in the short run, so that society is plagued by neither high unemployment nor high inflation This chapter is devoted to the theory of economic growth and to the policies that this theory suggests. Corresponding to the two tasks listed just above, there are two ways to think about what is to come in this and subsequent chapters. In discussing growth policy in this chapter, we study the factors that determine an economy’s long-run growth rate of potential GDP, and we consider how policy makers can try to speed it up. When we turn to stabilization policy, starting in the next chapter, we will investigate how and why actual GDP deviates from potential GDP in the short run and how policy makers can try to minimize these deviations. Thus the two views of the macroeconomy complement one another.

C O N T E N T S GROWTH POLICY: ENCOURAGING CAPITAL FORMATION

PUZZLE RESOLVED: WHY THE RELATIVE PRICE

THE THREE PILLARS OF PRODUCTIVITY GROWTH

GROWTH POLICY: IMPROVING EDUCATION AND TRAINING

GROWTH IN THE DEVELOPING COUNTRIES

Capital Technology Labor Quality: Education and Training

GROWTH POLICY: SPURRING TECHNOLOGICAL CHANGE

PUZZLE: WHY DOES COLLEGE EDUCATION KEEP

GETTING MORE EXPENSIVE?

LEVELS, GROWTH RATES, AND THE CONVERGENCE HYPOTHESIS

OF COLLEGE TUITION KEEPS RISING

The Three Pillars Revisited Some Special Problems of the Developing Countries

FROM THE LONG RUN TO THE SHORT RUN

THE PRODUCTIVITY SLOWDOWN AND SPEED-UP IN THE UNITED STATES The Productivity Slowdown, 1973–1995 The Productivity Speed-up, 1995–?

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Part 6

The Macroeconomy: Aggregate Supply and Demand

PUZZLE:

WHY DOES COLLEGE EDUCATION KEEP GETTING MORE EXPENSIVE?

Have you ever wondered why the cost of a college education rises more rapidly than most other prices year after year? If you have not, your parents surely have! And it’s not a myth. Between 1978 and 2007, the component of the Consumer Price Index (CPI) that measures college tuition costs rose by about 800 percent—compared to about 218 percent for the overall CPI. That is, the relative price of college tuition increased massively. Economists understand at least part of the reason, and it has little, if anything, to do with the efficiency (or lack thereof) with which colleges are run. Rather, it is a natural companion to the economy’s long-run growth rate. Furthermore, there is good reason to expect the relative price of college tuition to keep rising, and to rise more rapidly in faster-growing societies. Economists believe that the same explanation for the unusually rapid growth in the cost of attending college applies to services as diverse as visits to the doctor, theatrical performances, and restaurant meals—all of which also have become relatively more expensive over time. Later in this chapter, we shall see precisely the explanation for this.

SOURCE: © Jose Luis Pelaez, Inc./CORBIS

518

THE THREE PILLARS OF PRODUCTIVITY GROWTH As we learned in the previous chapter, the growth rate of potential GDP is the sum of the growth rates of hours of work and labor productivity. It is hardly mysterious that an economy will grow if its people keep working harder and harder, year after year. A few societies have followed that recipe successfully for relatively brief periods of time, but there is a limit to how much people can work or, more important, to how much they want to work. In fact, people typically want more leisure time, not longer hours of work, as they get richer. In consequence, the natural focus of growth policy is on enhancing productivity—on working smarter rather than working harder. The last chapter introduced a tool called the production function, which tells us how much output the economy can produce from specified inputs of labor and capital, given the state of technology. The discussion there focused on two of the three main determinants of productivity growth:1 • The rate at which the economy builds up its stock of capital • The rate at which technology improves Before introducing the third determinant, let us review how these first two pillars work.

1

If you need review, see pages 492–494 of Chapter 23.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 24

519

Economic Growth: Theory and Policy

Capital K

Output

3 Figure 1 resembles Figure 1 of the last chapter (see c page 492). The lower curve 0K1 is the production funcYc tion when the capital stock is some low number K1. Its K2 b upward slope indicates, naturally enough, that more Yb labor input produces more output. (Remember, technolK1 ogy is held constant in this graph.) The middle curve 0K2 a Y a is the production function corresponding to some larger capital stock K2, and the upper curve 0K3 pertains to an even larger capital stock K3. To keep things simple at first, suppose hours of work 0 L1 do not grow over time, but rather remain fixed at L1. However, the nation’s businesses invest in new plant Hours of Labor Input and equipment, so the capital stock grows from K1 in the first year to K2 in the second year and K3 in the third year. FI GURE 1 Then the economy’s capacity to produce will move up from point a in year 1 to point b in Production Functions year 2 and point c in year 3. Potential GDP will therefore rise from Ya to Yb to Yc. Because Corresponding to hours of work do not change in this example (by assumption), every bit of this growth Three Different 2 comes from rising productivity, which is in turn due to the accumulation of more capital. Capital Stocks In general:

For a given technology and a given labor force, labor productivity will be higher when the capital stock is larger.

This conclusion is hardly surprising. Employees who work with more capital can obviously produce more goods and services. Just imagine manufacturing a desk, first with only hand tools, then with power tools, and finally with all the equipment available in a modern furniture factory. Or think about selling books from a sidewalk stand, in a bookstore, or over the Internet. Your productivity would rise in each case. Furthermore, workers with more capital are almost certainly blessed with newer—and, hence, better—capital as well. This advantage, too, makes them more productive. Again, compare one of Henry Ford’s assembly-line workers of a century ago to an autoworker in a Ford plant today.

Technology In Chapter 23, we saw that a graph like Figure 1 can also be used to depict the effects of improvements in technology. So now imagine that curves 0K1, 0K2, and 0K3 all correspond to the same capital stock, but to different levels of technology. Specifically, the economy’s technology improves as we move up from 0K1 to 0K2 to 0K3. The graphical (and commonsense) conclusion is exactly the same: Labor becomes more productive from year 1 to year 2 to year 3, so improving technology leads directly to growth. In general: For given inputs of labor and capital, labor productivity will be higher when the technology is better.

Once again, this conclusion hardly comes as a surprise—indeed, it is barely more than the definition of technical progress. When we say that a nation’s technology improves, we mean, more or less, that firms in the country can produce more output from the same inputs. And of course, superior technology is a major factor behind the vastly higher productivity of workers in rich countries versus poor ones. Textile plants in North Carolina, for example, use technologies that are far superior to those employed in Africa.

2 Because productivity is the ratio Y/L, it is shown on the graph by the slope of the straight line connecting the origin to point a, or point b, or point c. Clearly, that slope is rising over time.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

520

Part 6

The Macroeconomy: Aggregate Supply and Demand

Labor Quality: Education and Training

Human capital is the amount of skill embodied in the workforce. It is most commonly measured by the amount of education and training.

It is now time to introduce the third pillar of productivity growth, the one not mentioned in Chapter 23: workforce quality. It is generally assumed—and supported by reams of evidence—that better-educated workers can produce more goods and services in an hour than can less well-educated workers. And the same lesson applies to training that takes place outside the schools, such as on the job: Better-trained workers are more productive. The amount of education and training embodied in a nation’s labor force is often referred to as its stock of human capital. Conceptually, an increase in human capital has the same effect on productivity as an increase in physical capital or an improvement in technology; that is, the same quantity of labor input becomes capable of producing more output. So we can use the ever-adaptable Figure 1 for yet a third purpose—to represent increasing workforce quality as we move up from 0K1 to 0K2 to 0K3. Once again, the general conclusion is obvious: For a given capital stock, labor force, and technology, labor productivity will be higher when the workforce has more education and training.

This third pillar is another obvious source of large disparities between rich nations, which tend to have well-educated populations, and poor nations, which do not. So we can add a third item to complete our list of the three principal determinants of a nation’s productivity growth rate: • The rate at which the economy builds up its stock of capital • The rate at which technology improves • The rate at which workforce quality (or “human capital”) is improving In the contemporary United States, average educational attainment is high and workforce quality changes little from year to year. But in some rapidly developing countries, improvements in education can be an important engine of growth. For example, average years of schooling in South Korea soared from less than five in 1970 to more than nine in 1990, which contributed mightily to South Korea’s remarkably rapid economic development. Although there is no unique formula for growth, the most successful growth strategies of the post–World War II era, beginning with the Japanese “economic miracle,” made ample use of all three pillars. Starting from a base of extreme deprivation after World War II, Japan showed the world how a combination of high rates of investment, a well-educated workforce, and the adoption of state-of-the-art technology could catapult a poor nation into the leading ranks within a few decades. The lessons were not lost on the so-called Asian Tigers—including Taiwan, South Korea, Singapore, and Hong Kong—which developed rapidly using their own versions of the Japanese model. Today, a number of other countries, most notably China, are applying variants of this growth formula once again. It works.

LEVELS, GROWTH RATES, AND THE CONVERGENCE HYPOTHESIS Notice that, where productivity growth rates are concerned, it is the rates of increase of capital, technology, and workforce quality that matter, rather than their current levels. This distinction may sound boring, but it is important. Productivity levels are vastly higher in the rich countries—that is why they are called rich. The wealthy nations have more bountiful supplies of capital, more highly skilled workers, and superior technologies. Naturally, they can produce more output per hour of work. Table 1 shows, for example, that an hour of labor in France in 2005 produced 99 percent as much output as an hour of labor in the United States, when evaluated in U.S. dollars, whereas the corresponding figure for Brazil was only 23 percent. But the growth rates of capital, workforce skills, and technology are not necessarily higher in the rich countries. For example, Country A might have abundant capital, but the amount might be increasing at a snail’s pace, whereas in Country B capital might be scarce

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

521

Economic Growth: Theory and Policy

but growing rapidly. When it comes to determining the long-run growth rate, it is the growth rates rather than the current levels of these three pillars that matter. In fact, GDP per hour of work actually grew faster over the 25 years covered in Table 1 in several countries that have lower average incomes than the United States. For example, productivity in South Korea, Ireland, France, and the United Kingdom all grew faster than in the United States. Why? Although a typical Irish worker in 1980 had far less physical and human capital than a typical American worker, and used substantially less advanced technology, the capital stock, average educational attainment, and level of technology all increased faster in Ireland than in the United States. The level of productivity in a nation depends on its supplies of human and physical capital and the state of its technology. But the growth rate of productivity depends on the rates of increase of these three factors.

TABLE 1 Productivity Levels and Productivity Growth Rates in Selected Countries

Country United States France United Kingdom Spain Ireland Argentina Mexico Brazil South Korea

GDP per Hour of Work 1980 (as percentage of U.S.) 100 86 71 62 57 51 44 33 20

100 99 85 62 96 37 25 23 48

Growth Rate 1.7 2.3 2.4 1.7 3.9 0.4 20.5 0.2 5.4

NOTE: All productivity data are measured in U.S. dollars. So countries whose currencies rise relative to the U.S. dollar gain on the United States, whereas countries whose currencies fall relative to the U.S. dollar lose ground.

The distinction between productivity levels and productivity growth rates may strike you as a piece of pedantic arithmetic, but it has many important practical applications. Here is a particularly striking one. If the productivity growth rate is higher in poorer countries than in richer ones, then poor countries will close the gap on rich ones. The so-called convergence hypothesis suggests that this is what normally happens. Convergence hypothesis: The productivity growth rates of poorer countries tend to be higher than those of richer countries.

The idea behind the convergence hypothesis, as illustrated in Figure 2, is that productivity growth will typically be faster where the initial level of productivity is lower. In this hypothetical example, the poorer country starts out with a per capita GDP of $2,000, just one-fifth that of the richer country. But the poor country’s real GDP per capita grows faster, so it gradually narrows the relative income gap. Why might we expect such convergence to be the norm? In some poor countries, the supply of capital may be growing very rapidly. In others, educational attainment may be rising quickly, albeit from a low base. The main reason to expect convergence in the long run is that low-productivity countries should be able to learn from high-productivity countries as scientific and managerial know-how spreads around the world. A country that is operating at the technological frontier can improve its technology only by innovating. It must constantly figure out ways to do things better. A less advanced country can boost its productivity simply by imitating, by adopting technologies that are already in common use in the advanced countries. Not surprisingly, it is much easier to “look it up” than to “think it up.” Modern communications assist the convergence $10,000 process by speeding the flow of information around the globe. The Internet was invented mainly in the United States and the United Kingdom, but it quickly spread to almost every corner of the world. Likewise, advances in human genomics and stem-cell research are now originating $2,000 in some of the most advanced countries, but they are communicated rapidly to scientists all over the world. A poor country that is skilled at importing Time scientific and engineering advances from the rich Real GDP per Capita

GDP per Hour of Work 2005 (as percentage of U.S.)

SOURCE: International Labour Organization, Key Indicators of the Labour Market (Geneva: 2007), Table 18A (at http://www.ilo.org/kilm).

Chapter 24

The convergence hypothesis holds that nations with low levels of productivity tend to have high productivity growth rates, so that international productivity differences shrink over time.

FI GURE 2 The Convergence Hypothesis

Richer country

Poorer country

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

522

Part 6

The Macroeconomy: Aggregate Supply and Demand

TABLE 2

countries can achieve very rapid productivity growth. Indeed, when Japan was a poor nation, successful imitation was one of its secrets to getting rich. India and China are trying that now—with considerable success. GDP per Capita Unfortunately, many poor countries seem unable to participate Growth Rate, in the convergence process. For a variety of reasons (some of which 1990 –2005 will be mentioned later in this chapter), a number of developing 2.0% countries seem incapable of adopting and adapting advanced tech20.4 nologies. In fact, Table 1 shows that per capita incomes in some of 22.4 2.3 these nations actually grew more slowly than in the rich countries 22.4 over the quarter-century covered by the table. Labor productivity 22.5 in Argentina and Brazil both grew much slower than that of the 20.9 United States, for example, whereas Mexico’s productivity (when measured in U.S. dollars) actually declined. Sadly, this kind of decline is not all that unusual. Real incomes have stagnated or even fallen in some of the poorest countries of the world, especially in Africa and many of the former communist countries (see Table 2). Convergence certainly cannot be taken for granted.

GDP per Capita, 2005*

Country Belarus Russia Ukraine Peru Haiti Burundi Sierra Leone

$1,868 2,445 960 2,337 434 105 218

* In constant 2000 U.S. dollars.

SOURCE: World Bank, World Development Indicators, 2007.

Levels and Growth Rates of GDP per Capita in Selected Poor Countries

Technological laggards can, and sometimes do, close the gap with technological leaders by imitating and adapting existing technologies. Within this “convergence club,” productivity growth rates are higher where productivity levels are lower. Unfortunately, some of the world’s poorest nations have been unable to join the club.

GROWTH POLICY: ENCOURAGING CAPITAL FORMATION

A nation’s capital is its available supply of plant, equipment, and software. It is the result of past decisions to make investments in these items. Investment is the flow of resources into the production of new capital. It is the labor, steel, and other inputs devoted to the construction of factories, warehouses, railroads, and other pieces of capital during some period of time. Capital formation is synonymous with investment. It refers to the process of building up the capital stock.

Let us now see how the government might spur growth by working on these three pillars, beginning with capital. First, we need to clarify some terminology. We have spoken of the supply of capital, by which we mean the volume of plant (factories, office buildings, and so on), equipment (drill presses, computers, and so on), and software currently available. Businesses add to the existing supply of capital whenever they make investment expenditures—purchases of new plant, equipment, and software. In this way, the growth of the capital stock depends on how much businesses spend on investment. That process is called capital formation—literally, forming new capital. But you don’t get something for nothing. Devoting more of society’s resources to producing investment goods generally means devoting fewer resources to producing consumer goods. A production possibilities frontier, as introduced in Chapter 3, can be used to depict the nature of this trade-off—and the choices open to a nation. Given its technology and existing resources of labor, capital, and so on, the country can in principle select any point on the production possibilities frontier AICD in Figure 3. If it picks a point like C, its citizens will enjoy many consumer goods, but it will not be investing much for the future. So it will grow slowly. If, on the other hand, it selects a point like I, its citizens will consume less today, but the nation’s higher level of investment means it will grow more quickly. Thus, at least within limits, the amount of capital formation and growth can be chosen. Now suppose the government wants the capital stock to grow faster, that is, it wants to move from a point like C toward a point like I in Figure 3. In a capitalist market economy such as ours, private businesses make almost all investment decisions—how many factories to build, how many computers to purchase, and so on. To speed up the process of capital formation, the government must somehow persuade private businesses to invest more. But how?

Real Interest Rates The most obvious way to increase investment by private businesses is to lower real interest rates. When real interest rates fall, investment normally rises. Why? Because businesses often borrow to finance their investments, and the real

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

523

Economic Growth: Theory and Policy

interest rate indicates how much firms must pay for that privilege. An investment project that looks unattractive at an interest rate of 10 percent may look highly profitable if the firm has to pay only 6 percent. The amount that businesses invest depends on the real interest rate they pay to borrow funds. The lower the real rate of interest, the more investment there will be.

Investment Goods Produced

Chapter 24

A

I

In subsequent chapters, we will learn how government policy, C especially monetary policy, influences interest rates—which gives policy makers some leverage over private investment decisions. D That relationship, in fact, is why monetary policy will play such a Consumer Goods Produced crucial role in subsequent chapters. We might as well come clean right away: For reasons to be examined later, the government’s ability to control real interest rates is imperfect. Furthermore, FI GURE 3 the rate of interest is only one of several determinants of investment spending. So Choosing between policy makers have only a limited ability to affect the level of investment by manipulating Investment and interest rates. Consumption

Tax Provisions The government also can influence investment spending by altering various provisions of the tax code. For example, President George W. Bush and Congress reduced the tax rate on capital gains—the profit earned by selling an asset for more than you paid for it—in 2003. The major argument for lowering capital gains taxes was the claim, much disputed by the critics, that it would lead to greater investment spending. In addition, the United States imposes a tax on corporate profits and can reduce that tax to spur investment as well. There are other, more complicated tax provisions relating to investment, too.3 To summarize: The tax law gives the government several ways to influence business spending on investment goods, but influence is far from total control.

Technical Change Technology, which we have listed as a separate pillar of growth, also drives investment. New business opportunities suddenly appear when a new product such as the mobile telephone is invented or when a technological breakthrough makes an existing product much cheaper or better, as is happening with flat-panel TVs. In a capitalist system, entrepreneurs pounce on such opportunities—building new factories, stores, and offices, and buying new equipment. Thus, if the government can figure out how to spur technological progress (a subject discussed later in this chapter), those same policies will probably boost investment. The Growth of Demand Rapid growth itself can induce businesses to invest more. When demand presses against capacity, executives are likely to believe that new factories and machinery can be employed profitably—which creates strong incentives to build new capital. Thus it was no coincidence that investment soared in the United States during the boom years of the 1990s, and collapsed during the sharp slump of 2008–2009. By contrast, if machinery and factories stand idle, businesses may find new investments unattractive. In summary: High levels of sales and expectations of rapid economic growth create an atmosphere conducive to investment.

This situation creates a kind of virtuous cycle in which high rates of investment boost economic growth, and rapid growth boosts investment. Of course, the same process can also operate in reverse—as a vicious cycle: When the economy stagnates, firms do not want to invest much, which damages prospects for further growth. 3 Any kind of a tax cut will reduce government revenue. Unless that revenue is made up by a spending cut or by some other tax, the government’s budget deficit will rise—which will also affect investment. We will study that channel in Chapter 32.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

524

Part 6

The Macroeconomy: Aggregate Supply and Demand

Political Stability and Property Rights There is one other absolutely critical determinant of investment spending that Americans simply take for granted. A business thinking about committing funds to, say, build a factory faces any number Property rights are laws of risks. Construction costs might run higher than estimates. Interest rates might rise. Deand/or conventions that assign owners the rights to mand for the product might prove weaker than expected. The list goes on and on. These use their property as they are the normal hazards of entrepreneurship, an activity that is not for the faint of heart. see fit (within the law)—for But, at a minimum, business executives contemplating a long-term investment want asexample, to sell the property surances that their property will not be taken from them for capricious or political reaand to reap the benefits sons. Republican businesspeople in the United States do not worry that their property will (such as rents or dividends) be seized if the Democrats win the next election. Nor do they worry that court rulings will while they own it. deprive them of their property rights without due process. By contrast, in many less well-organized societies, the rule of law is reguTABLE 3 larly threatened by combinations of arbitrary government actions, political Selected Countries Ranked by Level instability, anticapitalist ideology, rampant corruption, or runaway crime. of Investor Protection Such problems have posed serious impediments to long-term investment in Country Rating (0 –10 scale) many poor countries throughout history. They are among the chief reasons these countries have remained poor. And the litany of problems that threaten Singapore 9.3 United States 8.3 property rights is not just a matter of history—these issues remain relevant Canada 8.3 in Russia, much of Africa, and parts of Latin America today. Where busiUnited Kingdom 8.0 nesses fear that their property may be expropriated, a drop in interest rates Japan 7.0 of a few percentage points will not encourage much investment. Mexico 6.0 Needless to say, the strength of property rights, adherence to the rule of India 6.0 Sweden 5.7 law, the level of corruption, and the like are not easy things to measure. AnyBrazil 5.3 one who attempts to rank countries on such criteria must make many subjecItaly 5.0 tive judgments. Nevertheless, due to its recent interest in the subject, the China 5.0 World Bank currently ranks 175 countries on various aspects of their business Swaziland 2.3 climate, including their degree of investor protection. Some of their data are SOURCE: World Bank web site, www.doingbusiness displayed in Table 3. The ranking of the various countries is roughly what you .org, accessed August 2007. The index is constructed by rating countries on transparency of transactions, might expect. liability for self-dealing, and shareholders’ ability to sue for misconduct.

GROWTH POLICY: IMPROVING EDUCATION AND TRAINING Numerous studies in many countries confirm the fact that more educated and bettertrained workers earn higher wages. Economists naturally assume that the people who earn more are also more productive. Thus, more education and training presumably

To Grow Fast, Get the Institutions Right A few years ago, the World Bank surveyed the ways the governments of around 100 countries either encourage or discourage market activity. Its conclusion, as summarized in The Economist, was that “when poor people are allowed access to the institutions richer people enjoy, they can thrive and help themselves. A great deal of poverty, in other words, may be easily avoidable.” The World Bank study highlighted the importance of making simple institutions accessible to the poor—such as protection of property rights (especially over land), access to the judicial system, and a free and open flow of information—as key ingredients in successful economic development. The Economist put it graphically: If it is too expensive and time-consuming, for example, to open a bank account, the poor will stuff their savings under the

mattress. When it takes 19 steps, five months and more than an average person’s annual income to register a new business in Mozambique, it is no wonder that aspiring, cash-strapped entrepreneurs do not bother. The Bank’s conclusion reminded many people of the central message of a best-selling 2000 book by Peruvian economist and businessman Hernando de Soto—who found to his dismay that, in his own country, it took 700 bureaucratic steps to obtain legal title to a house! SOURCES: “Now, Think Small,” The Economist, September 15, 2001, pp. 40–42; and Hernando de Soto, The Mystery of Capital: Why Capitalism Triumphs in the West and Fails Everywhere Else (New York: Basic Books), 2000.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

525

Economic Growth: Theory and Policy

Chapter 24

contribute to higher productivity. Although private institutions play a role in the educational process, in most societies the state bears the primary responsibility for educating the population. So education policy is an obvious and critical component of growth policy. A modern industrial society is built more on brains than on brawn. Even ordinary bluecollar jobs often require a high school education. For this reason, policies that raise rates of high school attendance and completion and, perhaps as importantly, improve the quality of secondary education can make genuine contributions to growth. Unfortunately, such policies have proven difficult to devise and implement. So the debate over how to improve our public schools goes on and on, with no resolution in sight. President Obama’s recent efforts in this regard are only the latest in a long list of educational reforms. Finally, if knowledge is power in the information age, then sending more young people to college and graduate school may be crucial to economic success. It is well documented that the earnings gap between high school and college graduates in the United States has risen dramatically since the late 1970s. One graphical depiction of this rising disparity is shown in Figure 4. It shows clearly that the job market was rewarding the skills acquired in college ever more generously from about 1978 until about 2000. To the extent that high wages reflect high productivity, low-cost tuition (such as that paid at many state colleges and universities), student loans to low-income families, and other policies to encourage college attendance may yield society rich dividends. Devoting more resources to education should, therefore, raise an economy’s growth rate. By suitable reinterpretation, Figure 3 can again be used to illustrate the trade-off between present and future. Because expenditures on education are naturally thought of as investments in human capital, just interpret the vertical axis as now representing educational investments. If a society spends more on them and less on consumer goods (thus moving from point C toward point I), it should grow faster. China, to cite the most prominent example, is doing that with great enthusiasm right now. Education is not a panacea for all of an economy’s ills. Education in the former Soviet Union was outstanding in some respects, but it proved insufficient to prevent the Soviet economy from falling ever further behind the capitalist economies in terms of economic growth. On-the-job training may be just as important as formal education in raising productivity, but it is less amenable to influence by the government. For the most part, private

On-the-job training refers to skills that workers acquire while at work, rather than in school or in formal vocational training programs.

FIGU RE 4

50 Females

Percentage Wage Advantage

SOURCE: Lawrence Mishel, Jared Bernstein, Sylvia Allegretto, and Heather Boushey, The State of Working America, 2006–2007 (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 2007).

Wage Premium for College Graduates over High School Graduates

40 Males

30

20

1973 1975

1980

1985

1990 Year

1995

2000

2005

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

526

Part 6

The Macroeconomy: Aggregate Supply and Demand

businesses decide how much, and in what ways, to train their workers. Various public policy initiatives—ranging from government-run training programs, to subsidies for private-sector training, to mandated minimum training expenditures by firms—have been tried in various countries with mixed results. In the United States, mandates on companies have always been viewed as improper interferences with private business decisions, and they have been avoided. The government runs some training programs, though the biggest (by far) is the armed forces.

GROWTH POLICY: SPURRING TECHNOLOGICAL CHANGE Our third pillar of growth is technology, or getting more output from given supplies of inputs. Some of the most promising policies for speeding up the pace of technical progress have already been mentioned:

More Education Although some inventions and innovations are the product of dumb luck, most result from the sustained application of knowledge, resources, and brainpower to scientific, engineering, and managerial problems. We have just noted that more educated workers appear to be more productive per se. In addition, a society is likely to be more innovative if it has a greater supply of scientists, engineers, and skilled business managers who are constantly on the prowl for new opportunities. Modern growth theory emphasizes the pivotal role in the growth process of committing more human, physical, and financial resources to the acquisition of knowledge. High levels of education, especially scientific, engineering, and managerial education, contribute to the advancement of technology.

There is little doubt that the United States leads the world in the quality of its graduate programs in business and in many of the scientific and engineering disciplines. As evidence of this superiority, one need only look at the tens of thousands of foreign students who flock to our shores to attend graduate school—many of whom remain in America. It seems reasonable to suppose that America’s unquestioned leadership in scientific and business education contributes to our leadership in productivity. On this basis, many economists and politicians endorse policies designed to induce more bright young people to pursue scientific and engineering careers—such as scholarships, fellowships, and research grants—and worry that too few young Americans are choosing these career paths.

More Capital Formation We are all familiar with the fact that the latest versions of Invention is the act of discovering new products or new ways of making products. Innovation is the act of putting new ideas into effect by, for example, bringing new products to market, changing product designs, and improving the way in which things are done. Research and development (R&D) refers to activities aimed at inventing new products or processes, or improving existing ones.

cell phones, PCs, personal digital assistants (PDAs), and even televisions embody new features that were unavailable a year or even six months ago. The same is true of industrial capital. Indeed, new investment is the principal way in which the latest technological breakthroughs get hard-wired into the nation’s capital stock. As we mentioned in our earlier discussion of capital formation, newer capital is normally better capital. In this way, High rates of investment contribute to rapid technical progress.

So all of the policies we discussed earlier as ways to bolster capital formation can also be thought of as ways to speed up technical progress.

Research and Development There is a more direct way to spur invention and innovation: devote more of society’s resources to research and development (R&D). Driven by the profit motive, American businesses have long invested heavily in industrial R&D. According to the old saying, “Build a better mousetrap, and the world will beat a path to your door.” And innovative companies in the United States and elsewhere have been engaged in research on “better mousetraps” for decades. Polaroid invented instant photography, Xerox developed photocopying, and Apple pioneered the desktop computer. Boeing improved jet aircraft several times. U.S.-based pharmaceutical companies

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

527

Economic Growth: Theory and Policy

Chapter 24

have discovered many new, life-enhancing drugs. Intel has developed generation after generation of ever-faster microprocessors. The list goes on and on. All these companies and others have spent untold billions of dollars on R&D to discover new products, to improve old ones, and to make their industrial processes more efficient. Although many research dollars are inevitably “wasted” on false starts and experiments that don’t pan out, numerous studies have shown that the average dollar invested in R&D has yielded high returns to society. Heavy spending on R&D is, indeed, one of the keys to high productivity growth. The U.S. government supports and encourages R&D in several ways. First, it subsidizes private R&D spending through the tax code. Specifically, the Research and Experimentation Tax Credit reduces the taxes of companies that spend more money on R&D. Second, the government sometimes joins with private companies in collaborative research efforts. The Human Genome Project may be the best-known example of such a public–private partnership (some called it a race!). There also have been cooperative ventures in new automotive technology, alternative energy sources, and elsewhere. Last, and certainly not least, the federal government has over the years spent a great deal of taxpayer money directly on R&D. Much of this spending has been funneled through the Department of Defense, but the National Aeronautics and Space Administration (NASA), the National Science Foundation (NSF), the National Institutes of Health (NIH), and many other agencies have also played important roles. Inventions as diverse as atomic energy, advanced ceramic materials, and the Internet were originally developed in federal laboratories. Federal government R&D spending in fiscal year 2009 amounted to roughly $150 billion, more than half of which went through the Pentagon. Our multipurpose Figure 3 again illustrates the choice facing society. Now interpret the vertical axis as measuring investments in R&D. Devoting more resources to R&D—that is, choosing point I rather than point C—leads to less current consumption but more growth.

THE PRODUCTIVITY SLOWDOWN AND SPEED-UP IN THE UNITED STATES

The Productivity Slowdown, 1973–1995 The productivity slowdown after 1973 was a disconcerting development, and economists have

FI GURE 5 Average Productivity Growth Rates in the United States, 1948–2008

2.6

Percent per Year

SOURCE: U.S. Department of Labor at www.bls.gov/data.

Around 1973, productivity growth in the United States suddenly and mysteriously slowed down—from the rate of about 2.8 percent per year that had characterized the 1948–1973 period to about 1.4 percent thereafter (see Figure 5). Hardly anyone anticipated this productivity slowdown. Then, starting around 1995, productivity growth suddenly speeded up again—from about 1.4 percent per year during the 1973–1995 period back to about 2.6 percent since then (see Figure 5 again). Once again, the abrupt change in the growth rate caught most people by surprise. Recall from the discussion of compounding in Chapter 23 that a change in the growth rate 2.8 of around 1 percentage point, if sustained for decades, makes an enormous difference in living standards. So understanding these two major events is of critical importance. Yet even now, some 37 years later, economists remain puzzled about the 1973 productivity slowdown, and the 1.4 reasons behind the 1995 productivity speed-up are only partly understood. Let us see what economists know about these two episodes.

1948–1973

1973–1995

1995–2008

NOTE: Data pertain to the non-farm business sector.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

528

Part 6

The Macroeconomy: Aggregate Supply and Demand

been struggling to explain it ever since. Among the leading explanations that have been offered are the following.

Lagging Investment During the 1980s and early 1990s, many people suggested that inadequate investment was behind America’s productivity problem. Countries such as Germany and Japan, these critics observed, saved and invested far more than Americans did, thereby equipping their workers with more modern equipment that boosted labor productivity. United States tax policy, they argued, should create stronger incentives for business to invest and for households to save. Although the argument was logical, the facts never did support it. For example, the share of U.S. GDP accounted for by business investment did not decline during the period of slow productivity growth. Nor did the contribution of capital formation to growth fall. (See the box “Growth Accounting in the United States.”) High Energy Prices A second explanation begins with a tantalizing fact: The productivity slowdown started around 1973, just when the Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC) jacked up the price of oil. As a matter of logic, higher oil prices should reduce business use of energy, which should make labor less productive. Furthermore, productivity growth fell just at the time that energy prices rose, not just in the United States but all over the world—which is quite a striking coincidence. This circumstantial evidence points the finger at oil. The argument sounds persuasive until you remember another important fact: When energy prices dropped sharply in the mid-1980s, productivity growth did not revive. So the energy explanation of the productivity slowdown has many skeptics.

Inadequate Workforce Skills Could it be that the skills of the U.S. labor force failed to keep pace with the demands of new technology after 1973? Although workforce skills are notoriously difficult to measure, there was and is a widespread feeling that the quality of education in the United States has declined. For example, SAT scores peaked in the late 1960s and then declined for about 20 years.4 Yet standard measures such as school attendance rates, graduation rates, and average levels of educational attainment all continued to register gains in the 1970s and 1980s. Clearly, the proposition that the quality of the U.S. workforce declined is at least debatable. A Technological Slowdown? Could the pace of innovation have slowed in the 1973–1995 period? Most people instinctively answer “no.” After all, the microchip and the personal computer were invented in the 1970s, opening the door to what can only be called a revolution in computing and information technology (IT). Workplaces were transformed beyond recognition. Entirely new industries (such as those related to PCs) were spawned. Didn’t these technological marvels raise productivity by enormous amounts? The paradox of seemingly rapid technological advance coupled with sluggish productivity performance puzzled economists for years. How could the contribution of technology to growth have fallen? A satisfactory answer was never given. And then, all of a sudden, the facts changed.

The Productivity Speed-up, 1995–? Figure 5 shows that productivity growth speeded up remarkably after 1995, rising from about 1.4 percent per annum before that year to about 2.6 percent from 1995 to 2008. This time, the causes are better understood—and most of them relate to the IT revolution.

Surging Investment Bountiful new business opportunities in the IT sector and elsewhere, coupled with a strong national economy, led to a surge in business investment

4

The SAT was rescaled about a decade ago to reflect this decline in average scores.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 24

529

Economic Growth: Theory and Policy

Growth Accounting in the United States In this chapter, we have learned that labor productivity (output per hour of work) rises because more capital is accumulated, because technology improves, and because workforce quality rises. The last of these three pillars is quantitatively unimportant in the modern United States because average educational attainment has been high for a long time and has not changed much recently, but the other two pillars are very important. The table breaks down the growth rate of labor productivity into its two main components over three different periods of time. We see that the productivity slowdown after 1973 was entirely accounted for by slower technological improvement; the contribution of capital formation did not decline at all.* Similarly, the productivity speed-up after 1995 was mostly accounted for by faster technical progress, though higher rates of investment also played some role.

Growth rate of labor productivity Contribution of capital formation Contribution of technology

1948–1973

1973–1995

1995–2008

2.8% 0.9

1.4% 1.0

2.6% 1.3

1.9

0.4

1.3

SOURCE: Bureau of Labor Statistics at www.bls.gov/data.

* Changes in workforce quality are included in the technology component.

spending in the 1990s. Business investment as a percentage of real GDP rose from 9.1 percent in 1991 to 14.6 percent in 2000, and most of that increase was concentrated in computers, software, and telecommunications equipment. We have observed several times in this chapter that the productivity growth rate should rise when the capital stock grows faster—and it did in the late 1990s. But then investment fell when the stock market crashed, beginning in 2000. Over the entire 1995–2008 period, the table in the box above shows a slightly larger contribution of capital formation to productivity growth in 1995–2008 than in 1973–1995. So investment cannot be the whole answer.

Falling Energy Prices? For part of this period, especially the years 1996–1998, energy prices were falling. By the same logic used earlier, falling energy prices should have enhanced productivity growth. But, as we noted earlier, this argument did not seem to work so well when energy prices fell in the 1980s. Why, then, should we believe it for the 1990s? In addition, productivity continued to surge in the early years of this decade, after energy prices had started to rise.

Advances in Information Technology We seem to be on safer ground when we look to technological progress, especially in computers and semiconductors, to explain the speed-up in productivity growth. First, innovation seemed to have exploded in the 1990s. Computers became faster and much, much cheaper—as did telecommunications equipment and services. Corporate intranets became commonplace. The Internet grew from a scientific curiosity into a commercial reality, and so on. We truly entered the Information Age. Second, it probably took American businesses some time to learn how to use the computer and telecommunications technologies that were invented and adopted between, say, 1980 and the early 1990s. It was only in the late 1990s, some observers argue, that U.S. industry was positioned to reap the benefits of these advances in the form of higher productivity. Such long delays are not unprecedented. Research has shown, for example, that it took a long time for the availability of electric power at the end of the nineteenth century to contribute much to productivity growth. Like electric power, computers were a novel input to production, and it may have taken years for prospective users to find the most productive ways to employ them. In summary: The biggest pillar of productivity growth—technological change—seems to do most of the work of explaining why productivity accelerated in the United States after 1995.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

530

Part 6

The Macroeconomy: Aggregate Supply and Demand

PUZZLE RESOLVED:

WHY THE RELATIVE PRICE OF COLLEGE TUITION KEEPS RISING

Earlier in this chapter, we observed that the relative prices of services such as college tuition, medical care, and theater tickets seem to rise year after year. And we suggested that one main reason for this perpetual increase is tied to the economy’s long-run growth rate. We are now in a position to understand precisely how that mechanism works. Rising productivity is the key. The argument is based on three simple ideas.

IDEA 1 It stands to reason, and is verified by historical experience, that real wages tend to rise at the same rate as labor productivity. This relationship makes sense: Labor normally gets paid more when it produces more. Thus real wages will rise most rapidly in those economies with the fastest productivity growth.

IDEA 2 Although average labor productivity in the economy increases from year to year, there are a number of personally provided services for which productivity (output per hour) cannot or does not grow. We have already mentioned several of them. Your college or university can increase the “productivity” of its faculty by increasing class size, but most students and parents would view that as a decrease in educational quality. Similarly, a modern doctor takes roughly as long to give a patient a physical as his counterparts did 25 or 50 years ago. It also takes exactly the same time for an orchestra to play one of Beethoven’s symphonies today as it did in Beethoven’s time. There is a common ingredient in each of these diverse examples: The major sources of higher labor productivity that we have studied in this chapter—more capital and better technology—are completely or nearly irrelevant. It still takes one lecturer to teach a class, one doctor to examine a patient, and four musicians to play a string quartet—just as it did 100 years ago. Saving on labor by using more and better equipment is more or less out of the question.5 These so-called personal services stand in stark contrast to, say, working on an automobile assembly line or in a semiconductor plant, or even to working in service industries such as telecommunications—all instances in which both capital formation and technical progress regularly raise labor productivity.

IDEA 3 Real wages in different occupations must rise at similar rates in the long run. This point may sound wrong at first: Haven’t the wages of computer programmers risen faster than those of schoolteachers in recent years? Yes they have, and that is the market’s way of attracting more young people into computer programming. In the long run, these growth rates must (more or less) equilibrate, or else virtually no one would want to be a schoolteacher any more. Now let’s bring the three ideas together. College teachers are no more productive than they used to be, but autoworkers are (Idea 2). But in the long run, the real wages of college teachers and autoworkers must grow at roughly the same rate (Idea 3), which is the economy-wide productivity growth rate (Idea 1). As a result, wages of college teachers and doctors will rise faster than their productivity does, and so their services must grow ever more expensive compared to, say, computers and phone calls. That is, indeed, the way things seem to have worked out. Compared to the world in which your parents grew up, computers and telephone calls are now very cheap, whereas college tuition and doctors’ bills are very expensive. The same logic applies to the services of police officers (two per squad car), baseball players (nine per team), chefs, and many other occupations where productivity improvements are either impossible or undesirable. All of these services have grown much more expensive over the years. This phenomenon has been called the cost disease of the personal services.

According to the cost disease of the personal services, service activities that require direct personal contact tend to rise in price relative to other goods and services.

However, some people foresee a world in which some aspects of education and medical care will be delivered long distance over the Internet. We’ll see!

5

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 24

531

Economic Growth: Theory and Policy

Ironically, the villain of the piece is actually the economy’s strong productivity growth. If manufacturing and telecommunications workers had not become more productive over time, their real wages would not have risen. In that case, the real wages of teachers and doctors would not have had to keep pace, so their services would not have grown ever more expensive. Paradoxically, the enormous productivity gains that have blessed our economy and raised our standard of living also account for the problem of rising tuition costs. In the most literal sense, we are the victims of our own success.

GROWTH IN THE DEVELOPING COUNTRIES6 Ernest Hemingway once answered a query of F. Scott Fitzgerald’s by agreeing that, yes, the rich are different—they have more money! Similarly, whereas the main determinants of economic growth—increases in capital, improving technology, and rising workforce skills—are the same in both rich and poor countries, they look quite different in what is often called the Third World. This chapter has focused on growth in the industrialized countries so far. So let us now review the three pillars of productivity growth from the standpoint of the developing nations, using China as the most outstanding recent example of success.

The Three Pillars Revisited Capital We noted earlier that many poor countries are poorly endowed with capital. Given their low incomes, they simply have been unable to accumulate the volumes of business capital (factories, equipment, and the like) and public capital (roads, bridges, airports, and so on) that we take for granted in the industrialized world. In a super-rich country like the United States, $150,000 or more worth of capital stands behind a typical worker, whereas in a poor African country the corresponding figure may be less than $500. No wonder the American worker is vastly more productive than his African counterpart. Accumulating more capital can be exceptionally difficult in the developing world. We noted earlier that rich countries have a choice about how much of their resources to devote to current consumption versus investment for the future, but building capital for the future is a far more difficult task in poor countries, where much of the population may be living on the edge of survival and have little if anything to save for the future. For this reason, it has long been believed that development assistance, sometimes called foreign aid, is a crucial ingredient for growth in the developing world. Indeed, the World Bank was established in 1944 precisely to make low-interest development loans to poor countries. Development assistance has always been controversial. Critics of foreign aid argue that the money is often not well spent. Without honest and well-functioning governments, well-defined property rights, and so on, they argue, the developing countries cannot and will not make good use of the assistance they receive. Supporters of foreign aid counter that the donor countries have been far too stingy. The United States, for example, donates only about 0.1 percent of its GDP each year. Can grants that amount to $60 per person— which is a fairly typical figure for the recipient countries—really be expected to make much difference? Although foreign aid can be critical in certain instances, it has certainly not been the secret to China’s success. Instead, the Chinese have shown a remarkable willingness and ability to save and invest—nearly half of GDP in recent years—despite their relatively low incomes. In addition, China has welcomed foreign direct investment, often by multinational corporations, which it has received in great volume.

6

Development assistance (“foreign aid”) refers to outright grants and low-interest loans to poor countries from both rich countries and multinational institutions like the World Bank. The purpose is to spur economic development. Foreign direct investment is the purchase or construction of real business assets—such as factories, offices, and machinery—in a foreign country. Multinational corporations are corporations, generally large ones, that do business in many countries. Most, but not all, of these corporations have their headquarters in developed countries.

This section can be skipped in shorter courses.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

532

Part 6

The Macroeconomy: Aggregate Supply and Demand

Technology You need only visit a poor country to see that the level of technology is generally far below what we are accustomed to in the West. In principle, this handicap should be easy to overcome. As noted in our discussion of the convergence hypothesis, people in poor countries don’t have to invent anything; they can just adopt technologies that have already been invented in the rich countries. And indeed, a number of formerly poor countries have followed this strategy with great success. South Korea, which was destitute in the mid-1950s, is a prime example. China is doing this today. Indeed, much of the foreign direct investment flowing into China brings Western technology along with it. As we observed earlier, many of the developing nations, especially the poorest ones, seem unable to join this “convergence club.” They may lack the necessary scientific and engineering know-how. They may be short on educated workers. They may be woefully undersupplied with the necessary infrastructure, such as transportation and communications systems. Or they may simply be plagued by incompetent or corrupt governments. Whatever the reasons, they have been unable emulate the technological advances of the West. There are no easy solutions to this problem. One common suggestion is to encourage foreign direct investment by multinational corporations. Industrial giants like Toyota (Japan), IBM (United States), Siemens (Germany), and others bring their advanced technologies with them when they open a factory or office in a developing nation. They can train local workers and improve local transportation and communications networks, but, of course, these companies are foreign, and they come to make a profit—both of which may cause resentment in the local population. For this and other reasons, many developing countries have not always welcomed foreign investment. China, as mentioned above, is a big exception: It has welcomed foreign investment with enthusiasm, especially for the technology it brings, and it has learned avidly and openly from the West. However, multinational companies are rarely tempted to open factories in the poorest developing countries, such as those in sub-Saharan Africa, where skilled labor is in short supply, transportation systems may be inadequate, and governments are often unstable and unreliable. TABLE 4

Education and Training Huge discrepancies exist between the average lev-

Average Educational Attainment in Selected Countries, 2000*

els of educational attainment in the rich and poor countries. Table 4 shows some data on average years of schooling in selected countries, both developed and developing. The differences are dramatic—ranging from a high of 12.3 years in the United States to less than 5 years in India and less than 2 years in the Sudan. In most industrialized countries, universal primary education and high rates of high school completion are already realities. In many poor countries, even completing grade school may be the exception, leaving rudimentary skills such as reading, writing, and basic arithmetic in short supply. In such cases, expanding and improving primary education—including keeping children in school until they reach the age of 12—may be among the most cost-effective growth policies available. The problem is particularly acute in many traditional societies, where women are second-class citizens—or worse. In such countries, the education of girls may be considered unimportant or even inappropriate. China, again, offers a stunning contrast. It is raising the educational attainment of its population rapidly. It is sending legions of students abroad to study science, engineering, business, and economics (among other things). And it is seeking to develop world-class universities of its own.

United States Canada South Korea Japan United Kingdom Italy Mexico India Brazil Sudan

12.3 11.4 10.5 9.7 9.4 7.0 6.7 4.8 4.6 1.9

* For people older than 25 years of age SOURCE: Web site accompanying Robert J. Barro and Jong-Wha Lee, “International Data on Educational Attainment: Updates and Implications,” CID Working paper No. 42, Harvard University, 2000, http://www.cid.harvard .edu/ciddata/ ciddata.html.

Some Special Problems of the Developing Countries Accumulating capital, improving technology, and enhancing workforce skills are common ingredients of growth in rich and poor countries alike. But many Third World countries also must contend with some special handicaps to growth that are mostly absent in the West.

Geography Americans often forget how blessed we are geographically. We live in a temperate climate zone, on a land mass that has literally millions of acres of flat, fertile

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 24

Economic Growth: Theory and Policy

533

land that is ideal for agriculture. The fact that our nation literally stretches “from sea to shining sea” also means we have many fine seaports. Contrast this splendid set of geographical conditions with the situation of the world’s poorest region: sub-Saharan Africa. Many African nations are landlocked, have extremely hot climates, and/or are terribly short on arable land.

Health People in the rich countries rarely think about such debilitating tropical diseases as malaria, but they are rampant in many developing nations, especially in Africa. The AIDS epidemic, of course, is ravaging the continent. Although improvements in public health are important in all countries, they are literally matters of life and death in the poorest nations. And there is a truly vicious cycle here: Poor health is a serious impediment to economic growth, and poverty makes it hard to improve health standards.

Governance Complaining about low-quality or dishonest government is a popular pastime in many Western democracies. Americans do it every day, but most governments in industrialized nations are paragons of virtue and efficiency compared to the governments of some (though certainly not all) developing nations. As we have noted in this chapter, political stability, the rule of law, and respect for property rights are all crucial requirements for economic growth. By the same token, corruption and overregulation of business are obvious deterrents to investment. Lawlessness, tyrannical rule, and war are even more serious impediments. Unfortunately, too many poor nations have been victimized by a succession of corrupt dictators and tragic wars. It need hardly be said that those conditions are not exactly conducive to economic growth.

FROM THE LONG RUN TO THE SHORT RUN Most of this chapter has been devoted to explaining and evaluating the factors underpinning the growth rate of potential GDP. Over long periods of time, the growth rates of actual and potential GDP match up pretty well. But, just like people, economies do not always live up to their potential. As we observed in the previous chapter, GDP in the United States often diverges from potential GDP as a result of macroeconomic fluctuations. Sometimes it is higher; sometimes, as now, it is lower. Indeed, whereas this chapter has studied the factors that determine the rate at which the GDP of a particular country can grow from one year to the next, we have been reminded recently that GDP occasionally shrinks—during periods we call recessions. To study these fluctuations, we must supplement the long-run theory of aggregate supply, which we have just described, with a short-run theory of aggregate demand—a task that begins in the next chapter.

| SUMMARY | 1. More capital, improved workforce quality (which is normally measured by the amount of education and training), and better technology all raise labor productivity and therefore shift the production function upward. They constitute the three main pillars of growth. 2. The growth rate of labor productivity depends on the rate of capital formation, the rate of improvement of workforce quality, and the rate of technical progress. So growth policy concentrates on speeding up these processes. 3. Capital formation can be encouraged by low real interest rates, favorable tax treatment, rapid technical

change, rapid growth of demand, and a climate of political stability that respects property rights. Each of these factors is at least influenced by policy. 4. Policies that increase education and training—the second pillar of growth—can be expected to make a country’s workforce more productive. They range from universal primary education to postgraduate fellowships in science and engineering. 5. Technological advances can be encouraged by more education, by higher rates of investment, and also by direct expenditures—both public and private—on research and development (R&D).

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

534

The Macroeconomy: Aggregate Supply and Demand

Part 6

handicraft activities that are not amenable to labor-saving innovations, they suffer from a cost disease that makes them grow ever more expensive over time.

6. The convergence hypothesis holds that countries with lower productivity levels tend to have higher productivity growth rates, so that poor countries gradually close the gap on rich ones.

11. The same three pillars of economic growth—capital, technology, and education—apply in the developing countries. On all three fronts, conditions are much more difficult there—and improvements are harder to obtain.

7. One major reason to expect convergence is that technological know-how can be transferred quickly from the leading nations to the laggards. Unfortunately, not all countries seem able to benefit from this information transfer.

12. The rich countries try to help with all three pillars by providing development assistance, and multinational corporations sometimes provide capital and better technology via foreign direct investment. But both of these mechanisms are surrounded by controversy.

8. Productivity growth slowed precipitously in the United States around 1973, and economists are still not sure why. 9. Productivity growth in the United States has speeded up again since 1995, largely as a result of the information technology (IT) revolution.

13. Growth in many of the poor countries is also held back by adverse geographical conditions and/or corrupt governments.

10. Because many personal services—such as education, medical care, and police protection—are essentially

| KEY TERMS | capital

522

foreign direct investment

capital formation

522

convergence hypothesis

human capital 521

innovation

520

525

524

research and development (R&D) 526

invention

development assistance

multinational corporations

526

investment

on-the-job training property rights

526

cost disease of the personal services 530 531

531

522 531

| TEST YOURSELF | 1. The following table shows real GDP per hour of work in four imaginary countries in the years 2000 and 2010. By what percentage did labor productivity grow in each country? Is it true that productivity growth was highest where the initial level of productivity was the lowest? For which countries?

Country A Country B Country C Country D

Following Year 21%

5 Years Later 0%

10 Years Later 12%

3. Which of the following prices would you expect to rise rapidly? Why? a. Cable television rates b. Football tickets c. Internet access

Output per Hour 2000 2010 $40 $48 25 35 2 3 0.50 0.60

d. Household cleaning services e. Driving lessons 4. Two countries have the production possibilities frontier (PPF) shown in Figure 3. Consumia chooses point C, whereas Investia chooses point I. Which country will have the higher PPF the following year? Why?

2. Imagine that new inventions in the computer industry affect the growth rate of productivity as follows: Year of Invention 0%

Would such a pattern help explain U.S. productivity performance since the mid-1970s? Why?

20 Years Later 14%

5. Show on a graph how capital formation shifts the production function. Use this graph to show that capital formation increases labor productivity. Explain in words why labor is more productive when the capital stock is larger.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 24

Economic Growth: Theory and Policy

535

| DISCUSSION QUESTIONS | 1. Explain the different objectives of (long-run) growth policy versus (short-run) stabilization policy. 2. Explain why economic growth might be higher in a country with well-established property rights and a stable political system compared with a country where property rights are uncertain and the government is unstable. 3. Chapter 23 pointed out that, because faster capital formation comes at a cost (reduced current consumption), it is possible for a country to invest too much. Suppose the government of some country decides that its businesses are investing too much. What steps might it take to slow the pace of capital formation?

4. Explain why the best educational policies to promote faster growth might be different in the following countries. a. Mozambique b. Brazil c. France 5. Comment on the following: “Sharp changes in the volume of investment in the United States help explain both the productivity slowdown in 1973 and the productivity speed-up in 1995.” 6. Discuss some of the pros and cons of increasing development assistance, both from the point of view of the donor country and the point of view of the recipient country.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Aggregate Demand and the Powerful Consumer Men are disposed, as a rule and on the average, to increase their consumption as their income increases, but not by as much as the increase in their income. JOHN M AY NARD K EYN E S

T

he last chapter focused on the determinants of potential GDP—the economy’s capacity to produce. We turn our attention now to the factors determining actual GDP—how much of that potential is actually utilized. Will the economy be pressing against its capacity, and therefore perhaps also having trouble with inflation? Or will there be a great deal of unused capacity, and therefore high unemployment? The theory that economists use to answer such questions is based on the two concepts we first introduced in Chapter 22: aggregate demand and supply. The last chapter examined the long-run determinants of aggregate supply, a topic to which we will return in Chapter 27. In this chapter and the next, we will construct a simplified model of aggregate demand and learn the origins of the aggregate demand curve. Although aggregate supply rules the roost in the long run, Chapter 22’s whirlwind tour of U.S. economic history suggested that the strength of aggregate demand holds the key to the economy’s condition in the short run. When aggregate demand grows briskly, the economy booms, as in the late 1990s. When aggregate demand is weak, the economy stagnates, as in the late 2000s. The model we develop to understand aggregate demand in this chapter and the next will teach us much about this process. But it is too simple to deal with policy issues effectively, because the government and the financial system are largely ignored. We remedy these omissions in Part 7, where we give government spending, taxation, and interest rates appropriately prominent roles. The influence of the exchange rate between the U.S. dollar and foreign currencies is then considered in Part 8.

C O N T E N T S ISSUE: DEMAND MANAGEMENT AND THE ORNERY CONSUMER

AGGREGATE DEMAND, DOMESTIC PRODUCT, AND NATIONAL INCOME THE CIRCULAR FLOW OF SPENDING, PRODUCTION, AND INCOME CONSUMER SPENDING AND INCOME: THE IMPORTANT RELATIONSHIP

THE DETERMINANTS OF NET EXPORTS

THE CONSUMPTION FUNCTION AND THE MARGINAL PROPENSITY TO CONSUME

National Incomes Relative Prices and Exchange Rates

FACTORS THAT SHIFT THE CONSUMPTION FUNCTION

HOW PREDICTABLE IS AGGREGATE DEMAND?

ISSUE REVISITED: WHY THE TAX REBATES FAILED IN 1975 AND 2001

| APPENDIX | National Income Accounting

THE EXTREME VARIABILITY OF INVESTMENT

Defining GDP: Exceptions to the Rules GDP as the Sum of Final Goods and Services GDP as the Sum of All Factor Payments GDP as the Sum of Values Added

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

538

Part 6

The Macroeconomy: Aggregate Supply and Demand

ISSUE:

DEMAND MANAGEMENT AND THE ORNERY CONSUMER

In Chapter 22, we suggested that the government sometimes wants to shift the aggregate demand curve. It can do so a number of ways. One direct approach is to alter its own spending, spending freely when private demand is weak and tightening the budget when private demand is strong. Alternatively, the government can take a more indirect route by using taxes and other policy tools to influence private spending decisions. Because consumer expenditures constitute more than two-thirds of gross domestic product, the consumer presents the most tempting target. A case in point arose after the 2000 election, when the long boom of the 1990s ended abruptly and economic growth in the United States slowed to a crawl. President George W. Bush decided that consumer spending needed a boost, and Congress passed a multiyear tax cut in 2001. One provision of the tax cut gave taxpayers an advance rebate on their 2001 taxes. Checks ranging as high as $600 went out starting in July 2001. There should be no mystery about how changes in personal taxes are expected to affect consumer spending. Any reduction in personal taxes leaves consumers with more after-tax income to spend; any tax increase leaves them with less. The linkage from taxes to spendable income to consumer spending seems direct and unmistakable, and, in a certain sense, it is. Yet the congressional debate over the tax bill sent legislators and journalists scurrying to the scholarly evidence on a similar episode 26 years earlier. In the spring of 1975, as the U.S. economy hit a recessionary bottom, Congress enacted a tax rebate to spur consumer spending. That time consumers did not follow the wishes of the president and Congress. They saved a substantial share of their tax cuts, rather than spending them. As a result, the economy did not receive the expected boost. Perhaps the legislators should have taken the 1975 episode to heart. Early estimates of the effects of the 2001 rebates suggested that consumers spent relatively little of the money they received. Thus, in a sense, history repeated itself. But why? Why did these two temporary tax cuts seem to have so little effect? This chapter attempts to provide some answers. Before getting involved in such complicated issues, we must build some vocabulary and learn some basic concepts.

AGGREGATE DEMAND, DOMESTIC PRODUCT, AND NATIONAL INCOME First, some vocabulary. We have already introduced the concept of gross domestic product as the standard measure of the economy’s total output.1 For the most part, firms in a market economy produce goods only if they think they Aggregate demand is the can sell them. Aggregate demand is the total amount that all consumers, business firms, total amount that all government agencies, and foreigners spend on U.S. final goods and services. The consumers, business firms, downward-sloping aggregate demand curve of Chapter 22 alerted us to the fact that government agencies, and aggregate demand is a schedule, not a fixed number—the actual numerical value of aggregate foreigners spend on final demand depends on the price level. Several reasons for this dependence will emerge in goods and services. coming chapters. Consumer expenditure (C) The level of aggregate demand also depends on a variety of other factors—such as is the total amount spent by consumer incomes, various government policies, and events in foreign countries. To consumers on newly understand the nature of aggregate demand, it is best to break it up into its major compoproduced goods and services nents, as we do now. (excluding purchases of new Consumer expenditure (consumption for short) is simply the total value of all conhomes, which are considered sumer goods and services demanded. Because consumer spending constitutes more than investment goods).

1

See Chapter 22, pages 471–475.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Aggregate Demand and the Powerful Consumer

539

two-thirds of total spending, it is the main focus of this chapter. We represent it by the letter C. Investment spending, represented by the letter I, was discussed extensively in the last chapter. It is the amount that firms spend on factories, machinery, software, and the like, plus the amount that families spend on new houses. Notice that this usage of the word investment differs from common parlance. Most people speak of investing in the stock market or in a bank account, but that kind of investment merely swaps one form of financial asset (such as money) for another form (such as a share of stock). When economists speak of investment, they mean instead the purchase of some new physical asset, such as a drill press, a computer, or a house. The distinction is important here because only investments by the economists’ definition constitute direct additions to the demand for newly produced goods. The third major component of aggregate demand, government purchases of goods and services, includes items such as paper, computers, airplanes, ships, and labor bought by all levels of government. We use the symbol G for this variable. The final component of aggregate demand, net exports, is simply defined as U.S. exports minus U.S. imports. The reasoning here is simple. Part of the demand for American goods and services originates beyond our borders—as when foreigners buy our wheat, software, and banking services. So to obtain total demand for U.S. products, these goods and services must be added to U.S. domestic demand. Similarly, some items included in C and I are made abroad. Think, for example, of beer from Germany, cars from Japan, and shirts from Malaysia. These must be subtracted from the total amount demanded by U.S. consumers if we want to measure total spending on U.S. products. The addition of exports, X, and the subtraction of imports, IM, leads to the following shorthand definition of aggregate demand:

Investment spending (I) is the sum of the expenditures of business firms on new plant and equipment and households on new homes. Financial “investments” are not included, nor are resales of existing physical assets.

Aggregate demand is the sum of C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM).

The last concept we need for our vocabulary is a way to measure the total income of all individuals in the economy. It comes in two versions: one for before-tax incomes, called national income, and one for after-tax incomes, called disposable income.2 The term disposable income, which we will abbreviate DI, is meant to be descriptive—it tells us how much consumers actually have available to spend or to save. For that reason, it will play a prominent role in this chapter and in subsequent discussions.

Government purchases (G) refer to the goods (such as airplanes and paper clips) and services (such as school teaching and police protection) purchased by all levels of government. Net exports, or X – IM, is the difference between exports (X) and imports (IM). It indicates the difference between what we sell to foreigners and what we buy from them.

SOURCE: From The Wall Street Journal. Permission, Cartoon Features Syndicate

Chapter 25

“When I refer to it as disposable income, don’t get the wrong idea.”

THE CIRCULAR FLOW OF SPENDING, PRODUCTION, AND INCOME Enough definitions. How do these three concepts—domestic product, total expenditure, and national income—interact in a market economy? We can answer this best with a rather elaborate diagram (Figure 1). For obvious reasons, Figure 1 is called a circular flow diagram. It depicts a large tube in which an imaginary fluid circulates in the clockwise direction. At several points along the way, some of the fluid leaks out or additional fluid is injected into the tube. To examine this system, start on the far left. At point 1 on the circle, we find consumers. Disposable income (DI) flows into their pockets, and two things flow out: consumption (C), which stays in the circular flow, and saving (S), which “leaks out.” This outflow depicts the fact that consumers normally spend less than they earn and save the balance. The “leakage” to saving, of course, does not disappear; it flows into the financial system via banks, mutual funds, and so on. We defer consideration of what happens inside the financial system to Chapters 29 and 30.

2

More detailed information on these and other concepts is provided in the appendix to this chapter.

National income is the sum of the incomes that all individuals in the economy earn in the forms of wages, interest, rents, and profits. It excludes government transfer payments and is calculated before any deductions are taken for income taxes. Disposable income (DI) is the sum of the incomes of all individuals in the economy after all taxes have been deducted and all transfer payments have been added.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

The Macroeconomy: Aggregate Supply and Demand

F I GURE 1

Expenditures t

(C)

se

(G

C

)

3

) (IM ts (X) r o s Impxport E

Pu

S)

rc

Co

s

G

Inv

es

2

l+

ns

ion

+

( ing Sav

um

pt

Rest of the World

C+ l

(I)

en

Financial System

tm

The Circular Flow of Expenditures and Income

ha

Part 6

Investors

nt

540

Gov

Consumers

I + G + (X – IM)

er n

C+

me

4

1

Government Di s

sa

Taxes rs Tr an sf e

po bl e In

c

om

e

(D

I)

5

Firms (produce the domestic product)

6 Y) Gross me ( o c n I National

Income

The upper loop of the circular flow represents expenditures, and as we move clockwise to point 2, we encounter the first “injection” into the flow: investment spending (I). The diagram shows this injection as coming from “investors”—a group that includes both business firms and home buyers.3 As the circular flow moves past point 2, it is bigger than it was before: Total spending has increased from C to C 1 I. At point 3, there is yet another injection. The government adds its demand for goods and services (G) to those of consumers and investors (C 1 I). Now aggregate demand has grown to C 1 I 1 G. The next leakage and injection come at point 4. Here we see export spending entering the circular flow from abroad and import spending leaking out. The net effect of these two forces may increase or decrease the circular flow, depending on whether net exports are positive or negative. (In the United States today, they are strongly negative.) In either case, by the time we pass point 4, we have accumulated the full amount of aggregate demand, C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM). The circular flow diagram shows this aggregate demand for goods and services arriving at the business firms, which are located at point 5. Responding to this demand, firms produce the domestic product. As the circular flow emerges from the firms, however, we rename it gross national income. Why? The reason is that, except for some complications explained in the appendix, at the end of this chapter, National income and domestic product must be equal.

Why is this so? When a firm produces and sells $100 worth of output, it pays most of the proceeds to its workers, to people who have lent it money, and to the landlord who owns the property on which the plant is located. All of these payments represent income to some individuals. But what about the rest? Suppose, for example, that the firm pays wages, interest, and rent totaling $90 million and sells its output for $100 million. What happens to the remaining $10 million? The firm’s owners receive it as profits. Because these owners are citizens of the country, their incomes also count in national income.4

You are reminded that expenditure on housing, which is where the Great Recession started, is part of I, not part of C. 4 Some of the income paid out by American companies goes to noncitizens. Similarly, some Americans earn income from foreign firms. This complication is discussed in the appendix to this chapter. 3

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 25

541

Aggregate Demand and the Powerful Consumer

Thus, when we add up all the wages, interest, rents, and profits in the economy to obtain the national income, we must arrive at the value of output. The lower loop of the circular flow diagram shows national income leaving firms and heading for consumers. But some of the flow takes a detour along the way. At point 6, the government siphons off a portion of the national income in the form of taxes. But it also adds back government transfer payments, such as unemployment compensation and Social Security benefits, which government agencies give to certain individuals as outright grants rather than as payments for goods or services rendered. By subtracting taxes from gross domestic product (GDP) and adding transfer payments, we obtain disposable income:5 DI 5 GDP 2 Taxes 1 Transfer payments 5 GDP 2 (Taxes 2 Transfers) 5Y2T

Transfer payments are sums of money that the government gives certain individuals as outright grants rather than as payments for services rendered to employers. Some common examples are Social Security and unemployment benefits.

where Y represents GDP and T represents taxes net of transfers or simply net taxes. Disposable income flows unimpeded to consumers at point 1, and the cycle repeats. Figure 1 raises several complicated questions, which we pose now but will not try to answer until subsequent chapters: • Does the flow of spending and income grow larger or smaller as we move clockwise around the circle? Why? • Is the output that firms produce at point 5 (the GDP) equal to aggregate demand? If so, what makes these two quantities equal? If not, what happens? The next chapter provides the answers to these two questions. • Do the government’s accounts balance, so that what flows in at point 6 (net taxes) is equal to what flows out at point 3 (government purchases)? What happens if they do not balance? This important question is first addressed in Chapter 28 and then recurs many times, especially in Chapter 32, which discusses budget deficits and surpluses in detail. • Is our international trade balanced, so that exports equal imports at point 4? More generally, what factors determine net exports, and what consequences arise from trade deficits or surpluses? We take up these questions in the next two chapters but deal with them more fully in Part 8. However, we cannot dig very deeply into any of these issues until we first understand what goes on at point 1, where consumers make decisions. So we turn next to the determinants of consumer spending.

CONSUMER SPENDING AND INCOME: THE IMPORTANT RELATIONSHIP Recall that we started the chapter with a puzzle: Why did consumers respond so weakly to tax rebates in 1975 and 2001? An economist interested in predicting how consumer spending will respond to a change in income taxes must first ask how consumption (C) relates to disposable income (DI), because a tax increase decreases after-tax income and a tax reduction increases it. So this section examines what we know about how consumer spending is influenced by changes in disposable income. Figure 2 depicts the historical paths of C and DI for the United States since 1929. The association is extremely close, suggesting that consumption will rise whenever disposable income rises and fall whenever income falls. The vertical distance between the two lines represents personal saving: disposable income minus consumption.

5

This definition omits a few minor details, which are explained in the appendix at the end of the chapter.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

542

Part 6

The Macroeconomy: Aggregate Supply and Demand

F I GURE 2

10,000

Consumer Spending and Disposable Income

9,500 9,000 8,500 8,000 7,500 7,000 Billions of 2005 Dollars

6,500 6,000 5,500 5,000 4,500 4,000 Real disposable income

3,500 3,000 2,500 2,000 1,500

World War II

Real consumer spending

The Great Depression

1,000 500 0 1930

A scatter diagram is a graph showing the relationship between two variables (such as consumer spending and disposable income). Each year is represented by a point in the diagram, and the coordinates of each year’s point show the values of the two variables in that year.

1940

1950

1960

1970

1980

1990

2000

2010

Notice how little saving consumers did during the Great Depression of the 1930s (when the two lines run very close together); how much they did during World War II, when many consumer goods were either unavailable or rationed; and how little saving consumers have done lately. Of course, knowing that C will move in the same direction as DI is not enough for policy planners. They need to know how much one variable will go up when the other rises a given amount. Figure 3 presents the same data as in Figure 2, but in a way designed to help answer the “how much” question. Economists call such pictures scatter diagrams, and they are very useful in predicting how one variable (in this case, consumer spending) will change in response to a change in another variable (in this case, disposable income). Each dot in the diagram represents the data on C and DI corresponding to a particular year. For example, the point labeled “1996” shows that real consumer expenditures in 1996 were $6,291 billion (which we read off the vertical axis), whereas real disposable incomes amounted to $6,871 billion (which we read off the horizontal axis). Similarly, each year from 1929 to 2009 is represented by its own dot in Figure 3. To see how such a diagram can assist fiscal policy planners, imagine that you were a member of Congress way back in 1964, contemplating a tax cut. (In fact, Congress did cut taxes that year.) Legislators want to know how much additional consumer spending may be stimulated by tax cuts of various sizes. To assist your imagination, the scatter diagram in Figure 4 removes the points for 1964 through 2009 that appear in Figure 3; after all, these data were unknown in 1964. Years prior to 1947 have also been removed because, as Figure 2 showed, both the Great Depression and wartime rationing disturbed the normal relationship between DI and C. With no more training in economics than you have right now, what would you suggest?

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

543

Aggregate Demand and the Powerful Consumer

Chapter 25

FIGU R E 3 Scatter Diagram of Consumer Spending and Disposable Income

2008 2007 2006 2005 2009 2004 2003 2002 2001 2000 1999 1998 1997 1996

$6,291 Real Consumer Spending

1995 1992 1988 1985 1980 1977 1976 1973 1972 1969 1970 1966 1967

$3,393

1963 1955

1994 1993

1989

1986

1984 1983 1982

1964

1959

1950 1946 1940 1942 1931 1929 $3,838 Real Disposable Income

$6,871

NOTE: Figures are in billions of 2005 dollars.

One rough-and-ready approach is to get a ruler, set it down on Figure 4, and sketch a straight line that comes as close as possible to hitting all the points. That has been done for you in the figure, and you can see that the resulting line comes remarkably close to touching all the points. The line summarizes, in a very rough way, the normal relationship between income and consumption. The two variables certainly appear to be closely related. The slope of the straight line in Figure 4 is very important.6 Specifically, we note that it is Slope 5

Vertical change $180 billion 5 5 0.90 Horizontal change $200 billion

Because the horizontal change involved in the move from A to B represents a rise in disposable income of $200 billion (from $1,500 billion to $1,700 billion), and the corresponding vertical change represents the associated $180 billion rise in consumer spending

6

To review the concept of slope, see Chapter 1’s appendix, pages 15–17.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

544

Part 6

The Macroeconomy: Aggregate Supply and Demand

F I GURE 4 Scatter Diagram of Consumer Spending and Disposable Income, 1947–1963 Real Consumer Spending

1963

B

1540 $180 billion 1360

A $200 billion

1947

0

1500 1700 Real Disposable Income

NOTE: Figures are in billions of 2005 dollars.

(from $1,360 billion to $1,540 billion), the slope of the line indicates how consumer spending responds to changes in disposable income. In this case, we see that each additional $1 of income leads to 90 cents of additional spending. Now let us return to tax policy. First, recall that each dollar of tax cut increases disposable income by exactly $1. Next, apply the finding from Figure 4 that each additional dollar of disposable income increases consumer spending by about 90 cents. The conclusion is that a tax cut of, say, $9 billion—which is about what happened in 1964—would be expected to increase consumer spending by about $9 3 0.9 5 $8.1 billion.

THE CONSUMPTION FUNCTION AND THE MARGINAL PROPENSITY TO CONSUME The consumption function shows the relationship between total consumer expenditures and total disposable income in the economy, holding all other determinants of consumer spending constant. The marginal propensity to consume (MPC) is the ratio of the change in consumption relative to the change in disposable income that produces the change in consumption. On a graph, it appears as the slope of the consumption function.

It has been said that economics is just systematized common sense. So let us now organize and generalize what has been a completely intuitive discussion up to now. One thing we have discovered is the apparently close relationship between consumer spending, C, and disposable income, DI. Economists call this relationship the consumption function. A second fact we have gleaned from these figures is that the slope of the consumption function is quite constant. We infer this constancy from the fact that the straight line drawn in Figure 4 comes so close to touching every point. If the slope of the consumption function had varied widely, we could not have done so well with a single straight line.7 Because of its importance in applications such as the tax cut, economists have given this slope a special name—the marginal propensity to consume, or MPC for short. The MPC tells us how much more consumers will spend if disposable income rises by $1. MPC 5

Change in C Change in DI that produces the change in C

The MPC is best illustrated by an example, and for this purpose we turn away from U.S. data for a moment and look at consumption and income in a hypothetical country whose data come in nice round numbers—which facilitates computation.

Figure 4 is limited to 17 years of data, so try fitting a single straight line to all of the data in Figure 3. You will find that you can do that rather well. 7

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 25

545

Aggregate Demand and the Powerful Consumer

Columns (1) and (2) of Table 1 below show annual consumer expenditure and disposable income, respectively, from 2005 to 2010. These two columns constitute the consumption function, and they are plotted in Figure 5. Column (3) in the table shows the marginal propensity to consume (MPC), which is the slope of the line in Figure 5; it is derived from the first two columns. We can see that, between 2007 and 2008, DI rose by $400 billion (from $4,000 billion to $4,400 billion) while C rose by $300 billion (from $3,300 billion to $3,600 billion). Thus, the MPC was MPC 5

Change in C $300 5 5 0.75 Change in DI $400

As you can easily verify, the MPC between any other pair of years in Table 1 is also 0.75. This relationship explains why the slope of the line in Figure 4 was so crucial in estimating the effect of a tax cut. This slope, which we found there to be 0.90, is simply the MPC for the United States. The MPC tells us how much additional spending will be induced by each dollar change in disposable income. For each $1 of tax cut, economists expect consumption to rise by $1 times the marginal propensity to consume. To estimate the initial effect of a tax cut on consumer spending, economists must first estimate the MPC and then multiply the amount of the tax cut by the estimated MPC.8 Because they never know the true MPC with certainty, their prediction is always subject to some margin of error.

FI GURE 5 A Consumption Function

TABLE 1 Consumption and Income in a Hypothetical Economy

(2) Disposable Income, DI

2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010

$2,700 3,000 3,300 3,600 3,900 4,200

$3,200 3,600 4,000 4,400 4,800 5,200

(3) Marginal Propensity to Consume, MPC 0.75 0.75 0.75 0.75 0.75

Real Consumer Spending, C

Year

(1) Consumption, C

C $4,200 3,900 3,600 $300 3,300 $400

3,000 2,700 0

3,200 3,600 4,000 4,400 4,800 5,200 Real Disposable Income, DI

NOTE: Amounts are in billions of dollars.

FACTORS THAT SHIFT THE CONSUMPTION FUNCTION Unfortunately for policy planners, the consumption function does not always stand still. Recall from Chapter 4 the important distinction between a movement along a demand curve and a shift of the curve, but a demand curve depicts the relationship between quantity demanded and one of its many determinants—price. Thus a change in price causes a movement along the demand curve, but a change in any other factor that influences quantity demanded causes a shift of the entire demand curve. Because factors other than disposable income influence consumer spending, a similar distinction is vital to understanding real-world consumption functions. Look back at the definition of the consumption function in the margin of page 544. A change in disposable income leads to a movement along the consumption function precisely because the consumption function depicts the relationship between C and DI. Such movements, which are what we have been considering so far, are indicated by the brick-colored arrows in Figure 6. 8 The word initial in this sentence is an important one. The next chapter will explain why the effects discussed in this chapter are only the beginning of the story.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

546

Part 6

The Macroeconomy: Aggregate Supply and Demand

Movements along consumption function Real Consumer Spending

C1 C0 C2 A Shifts of consumption function

Real Disposable Income

F I GURE 6 Shifts of the Consumption Function

A money-fixed asset is an asset whose value is a fixed number of dollars.

Consumption also has other determinants, and a change in any of them will shift the entire consumption function— as indicated by the blue arrows in Figure 6. Such shifts account for many of the errors in forecasting consumption. To summarize: Any change in disposable income moves us along a given consumption function. A change in any of the other determinants of consumption shifts the entire consumption schedule (see Figure 6).

Because disposable income is far and away the main determinant of consumer spending, the real-world data in Figure 3 come close to lying along a straight line. However, if you use a ruler to draw such a line, you will find that it misses a number of points badly. These deviations reflect the influence of the “other determinants” just mentioned. Let us see what some of them are.

Wealth One factor affecting spending is consumers’ wealth, which is a source of purchasing power in addition to income. Wealth and income are different things. For example, a wealthy retiree with a huge bank balance may earn little current income when interest rates are low. However, a high-flying investment banker who spends every penny of the high income she earns will not accumulate much wealth. To appreciate the importance of the distinction, think about two recent college graduates, each of whom earns $40,000 per year. If one of them has $100,000 in the bank and the other has no assets at all, who do you think will spend more? Presumably the one with the big bank account. The general point is that current income is not the only source of spendable funds; households can also finance spending by cashing in some of the wealth they have previously accumulated. One important implication of this analysis is that the stock market can exert a major influence on consumer spending. A stock market boom adds to wealth and thus raises the consumption function, as depicted by the shift from C0 to C1 in Figure 6. That is what happened in the late 1990s, when the stock market soared and American consumers went on a spending spree. Correspondingly, a collapse of stock prices, like the one that occurred in 2008–2009, should shift the consumption function down (see the shift from C0 to C2). Using the same logic, falling house prices made consumers less wealthy and therefore less willing to spend in 2007–2009.

The Price Level Stocks and houses are not the only form of wealth. People hold a great deal of wealth in forms that are fixed in money terms. Bank accounts are the most obvious example, but government and corporate bonds also have fixed face values in money terms. The purchasing power of such money-fixed assets obviously declines whenever the price level rises, which means that the asset can buy less. For example, if the price level rises by 10 percent, a $1,000 government bond will buy about 10 percent less than it could when prices were lower. This is no trivial matter. Consumers in the United States hold money-fixed assets worth well over $8 trillion, so that each 1 percent rise in the price level reduces the purchasing power of consumer wealth by more than $80 billion, a tidy sum. This process, of course, operates equally well in reverse, because a decline in the price level increases the purchasing power of money-fixed assets. The Real Interest Rate A higher real rate of interest raises the rewards for saving. For this reason, many people believe it is “obvious” that higher real interest rates encourage saving and therefore discourage spending. Surprisingly, however, statistical studies of this relationship suggest otherwise. With very few exceptions, they show that interest rates have negligible effects on consumption decisions in the United States and other

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 25

Aggregate Demand and the Powerful Consumer

547

P OLICY D E B AT E

Using the Tax Code to Spur Saving

SOURCE: © Elizabeth Simpson/Taxi/Getty Images

Compared to the citizens of virtually every other industrial nation, Americans save very little. Many policy makers consider this lack of saving to be a serious problem, so they have proposed numerous changes in the tax laws to increase incentives to save. In 2001, for example, Congress expanded Individual Retirement Accounts (IRAs), which allow taxpayers to save taxfree. In 2003, the taxation of dividends was reduced. Further tax incentives for saving seem to be proposed every year. All of these tax changes are designed to increase the after-tax return on saving. For example, if you put away money in a bank at a 5 percent rate of interest and your income is taxed at a 30 percent rate, your after-tax rate of return on saving is just 3.5 percent (70 percent of 5 percent). However, if the interest is earned tax-free, as in an IRA,

you get to keep the full 5 percent. Over long periods of time, this seemingly small interest differential compounds to make an enormous difference in returns. For example, $100 invested for 20 years at 3.5 percent interest grows to $199. At 5 percent, it grows to $265. Members of Congress who advocate tax incentives for saving argue that lower tax rates will therefore induce Americans to save more. This idea seems reasonable and has many supporters. Unfortunately, the evidence runs squarely against it. Economists have conducted many studies of the effect of higher rates of return on saving. With very few exceptions, they detect little or no impact. Although the evidence fails to support the “commonsense” solution to the undersaving problem, the debate goes on. Many people, it seems, refuse to believe the evidence.

countries. Hence, in developing our model of the economy, we will assume that changes in real interest rates do not shift the consumption function. (See the box “Using the Tax Code to Spur Saving.”)

Future Income Expectations It is hardly earth-shattering to suggest that consumers’ expectations about their future incomes should affect how much they spend today. This final determinant of consumer spending holds the key to resolving the puzzle posed at the beginning of the chapter: Why did tax policy designed to boost consumer spending apparently fail in 1975 and succeed only modestly in 2001?

ISSUE REVISITED:

WHY THE TAX REBATES FAILED IN 1975 AND 2001

To understand how expectations of future incomes affect current consumer expenditures, consider the abbreviated life histories of three consumers given in Table 2. (The reason for giving our three imaginary individuals such odd names will be apparent shortly.) The consumer named “Constant” earned $100 in each of the years considered in the table. The consumer named “Temporary” earned $100 in three of the four years but had a good year in 1975. The consumer named “Permanent” enjoyed a perTABLE 2 manent increase in income in 1975 and was therefore Incomes of Three Consumers clearly the richest. Now let us use our common sense to figure out how Incomes in Each Year much each of these consumers might have spent in 1975. Consumer 1974 1975 1976 1977 Total Income Temporary and Permanent had the same income that year. Constant $100 $100 $100 $100 $400 Do you think they spent the same amount? Not if they Temporary 100 120 100 100 420 had some ability to foresee their future incomes, because Permanent 100 120 120 120 460 Permanent was richer in the long run.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

548

Part 6

The Macroeconomy: Aggregate Supply and Demand

Now compare Constant and Temporary. Temporary had 20 percent higher income in 1975 ($120 versus $100), but only 5 percent more over the entire four-year period ($420 versus $400). Do you think his spending in 1975 was closer to 20 percent above Constant’s or closer to 5 percent above it? Most people guess the latter. The point of this example is that consumers decide reasonably on their current consumption spending by looking at their long-run income prospects. This should come as no surprise to a college student. You are probably spending more than you earn this year, but that does not make you a foolish spendthrift. On the contrary, you know that your college education will likely give you a much higher income in the future, and you are spending with that in mind. To relate this example to the failure of the 1975 income tax cut, now imagine that the three rows in Table 2 represent the entire economy under three different government policies. Recall that 1975 was the year of the temporary tax cut. The first row (Constant) shows the unchanged path of disposable income in the absence of a tax cut. The second (Temporary) shows an increase in disposable income attributable to a tax cut for one year only. The bottom row (Permanent) shows a policy that increases DI in every future year by cutting taxes permanently in 1975. Which of the two lower rows do you imagine would have generated more consumer spending in 1975? The bottom row (Permanent), of course. What we have concluded, then, is this: Permanent cuts in income taxes cause greater increases in consumer spending than do temporary cuts of equal magnitude.

The application of this analysis to the 1975 and 2001 tax rebates is immediate. The 1975 tax cut was advertised as a one-time increase in after-tax income, like that experienced by Temporary in Table 2. No future income was affected, so consumers did not increase their spending as much as government officials had hoped. Ironically, the 2001 tax rebate checks actually represented the first installment of a projected permanent tax reduction. However, they were so widely advertised as a one-time event that most people receiving the checks probably thought they were temporary. We have, then, what appears to be a general principle, backed up by both historical evidence and common sense. Permanent changes in income taxes have more significant effects on consumer spending than do temporary ones. This conclusion may seem obvious, but it is not a lesson you would have learned from an introductory textbook prior to 1975. It is one we learned the hard way, through bitter experience.

THE EXTREME VARIABILITY OF INVESTMENT Next, we turn to the most volatile component of aggregate demand: investment spending.9 Although Figure 2 showed that consumer spending follows movements in disposable income quite closely, investment spending swings from high to low levels with astonishing speed. For example, when real GDP in the United States slowed abruptly from a 0.4 percent growth rate in 2008 to a minus 2.4 percent rate in 2009, a drop of about 2.8 percentage points, the growth rate of real investment spending dropped from minus 7.3 percent to minus 23.1 percent, a swing of over 30 percentage points. What accounts for such dramatic changes in investment spending? Several factors that influence how much businesses want to invest were discussed in the previous chapter, including interest rates, tax provisions, technical change, and the

9 We repeat the warning given earlier about the meaning of the word investment. It includes spending by businesses and individuals on newly produced factories, machinery, and houses, but it excludes sales of used industrial plants, equipment, and homes as well as purely financial transactions, such as the purchases of stocks and bonds.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 25

Aggregate Demand and the Powerful Consumer

strength of the economy. Sometimes these determinants change abruptly, leading to dramatic variations in investment. Perhaps the most important factor accounting for the volatility of investment spending was not discussed much in Chapter 24: the state of business confidence, which in turn depends on expectations about the future. Although confidence is tricky to measure, it does seem obvious that businesses will build more factories and purchase more new machines when they are optimistic. Correspondingly, their investment plans will be very cautious if the economic outlook appears bleak. Keynes pointed out that psychological perceptions such as these are subject to abrupt shifts, so that fluctuations in investment can be a major cause of instability in aggregate demand. Unfortunately, neither economists nor, for that matter, psychologists have many good ideas about how to measure—much less control—business confidence. So economists usually focus on several more objective determinants of investment that are easier to quantify and even influence—factors such as interest rates and tax provisions.

THE DETERMINANTS OF NET EXPORTS Another highly variable source of demand for U.S. products is foreign purchases of U.S. goods—our exports. As we observed earlier in this chapter, we obtain the net contribution of foreigners to U.S. aggregate demand by subtracting imports, which is the portion of domestic demand that is satisfied by foreign producers, from our exports to get net exports. What determines net exports?

National Incomes Although both exports and imports depend on many factors, the predominant one is income levels in different countries. When American consumers and firms spend more on consumption and investment, some of this new spending goes toward the purchase of foreign goods. Therefore: Our imports rise when our GDP rises and fall when our GDP falls.

Similarly, because our exports are the imports of other countries, our exports depend on their GDPs, not on our own. Thus: Our exports are relatively insensitive to our own GDP, but are quite sensitive to the GDPs of other countries.

Putting these two ideas together leads to a clear implication: When our economy grows faster than the economies of our trading partners, our net exports tend to shrink. Conversely, when foreign economies grow faster than ours, our net exports tend to rise. Recent events illustrate these points dramatically. As the U.S. economy grew rapidly from 2003 to 2006, our net exports fell from –$604 billion to –$729 billion. But then, as our economy first slowed and then plunged into a deep recession, U.S. net exports rose dramatically from –$729 billion in 2006 to –$354 billion in 2009. (Remember, –354 is a larger number than –729.)

Relative Prices and Exchange Rates Although GDP levels here and abroad are important influences on a country’s net exports, they are not the only relevant factors. International prices matter, too. To make things concrete, let’s focus on trade between the United States and Japan. Suppose American prices rise while Japanese prices fall, making U.S. goods more expensive relative to Japanese goods. If American consumers react to these new relative prices by buying more Japanese goods, U.S. imports rise. If Japanese consumers react to the same relative price changes by buying fewer American products, U.S. exports fall. Both reactions reduce America’s net exports.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

549

550

Part 6

The Macroeconomy: Aggregate Supply and Demand

Naturally, a decline in American prices (or a rise in Japanese prices) does precisely the opposite. Thus: A rise in the prices of a country’s goods will lead to a reduction in that country’s net exports. Analogously, a decline in the prices of a country’s goods will raise that country’s net exports. Similarly, price increases abroad raise the home country’s net exports, whereas price decreases abroad have the opposite effect.

This simple idea holds the key to understanding how exchange rates among the world’s currencies influence exports and imports—an important topic that we will consider in depth in Chapters 35 and 36. The reason is that exchange rates translate foreign prices into terms that are familiar to home country customers—their own currencies. Consider, for example, Americans interested in buying Japanese cars that cost ¥3,000,000. If it takes ¥100 to buy a dollar, these cars cost American buyers $30,000. But if the dollar is worth ¥150, those same cars cost Americans just $20,000, and consumers in the United States are likely to buy more of them. These sorts of responses help explain why American automakers lost market share to Japanese imports when the dollar rose against the yen in the late 1990s. They also explain why, today, so many U.S. manufacturers want to see the value of the Chinese yuan rise.

HOW PREDICTABLE IS AGGREGATE DEMAND? We have now learned enough to see why economists often have difficulty predicting aggregate demand. Consider the four main components, starting with consumer spending. Because wealth affects consumption, forecasts of spending can be thrown off by unexpected movements of the stock market, house prices, or by poor forecasts of future prices. It may also be difficult to anticipate how taxpayers will view changes in the income tax law. If the government says that a tax cut is permanent (as, for example, in 1964), will consumers take the government at its word and increase their spending accordingly? Perhaps not, if the government has a history of raising taxes after promising to keep them low. Similarly, when (as in 1975) the government explicitly announces that a tax cut is temporary, will consumers always believe the announcement? Or might they greet it with a hefty dose of skepticism? Such a reaction is quite possible if there is a history of “temporary” tax changes that stayed on the books indefinitely. Swings in investment spending are even more difficult to predict, partly because they are tied so closely to business confidence and expectations. Developments abroad also often lead to surprises in the net export account. Even the final component of aggregate demand, government purchases (G), is subject to the vagaries of politics and to sudden military and national security events such as 9/11 and the wars in Iraq and Afghanistan. We could say much more about the determinants of aggregate demand, but it is best to leave the rest to more advanced courses. For we are now ready to apply our knowledge of aggregate demand to the construction of the first model of the economy. Although it is true that income determines consumption, the consumption function in turn helps to determine the level of income. If that sounds like circular reasoning, read the next chapter!

| SUMMARY | 1. Aggregate demand is the total volume of goods and services purchased by consumers, businesses, government units, and foreigners. It can be expressed as the sum C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM), where C is consumer spending, I is investment spending, G is government purchases, and X 2 IM is net exports.

2. Aggregate demand is a schedule: The aggregate quantity demanded depends on (among other things) the price level. But, for any given price level, aggregate demand is a number. 3. Economists reserve the term investment to refer to purchases of newly produced factories, machinery, software, and houses.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

551

Aggregate Demand and the Powerful Consumer

Chapter 25

4. Gross domestic product is the total volume of final goods and services produced in the country.

total consumer wealth, the price level, and expected future incomes.

5. National income is the sum of the before-tax wages, interest, rents, and profits earned by all individuals in the economy. By necessity, it must be approximately equal to domestic product.

10. Because consumers hold so many money-fixed assets, they lose purchasing power when prices rise, which leads them to reduce their spending.

6. Disposable income is the sum of the incomes of all individuals in the economy after taxes and transfers. It is the chief determinant of consumer expenditures.

11. The government often tries to manipulate aggregate demand by influencing private consumption decisions, usually through changes in the personal income tax. But this policy did not work well in 1975 or 2001.

7. All of these concepts, and others, can be depicted in a circular flow diagram that shows expenditures on all four sources flowing into business firms and national income flowing out.

12. Future income prospects help explain why. The 1975 tax cut was temporary and therefore left future incomes unaffected. The 2001 tax cut was also advertised as a one-time event.

8. The close relationship between consumer spending (C) and disposable income (DI) is called the consumption function. Its slope, which is used to predict the change in consumption that will be caused by a change in income taxes, is called the marginal propensity to consume (MPC).

13. Investment is the most volatile component of aggregate demand, largely because it is closely tied to confidence and expectations. 14. Policy makers cannot influence confidence in any reliable way, so policies designed to spur investment focus on more objective, although possibly less important, determinants of investment—such as interest rates and taxes.

9. Changes in disposable income move us along a given consumption function. Changes in any of the other variables that affect C shift the entire consumption function. Among the most important of these other variables are

15. Net exports depend on GDPs and relative prices both domestically and abroad.

| KEY TERMS | investment spending (I) 539

net exports (X 2 IM) 539 permanent tax change

consumer expenditure (C) 538

marginal propensity to consume (MPC) 544

consumption function

money-fixed assets

shifts of consumption function 546

aggregate demand

538

circular flow diagram

539 544

C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM) 539 disposable income (DI) 539 government purchases (G)

539

scatter diagram 542

546

movement along the consumption function 545 national income

548

temporary tax change

539

548

transfer payments 541

| TEST YOURSELF | 1. What are the four main components of aggregate demand? Which is the largest? Which is the smallest? 2. Which of the following acts constitute investment according to the economist’s definition of that term? a. Pfizer builds a new factory in the United States to manufacture pharmaceuticals. b. You buy 100 shares of Pfizer stock. c. A small drugmaker goes bankrupt, and Pfizer purchases its factory and equipment. d. Your family buys a newly constructed home from a developer. e. Your family buys an older home from another family. (Hint: Are any new products demanded by this action?)

3. On a piece of graph paper, construct a consumption function from the data given here and determine the MPC.

Year

Consumer Spending

Disposable Income

2003 2004 2005 2006 2007

$1,200 1,440 1,680 1,920 2,160

$1,500 1,800 2,100 2,400 2,700

4. In which direction will the consumption function shift if the price level rises? Show this on your graph from the previous question.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

552

Part 6

The Macroeconomy: Aggregate Supply and Demand

| DISCUSSION QUESTIONS | 1. Explain the difference between investment as the term is used by most people and investment as defined by an economist.

6. Explain why permanent tax cuts are likely to lead to bigger increases in consumer spending than temporary tax cuts do.

2. What would the circular flow diagram (Figure 1) look like in an economy with no government? Draw one for yourself.

7. In 2001 and again in 2003, Congress enacted changes in the tax law designed to promote saving. If such saving incentives had been successful, how would the consumption function have shifted?

3. The marginal propensity to consume (MPC) for the United States as a whole is roughly 0.90. Explain in words what this means. What is your personal MPC at this stage in your life? How might that change by the time you are your parents’ age? 4. Look at the scatter diagram in Figure 3. What does it tell you about what was going on in this country in the years 1942 to 1945? 5. What is a consumption function, and why is it a useful device for government economists planning a tax cut?

8. (More difficult) Between 2007 and 2008, real disposable income (in 2005 dollars) barely increased at all, owing to a recession. (It rose from $9,861 billion to $9,913 billion.) Use the data on real consumption expenditures given on the inside back cover of this book to compare the change in C to this $52 billion change in DI. Explain why dividing the two does not give a good estimate of the marginal propensity to consume.

| APPENDIX | National Income Accounting The type of macroeconomic analysis presented in this book dates from the publication of John Maynard Keynes’s The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money in 1936. At that time, there was really no way to test Keynes’s theories because the necessary data did not exist. It took some years for the theoretical notions used by Keynes to find concrete expression in realworld data. The system of measurement devised for collecting and expressing macroeconomic data is called national income accounting.

The development of this system of accounts ranks as a great achievement in applied economics, perhaps as important in its own right as was Keynes’s theoretical work. Without it, the practical value of Keynesian analysis would be severely limited. Economists spent long hours wrestling with the many difficult conceptual questions that arose as they translated the theory into numbers. Along the way, some more or less arbitrary decisions and conventions had to be made. You may not agree with all of them, but the accounting framework that was devised, though imperfect, is eminently serviceable.

DEFINING GDP: EXCEPTIONS TO THE RULES We first encountered the concept of gross domestic product (GDP) in Chapter 22. Gross domestic product (GDP) is the sum of the money values of all final goods and services produced during a specified period of time, usually one year.

However, the definition of GDP has certain exceptions that we have not yet noted. First, the treatment of government output involves a minor departure from the principle of using market prices. Unlike private products, the “outputs” of government offices are not sold; indeed, it is sometimes even difficult to define what those outputs are. Lacking prices for outputs, national income accountants fall back on the only prices they have: prices for the inputs from which the outputs are produced. Thus: Government outputs are valued at the cost of the inputs needed to produce them.

This means, for example, that if a clerk at the Department of Motor Vehicles who earns $20 per hour spends one-half hour torturing you with explanations of why you cannot get a driver’s license, that particular government “service” increases GDP by $10. Second, some goods that are produced but not sold during the year are nonetheless counted in that year’s GDP. Specifically, goods that firms add to their inventories count in the GDP even though they do not pass through markets. National income statisticians treat inventories as if they were “bought” by the firms that produced them, even though these “purchases” do not actually take place.

Finally, the treatment of investment goods can be thought of as running slightly counter to the rule that GDP includes only final goods. In a broad sense, factories, generators, machine tools, and the like might be considered intermediate goods. After all, their owners want them only for use in producing other goods,

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 25

not for any innate value that they possess. But this classification would present a real problem. Because factories and machines normally are never sold to consumers, when would we count them in GDP? National income statisticians avoid this problem by defining investment goods as final products demanded by the firms that buy them. Now that we have a more complete definition of what the GDP is, let us turn to the problem of actually measuring it. National income accountants have devised three ways to perform this task, and we consider each in turn.

GDP AS THE SUM OF FINAL GOODS AND SERVICES The first way to measure GDP is the most natural, because it follows so directly from the circular flow diagram (Figure 1). It also turns out to be the most useful definition for macroeconomic analysis. We simply add up the final demands of all consumers, business firms, government, and foreigners. Using the symbols Y, C, I, G, and (X 2 IM) as we did in the chapter, we have:

553

Aggregate Demand and the Powerful Consumer

product that government uses up for its own purposes—to pay for armies, bureaucrats, paper, and ink—whereas transfer payments merely shuffle purchasing power from one group of citizens to another. Except for the administrators needed to run these programs, real economic resources are not used up in this process. In adding up the nation’s total output as the sum of C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM), we sum the shares of GDP that are used up by consumers, investors, government, and foreigners, respectively. Because transfer payments merely give someone the capability to spend on C, it is logical to exclude transfers from our definition of G, including in C only the portion of these transfer payments that consumers spend. If we included transfers in G, the same spending would get counted twice: once in G and then again in C. The final component of GDP is net exports, which are simply exports of goods and services minus imports of goods and services. Table 3 shows GDP for 2008, in both nominal and real terms, computed as the sum of C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM). Note that the numbers for net exports in the table are actually negative. We will say much more about America’s trade deficit in Part 8.

Y 5 C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM)

The I that appears in the actual U.S. national accounts is called gross private domestic investment. We will explain the word gross presently. Private indicates that government investment is considered part of G, and domestic means that, say, machinery sold by American firms to foreign companies is included in exports rather than in I (investment). Gross private domestic investment (I) includes business investment in plant, equipment, and software; residential construction; and inventory investment.

We repeat again that only these three things are investment in national income accounting terminology. As defined in the national income accounts, investment includes only newly produced capital goods, such as machinery, factories, and new homes. It does not include exchanges of existing assets.

The symbol G, for government purchases, represents the volume of current goods and services purchased by all levels of government. Thus, all government payments to its employees are counted in G, as are all of its purchases of goods. Few citizens realize, however, that the federal government spends most of its money, not for purchases of goods and services, but rather on transfer payments—literally, giving away money—either to individuals or to other levels of government. The importance of this conceptual distinction lies in the fact that G represents the part of the national

TABLE 3 Gross Domestic Product in 2008 as the Sum of Final Demands

Item Personal consumption expenditures (C) Gross private domestic investment (I) Government purchases of goods and services (G) Net exports (X 2 IM) Exports (X) Imports (IM) Gross domestic product (Y)

Nominal Amount*

Real Amount†

$10,130

$9,291

2,136

1,989

2,883

2,518

2708 1,831 2,539 14,441

2494 1,629 2,124 13,312

*In billions of current dollars. †In billions of 2005 dollars. SOURCE: U.S. Department of Commerce. Totals do not add up precisely due to rounding and method of deflating.

GDP AS THE SUM OF ALL FACTOR PAYMENTS We can count up the GDP another way: by adding up all incomes in the economy. Let’s see how this method handles some typical transactions. Suppose General Electric builds a generator and sells it to General Motors for $1 million. The first method of calculating GDP simply counts the $1 million as part of I. The second method asks: What incomes resulted from

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

554

Part 6

The Macroeconomy: Aggregate Supply and Demand

producing this generator? The answer might be something like this: Wages of GE employees Interest to bondholders Rentals of buildings Profits of GE stockholders

$400,000 50,000 50,000 100,000

The total is $600,000. The remaining $400,000 is accounted for by inputs that GE purchased from other companies: steel, circuitry, tubing, rubber, and so on. If we traced this $400,000 back even further, we would find that it is accounted for by the wages, interest, and rentals paid by these other companies, plus their profits, plus their purchases from other firms. In fact, for every firm in the economy, there is an accounting identity that says:

Revenue from sales 5

H

Wages paid 1 Interest paid 1 Rentals paid 1 Profits earned 1 Purchases from other firms

Why must this always be true? Because profits are the balancing item; they are what is left over after the firm has made all other payments. In fact, this accounting identity really reflects the definition of profits: sales revenue less all costs. Now apply this accounting identity to all firms in the economy. Total purchases from other firms are precisely what we call intermediate goods. What, then, do we get if we subtract these intermediate transactions from both sides of the equation?

H

Wages paid 1 Revenue from sales minus Interest paid 1 purchases from other firms 5 Rentals paid 1 Profits earned On the right-hand side, we have the sum of all factor incomes: payments to labor, land, and capital. On the left-hand side, we have total sales minus sales of intermediate goods. This means that we have sales of final goods, which is precisely our definition of GDP. Thus, the accounting identity for the entire economy can be rewritten as follows: GDP 5 Wages 1 Interest 1 Rents 1 Profits

This definition gives national income accountants another way to measure the GDP. Table 4 shows how to obtain GDP from the sum of all incomes. Once again, we have omitted a few details in our discussion. By adding up wages, interest, rents, and profits, we obtain only $11,528 billion, whereas GDP in 2008 was $14,441 billion. When sales taxes, excise taxes, and the like are added to the sum of wages,

TABLE 4 Gross Domestic Product in 2008 as the Sum of Incomes

Item Compensation of employees (wages) plus Net interest plus Rental income plus Profits Corporate profits Proprietors’ income plus Indirect business taxes and misc. items equals National income plus Statistical discrepancy equals Net national product plus Depreciation equals Gross national product minus Income received from other countries plus Income paid to other countries equals Gross domestic product

Amount $8,037 815 210 2,466 1,360 1,106 1,107 12,635 101 12,736 1,847 14,583 809 667 14,441

NOTE: Amounts are in billions of current dollars. SOURCE: U.S. Department of Commerce. Totals do not add up precisely due to rounding.

interest, rents, and profits, we obtain what is called national income—the sum of all factor payments, including indirect business taxes. National income is the sum of the incomes that all individuals in the country earn in the forms of wages, interest, rents, and profits. It includes indirect business taxes but excludes transfer payments and makes no deduction for income taxes.

Notice that national income is a measure of the factor incomes of all Americans, regardless of whether they work in this country or somewhere else. Likewise, incomes earned by foreigners in the United States are excluded from (our) national income. We will return to this distinction shortly. But, reading down Table 4, we next encounter a new concept: net national product (NNP), a measure of production. For reasons explained in the chapter, NNP is conceptually identical to national income. However, in practice, national income accountants estimate income and production independently; and so the two measures are never precisely equal. The difference in 2008 was $101 billion, or just 0.8 percent of NNP; it is called the statistical discrepancy.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 25

Moving further down the table, the only difference between NNP and gross national product (GNP) is depreciation of the nation’s capital stock. Thus the adjective “net” means excluding depreciation, and “gross” means including it. GNP is thus a measure of all final production, making no adjustment for the fact that some capital is used up each year and thus needs to be replaced. NNP deducts the required replacements to arrive at a net production figure. Depreciation is the value of the portion of the nation’s capital equipment that is used up within the year. It tells us how much output is needed just to maintain the economy’s capital stock.

From a conceptual point of view, most economists feel that NNP is a more meaningful indicator of the economy’s output than is GNP. After all, the depreciation component of GNP represents the output that is needed just to repair and replace worn-out factories and machines; it is not available for anybody to consume.10 Therefore, NNP seems to be a better measure of production than GNP. Alas, GNP is much easier to measure because depreciation is a particularly tricky item. What fraction of his tractor did Farmer Jones “use up” last year? How much did the Empire State Building depreciate during 2008? If you ask yourself difficult questions like these, you will understand why most economists believe that we can measure GNP more accurately than NNP. For this reason, most economic models are based on GNP. The final two adjustments that bring us to GDP return to a fact mentioned earlier. Some American citizens earn their incomes abroad, and some of the payments made by American companies are paid to foreign citizens. Thus, to obtain a measure of total production in the U.S. domestic economy (which is GDP) rather than a measure of the total production by U.S. nationals (which is GNP), we must subtract the income that Americans receive for factors supplied abroad and add the income that foreigners receive for factors supplied here. The net of these two adjustments is a very small number, as Table 4 shows. Thus, GDP and GNP are almost equal. In Table 4, you can hardly help noticing the preponderant share of employee compensation in total factor payments—about 70 percent. Labor is by far the most important factor of production. The return on land is under 2 percent of factor payments, and interest accounts for about 7 percent. Profits account for the remaining 21 percent, although the size of corporate profits (just 9 percent of GDP in 2008) is much less than the public thinks. If, by some magic stroke, we could convert all corporate profits into wages without If the capital stock is used for consumption, it will decline, and the nation will wind up poorer than it was before. 10

Aggregate Demand and the Powerful Consumer

555

upsetting the economy’s performance, the average worker would get a raise of about 17 percent!

GDP AS THE SUM OF VALUES ADDED It may strike you as strange that national income accountants include only final goods and services in GDP. Aren’t intermediate goods part of the nation’s product? Of course they are. The problem is that, if all intermediate goods were included in GDP, we would wind up double- and triple-counting certain goods and services and therefore get an exaggerated impression of the actual level of economic activity. To explain why, and to show how national income accountants cope with this difficulty, we must introduce a new concept, called value added. The value added by a firm is its revenue from selling a product minus the amount paid for goods and services purchased from other firms.

The intuitive sense of this concept is clear: If a firm buys some inputs from other firms, does something to them, and sells the resulting product for a price higher than it paid for the inputs, we say that the firm has “added value” to the product. If we sum up the values added by all firms in the economy, we must get the total value of all final products. Thus: GDP can be measured as the sum of the values added by all firms.

To verify this fact, look back at the second accounting identity in the left column of page 554. The left-hand side of this equation, sales revenue minus purchases from other firms, is precisely the firm’s value added. Thus: Value added 5 Wages 1 Interest 1 Rents 1 Profits

Because the second method we gave for measuring GDP is to add up wages, interest, rents, and profits, we see that the value-added approach must yield the same answer. The value-added concept is useful in avoiding double-counting. Often, however, intermediate goods are difficult to distinguish from final goods. Paint bought by a painter, for example, is an intermediate good. But paint bought by a do-it-yourselfer is a final good. What happens, then, if the professional painter buys some paint to refurbish his own garage? The intermediate good becomes a final good. You can see that the line between intermediate goods and final goods is a fuzzy one in practice. If we measure GDP by the sum of values added, however, we need not make such subtle distinctions. In this method, every purchase of a new good or service counts, but we do not count the entire selling price, only the portion that represents value added.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

556

Part 6

The Macroeconomy: Aggregate Supply and Demand

To illustrate this idea, consider the data in Table 5 and how they would affect GDP as the sum of final products. Our example begins when a farmer who grows soybeans sells them to a mill for $3 per bushel. This transaction does not count in the GDP because the miller does not purchase the soybeans for her own use. The miller then grinds up the soybeans and sells the resulting bag of soy meal to a factory that produces soy sauce. The miller receives $4, but GDP still has not increased because the ground beans are also an intermediate product. Next, the factory turns the beans into soy sauce, which it sells to your favorite Chinese restaurant for $8. Still no effect on GDP. TABLE 5 An Illustration of Final and Intermediate Goods

Item

Seller

Buyer

Price

Bushel of soybeans Bag of soy meal Gallon of soy sauce Gallon of soy sauce used as seasoning

Farmer Miller Factory

Miller Factory Restaurant

$3 4 8

Restaurant

Consumers 10 Total: $25 Addendum: Contribution to GDP $10

calculations enable us to come up with the right answer ($10) by counting only part of each transaction. The basic idea is to count at each step only the contribution to the value of the ultimate final product that is made at that step, excluding the values of items produced at other steps. Ignoring the minor items (such as fertilizer) that the farmer purchases from others, the entire $3 selling price of the bushel of soybeans is new output produced by the farmer; that is, the whole $3 is value added. The miller then grinds the beans and sells them for $4. She has added $4 minus $3, or $1 to the value of the beans. When the factory turns this soy meal into soy sauce and sells it for $8, it has added $8 minus $4, or $4 more in value. Finally, when the restaurant sells it to hungry customers for $10, a further $2 of value is added. The last column of Table 6 shows this chain of creation of value added. We see that the total value added by all four firms is $10, exactly the same as the restaurant’s selling price. This is as it must be, for only the restaurant sells the soybeans as a final product. TABLE 6

Then the big moment arrives: The restaurant sells the sauce to you and other customers as a part of your meals, and you eat it. At this point, the $10 worth of soy sauce becomes part of a final product and does count in the GDP. Notice that if we had also counted the three intermediate transactions (farmer to miller, miller to factory, factory to restaurant), we would have come up with $25—21⁄2 times too much. Why is it too much? The reason is straightforward. Neither the miller, the factory owner, nor the restaurateur values the product we have been considering for its own sake. Only the customers who eat the final product (the soy sauce) have increased their material well-being, so only this last transaction counts in the GDP. However, as we shall now see, value-added

An Illustration of Value Added

Seller

Buyer

Price

Value Added

Farmer

Miller

$3

$3

Miller

Factory

4

1

Factory

Restaurant

8

4

Consumers 10 Total: $25 Addendum: Contribution to GDP Final Products $10 Sum of values added $10

2 $10

Item Bushel of soybeans Bag of soy meal Gallon of soy sauce Gallon of soy sauce used as seasoning

Restaurant

| SUMMARY | 1. Gross domestic product (GDP) is the sum of the money values of all final goods and services produced during a year and sold on organized markets. There are, however, certain exceptions to this definition. 2. One way to measure the GDP is to add up the final demands of consumers, investors, government, and foreigners: GDP 5 C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM).

constitute the national income and then add indirect business taxes and depreciation. 4. A third way to measure the GDP is to sum up the values added by every firm in the economy (and then once again add indirect business taxes and depreciation). 5. Except for possible bookkeeping and statistical errors, all three methods must give the same answer.

3. A second way to measure the GDP is to start with all factor payments—wages, interest, rents, and profits—that

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

557

Aggregate Demand and the Powerful Consumer

Chapter 25

| KEY TERMS | depreciation

555

gross domestic product (GDP) 552 gross national product (GNP) 555

gross private domestic investment (I) 553 national income

net national product (NNP) 554

554

value added

national income accounting

555

552

| TEST YOURSELF | 1. Which of the following transactions are included in the gross domestic product, and by how much does each raise GDP? a. You buy a new Toyota, made in the United States, paying $25,000. b. You buy a new Toyota, imported from Japan, paying $25,000. c. You buy a used Cadillac, paying $12,000. d. Google spends $500 million to increase its Internet capacity. e. Your grandmother receives a Social Security check for $1,500. f. Chrysler manufactures 1,000 automobiles at a cost of $15,000 each. Unable to sell them, the company holds the cars as inventories. g. Mr. Black and Mr. Blue, each out for a Sunday drive, have a collision in which their cars are destroyed. Black and Blue each hire a lawyer to sue the other, paying the lawyers $5,000 each for services rendered. The judge throws the case out of court. h. You sell a used computer to your friend for $100. 2. The following outline provides a complete description of all economic activity in Trivialand for 2010. Draw up versions of Tables 3 and 4 for Trivialand showing GDP computed in two different ways.11 i. There are thousands of farmers but only two big business firms in Trivialand: Specific Motors (an auto company) and Super Duper (a chain of food markets). There is no government and no depreciation. ii. Specific Motors produced 1,000 small cars, which it sold at $6,000 each, and 100 trucks, which it sold at $8,000 each. Consumers bought 800 of the cars, and the remaining 200 cars were exported to the United States. Super Duper bought all the trucks.

In Trivialand, net national product and net domestic product are the same. So there are no entries corresponding to “income received from other countries” or “income paid to other countries,” as in Table 4.

iii. Sales at Super Duper markets amounted to $14 million, all of it sold to consumers. iv. All farmers in Trivialand are self-employed and sell all of their wares to Super Duper. v. The costs incurred by all of Trivialand’s businesses were as follows: Specific Motors Wages $3,800,000 Interest 100,000 Rent 200,000 Purchases 0 of food

Super Duper

Farmers

$4,500,000 $ 0 200,000 700,000 1,000,000 2,000,000 7,000,000 0

3. (More difficult) Now complicate Trivialand in the following ways and answer the same questions. In addition, calculate national income and disposable income.12 a. The government bought 50 cars, leaving only 150 cars for export. In addition, the government spent $800,000 on wages and made $1,200,000 in transfer payments. b. Depreciation for the year amounted to $600,000 for Specific Motors and $200,000 for Super Duper. (The farmers had no depreciation.) c. The government levied sales taxes amounting to $500,000 on Specific Motors and $200,000 on Super Duper (but none on farmers). In addition, the government levied a 10 percent income tax on all wages, interest, and rental income. d. In addition to the food and cars mentioned in Test Yourself Question 2, consumers in Trivialand imported 500 computers from the United States at $2,000 each.

11

12 In this context, disposable income is national income plus transfer payments minus taxes.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

558

Part 6

The Macroeconomy: Aggregate Supply and Demand

| DISCUSSION QUESTIONS | 1. Explain the difference between final goods and intermediate goods. Why is it sometimes difficult to apply this distinction in practice? In this regard, why is the concept of value added useful?

3. Explain why national income and gross domestic product would be essentially equal if there were no depreciation.

2. Explain the difference between government spending and government purchases of goods and services (G). Which is larger?

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Demand-Side Equilibrium: Unemployment or Inflation? A definite ratio, to be called the Multiplier, can be established between income and investment. JOHN M AY NARD K EYN E S

L

et’s briefly review where we have just been. In Chapter 22, we learned that the interaction of aggregate demand and aggregate supply determines whether the economy will stagnate or prosper, whether our labor and capital resources will be fully employed or unemployed. In Chapter 25, we learned that aggregate demand has four components: consumer expenditure (C), investment (I), government purchases (G), and net exports (X 2 IM). It is now time to start building a theory that puts the pieces together so we can see where the aggregate demand and aggregate supply curves come from. Because it is best to walk before you try to run, our approach is sequential. We begin in this chapter by assuming that taxes, the price level, the rate of interest, and the international value of the dollar are all constant. None of these assumptions is true, of course, and we will dispense with all of them in subsequent chapters. But we reap two important benefits from making these unrealistic assumptions now. First, they enable us to construct a simple but useful model of how the strength of aggregate demand influences the level of gross domestic product (GDP)—a model we will use to derive specific numerical solutions. Second, this simple model enables us to obtain an initial answer to a question of great importance to policy makers: Can we expect the economy to achieve full employment if the government does not intervene?

C O N T E N T S ISSUE: WHY DOES THE MARKET PERMIT

THE COORDINATION OF SAVING AND INVESTMENT

THE MULTIPLIER AND THE AGGREGATE DEMAND CURVE

THE MEANING OF EQUILIBRIUM GDP

CHANGES ON THE DEMAND SIDE: MULTIPLIER ANALYSIS

| APPENDIX A | The Simple Algebra of Income Determination and the Multiplier

The Magic of the Multiplier Demystifying the Multiplier: How It Works Algebraic Statement of the Multiplier

| APPENDIX B | The Multiplier with Variable Imports

UNEMPLOYMENT?

THE MECHANICS OF INCOME DETERMINATION THE AGGREGATE DEMAND CURVE DEMAND-SIDE EQUILIBRIUM AND FULL EMPLOYMENT

THE MULTIPLIER IS A GENERAL CONCEPT

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

560

Part 6

The Macroeconomy: Aggregate Supply and Demand

ISSUE:

WHY DOES THE MARKET PERMIT UNEMPLOYMENT?

Economists are fond of pointing out, with some awe, the amazing achievements of free markets. Without central direction, they somehow get businesses to produce just the goods and services that consumers want—and to do so cheaply and efficiently. If consumers want less meat and more fish, markets respond. If people subsequently change their minds, markets respond again. Free markets seem able to coordinate literally millions of decisions effortlessly and seamlessly. Yet for hundreds of years and all over the globe, market economies have stumbled over one particular coordination problem: the periodic bouts of mass unemployment that we call recessions and depressions. Widespread unemployment represents a failure to coordinate economic activity in the following sense. If the unemployed were hired, they would be able to buy the goods and services that businesses cannot sell. The revenues from those sales would, in turn, allow firms to pay the workers. So a seemingly straightforward “deal” offers jobs for the unemployed and sales for the firms. But somehow this deal is not made. Workers remain unemployed and firms get stuck with unsold output. Thus, free markets, which somehow manage to get rough diamonds dug out of the ground in South Africa and turned into beautiful rings that grooms buy for brides in Los Angeles, cannot seem to solve the coordination problem posed by unemployment. Why not? For centuries, economists puzzled over this question. By the end of the chapter, we will be well on the way toward providing an answer.

THE MEANING OF EQUILIBRIUM GDP

Equilibrium refers to a situation in which neither consumers nor firms have any incentive to change their behavior. They are content to continue with things as they are.

First, let’s put the four components of aggregate demand together to see how they interact, using as our organizing framework the circular flow diagram from the last chapter. In doing so, we initially ignore a possibility raised in earlier chapters: that the government might use monetary and fiscal policy to steer the economy in some desired direction. Aside from pedagogical simplicity, there is an important reason for doing so. One of the crucial questions surrounding stabilization policy is whether the economy would automatically gravitate toward full employment if the government simply left it alone. Contradicting the teachings of generations of economists before him, Keynes claimed it would not, but Keynes’s views are controversial to this day. We can study the issue best by imagining an economy in which the government never tries to manipulate aggregate demand, which is just what we do in this chapter. To begin to construct such a model, we must first understand what we mean by equilibrium GDP. Figure 1, which repeats Figure 1 from the last chapter, is a circular flow diagram that will help us do this. As explained in the last chapter, total production and total income must be equal, but the same need not be true of total spending. Imagine that, for some reason, the total expenditures made after point 4 in the figure, C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM), exceed the output produced by the business firms at point 5. What happens then? Because consumers, businesses, government, and foreigners together are buying more than firms are producing, businesses will start pulling goods out of their warehouses to meet demand. Thus, inventory stocks will fall—which signals retailers that they need to increase their orders and manufacturers that they need to step up production. Consequently, output is likely to rise. At some later date, if evidence indicates that the high level of spending is not just a temporary aberration, manufacturers and retailers may also respond to buoyant sales performances by raising their prices. Economists therefore say that neither output nor the price level is in equilibrium when total spending exceeds current production.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

t

en

tm

(

3

2

es

ion

(G

)

C

) IM ) s( ort rts (X p Im xpo E

s se Pu

rc

G

S) g(

ha

Co

I nv

n

pt

l+

s

um

Rest of the World

C+ l

(I)

C)

+

vin

1

nt

+ (X – IM)

Consumers

Gov

ern

I+G

me

4

C+

Investors

Government Dis

sa

Taxes rs T ransfe

po ble

In

om

c

The equilibrium level of GDP on the demand side cannot be one at which total spending exceeds output because firms will notice that they are depleting their inventory stocks. Firms may first decide to increase production sufficiently to meet the higher demand. Later they may decide to raise prices.

Expenditures Financial System

Sa

The definition of equilibrium in the margin tells us that the economy cannot be in equilibrium when total spending exceeds production, because falling inventories demonstrate to firms that their production and pricing decisions were not quite right.1 Thus, because we normally use GDP to measure output:

561

Demand-Side Equilibrium: Unemployment or Inflation?

Chapter 26

e

(D

I)

5

Firms (produce the domestic product)

6 Y s G ro s o m e ( nc I l a n o Nati

)

In c om e

Now imagine the other case, in which the flow of spending reaching firms falls short of current production. Unsold output winds up as additional inventories. The inventory pile-up signals firms that either their pricing or output decisions were wrong. Once again, they will probably react first by cutting back on production, causing GDP to fall (at point 5 in Figure 1). If the imbalance persists, they may also lower prices to stimulate sales. However, they certainly will not be happy with things as they are. Thus:

FI GURE 1 The Circular Flow Diagram

The equilibrium level of GDP on the demand side cannot be one at which total spending is less than output, because firms will not allow inventories to pile up. They may decide to decrease production, or they may decide to cut prices in order to stimulate demand.

We have now determined, by process of elimination, the only level of output that is consistent with people’s desires to spend. We have reasoned that GDP will rise whenever it is less than total spending, C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM), and that GDP will fall whenever it exceeds C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM). Equilibrium can occur, then, only when there is just enough spending to absorb the current level of production. Under such circumstances, producers conclude that their price and output decisions are correct and have no incentive to change. We conclude that: The equilibrium level of GDP on the demand side is the level at which total spending equals production. In such a situation, firms find their inventories remaining at desired levels, so they have no incentive to change output or prices.

Thus, the circular flow diagram has helped us to understand the concept of equilibrium GDP and has shown us how the economy is driven toward this equilibrium. It leaves unanswered, however, three important questions: • How large is the equilibrium level of GDP? • Will the economy suffer from unemployment, inflation, or both? • Is the equilibrium level of GDP on the demand side also consistent with firms’ desires to produce? That is, is it also an equilibrium on the supply side? The first two questions will occupy our attention in this chapter; the third is reserved for the next.

All the models in this book assume, strictly for simplicity, that firms seek constant inventories. Deliberate inventory changes are treated in more advanced courses.

1

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

562

Part 6

The Macroeconomy: Aggregate Supply and Demand

THE MECHANICS OF INCOME DETERMINATION

Real Expenditure

Our first objective is to determine precisely the equilibrium level of GDP on the demand side. To make the analysis more concrete, we turn to a numerical example. Specifically, we examine the relationship between total spending and GDP in the hypothetical economy we introduced in the last chapter. Columns 1 and 2 of Table 1 repeat the relationship between consumption and GDP that we first encountered TABLE 1 in the preceding chapter. They show how consumer The Total Expenditure Schedule spending, C, depends on GDP, which we symbolize by the (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) letter Y. Columns 3 through 5 provide the other three comGovernment Net ponents of total spending—I, G, and X 2 IM—through the GDP Consumption Investment Purchases Exports Total simplifying assumptions that each is just a fixed number (Y ) (C ) (I ) (G ) (X 2 IM) Expenditure regardless of the level of GDP. Specifically, we assume that 4,800 3,000 900 1,300 2100 5,100 investment spending is $900 billion, government pur5,200 3,300 900 1,300 2100 5,400 chases are $1,300 billion, and net exports are 2$100 bil5,600 3,600 900 1,300 2100 5,700 lion—meaning that in this hypothetical economy, as in the 6,000 3,900 900 1,300 2100 6,000 6,400 4,200 900 1,300 2100 6,300 United States at present, imports exceed exports. 6,800 4,500 900 1,300 2100 6,600 By adding columns 2 through 5, we calculate C 1 I 1 7,200 4,800 900 1,300 2100 6,900 G 1 (X 2 IM), or total expenditure, which appears in column 6 of Table 1. Columns 1 and 6 are highlighted in blue to show how total expenditure deF I GURE 2 pends on income. We call this relaConstruction of the Expenditure Schedule tionship the expenditure schedule. Figure 2 shows the construction C+I+G of the expenditure schedule graphically. The black line labeled C is C + I + G + (X – IM ) the consumption function; it plots on a graph the numbers given in columns 1 and 2 of Table 1. X – IM = –$100 The blue line, labeled C 1 I, displays our assumption that in6,100 vestment is fixed at $900 billion. It 6,000 lies a fixed distance (corresponding to $900 billion) above the C C+I G = $1,300 line. If investment were not always $900 billion, the two lines would either move closer together or grow farther apart. For example, our analysis of the determinants of investment spending C 4,800 suggested that I might be larger when GDP is higher. Such added investment as GDP rises—which I = $900 is called induced investment— would give the resulting C 1 I line a steeper slope than the C line. We ignore that possibility 3,900 here for simplicity. The green line, labeled C 1 I 1 G, adds government purchases. Because they are assumed to be $1,300 5,600 6,000 6,400 6,800 7,200 5,200 billion regardless of the size of GDP, Real GDP the green line is parallel to the blue line and $1,300 billion higher. NOTE: Figures are in billions of dollars per year.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 26

563

Demand-Side Equilibrium: Unemployment or Inflation?

Finally, the brick-colored line labeled C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM) adds in net exports. It is Induced investment is parallel to the green line and $100 billion lower, reflecting our assumption that net exports the part of investment are always 2$100 billion. Once again, if imports depended on GDP, as Chapter 25 suggested, spending that rises when GDP rises and falls when the C 1 I 1 G and C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM) lines would not be parallel. We deal with this GDP falls. more complicated case in Appendix B to this chapter. We are now ready to determine demand-side equilibrium in our hypothetical economy. An expenditure schedule Table 2 presents the logic of the circular flow argument in tabular form. The first two columns shows the relationship reproduce the expenditure schedule that we have just constructed. The other columns ex- between national income (GDP) and total spending. plain the process by which the economy approaches equilibrium. Let us see why a GDP of $6,000 billion must be the equilibrium level. Consider first any output level below $6,000 billion. For TA BLE 2 example, at output level The Determination of Equilibrium Output Y 5 $5,200 billion, total expendi(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) ture is $5,400 billion, as shown in Output Total Spending Balance of Inventory Producer column 2. This is $200 billion (Y ) [C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM )] Spending and Output Status Response more than production. With 4,800 5,100 Spending exceeds output Falling Produce more spending greater than output, as 5,200 5,400 Spending exceeds output Falling Produce more noted in column 3, inventories 5,600 5,700 Spending exceeds output Falling Produce more will fall (see column 4). As the 6,000 6,000 Spending 5 output Constant No change table suggests in column 5, this 6,400 6,300 Output exceeds spending Rising Produce less will signal producers to raise 6,800 6,600 Output exceeds spending Rising Produce less 7,200 6,900 Output exceeds spending Rising Produce less their output. Clearly, then, no output level below Y 5 $6,000 NOTE: Amounts are in billions of dollars. billion can be an equilibrium, because output is too low. A similar line of reasoning eliminates any output level above $6,000 billion. Consider, for example, Y 5 $6,800 billion. The table shows that total spending would be $6,600 billion if output were $6,800 billion, so $200 billion would go unsold. This would raise producers’ inventory stocks and signal them that their rate of production was too high. Just as we concluded from our circular flow diagram, equilibrium will be achieved only FI GURE 3 when total spending, C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM), exactly equals GDP, Y. In symbols, our conIncome-Expenditure dition for equilibrium GDP is Diagram

Y 5 C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM)

6,800 C+I+G+ (X – IM)

6,400 E 6,000

Equilibrium 5,600 5,200

4,800

0 If you need review, see Chapter 1’s appendix, especially pages 17–18.

Output exceeds spending 45

7,200

Real Expenditure

Table 2 shows that this equation holds only at a GDP of $6,000 billion, which must therefore be the equilibrium level of GDP. Figure 3 depicts the same conclusion graphically, by adding a 45° line to Figure 2. Why a 45° line? Recall from Chapter 1’s appendix that a 45° line marks all points on a graph at which the value of the variable measured on the horizontal axis (in this case, GDP) equals the value of the variable measured on the vertical axis (in this case, total expenditure).2 Thus, the 45° line in Figure 3 shows all the points at which output and spending are equal—that is, where Y 5 C 1 I 1 G 1(X 2 IM). The 45° line therefore displays all the points at which the economy can possibly be in demand-side equilibrium, for firms will be content with current output levels only if total spending equals production.

Spending exceeds output 4,800 5,200 5,600 6,000 6,400 6,800 7,200 Real GDP

2

NOTE: Figures are in billions of dollars per year.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

564

Part 6

The Macroeconomy: Aggregate Supply and Demand

An income-expenditure diagram, or 45° line diagram, plots total real expenditure (on the vertical axis) against real income (on the horizontal axis). The 45° line marks off points where income and expenditure are equal.

Now we must compare these potential equilibrium points with the actual combinations of spending and output that are consistent with the current behavior of consumers and investors. That behavior is described by the C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM) line in Figure 3, which shows how total expenditure varies as income changes. The economy will always be on the expenditure line because only points on the C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM) line describe the spending plans of consumers and investors. Similarly, if the economy is in equilibrium, it must be on the 45° line. As Figure 3 shows, these two requirements imply that the only viable equilibrium is at point E, where the C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM) line intersects the 45° line. Only this point is consistent with both equilibrium and people’s actual desires to consume and invest. Notice that to the left of the equilibrium point, E, the expenditure line lies above the 45° line. This means that total spending exceeds total output, as we have already noted. Hence, inventories will be falling and firms will conclude that they should increase production. Thus, production will rise toward the equilibrium point, E. The opposite is true to the right of point E. Here spending falls short of output, inventories rise, and firms will cut back production—thereby moving closer to E. In other words, whenever production is above the equilibrium level, market forces will drive output down. And whenever production is below equilibrium, market forces will drive output up. In either case, deviations from demand-side equilibrium will gradually be eliminated. Diagrams such as Figure 3 will recur so frequently in this and the next several chapters that it will be convenient to have a name for them. We call them income-expenditure diagrams, because they show how expenditures vary with income, or simply 45° line diagrams.

THE AGGREGATE DEMAND CURVE Chapter 22 introduced aggregate demand and aggregate supply curves relating aggregate quantities demanded and supplied to the price level. The expenditure schedule graphed in Figure 3 is certainly not the aggregate demand curve, for we have yet to bring the price level into our discussion. It is now time to remedy this omission and derive the aggregate demand curve. To do so, we need only recall something we learned in the last chapter. As we noted on page 546, households own a great deal of money-fixed assets whose real value declines when the price level rises. The money in your bank account is a prime example. If prices rise, that money will buy less. Because of that fact, consumers’ real wealth declines whenever the price level rises—and that affects their spending. Specifically: Higher prices decrease the demand for goods and services because they erode the purchasing power of consumer wealth. Conversely, lower prices increase the demand for goods and services by enhancing the purchasing power of consumer wealth.

For these reasons, a change in the price level will shift the entire consumption function. To represent this shift graphically, Figure 4 (which looks just like Figure 6 from Chapter 8) shows that: A higher price level leads to lower real wealth and therefore to less spending at any given level of real income. Thus, a higher price level leads to a lower consumption function (such as C1 in Figure 4), and a lower price level leads to a higher consumption function (such as C2 in Figure 4).

Because students are sometimes confused by this point, it is worth repeating that the depressing effect of the price level on consumer spending works through real wealth, not through real income. The consumption function is a relationship between real consumer income and real consumer spending. Thus, any decline in real income, regardless of its

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

565

Demand-Side Equilibrium: Unemployment or Inflation?

Chapter 26

Real Consumer Spending

cause, moves the economy leftward along a fixed consumpEffect of changes in tion function; it does not shift the consumption function. real income By contrast, a decline in real wealth will shift the entire conC2 sumption function downward, meaning that people spend C0 less at any given level of real income. C1 Lower price In terms of the 45° line diagram, a rise in the price level level will therefore pull down the consumption function depicted in Figure 2 and hence will pull down the total expenditure A schedule as well. Conversely, a fall in the price level will raise both the C and C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM) schedules in Higher price level the diagram. The two panels of Figure 5 illustrate both of these shifts. How, then, do changes in the price level affect the equilibrium level of real GDP on the demand side? Common sense says that, with lower spending, equilibrium GDP Real Disposable Income should fall; and Figure 5 shows that this conclusion is correct. Figure 5(a) shows that a rise in the price level, by FI GURE 4 shifting the expenditure schedule downward, leads to a How the Price Level reduction in the equilibrium quantity of real GDP demanded from Y0 to Y1. Conversely, Shifts the Consumption Figure 5(b) shows that a fall in the price level, by shifting the expenditure schedule Function upward, leads to a rise in the equilibrium quantity of real GDP demanded from Y0 to Y2. In summary: A rise in the price level leads to a lower equilibrium level of real aggregate quantity demanded. This relationship between the price level and real GDP (depicted in Figure 6) is precisely what we called the aggregate demand curve in earlier chapters. It comes directly from the 45° line diagrams in Figure 5. Thus, points E0, E1, and E2 in Figure 6 correspond precisely to the points bearing the same labels in Figure 5.

The effect of higher prices on consumer wealth is just one of several reasons why the aggregate demand curve slopes downward. A second reason comes from international trade. In Chapter 25’s discussion of the determinants of net exports (see pages

FIGU RE 5 The Effect of the Price Level on Equilibrium Aggregate Quantity Demanded

45

45

C2 + I + G + (X – IM) Real Expenditure

C 0 + I + G + (X – IM) E0 C1 + I + G + (X – IM)

E1

45

Real Expenditure

E2 C0 + I + G + (X – IM)

E0

45 Y1

Y0 Real GDP

(a) Rise in Price Level

Y0 Y2 Real GDP

(b) Fall in Price Level

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

566

Part 6

The Macroeconomy: Aggregate Supply and Demand

549–550), we pointed out that higher U.S. prices (holding foreign prices constant) will depress exports (X) and stimulate imports (IM). That means that, holding other things equal, a higher U.S. price level will reduce the (X 2 IM) component of total expenditure, thereby shifting the C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM) line downward and lowering real GDP, as depicted in Figure 5(a). Later in this book, after we have studied interest rates and exchange rates, we will encounter still more reasons for a downward-sloping aggregate demand curve. All of them imply that:

F IGURE 6

Price Level

The Aggregate Demand Curve

P1

E1 E0

P0

E2

P2

Y1

Y0 Y2 Real GDP

An income-expenditure diagram like Figure 3 can be drawn only for a specific price level. At different price levels, the C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM) schedule will be different and, hence, the equilibrium quantity of GDP demanded will also be different.

As we will now see, this seemingly technical point about graphs is critical to understanding the genesis of unemployment and inflation.

DEMAND-SIDE EQUILIBRIUM AND FULL EMPLOYMENT

Real Expenditure

We now turn to the second major question posed on page 561: Will the economy achieve an equilibrium at full employment without inflation, or will we see unemployment, inflation, or both? This question is a crucial one for stabilization policy, for if the economy always gravitates toward full employment automatically, then the government should simply leave it alone. In the income-expenditure diagrams used so far, the equilibrium level of GDP demanded appears as the intersection of the expenditure schedule and the 45° line, regardless of the GDP level that corresponds to full employment. However, as we will see now, when equilibrium GDP falls above potential GDP, the economy probably will be plagued by inflation, and when equilibrium falls below potential GDP, unemployment and recession will result. This notable fact was one of the principal messages F I GURE 7 of Keynes’s General Theory of Employment, Interest, and A Recessionary Gap Money. Writing during the Great Depression, it was natural for Keynes to focus on the case in which equiPotential librium falls short of full employment, leaving some GDP 45 resources unemployed. Figure 7 illustrates this possibility. A vertical line has been drawn at the level of potential GDP, a number that depends on the kinds of aggregate supply considerations discussed at length in F Chapter 24—and to which we will return in the next C + I + G + (X – IM ) chapter. Here, potential GDP is assumed to be $7,000 billion. We see that the C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM) curve cuts the 45° line at point E, which corresponds to a E B GDP (Y 5 $6,000 billion) below potential GDP. In this case, the expenditure curve is too low to lead to full Recessionary gap employment. Such a situation arose in the United States in 2008, after the economy, hampered by a slump in housing and a variety of financial problems, slowed down abruptly late in 2007. An equilibrium below potential GDP can arise 45 when consumers or investors are unwilling to spend 6,000 7,000 at normal rates, when government spending is Real GDP low, when foreign demand is weak, or when the price NOTE: Figures are in billions of dollars per year. level is “too high.” Any of these events would depress

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 26

567

Demand-Side Equilibrium: Unemployment or Inflation?

The recessionary gap is the amount by which the equilibrium level of real GDP falls short of potential GDP.

FI GURE 8 An Inflationary Gap

45

E C + I + G + (X – IM)

Real Expenditure

the C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM) curve. Unemployment must then occur because not enough output is demanded to keep the entire labor force at work. The distance between the equilibrium level of output demanded and the full-employment level of output (that is, potential GDP) is called the recessionary gap; it is shown by the horizontal distance from point E to point B in Figure 7. Although the figure is entirely hypothetical, real-world gaps of precisely this sort were shown shaded in blue in Figure 2 of Chapter 23 (page 496). They have been a regular feature of U.S. economic history. Figure 7 clearly shows that full employment can be reached by raising the total expenditure schedule to eliminate the recessionary gap. Specifically, the C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM) line must move upward until it cuts the 45° line at point F. Can this happen without government intervention? We know that a sufficiently large drop in the price level can do the job. But is that a realistic prospect? We will return to this question in the next chapter, after we bring the supply side into the picture, for we cannot discuss price determination without bringing in both supply and demand. First, however, let us briefly consider the other case—when equilibrium GDP exceeds full employment. Figure 8 illustrates this possibility, which many people believe characterized the U.S. economy in 2006 and into 2007, when the unemployment rate dipped below 5 percent. Now the expenditure schedule intersects the Potential GDP 45° line at point E, where GDP is $8,000 billion. But this Inflationary gap exceeds the full-employment level, Y 5 $7,000 billion. B A case such as this can arise when consumer or investment spending is unusually buoyant, when foreign demand is particularly strong, when the government spends too much, or when a “low” price level pushes the C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM) curve upward. To reach an equilibrium at full employment, the F price level would have to rise enough to drive the expenditure schedule down until it passed through point F. The horizontal distance BE—which indicates the amount by which the quantity of GDP demanded exceeds potential GDP—is now called the inflationary gap. If there is an inflationary gap, a higher price level 45 or some other means of reducing total expenditure is 7,000 necessary to reach an equilibrium at full employment. Real GDP Rising prices will eventually pull the C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM) line down until it passes through point F. NOTE: Figures are in billions of dollars per year. Real-world inflationary gaps were shown shaded in pink in Figure 2 of Chapter 23 (page 496). In sum: Only if the price level and spending plans are “just right” will the expenditure curve intersect the 45° line precisely at full employment, so that neither a recessionary gap nor an inflationary gap occurs.

8,000

The inflationary gap is the amount by which equilibrium real GDP exceeds the full-employment level of GDP.

Are there reasons to expect this outcome? Does the economy have a self-correcting mechanism that automatically eliminates recessionary or inflationary gaps and propels it toward full employment? And why do inflation and unemployment sometimes rise or fall together? We are not ready to answer these questions yet because we have not yet brought aggregate supply into the picture. However, it is not too early to get an idea about why things can go wrong during a recession like the recent one.

THE COORDINATION OF SAVING AND INVESTMENT To do so, it is useful to pose the following question: Must the full-employment level of GDP be a demand-side equilibrium? Decades ago, economists thought the answer was “yes.” Since Keynes, most economists believe the answer is “not necessarily.”

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

568

Part 6

The Macroeconomy: Aggregate Supply and Demand

F I GURE 9 A Simplified Circular Flow

Expenditures t

en

es

pt

C+l

( I)

C)

2

I nv

m

ing

Co

n

S av

su

( ion

tm

Financial System

) (S

Investors C+I

Consumers

1

3

Y

In c o m e

Firms (produce the domestic product)

To help us see why, Figure 9 offers a simplified circular flow diagram that ignores exports, imports, and the government. In this version, income can “leak out” of the circular flow only at point 1, where consumers save some of their income. Similarly, lost spending can be replaced only at point 2, where investment enters the circular flow. What happens if firms produce exactly the full-employment level of GDP at point 3 in the diagram? Will this income level be maintained as we move around the circle, or will it shrink or grow? The answer is that full-employment income will be maintained only if the spending by investors at point 2 exactly balances the saving done by consumers at point 1. In other words: The economy will reach an equilibrium at full employment on the demand side only if the amount that consumers wish to save out of their full-employment incomes happens to equal the amount that investors want to invest. If these two magnitudes are unequal, full employment will not be an equilibrium.

Thus, the basic answer to the puzzle we posed at the start of this chapter is: The market will permit unemployment when total spending is too low to employ the entire labor force.

A coordination failure occurs when party A would like to change his behavior if party B would change hers, and vice versa, and yet the two changes do not take place because the decisions of A and B are not coordinated.

IDEAS FOR BEYOND THE FINAL EXAM

Now, how can that occur? The circular flow diagram shows that if saving exceeds investment at full employment, the total demand received by firms at point 3 will fall short of total output because the added investment spending will not be enough to replace the leakage to saving. With demand inadequate to support production at full employment, GDP must fall below potential. There will be a recessionary gap. Conversely, if investment exceeds saving when the economy is at full employment, then total demand will exceed potential GDP and production will rise above the full-employment level. There will be an inflationary gap. Now, this discussion does nothing but restate what we already know in different words.3 But these words provide the key to understanding why the economy sometimes finds itself stuck above or below full employment, for the people who invest are not the same as the people who save. In a modern capitalist economy, investing is done by one group of individuals (primarily corporate executives and home buyers), whereas saving is done by another group.4 It is easy to imagine that their plans may not be well coordinated. If they are not, we have just seen how either unemployment or inflation can occur. Neither of these problems would arise if the acts of saving and investing were perfectly coordinated. Although perfection is never attainable, the analysis in the box, “Unemployment and Inflation as Coordination Failures,” raises a tantalizing possibility. If both high unemployment and high inflation arise from coordination failures, might the government be able to do something about this problem? Keynes suggested that it could, by using its powers over monetary and fiscal policy. His ideas, which constitute one of our Ideas for Beyond the Final Exam, will be examined in detail in later chapters. However, even the simple football analogy described in the box reminds us that a central authority may not find it easy to solve a coordination problem. In symbols, our equilibrium condition without government or foreign trade is Y 5 C 1 I. If we note that Y is also the sum of consumption plus saving, Y 5 C 1 S, then it follows that C 1 S 5 C 1 I, or S 5 I, is a restatement of the equilibrium condition. 4 In a modern economy, not only do households save but businesses also save in the form of retained earnings. Nonetheless, households are the ultimate source of the saving needed to finance investment. 3

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 26

569

Demand-Side Equilibrium: Unemployment or Inflation?

The idea that unemployment stems from a lack of coordination between the decisions of savers and investors may seem abstract, but we encounter coordination failures in the real world quite frequently. The following familiar example may bring the idea down to earth. Picture a crowd watching a football game. Now something exciting happens and the fans rise from their seats. People in the front rows begin standing first, and those seated behind them are forced to stand if they want to see the game. Soon everyone in the stadium is on their feet. With everyone standing, though, no one can see any better than when everyone was sitting. And the fans are enduring the further discomfort of being on their feet. (Never mind that stadium seats are uncomfortable!) Everyone in the stadium would be better off if everyone sat down, which sometimes happens; but the crowd rises to its feet again on every exciting play. There is simply no way to coordinate the individual decisions of tens of thousands of football fans. Unemployment poses a similar coordination problem. During a deep recession, workers are unemployed and businesses cannot sell their wares. Figuratively speaking, everyone is “standing” and unhappy about it. If only the firms could agree to hire more workers, those newly employed people could afford to buy more of the goods and services the firms want to produce. However, as at the football stadium, there is no central authority to coordinate these millions of decisions.

SOURCE: © Thinkstock Images/Jupiterimages

Unemployment and Inflation as Coordination Failures

The coordination failure idea also helps to explain why it is so difficult to stop inflation. Virtually everyone prefers stable prices to rising prices. Now think of yourself as the seller of a product. If all other participants in the economy would hold their prices steady, you would happily hold yours steady, too. If you believe that others will continue to raise their prices at a rate of, say, 5 percent per year, you may find it dangerous not to increase your prices apace. Hence, society may get stuck with 5 percent inflation even though everyone agrees that zero inflation is better.

CHANGES ON THE DEMAND SIDE: MULTIPLIER ANALYSIS We have just learned how demand-side equilibrium depends on the consumption function and on the amounts spent on investment, government purchases, and net exports. But none of these is a constant of nature; they all change from time to time. How does equilibrium GDP change when the consumption function shifts or when I, G, or (X 2 IM) changes? As we will see now, the answer is simple: by more! A remarkable result called the multiplier says that a change in spending will bring about an even larger change in equilibrium GDP on the demand side. Let us see why.

The multiplier is the ratio of the change in equilibrium GDP (Y) divided by the original change in spending that causes the change in GDP.

TABLE 3

The Magic of the Multiplier Because it is subject to abrupt swings, investment spending often causes business fluctuations in the United States and elsewhere. So let us ask what would happen if firms suddenly decided to spend more on investment goods. As we will see next, such a decision would have a multiplied effect on GDP; that is, each $1 of additional investment spending would add more than $1 to GDP. To see why, refer first to Table 3, which looks very much like Table 1. The only difference is that we now assume that firms want to invest $200 billion more than previously—for a total of $1,100 billion. As indicated by the blue numbers, only income level Y 5 $6,800 billion is

Total Expenditure after a $200 Billion Increase in Investment Spending

(1) Income (Y ) 4,800 5,200 5,600 6,000 6,400 6,800 7,200

(2)

(3)

(4) Government Consumption Investment Purchases (C ) (I ) (G ) 3,000 3,300 3,600 3,900 4,200 4,500 4,800

1,100 1,100 1,100 1,100 1,100 1,100 1,100

1,300 1,300 1,300 1,300 1,300 1,300 1,300

(5) (6) Net Exports Total (X 2 IM) Expenditure 2100 2100 2100 2100 2100 2100 2100

NOTE: Figures are in billions of dollars per year.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

5,300 5,600 5,900 6,200 6,500 6,800 7,100

570

Part 6

The Macroeconomy: Aggregate Supply and Demand

an equilibrium on the demand side of the economy now, because only at this level is total spending, C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM), equal to production (Y). The multiplier principle says that GDP will rise by more than the $200 billion increase in investment. Specifically, the multiplier is defined as the ratio of the change in equilibrium GDP (Y) to the original change in spending that caused GDP to change. In shorthand, when we deal with the multiplier for investment (I), the formula is Multiplier 5

FIGURE 10

Real Expenditure

Illustration of the Multiplier

$200 billion

0

Change in Y Change in I

Let us verify that the multiplier is, indeed, greater than 1. Table 3 shows how the new expenditure schedule is constructed by adding up C, I, G, and (X 2 IM) at each level of Y, just as we did earlier—only now I is $1,100 billion rather than $900 billion. If you compare the last columns of Table 1 and Table 3, you will see that the new expenditure schedule lies uniformly above the old one by $200 billion. Figure 10 depicts this change graphically. The curve marked C 1 I0 1 G 1 (X 2 IM) is derived from the last column of Table 1, 45 whereas the higher curve marked C 1 I1 1 C + I1 + G + (X – IM ) G 1 (X 2 IM) is derived from the last column of Table 3. The two expenditure lines are C + I0 + G + (X – IM ) E1 parallel and $200 billion apart. So far things look just as you might expect, but one more step will bring the multiplier rabbit out of the hat. Let us see what the upward shift of the expenditure line does to equilibrium income. In Figure 10, equilibrium moves outward from point E0 E0 to point E1, or from $6,000 billion to $6,800 billion. The difference is an increase of $800 billion in GDP. All this from a $200 billion stimulus to investment? That is the magic of the multiplier. Because the change in I is $200 billion and 6,800 6,000 the change in equilibrium Y is $800 billion, Real GDP by applying our definition, the multiplier is

NOTE: Figures are in billions of dollars per year.

Multiplier 5

Change in Y $800 5 54 Change in I $200

This tells us that, in our example, each additional $1 of investment demand will add $4 to equilibrium GDP! This result does, indeed, seem mysterious. Can something be created from nothing? Let’s first check that the graph has not deceived us. The first and last columns of Table 3 show in numbers what Figure 10 shows graphically. Notice that equilibrium now comes at Y 5 $6,800 billion, because only at that point is total expenditure equal to production (Y). This equilibrium level of GDP is $800 billion higher than the $6,000 billion level found when investment was $200 billion lower. Thus, a $200 billion rise in investment does indeed lead to an $800 billion rise in equilibrium GDP. The multiplier really is 4.

Demystifying the Multiplier: How It Works The multiplier result seems strange at first, but it loses its mystery once we recall the circular flow of income and expenditure and the simple fact that one person’s spending is another person’s income. To illustrate the logic of the multiplier and see why it is exactly 4 in our example, think about what happens when businesses decide to spend $1 million on investment goods.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 26

571

Demand-Side Equilibrium: Unemployment or Inflation?

Cumulative Spending Total

Suppose that Microhard—a major corporation in our hypothetical country—decides to spend $1 million to upgrade an office building. Its $1 million expenditure goes to construction workers and owners of construction companies as wages and profits. That is, the $1 million becomes their income. The construction firm’s owners and workers will not keep all of their $1 million in the bank; instead, they will spend most of it. If they are “typical” consumers, their spending will be $1 million times the marginal propensity to consume (MPC). In our example, the MPC is 0.75, so assume they spend $750,000 and save the rest. This $750,000 expenditure is a net addition to the nation’s demand for goods and services, just as Microhard’s original $1 million expenditure was. So, at this stage, the $1 million investment has already pushed GDP up by some $1.75 million. The process is by no means over. Shopkeepers receive the $750,000 spent by construction workers, and TABLE 4 they in turn also spend 75 percent of their new income. This activity acThe Multiplier Spending Chain counts for $562,500 (75 percent of $750,000) in additional consumer (1) (2) (3) spending in the “third round.” Next follows a fourth round in which the Round Spending in Cumulative recipients of the $562,500 spend 75 percent of this amount, or $421,875, Number This Round Total and so on. At each stage in the spending chain, people spend 75 percent 1 $1,000,000 $1,000,000 of the additional income they receive, and the process continues—with 2 750,000 1,750,000 consumption growing in every round. 3 562,500 2,312,500 Where does it all end? Does it all end? The answer is that, yes, it does 4 421,875 2,734,375 eventually end—with GDP a total of $4 million higher than it was before 5 316,406 3,050,781 6 237,305 3,288,086 Microhard built the original $1 million office building. The multiplier is 7 177,979 3,466,065 indeed 4. 8 133,484 3,599,549 Table 4 displays the basis for this conclusion. In the table, “Round 1” 9 100,113 3,699,662 represents Microhard’s initial investment, which creates $1 million in in10 75,085 3,774,747 come for construction workers. “Round 2” represents the construction o o o 20 4,228 3,987,317 workers’ spending, which creates $750,000 in income for shopkeepers. The o o o rest of the table proceeds accordingly; each entry in column 2 is 75 percent “Infinity” 0 4,000,000 of the previous entry. Column 3 tabulates the running sum of column 2. We see that after 10 rounds of spending, the initial $1 million investment has mushroomed to $3.77 million—and the sum is still growing. After 20 rounds, the total increase in GDP is over $3.98 million—near its eventual value of $4 million. Although it takes quite a few rounds of spending before the multiplier chain nears 4, we see from the table that it hits 3 rather quickly. If each income recipient in the chain waits, say, two months before spending his new income, the multiplier will reach 3 in only FIGURE 11 about ten months. How the Multiplier Figure 11 provides a graphical presentation of the Builds numbers in the last column of Table 4. Notice how the multiplier builds up rapidly at first and then tapers $4.0 off to approach its ultimate value (4 in this example) gradually. And, of course, all this operates exactly the same— 3.0 but in the opposite direction—when spending falls. For example, when the boom in housing in America ended in 2006, spending on new houses began to decline. 2.0 As this process progressed, the slowdown in housing created a negative multiplier effect on everything from appliances and furniture to carpeting and insulation. 1.0 Indeed, the downward pull of housing on overall GDP was so strong that it pushed the whole economy into a recession. 0

Algebraic Statement of the Multiplier Figure 11 and Table 4 probably make a persuasive case that the multiplier eventually reaches 4, but for the

2

4

6

8

10

15

Spending Round NOTE: Amounts are in millions of dollars.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

20

572

Part 6

The Macroeconomy: Aggregate Supply and Demand

remaining skeptics, we offer a simple algebraic proof.5 Most of you learned about something called an infinite geometric progression in high school. This term refers to an infinite series of numbers, each one of which is a fixed fraction of the previous one. The fraction is called the common ratio. A geometric progression beginning with 1 and having a common ratio of 0.75 looks like this:

1 1 0.75 1 1 0.75 2 2 1 1 0.75 2 3 1 . . .

More generally, a geometric progression beginning with 1 and having a common ratio R would be 1 1 R 1 R2 1 R3 1 . . .

A simple formula enables us to sum such a progression as long as R is less than 1.6 The formula is7 Sum of infinite geometric progression 5

1 12R

We now recognize that the multiplier chain in Table 4 is just an infinite geometric progression with 0.75 as its common ratio. That is, each $1 that Microhard spends leads to a (0.75) 3 $1 expenditure by construction workers, which in turn leads to a (0.75) 3 (0.75 3 $1) 5 (0.75)2 3 $1 expenditure by the shopkeepers, and so on. Thus, for each initial dollar of investment spending, the progression is

1 1 0.75 1 1 0.75 2 2 1 1 0.75 2 3 1 1 0.75 2 4 1 . . .

Applying the formula for the sum of such a series, we find that

Multiplier 5

1 1 5 54 1 2 0.75 0.25

Notice how this result can be generalized. If we did not have a specific number for the marginal propensity to consume, but simply called it MPC, the geometric progression in Table 4 would have been 1 1 MPC 1 1 MPC 2 2 1 1 MPC 2 3 1 . . .

This progression uses the MPC as its common ratio. Applying the same formula for summing a geometric progression to this more general case gives us the following general result: Oversimplified Multiplier Formula 1 Multiplier 5 1 2 MPC

We call this formula “oversimplified” because it ignores many factors that are important in the real world. You can begin to appreciate just how unrealistic the oversimplified formula is by considering some real numbers for the U.S. economy. The MPC is over 0.95. From our oversimplified formula, then, it would seem that the multiplier should be at least

Multiplier 5

1 1 5 5 20 1 2 0.95 0.05

In fact, the actual multiplier for the U.S. economy is less than 2. That is quite a discrepancy!

Students who blanch at the sight of algebra should not be put off. Anyone who can balance a checkbook (even many who cannot!) will be able to follow the argument. 6 If R exceeds 1, no one can possibly sum it—not even with the aid of a modern computer—because the sum is not a finite number. 7 The proof of the formula is simple. Let the symbol S stand for the (unknown) sum of the series: S 5 1 1 R 1 R2 1 R3 1 . . . Then, multiplying by R, RS 5 R 1 R2 1 R3 1 R4 1 . . . By subtracting RS from S, we obtain 1 S 2 RS 5 1 or S 5 12R 5

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 26

Demand-Side Equilibrium: Unemployment or Inflation?

573

This discrepancy does not mean that anything we have said about the multiplier so far is incorrect. Our story is simply incomplete. As we progress through this and subsequent chapters, you will learn why the multiplier in the United States is less than 2 even though the country’s MPC is over 0.95. One such reason relates to international trade—in particular, the fact that a country’s imports depend on its GDP. We deal with this complication in Appendix B to this chapter. A second factor is inflation, a complication we will address in the next chapter. A third factor is income taxation, a point we will elaborate in Chapter 28. The last important reason arises from the financial system and, after we discuss money and banking in Chapters 29 and 30, we will explain in Chapter 31 how the financial system influences the multiplier. As you will see, each of these factors reduces the size of the multiplier. So: Although the multiplier is larger than 1 in the real world, it cannot be calculated accurately with the oversimplified multiplier formula. The actual multiplier is much lower than the formula suggests.

THE MULTIPLIER IS A GENERAL CONCEPT Although we have used business investment to illustrate the workings of the multiplier, it should be clear from the logic that any increase in spending can kick off a multiplier chain. To see how the multiplier works when the process is initiated by an upsurge in consumer spending, we must distinguish between two types of change in consumer spending. To do so, look back at Figure 4. When C rises because income rises—that is, when consumers move outward along a fixed consumption function—we call the increase in C an An induced increase induced increase in consumption. (See the brick-colored arrows in the figure.) When C in consumption is an rises because the entire consumption function shifts upward (such as from C0 to C2 in the increase in consumer figure), we call it an autonomous increase in consumption. The name indicates that con- spending that stems from sumption changes independently of income. The discussion of the consumption function in an increase in consumer Chapter 25 pointed out that a number of events, such as a change in the value of the stock incomes. It is represented on a graph as a movement market, can initiate such a shift. along a fixed consumption If consumer spending were to rise autonomously by $200 billion, we would revise our function. table of aggregate demand to look like Table 5. Comparing this new table to Table 3, we note that each entry in column 2 is $200 billion higher than the corresponding entry in An autonomous increase Table 3 (because consumption is higher), and each entry in column 3 is $200 billion lower in consumption is an increase in consumer (because in this case investment is only $900 billion). spending without any Column 6, the expenditure schedule, is identical in both tables, so the equilibrium level increase in consumer of income is clearly Y 5 $6,800 billion once again. The initial rise of $200 billion in con- incomes. It is represented sumer spending leads to an eventual rise of $800 billion in GDP, just as it did in the case of on a graph as a shift of the higher investment spending. In fact, Figure 10 applies directly to this case once we note entire consumption function. that the upward shift is now caused by an autonomous change in C rather than in I. The multiplier for auTABLE 5 tonomous changes in consumer spending, then, is also Total Expenditure after Consumers Decide to Spend 4 (5 $800/$200). $200 Billion More The reason is straightforward. It does not matter (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) who injects an additional dollar of spending into the Government economy—business investors or consumers. Whatever Income Consumption Investment Purchases Net Exports Total the source of the extra dollar, 75 percent of it will be (Y ) (C ) (I ) (G ) (X 2 IM) Expenditure respent if the MPC is 0.75, and the recipients of this 4,800 3,200 900 1,300 2100 5,300 second round of spending will, in turn, spend 75 per5,200 3,500 900 1,300 2100 5,600 cent of their additional income, and so on. That contin5,600 3,800 900 1,300 2100 5,900 ued spending constitutes the multiplier process. Thus 6,000 4,100 900 1,300 2100 6,200 6,400 4,400 900 1,300 2100 6,500 a $200 billion increase in government purchases (G) or 6,800 4,700 900 1,300 2100 6,800 in net exports (X 2 IM) would have the same multi7,200 5,000 900 1,300 2100 7,100 plier effect, as depicted in Figure 10. The multipliers are identical because the logic behind them is identical. NOTE: Figures are in billions of dollars per year. Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

574

Part 6

The Macroeconomy: Aggregate Supply and Demand

The idea that changes in G have multiplier effects on GDP will play a central role in the discussion of government stabilization policy that begins in Chapter 28. So it is worth noting here that: Changes in the volume of government purchases of goods and services will change the equilibrium level of GDP on the demand side in the same direction, but by a multiplied amount.

FIGURE 12 Two Views of the Multiplier

To cite a recent example, heavy federal government spending to fight the recession since 2008 has boosted the G component of C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM), which had a multiplier effect on GDP. Applying the same multiplier idea to exports and imports teaches us another important lesson: Booms and recessions tend to be transmitted across national borders. Why is that? Suppose a boom abroad raises GDPs in foreign countries. With rising incomes, foreigners will buy more American goods—which means that U.S. exports will increase. An increase in our exports will, via the multiplier, raise GDP in the United States. By this mechanism, rapid economic growth abroad contributes to rapid economic growth here. And, of course, the same mechanism also oper45 ates in reverse. Thus: C + I1 + G + (X – IM ) C + I0 + G + (X – IM )

Real Expenditure

E1

$200 billion E0

0

6,000

D0

Price Level

The GDPs of the major economies are linked by trade. A boom in one country tends to raise its imports and hence push up exports and GDP in other countries. Similarly, a recession in one country tends to pull down GDP in other countries.

THE MULTIPLIER AND THE AGGREGATE DEMAND CURVE 6,800

D1

E0

E1

100 D1 (I = $1,100) D0 (I = $900)

6,000

6,800 Real GDP

NOTE: Figures are in billions of dollars per year.

One last mechanical point about the multiplier: Recall that income-expenditure diagrams such as Figure 3 can be drawn only for a given price level. Different price levels lead to different total expenditure curves. This means that our oversimplified multiplier formula indicates the increase in real GDP demanded that would occur if the price level were fixed. Graphically, this means that it measures the horizontal shift of the economy’s aggregate demand curve. Figure 12 illustrates this conclusion by supposing that the price level that underlies Figure 3 is P 5 100. The top panel simply repeats Figure 10 and shows how an increase in investment spending from $900 to $1,100 billion leads to an increase in GDP from $6,000 to $6,800 billion. The bottom panel shows two downward-sloping aggregate demand curves. The first, labeled D0D0, depicts

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 26

Demand-Side Equilibrium: Unemployment or Inflation?

575

the situation when investment is $900 billion. Point E0 on this curve corresponds exactly to point E0 in the top panel. It indicates that, at the given price level (P 5 100), the equilibrium quantity of GDP demanded is $6,000 billion. The second aggregate demand curve, D1D1, depicts the situation after investment has risen to $1,100 billion. Point E1 on this curve indicates that the equilibrium quantity of GDP demanded when P 5 100 has risen to $6,800 billion, which corresponds exactly to point E1 in the top panel. As Figure 12 shows, the horizontal distance between the two aggregate demand curves is exactly equal to the increase in real GDP shown in the income-expenditure diagram—in this case, $800 billion. Thus: An autonomous increase in spending leads to a horizontal shift of the aggregate demand curve by an amount given by the oversimplified multiplier formula.

So everything we have just learned about the multiplier applies to shifts of the economy’s aggregate demand curve. If businesses decide to increase their investment spending, if the consumption function shifts upward, or if the government or foreigners decide to buy more goods, then the aggregate demand curve moves horizontally to the right—as indicated in Figure 12. If any of these variables moves downward instead, the aggregate demand curve moves horizontally to the left. Thus, the economy’s aggregate demand curve cannot be expected to stand still for long. Autonomous changes in one or another of the four components of total spending will cause it to move around. But to understand the consequences of such shifts of aggregate demand, we must bring the aggregate supply curve back into the picture. That is the task for the next chapter.

| SUMMARY | 1. The equilibrium level of GDP on the demand side is the level at which total spending just equals production. Because total spending is the sum of consumption, investment, government purchases, and net exports, the condition for equilibrium is Y 5 C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM). 2. Output levels below equilibrium are bound to rise because when spending exceeds output, firms will see their inventory stocks being depleted and will react by stepping up production. 3. Output levels above equilibrium are bound to fall because when total spending is insufficient to absorb total output, inventories will pile up and firms will react by curtailing production. 4. The determination of the equilibrium level of GDP on the demand side can be portrayed on a convenient income-expenditure diagram as the point at which the expenditure schedule—defined as the sum of C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM)—crosses the 45° line. The 45° line is significant because it marks off points at which spending and output are equal—that is, at which Y 5 C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM), which is the basic condition for equilibrium. 5. An income-expenditure diagram can be drawn only for a specific price level. Thus, the equilibrium GDP so determined depends on the price level. 6. Because higher prices reduce the purchasing power of consumers’ wealth, they reduce total expenditures on the 45o line diagram. Equilibrium real GDP demanded is therefore lower when prices are higher. This downward-sloping relationship is known as the aggregate demand curve.

7. Equilibrium GDP can be above or below potential GDP, which is defined as the GDP that would be produced if the labor force were fully employed. 8. If equilibrium GDP exceeds potential GDP, the difference is called an inflationary gap. If equilibrium GDP falls short of potential GDP, the resulting difference is called a recessionary gap. 9. Such gaps can occur because of the problem of coordination failure: The saving that consumers want to do at full-employment income levels may differ from the investing that investors want to do. 10. Any autonomous increase in expenditure has a multiplier effect on GDP; that is, it increases GDP by more than the original increase in spending. 11. The multiplier effect occurs because one person’s additional expenditure constitutes a new source of income for another person, and this additional income leads to still more spending, and so on. 12. The multiplier is the same for an autonomous increase in consumption, investment, government purchases, or net exports. 13. A simple formula for the multiplier says that its numerical value is 1/(1 2 MPC). This formula is too simple to give accurate results, however. 14. Rapid (or sluggish) economic growth in one country contributes to rapid (or sluggish) growth in other countries because one country’s imports are other countries’ exports.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

576

The Macroeconomy: Aggregate Supply and Demand

Part 6

| KEY TERMS | aggregate demand curve

564

expenditure schedule

563

induced investment

autonomous increase in consumption 573

full-employment level of GDP (or potential GDP) 567

inflationary gap

coordination failure

income-expenditure (or 45° line) diagram 564

recessionary gap

568

coordination of saving and investment 567–568 equilibrium

induced increase in consumption 573

560

multiplier

562, 563

567

569 567

Y 5 C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM) 563

| TEST YOURSELF | 1. From the following data, construct an expenditure schedule on a piece of graph paper. Then use the income-expenditure (45° line) diagram to determine the equilibrium level of GDP.

Income

Consumption

Investment

Government Purchases

$3,600 3,700 3,800 3,900 4,000

$3,220 3,310 3,400 3,490 3,580

$240 240 240 240 240

$120 120 120 120 120

Net Exports $40 40 40 40 40

On a piece of graph paper, use these data to construct an aggregate demand curve. Why do you think this example supposes that consumption declines as the price level rises? 4. (More difficult)8 Consider an economy in which the consumption function takes the following simple algebraic form:

C 5 300 1 0.75DI and in which investment (I) is always $900 and net exports are always 2$100. Government purchases are fixed at $1,300 and taxes are fixed at $1,200. Find the equilibrium level of GDP, and then compare your answer to Table 1 and Figure 2. (Hint: Remember that disposable income is GDP minus taxes: DI 5 Y 2 T 5 Y 2 1,200.)

Now suppose investment spending rises to $260, and the price level is fixed. By how much will equilibrium GDP increase? Derive the answer both numerically and graphically.

5. (More difficult) Keep everything the same as in Test Yourself Question 4 except change investment to I 5 $1,100. Use the equilibrium condition Y 5 C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM) to find the equilibrium level of GDP on the demand side. (In working out the answer, assume the price level is fixed.) Compare your answer to Table 3 and Figure 10. Now compare your answer to the answer to Test Yourself Question 4. What do you learn about the multiplier?

2. From the following data, construct an expenditure schedule on a piece of graph paper. Then use the income-expenditure (45° line) diagram to determine the equilibrium level of GDP. Compare your answer with your answer to the previous question.

Income

Consumption

Investment

Government Purchases

Net Exports

$3,600 3,700 3,800 3,900 4,000

$3,280 3,340 3,400 3,460 3,520

$180 210 240 270 300

$120 120 120 120 120

$40 40 40 40 40

6. (More difficult) An economy has the following consumption function:

C 5 200 1 0.8DI The government budget is balanced, with government purchases and taxes both fixed at $1,000. Net exports are $100. Investment is $600. Find equilibrium GDP. What is the multiplier for this economy? If G rises by $100, what happens to Y? What happens to Y if both G and T rise by $100 at the same time?

3. Suppose that investment spending is always $250, government purchases are $100, net exports are always $50, and consumer spending depends on the price level in the following way: Price Level

Consumer Spending

90 95 100 105 110

$740 720 700 680 660

The answer to this question is provided in Appendix A to this chapter.

8

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Demand-Side Equilibrium: Unemployment or Inflation?

Chapter 26

7. Use both numerical and graphical methods to find the multiplier effect of the following shift in the consumption function in an economy in which investment is always $220, government purchases are always $100, and net exports are always 2$40. (Hint: What is the marginal propensity to consume?)

Income

Consumption before Shift

Consumption after Shift

$1,080 1,140 1,200 1,260 1,320 1,380 1,440 1,500 1,560

$ 880 920 960 1,000 1,040 1,080 1,120 1,160 1,200

$ 920 960 1,000 1,040 1,080 1,120 1,160 1,200 1,240

577

| DISCUSSION QUESTIONS | 1. For over 25 years now, imports have consistently exceeded exports in the U.S. economy. Many people consider this imbalance to be a major problem. Does this chapter give you any hints about why? (You may want to discuss this issue with your instructor. You will learn more about it in later chapters.) 2. Look back at the income-expenditure diagram in Figure 3 and explain why some level of real GDP other than $6,000 (say, $5,000 or $7,000) is not an equilibrium on the demand side of the economy. Do not give a

mechanical answer to this question. Explain the economic mechanism involved. 3. Does the economy this year seem to have an inflationary gap or a recessionary gap? (If you do not know the answer from reading the newspaper, ask your instructor.) 4. Try to remember where you last spent a dollar. Explain how this dollar will lead to a multiplier chain of increased income and spending. (Who received the dollar? What will he or she do with it?)

| APPENDIX A | The Simple Algebra of Income Determination and the Multiplier The model of demand-side equilibrium that the chapter presented graphically and in tabular form can also be handled with some simple algebra. Written as an equation, the consumption function in our example is

C 5 300 1 0.75DI 5 300 1 0.75(Y 2 T ) because, by definition, DI 5 Y 2 T. This is simply the equation of a straight line with a slope of 0.75 and an intercept of 300 2 0.75T. Because T 5 1,200 in our example, the intercept is 2600 and the equation can be written more simply as follows:

C 5 2600 1 0.75Y Investment in the example was assumed to be 900, regardless of the level of income, government purchases were 1,300, and net exports were 2100. So the sum C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM) is

C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM) 5 2600 1 0.75Y 1 900 1 1,300 2 100 5 1,500 1 0.75Y This equation describes the expenditure curve in Figure 3. Because the equilibrium quantity of GDP demanded is defined by Y 5 C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM)

we can solve for the equilibrium value of Y by substituting 1,500 1 0.75Y for C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM) to get

Y 5 1,500 1 0.75Y To solve this equation for Y, first subtract 0.75Y from both sides to get

0.25Y 5 1,500 Then divide both sides by 0.25 to obtain the answer:

Y 5 6,000 This, of course, is precisely the solution we found by graphical and tabular methods in the chapter. We can easily generalize this algebraic approach to deal with any set of numbers in our equations. Suppose that the consumption function is as follows:

C 5 a 1 bDI 5 a 1 b(Y 2 T ) (In the example, a 5 300, T 5 1,200, and b 5 0.75.) Then the equilibrium condition that Y 5 C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM) implies that

Y 5 a 1 bDI 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM) 5 a 2 bT 1 bY 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM) Subtracting bY from both sides leads to

(1 2 b)Y 5 a 2 bT 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM)

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

578

Part 6

The Macroeconomy: Aggregate Supply and Demand

and dividing through by 1 2 b gives Y5

By comparing this expression with the previous expression for Y, we see that a one-unit change in any component of spending changes equilibrium GDP by

a 2 bT 1 I 1 G 1 1 X 2 IM 2 12b

This formula is valid for any numerical values of a, b, T, G, I, and (X 2 IM) (so long as b is between 0 and 1). From this formula, it is easy to derive the oversimplified multiplier formula algebraically and to show that it applies equally well to a change in investment, autonomous consumer spending, government purchases, or net exports. To do so, suppose that any of the symbols in the numerator of the multiplier formula increases by one unit. Then GDP would rise from the previous formula to

Y5

a 2 bT 1 I 1 G 1 1 X 2 IM 2 1 1 12b

a 2 bT 1 I 1 G 1 1 X 2 IM 2 1 1 12b a 2 bT 1 I 1 G 1 1 X 2 IM 2 2 12b

Change in Y 5

or Change in Y 5

1 12b

Recalling that b is the marginal propensity to consume, we see that this is precisely the oversimplified multiplier formula.

| TEST YOURSELF | 1. Find the equilibrium level of GDP demanded in an economy in which investment is always $300, net exports are always 2$50, the government budget is balanced with purchases and taxes both equal to $400, and the consumption function is described by the following algebraic equation:

C 5 150 1 0.75DI (Hint: Do not forget that DI 5 Y 2 T.) 2. Referring to Test Yourself Question 1, do the same for an economy in which investment is $250, net exports are zero, government purchases and taxes are both $400, and the consumption function is as follows:

Imagine also that investors want to spend $500 at every level of income (I 5 $500), net exports are zero (X 2 IM 5 0), government purchases are $300, and taxes are $200. a. What is the equilibrium level of GDP? b. If potential GDP is $3,000, is there a recessionary or inflationary gap? If so, how much? c. What will happen to the equilibrium level of GDP if investors become optimistic about the country’s future and raise their investment to $600? d. After investment has increased to $600, is there a recessionary or inflationary gap? How much? 5. Fredonia has the following consumption function:

C 5 250 1 0.5DI 3. In each of these cases, how much saving is there in equilibrium? (Hint: Income not consumed must be saved.) Is saving equal to investment? 4. Imagine an economy in which consumer expenditure is represented by the following equation:

C 5 100 1 0.8DI Firms in Fredonia always invest $700 and net exports are zero, initially. The government budget is balanced with spending and taxes both equal to $500. a. Find the equilibrium level of GDP. b. How much is saved? Is saving equal to investment?

C 5 50 1 0.75DI

c. Now suppose that an export-promotion drive succeeds in raising net exports to $100. Answer (a) and (b) under these new circumstances.

| DISCUSSION QUESTIONS | 1. Explain the basic logic behind the multiplier in words. Why does it require b, the marginal propensity to consume, to be between 0 and 1?

2. (More difficult) What would happen to the multiplier analysis if b 5 0? If b 5 1?

| APPENDIX B | The Multiplier with Variable Imports In the chapter, we assumed that net exports were a fixed number, 2100 in the example. In fact, a nation’s imports vary along with its GDP for a simple reason:

Higher GDP leads to higher incomes, some of which is spent on foreign goods. Thus:

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Demand-Side Equilibrium: Unemployment or Inflation?

Chapter 26

579

that once we recognize the dependence of a nation’s imports on its GDP,

Our imports rise as our GDP rises and fall as our GDP falls.

Similarly, our exports are the imports of other countries, so it is to be expected that our exports depend on their GDPs, not on our own. Thus:

International trade lowers the value of the multiplier.

To see why, we begin with Table 6, which adapts the example of our hypothetical economy to allow imports to depend on GDP. Columns 1 through 4 are the same as in Table 1; they show C, I, and G at alternative levels of GDP. Columns 5 and 6 record revised assumptions about the behavior of exports and imports.

Our exports are relatively insensitive to our own GDP, but are quite sensitive to the GDPs of other countries.

This appendix derives the implications of these rather elementary observations. In particular, it shows TABLE 6 Equilibrium Income with Variable Imports

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

(7)

(8)

Gross Domestic Product (Y)

Consumer Expenditures (C)

Investment (I)

Government Purchases ( G)

Exports (X)

Imports (IM)

Net Exports (X 2 IM)

Total Expenditure (C 1 I 1 G 1 [X 2 IM])

4,800 5,200 5,600 6,000 6,400 6,800 7,200

3,000 3,300 3,600 3,900 4,200 4,500 4,800

900 900 900 900 900 900 900

1,300 1,300 1,300 1,300 1,300 1,300 1,300

650 650 650 650 650 650 650

570 630 690 750 810 870 930

180 120 240 2100 2160 2220 2280

5,280 5,520 5,760 6,000 6,240 6,480 6,720

NOTE: Figures are in billions of dollars per year.

FIGURE 13 The Dependence of Net Exports on GDP IM

Real Exports and Imports

950 850 Negative net exports

750 650 550

X

Positive net exports

450

0

4,800 5,200 5,600 6,000 6,400 6,800 7,200 Real GDP

Real Net Exports

200 100 Positive Positive net net exports exports 0 4,800 5,200 6,000 6,400 6,800 7,200 –100 Negative net 5,600 exports –200 –300

X – IM Real GDP

NOTE: Figures are in billions of dollars per year.

Exports are fixed at $650 billion regardless of GDP. Imports are assumed to rise by $60 billion for every $400 billion rise in GDP, which is a simple numerical example of the idea that imports depend on GDP. Column 7 subtracts imports from exports to get net exports, (X 2 IM), and column 8 adds up the four components of total expenditure, C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM). The equilibrium, you can see, occurs at Y 5 $6,000 billion, just as it did in the chapter. Figures 13 and 14 display the same conclusion graphically. The upper panel of Figure 13 shows that exports are fixed at $650 billion regardless of GDP, whereas imports increase as GDP rises, just as in Table 6. The difference between exports and imports, or net exports, is positive until GDP approaches $5,300 billion, and negative once GDP surpasses that amount. The bottom panel of Figure 13 shows the subtraction explicitly by displaying net exports. It shows clearly that Net exports decline as GDP rises.

Figure 14 carries this analysis over to the 45° line diagram. We begin with the familiar C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM) line in

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

580

Part 6

The Macroeconomy: Aggregate Supply and Demand

FIGURE 14

FIGURE 15

Equilibrium GDP with Variable Imports

The Multiplier with Variable Imports

45

C + I + G + (X0 – IM ) Real Expenditure

Real Expenditure

C + I + G + (X1 – IM )

A

C + I + G + (X – IM ) (variable imports)

E

Positive net exports

45

C + I + G + (X – IM ) (fixed imports) Rise in exports = $160 E

Rise in GDP = $400

Negative net exports 6,000

X – IM 6,000 Real GDP

6,400 Real GDP

TAB LE 7 Equilibrium Income after a $160 Billion Increase in Exports

(1) Gross Domestic Product (Y)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

(7)

(8)

Consumer Expenditures (C)

Investment (I)

Government Purchases (G)

Exports (X)

Imports (IM)

Net Exports (X 2 IM)

Total Expenditure (C 1 I 1 G 1 [X 2 IM])

4,800 5,200 5,600 6,000 6,400 6,800 7,200

3,000 3,300 3,600 3,900 4,200 4,500 4,800

900 900 900 900 900 900 900

1,300 1,300 1,300 1,300 1,300 1,300 1,300

810 810 810 810 810 810 180

570 630 690 750 810 870 930

1240 1180 1120 160 0 260 2120

5,440 5,680 5,920 6,160 6,400 6,640 6,800

NOTE: Figures are in billions of dollars per year.

black. Previously, we simply assumed that net exports were fixed at 2$100 billion regardless of GDP. Now that we have amended our model to note that net exports decline as GDP rises, the sum C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM) rises more slowly than we previously assumed. This change is shown by the brick-colored line. Note that it is less steep than the black line. Let us now consider what happens if exports rise by $160 billion while imports remain as in Table 6. Table 7 shows that equilibrium now occurs at a GDP of Y 5 $6,400 billion. Naturally, higher exports have raised domestic GDP, but consider the magnitude. A $160 billion increase in exports (from $650 billion to $810 billion) leads to an increase of $400 billion in GDP (from $6,000 billion to $6,400 billion). So the multiplier is 2.5 (5 $400/$160).9 EXERCISE: Construct a version of Table 6 to show what would happen if imports rose by $160 billion at every level of GDP and exports remained at $650 billion. You should be able to show that the new equilibrium would be Y 5 $5,600.

9

This same conclusion is shown graphically in Figure 15, where the line C 1 I 1 G 1 (X0 2 IM) represents the original expenditure schedule and the line C 1 I 1 G 1 (X1 2 IM) represents the expenditure schedule after the $160 billion increase in exports. Equilibrium shifts from point E to point A, and GDP rises by $400 billion. Notice that the multiplier in this example is 2.5, whereas in the chapter, with net exports taken to be a fixed number, it was 4. This simple example illustrates a general result: International trade lowers the numerical value of the multiplier. Why is this so? Because, in an open economy, any autonomous increase in spending is partly dissipated in purchases of foreign goods, which creates additional income for foreigners rather than for domestic citizens. Thus, international trade gives us the first of what will eventually be several reasons why the oversimplified multiplier formula overstates the true value of the multiplier.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Demand-Side Equilibrium: Unemployment or Inflation?

Chapter 26

581

| SUMMARY | 1. Because imports rise as GDP rises, while exports are insensitive to (domestic) GDP, net exports decline as GDP rises.

2. If imports depend on GDP, international trade reduces the value of the multiplier.

| TEST YOURSELF | 1. Suppose exports and imports of a country are given by the following: GDP $2,500 3,000 3,500 4,000 4,500 5,000

Exports $400 400 400 400 400 400

shown in the following table, construct a 45° line diagram and locate the equilibrium level of GDP.

Imports GDP $2,500 3,000 3,500 4,000 4,500 5,000

$250 300 350 400 450 500

Domestic Expenditures $3,100 3,400 3,700 4,000 4,300 4,600

Calculate net exports at each level of GDP. 2. If domestic expenditure (the sum of C 1 I 1 G in the economy described in Test Yourself Question 1) is as

3. Now raise exports to $650 and find the equilibrium again. How large is the multiplier?

| DISCUSSION QUESTION | 1. Explain the logic behind the finding that variable imports reduce the numerical value of the multiplier.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Bringing in the Supply Side: Unemployment and Inflation? We might as well reasonably dispute whether it is the upper or the under blade of a pair of scissors that cuts a piece of paper, as whether value is governed by [demand] or [supply]. AL FRED M AR S HA LL

T

he previous chapter taught us that the position of the economy’s total expenditure (C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM)) schedule governs whether the economy will experience a recessionary or an inflationary gap. Too little spending leads to a recessionary gap. Too much leads to an inflationary gap. Which sort of gap actually occurs is of considerable practical importance, because a recessionary gap translates into unemployment whereas an inflationary gap leads to inflation. The tools provided in Chapter 26 cannot tell us which sort of gap will arise because, as we learned, the position of the expenditure schedule depends on the price level—and the price level is determined by both aggregate demand and aggregate supply. So this chapter has a clear task: to bring the supply side of the economy back into the picture. Doing so will put us in a position to deal with the crucial question raised in earlier chapters: Does the economy have an efficient self-correcting mechanism? We shall see that the answer is “yes, but”: Yes, but it works slowly. The chapter will also enable us to explain the vexing problem of stagflation—the simultaneous occurrence of high unemployment and high inflation—which plagued the economy in the 1980s and which some people worry may stage a comeback.

C O N T E N T S PUZZLE: WHAT CAUSES STAGFLATION?

THE AGGREGATE SUPPLY CURVE Why the Aggregate Supply Curve Slopes Upward Shifts of the Aggregate Supply Curve

EQUILIBRIUM OF AGGREGATE DEMAND AND SUPPLY

ADJUSTING TO A RECESSIONIONARY GAP: DEFLATION OR UNEMPLOYMENT? Why Nominal Wages and Prices Won’t Fall (Easily) Does the Economy Have a Self-Correcting Mechanism? An Example from Recent History: Deflation in Japan

INFLATION AND THE MULTIPLIER

ADJUSTING TO AN INFLATIONARY GAP: INFLATION

RECESSIONARY AND INFLATIONARY GAPS REVISITED

Demand Inflation and Stagflation A U.S. Example

STAGFLATION FROM A SUPPLY SHOCK APPLYING THE MODEL TO A GROWING ECONOMY Demand-Side Fluctuations Supply-Side Fluctuations

PUZZLE RESOLVED: EXPLAINING STAGFLATION

A ROLE FOR STABILIZATION POLICY

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

584

Part 6

The Macroeconomy: Aggregate Supply and Demand

PUZZLE:

WHAT CAUSES STAGFLATION?

When the inflation rate briefly topped 5 percent in 2008, the financial press was full of stories about the possible return of the dreaded disease of stagflation, which plagued the U.S. economy in the 1970s and early 1980s. Many economists, however, found this talk unduly alarming. (And, in fact, inflation fell very quickly.) On the surface, the very existence of stagflation—the combination of economic stagnation and inflation—seems to contradict one of our Ideas for Beyond the Final Exam from Chapter 1: there is a trade-off between inflation and unemployment. Low unemployment is supposed to make the inflation rate rise, and high unemployment is supposed to make inflation fall. (This trade-off will be discussed in more detail in Chapter 33.) Yet things do not always work out this way. For example, both unemployment and inflation rose together in the early 1980s and then fell together in the late 1990s. Why is that? What determines whether inflation and unemployment move in opposite directions (as in the trade-off view) or in the same direction (as during a stagflation)? This chapter will provide some answers.

THE AGGREGATE SUPPLY CURVE

The aggregate supply curve shows, for each possible price level, the quantity of goods and services that all the nation’s businesses are willing to produce during a specified period of time, holding all other determinants of aggregate quantity supplied constant.

In earlier chapters, we noted that aggregate demand is a schedule, not a fixed number. The quantity of real gross domestic product (GDP) that will be demanded depends on the price level, as summarized in the economy’s aggregate demand curve. The same point applies to aggregate supply: The concept of aggregate supply does not refer to a fixed number, but rather to a schedule (an aggregate supply curve). The volume of goods and services that profit-seeking enterprises will provide depends on the prices they obtain for their outputs, on wages and other production costs, on the capital stock, on the state of technology, and on other things. The relationship between the price level and the quantity of real GDP supplied, holding all other determinants of quantity supplied constant, is called the economy’s aggregate supply curve. Figure 1 shows a typical aggregate supply curve. It slopes upward, meaning that as prices rise, more output is produced, other things held constant. Let’s see why.

Why the Aggregate Supply Curve Slopes Upward

F I GURE 1

Producers are motivated mainly by profit. The profit made by producing an additional unit of output is simply the difference between the price at which it is sold and the unit cost of production: Unit profit 5 Price 2 Unit cost

An Aggregate Supply Curve

Price Level

S

S

Real GDP

The response of output to a rising price level—which is what the slope of the aggregate supply curve shows—depends on the response of costs. So the question is: Do costs rise along with selling prices, or not? The answer is: Some do, and some do not. Many of the prices that firms pay for labor and other inputs remain fixed for periods of time—although certainly not forever. For example, workers and firms often enter into long-term labor contracts that set nominal wages a year or more in advance. Even where no explicit contracts exist, wage rates typically adjust only annually. Similarly, a variety of material inputs are delivered to firms under long-term contracts at prearranged prices. This fact is significant because firms decide how much to produce by comparing their selling prices with their costs of production. If the selling prices of the firm’s products rise

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 27

Bringing in the Supply Side: Unemployment and Inflation?

while its nominal wages and other factor costs are fixed, production becomes more profitable, and firms will presumably produce more. A simple example will illustrate the idea. Suppose that, given the scale of its operations, a particular firm needs one hour of labor to manufacture one additional gadget. If the gadget sells for $9, workers earn $8 per hour, and the firm has no other costs, its profit on this unit will be Unit profit 5 Price 2 Unit cost

5 $9 2 $8 5 $1 If the price of the gadget then rises to $10, but wage rates remain constant, the firm’s profit on the unit becomes Unit profit 5 Price 2 Unit cost

5 $10 2 $8 5 $2 With production more profitable, the firm presumably will supply more gadgets. The same process operates in reverse. If selling prices fall while input costs remain relatively fixed, profit margins will be squeezed and production cut back. This behavior is summarized by the upward slope of the aggregate supply curve: Production rises when the price level (henceforth, P) rises, and falls when P falls. In other words, The aggregate supply curve slopes upward because firms normally can purchase labor and other inputs at prices that are fixed for some period of time. Thus, higher selling prices for output make production more attractive.1

The phrase “for some period of time” alerts us to the important fact that the aggregate supply curve may not stand still for long. If wages or prices of other inputs change, as they surely will during inflationary times, then the aggregate supply curve will shift.

Shifts of the Aggregate Supply Curve So let’s consider what happens when input prices change.

The Nominal Wage Rate The most obvious determinant of the position of the aggregate supply curve is the nominal wage rate (sometimes called the “money wage rate”). Wages are the major element of cost in the economy, accounting for more than 70 percent of all inputs. Because higher wage rates mean higher costs, they spell lower profits at any given selling prices. That relationship explains why companies have sometimes been known to dig in their heels when workers demand increases in wages and benefits. For example, negotiations between General Motors and the United Auto Workers led to a brief strike in September 2007 because GM felt it had to reduce its labor costs in order to survive. Returning to our example, consider what would happen to a gadget producer if the nominal wage rate rose to $8.75 per hour while the gadget’s price remained $9. Unit profit would decline from $1 to

$9.00 2 $8.75 5 $0.25 With profits thus squeezed, the firm would probably cut back on production. Thus, a wage increase leads to a decrease in aggregate quantity supplied at current prices. Graphically, the aggregate supply curve shifts to the left (or inward) when nominal wages rise, as shown in Figure 2. In this diagram, firms are willing to supply $6,000 billion in goods and services at a price level of 100 when wages are low (point A). But after wages increase, the same firms are willing to supply only $5,500 billion at this

There are both differences and similarities between the aggregate supply curve and the microeconomic supply curves studied in Chapter 4. Both are based on the idea that quantity supplied depends on how output prices move relative to input prices. But the aggregate supply curve pertains to the behavior of the overall price level, whereas a microeconomic supply curve pertains to the price of some particular commodity.

1

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

585

586

Part 6

The Macroeconomy: Aggregate Supply and Demand

price level (point B). By similar reasoning, the aggregate supply curve will shift to the right (or outward) if wages fall.

F I GURE 2 A Shift of the Aggregate Supply Curve

Price Level (P )

S1 (higher wages) S0 (lower wages) B

100

A

An increase in the nominal wage shifts the aggregate supply curve inward, meaning that the quantity supplied at any price level declines. A decrease in the nominal wage shifts the aggregate supply curve outward, meaning that the quantity supplied at any price level increases.

S1

The logic behind these shifts is straightforward. Consider a wage increase, as indicated by the brickcolored line in Figure 2. With selling prices fixed, at 100 5,500 6,000 in the illustration, an increase in the nominal wage Real GDP (Y ) means that wages rise relative to prices. In other words, the real wage rate rises. It is this increase in the firms’ NOTE: Amounts are in billions of dollars per year. real production costs that induces a contraction of quantity supplied—from A to B in the diagram. S0

Prices of Other Inputs

In this regard, wages are not unique. An increase in the price of any input that firms buy will shift the aggregate supply curve in the same way. That is, The aggregate supply curve is shifted to the left (or inward) by an increase in the price of any input to the production process, and it is shifted to the right (or outward) by any decrease.

The logic is exactly the same. Although producers use many inputs other than labor, the one that has attracted the most attention in recent decades is energy. Increases in the prices of imported energy, such as those that took place over most of the period from 2002 to 2008, push the aggregate supply curve inward—as shown in Figure 2. By the same token, decreases in the price of imported oil, such as the ones we enjoyed after oil prices peaked in 2008, shift the aggregate supply curve in the opposite direction—outward.

Technology and Productivity Another factor that can shift the aggregate supply curve Productivity is the amount of output produced by a unit of input.

is the state of technology. The idea that technological progress increases the productivity of labor is familiar from earlier chapters. Holding wages constant, any increase of productivity will decrease business costs, improve profitability, and encourage more production. Once again, our gadget example will help us understand how this process works. Suppose the price of a gadget stays at $9 and the hourly wage rate stays at $8, but gadget workers become more productive. Specifically, suppose the labor input required to manufacture a gadget decreases from one hour (which costs $8) to three-quarters of an hour (which costs just $6). Then unit profit rises from $1 to

$9 2 (3⁄4) $8 5 $9 2 $6 5 $3 The lure of higher profits should induce gadget manufacturers to increase output— which is, of course, why companies constantly strive to raise their productivity. In brief, we have concluded that Improvements in productivity shift the aggregate supply curve outward.

We can therefore interpret Figure 2 as illustrating the effect of a decline in productivity. As we mentioned in Chapter 24, a slowdown in productivity growth was a persistent problem for the United States for more than two decades starting in 1973.

Available Supplies of Labor and Capital The last determinants of the position of the aggregate supply curve are the ones we studied in Chapter 24: The bigger the

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 27

Bringing in the Supply Side: Unemployment and Inflation?

587

economy—as measured by its available supplies of labor and capital—the more it is capable of producing. Thus: As the labor force grows or improves in quality, and as investment increases the capital stock, the aggregate supply curve shifts outward to the right, meaning that more output can be produced at any given price level.

So, for example, the great investment boom of the late 1990s, by boosting the supply of capital, left the U.S. economy with a greater capacity to produce goods and services—that is, it shifted the aggregate supply curve outward. The investment slump of the late 2000s did precisely the reverse. These factors, then, are the major “other things” that we hold constant when drawing an aggregate supply curve: nominal wage rates, prices of other inputs (such as energy), technology, labor force, and capital stock. A change in the price level moves the economy along a given supply curve, but a change in any of these determinants of aggregate quantity supplied shifts the entire supply schedule.

EQUILIBRIUM OF AGGREGATE DEMAND AND SUPPLY

Price Level (P )

Chapter 26 taught us that the price level is a crucial determinant of whether equilibrium GDP falls below full S employment (a “recessionary gap”), precisely at full emD ployment, or above full employment (an “inflationary 130 gap”). We can now analyze which type of gap, if any, will 120 occur in any particular case by combining the aggregate 110 E 100 supply analysis we just completed with the aggregate de90 mand analysis from the last chapter. 80 Figure 3 displays the simple mechanics. In the figure, the D aggregate demand curve DD and the aggregate supply S curve SS intersect at point E, where real GDP (Y) is $6,000 billion and the price level (P) is 100. As can be seen in the 5,200 5,600 6,000 6,400 6,800 graph, at any higher price level, such as 120, aggregate Real GDP (Y ) quantity supplied would exceed aggregate quantity demanded. In such a case, there would be a glut of goods on NOTE: Amounts are in billions of dollars per year. FI GURE 3 the market as firms found themselves unable to sell all their Equilibrium of Real output. As inventories piled up, firms would compete more vigorously for the available GDP and the customers, thereby forcing prices down. Both the price level and production would fall. Price Level At any price level lower than 100, such as 80, quantity demanded would exceed quantity TABLE 1 supplied. There would be a shortage of goods Determination of the Equilibrium Price Level on the market. With inventories disappearing and customers knocking on their doors, firms (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) would be encouraged to raise prices. The price Aggregate Aggregate Balance of Quantity Quantity Supply and Prices level would rise, and so would output. Only Price Level Demanded Supplied Demand will be: when the price level is 100 are the quantities of real GDP demanded and supplied equal. 80 $6,400 $5,600 Demand Rising exceeds supply Therefore, only the combination of P 5 100 and 90 6,200 5,800 Demand Rising Y 5 $6,000 is an equilibrium. exceeds supply Table 1 illustrates this conclusion by using a 100 6,000 6,000 Demand Unchanged tabular analysis similar to the one in the previequals supply ous chapter. Columns (1) and (2) constitute an 110 5,800 6,200 Supply Falling exceeds demand aggregate demand schedule corresponding to 120 5,600 6,400 Supply Falling curve DD in Figure 3. Columns (1) and (3) conexceeds demand stitute an aggregate supply schedule corresponding to aggregate supply curve SS. NOTE: Quantities are in billions of dollars.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

588

Part 6

The Macroeconomy: Aggregate Supply and Demand

The table clearly shows that equilibrium occurs only at P 5 100. At any other price level, aggregate quantities supplied and demanded would be unequal, with consequent upward or downward pressure on prices. For example, at a price level of 90, customers demand $6,200 billion worth of goods and services, but firms wish to provide only $5,800 billion. In this case, the price level is too low and will be forced upward. Conversely, at a price level of 110, quantity supplied ($6,200 billion) exceeds quantity demanded ($5,800 billion), implying that the price level must fall.

INFLATION AND THE MULTIPLIER To illustrate the importance of the slope of the aggregate supply curve, we return to a question we posed in Chapter 26: What happens to equilibrium GDP if the aggregate demand curve shifts outward? We saw in Chapter 26 that such changes have a multiplier effect, and we noted that the actual numerical value of the multiplier is considerably smaller than suggested by the oversimplified multiplier formula. One of the reasons, variable imports, emerged in Appendix B to that chapter. We are now in a position to understand a second reason: Inflation reduces the size of the multiplier.

The basic idea is simple. In Chapter 26, we described a multiplier process in which one person’s spending becomes another person’s income, which leads to further spending by the second person, and so on. But this story was confined to the demand side of the economy; it ignored what is likely to be happening on the supply side. The question is: As the multiplier process unfolds, will firms meet the additional demand without raising prices? If the aggregate supply curve slopes upward, the answer is no. More goods will be provided only at higher prices. Thus, as the multiplier chain progresses, pulling income and employment up, prices will rise, too. This development, as we know from earlier chapters, will reduce net exports and dampen consumer spending because rising prices erode the purchasing power of consumers’ wealth. As a consequence, the multiplier chain will not proceed as far as it would have in the absence of inflation. How much inflation results from a given rise in aggregate demand? How much is the multiplier chain muted by inflation? The answers to these questions depend on the slope of the economy’s aggregate supply curve. For a concrete example, let us return to the $200 billion increase in investment spending used in Chapter 26. There we found (see especially Figure 10 on page 570) that $200 billion in additional investment spending would eventually lead to $800 billion in additional spending if the price level did not rise—that is, it tacitly assumed that the aggregate supply curve was horizontal. That is not so. The slope of the aggregate supply curve tells us how any expansion of aggregate demand gets apportioned between higher output and higher prices. In our example, Figure 4 shows the $800-billion rightward shift of the aggregate demand curve, from D0D0 to D1D1, that we derived from the oversimplified multiplier formula in Chapter 26. We see that, as the economy’s equilibrium moves from point E0 to point E1, real GDP does not rise by $800 billion. Instead, prices rise, cancelling out part of the increase in quantity demanded. As a result, output rises from $6,000 billion to $6,400 billion—an increase of only $400 billion. Thus, in the example, inflation reduces the multiplier from $800/$200 5 4 to $400/$200 5 2. In general: As long as the aggregate supply curve slopes upward, any increase in aggregate demand will push up the price level. Higher prices, in turn, will drain off some of the higher real demand by eroding the purchasing power of consumer wealth and by reducing net exports. Thus, inflation reduces the value of the multiplier below what is suggested by the oversimplified formula.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 27

589

Bringing in the Supply Side: Unemployment and Inflation?

Notice also that the price level in this example has been pushed up (from 100 to 120, or by 20 percent) by the rise in investment demand. This, too, is a general result:

FIGURE 4 Inflation and the Multiplier

As long as the aggregate supply curve slopes upward, any outward shift of the aggregate demand curve will increase the price level. D

Price Level (P )

1 The economic behavior behind these results is certainly not surprising. Firms faced with large increases in quanD0 tity demanded at their original prices respond to these $800 130 changed circumstances in two natural ways: They raise billion E1 120 production (so that real GDP rises), and they raise prices 110 E0 A (so the price level rises). This rise in the price level, in turn, 100 90 reduces the purchasing power of the bank accounts and 80 bonds held by consumers, and they, too, react in the natural way: They reduce their spending. Such a reaction D0 S amounts to a movement along aggregate demand curve D1D1 in Figure 4 from point A to point E1. 6,000 6,400 6,800 Figure 4 also shows us exactly where the oversimplified multiplier formula goes wrong. By ignoring the efReal GDP (Y ) fects of the higher price level, the oversimplified formula erroneously pretends that the economy moves horizonNOTE: Amounts are in billions of dollars per year. tally from point E0 to point A—which it will not do unless the aggregate supply curve is horizontal. As the diagram clearly shows, output actually rises by less, which is one reason why the oversimplified formula exaggerates the size of the multiplier.

RECESSIONARY AND INFLATIONARY GAPS REVISITED With this understood, let us now reconsider the question we have been deferring: Will equilibrium occur at, below, or beyond potential GDP? We could not answer this question in Chapter 9 because we had no way to determine the equilibrium price level, and therefore no way to tell which type of gap, if any, would arise. The aggregate supply-and-demand analysis presented in this chapter now gives us what we need, but we find that our answer is still the same: Anything can happen. The reason is that Figure 3 tells us nothing about where potential GDP falls. The factors determining the economy’s capacity to produce were discussed extensively in Chapter 24, but that analysis could leave potential GDP above the $6,000 billion equilibrium level or below it. Depending on the locations of the aggregate demand and aggregate supply curves, then, we can reach equilibrium beyond potential GDP (an inflationary gap), at potential GDP, or below potential GDP (a recessionary gap). All three possibilities are illustrated in Figure 5. The three upper panels duplicate diagrams that we encountered in Chapter 26.2 Start with the upper-middle panel, in which the expenditure schedule C 1 I1 1 G 1 (X 2 IM) crosses the 45o line exactly at potential GDP—which we take to be $7,000 billion in the example. Equilibrium is at point E, with neither a recessionary nor an inflationary gap. Now suppose that total expenditures either fall to C 1 I0 1 G 1 (X 2 IM) (producing the upperleft diagram) or rise to C 1 I2 1 G 1 (X 2 IM) (producing the upper-right diagram). As we read across the page from left to right, we see equilibrium occurring with a recessionary gap, exactly at full employment, or with an inflationary gap—depending on the position 2 Recall that each income-expenditure diagram considers only the demand side of the economy by treating the price level as fixed.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

S

D1

590

Part 6

The Macroeconomy: Aggregate Supply and Demand

F IGURE 5 Recessionary and Inflationary Gaps Revisited

Potential GDP

Potential GDP

Potential GDP 45°

45°

45°

Real Expenditure

B Inflationary gap

C + I0 + G + (X – IM)

E B

6,000

E

C + I2 + G + (X – IM)

C + I1 + G + (X – IM)

Recessionary gap

7,000 Real GDP

7,000 Real GDP

7,000 Real GDP

Potential GDP

Potential GDP

Potential D2 GDP B

Price Level

D1 D0

E

Inflationary gap

E

B

8,000

S

S

E

E

S D2

Recessionary gap D1

S

S

S

D0 6,000

7,000 Real GDP

7,000 Real GDP

7,000 Real GDP

8,000

NOTE: Real GDP is in billions of dollars per year.

of the C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM) line. In Chapter 26, we learned of several variables that might shift the expenditure schedule up and down in this way. One of them was the price level. The three lower panels portray the same three cases differently—in a way that can tell us what the price level will be. These diagrams consider both aggregate demand and aggregate supply, and therefore determine both the equilibrium price level and the equilibrium GDP at point E—the intersection of the aggregate supply curve SS and the aggregate demand curve DD. However, there are still three possibilities. In the lower-left panel, aggregate demand is too low to provide jobs for the entire labor force, so we have a recessionary gap equal to distance EB, or $1,000 billion. This situation corresponds precisely to the one depicted on the income-expenditure diagram immediately above it. In the lower-right panel, aggregate demand is so high that the economy reaches an equilibrium beyond potential GDP. An inflationary gap equal to BE, or $1,000 billion, arises, just as in the diagram immediately above it.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 27

591

Bringing in the Supply Side: Unemployment and Inflation?

In the lower-middle panel, the aggregate demand curve D1D1 is at just the right level to produce an equilibrium at potential GDP. Neither an inflationary gap nor a recessionary gap occurs, as in the diagram just above it. It may seem, therefore, that we have simply restated our previous conclusions. But, in fact, we have done much more. For now that we have studied the determination of the equilibrium price level, we are able to examine how the economy adjusts to either a recessionary gap or an inflationary gap. Specifically, because wages are fixed in the short run, any one of the three cases depicted in Figure 5 can occur. In the long run, however, wages will adjust to labor market conditions, which will shift the aggregate supply curve. It is to that adjustment that we now turn.

ADJUSTING TO A RECESSIONARY GAP: DEFLATION OR UNEMPLOYMENT?

Price Level (P )

Suppose the economy starts with a recessionary gap—that is, an equilibrium below potential GDP—as depicted in the lower-left panel of Figure 5. Such a situation might be caused, for example, by inadequate consumer spending or by anemic investment spending. When the recent recession started at the end of 2007, the United States economy was pretty close to full employment. Then the recessionary gap began to grow, reaching a peak estimated to be 8 to 9 percent of GDP by late 2009—the biggest gap this country has seen since the early 1980s. What happens when an economy experiences such a recessionary gap? With equilibrium GDP below potential (point E in Figure 6), jobs will be difficult to find. The ranks of the unemployed will exceed the number of people who are jobless because of moving, changing occupations, and so on. In the terminology of Chapter 23, the economy will experience a considerable amount of cyclical unemployment. Businesses, by contrast, will have little trouble finding workers, and their current employees will be eager to hang on to their jobs. Such an environment makes it difficult for workers to win wage increases. Indeed, in extreme situations, wages may even fall—thereby shifting the aggregate supply curve outward. (Remember: An aggregate supply curve is drawn for a given nominal wage.) But as the aggregate supply curve shifts to the right—eventually moving from S0S0 to S1S1 in FI GURE 6 Figure 6—prices decline and the recessionary gap shrinks. By this process, deflation gradually erodes the recessionary gap—leading eventually to an equilibrium at potential GDP The Elimination of a Recessionary Gap (point F in Figure 6). There is an important catch. In our modern economy, this adjustment process proceeds slowly—painfully Potential slowly. Our brief review of the historical record in ChapGDP ter 22 showed that the history of the United States includes several examples of deflation before World War II S0 but none since then. Not even severe recessions have S1 forced average prices and wages down except fleetingly, although they have certainly slowed their rates of increase D to a crawl. The only protracted episode of deflation in an advanced economy since the 1930s is the experience of E B Japan over roughly the last decade, and even there the 100 Recessionary rate of deflation has been quite mild. F

Why Nominal Wages and Prices Won’t Fall (Easily) Exactly why wages and prices rarely fall in a modern economy is still a subject of intense debate among economists. Some economists emphasize institutional factors such as minimum wage laws, union contracts, and a variety of

S0

gap D

S1 5,000

6,000 Real GDP (Y )

NOTE: Amounts are in billions of dollars per year.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

592

Part 6

The Macroeconomy: Aggregate Supply and Demand

government regulations that place legal floors under particular wages and prices. Because most of these institutions are of recent vintage, this theory successfully explains why wages and prices fall less frequently now than they did before World War II. Only a small minority of the U.S. economy is subject to legal restraints on wage and price cutting. So it seems doubtful that legal restrictions take us very far in explaining sluggish wage-price adjustments in the United States. In Europe, however, these institutional factors may be more important. Other observers suggest that workers have a profound psychological resistance to accepting a wage reduction. This theory has roots in psychological research that finds people to be far more aggrieved when they suffer an absolute loss (e.g., a nominal wage reduction) than when they receive only a small gain. So, for example, businesses may find it relatively easy to cut the rate of wage increase from 3 percent to 1 percent, but excruciatingly hard to cut it from 1 percent to minus 1 percent. This psychological theory has the ring of truth. Think how you might react if your boss announced he was cutting your hourly wage rate. You might quit, or you might devote less care to your job. If the boss suspects you will react this way, he may be reluctant to cut your wage. Nowadays, genuine wage reductions are rare enough to be newsworthy. Although no one doubts that wage cuts can damage morale, the psychological theory still must explain why the resistance to wage cuts apparently started only after World War II. A third explanation is based on a fact we emphasized in Chapter 22—that business cycles have been less severe in the postwar period than they were in the prewar period. As workers and firms came to realize that recessions would not turn into depressions, the argument goes, they decided to wait out the bad times rather than accept wage or price reductions that they would later regret. Yet another theory is based on the old adage, “You get what you pay for.” The idea is that workers differ in productivity but that the productivities of individual employees are difficult to identify. Firms therefore worry that they will lose their best employees if they reduce wages—because these workers have the best opportunities elsewhere in the economy. Rather than take this chance, the argument goes, firms prefer to maintain high wages even in recessions. Other theories also have been proposed, none of which commands a clear majority of professional opinion. Regardless of the cause, we may as well accept it as a well-established fact that wages fall only sluggishly, if at all, when demand is weak. The implications of this rigidity are quite serious, for a recessionary gap cannot cure itself without some deflation. And if wages and prices will not fall, recessionary gaps like EB in Figure 6 will linger for a long time. That is, When aggregate demand is low, the economy may get stuck with a recessionary gap for a long time. If wages and prices fall very slowly, the economy will endure a prolonged period of production below potential GDP.

Does the Economy Have a Self-Correcting Mechanism? Now a situation like that described earlier would, presumably, not last forever. As the recession lengthened and perhaps deepened, more and more workers would be unable to find jobs at the prevailing “high” wages. Eventually, their need to be employed would overwhelm their resistance to wage cuts. Firms, too, would become increasingly willing to cut prices as the period of weak demand persisted and managers became convinced that the slump was not merely a temporary aberration. Prices and wages did, in fact, fall in many countries during the Great Depression of the 1930s, and they have fallen in Japan for about a decade, albeit very slowly. Thus, starting from any recessionary gap, the economy will eventually return to potential GDP—following a path something like the brick-colored arrow from E to F in Figure 6. For this reason, some economists think of the vertical line at potential GDP as representing the economy’s long-run aggregate supply curve, but this “long run” might be long indeed.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 27

593

Bringing in the Supply Side: Unemployment and Inflation?

Nowadays, political leaders of both parties—and in virtually all countries—believe that it is folly to wait for falling wages and prices to eliminate a recessionary gap. They agree that government action is both necessary and appropriate under recessionary conditions. Nevertheless, vocal—and highly partisan—debate continues over how much and what kind of intervention is warranted, as became abundantly clear in this country in 2008 and 2009. One reason for the disagreement is that the self-correcting mechanism does operate—if only weakly—to cure recessionary gaps.

An Example from Recent History: Deflation in Japan The world’s second-largest economy, Japan, is the only recent example of very long-lasting recessionary gaps. The Japanese economy has been weak for most of the period since the early 1990s—including several recessions. As a result, Japan has experienced persistent recessionary gaps for over 15 years. Unsurprisingly, Japan’s modest inflation rate of the early 1990s evaporated and, from 1999 through 2009, turned into a small deflation rate. Qualitatively, this is just the sort of behavior the theoretical model of the self-correcting mechanism predicts. But it took a long time! Hence, the practical policy question is: How long can a country afford to wait?

The economy’s self-correcting mechanism refers to the way money wages react to either a recessionary gap or an inflationary gap. Wage changes shift the aggregate supply curve and therefore change equilibrium GDP and the equilibrium price level.

ADJUSTING TO AN INFLATIONARY GAP: INFLATION

Price Level (P )

Let us now turn to what happens when the economy finds itself beyond full employment—that is, with an inflationary gap like that shown in Figure 7. When the aggregate supply curve is S0S0 and the aggregate demand curve is DD, the economy will initially reach equilibrium (point E) with an inflationary gap, shown by the segment BE. According to some economists, a situation like this arose in the United States in 2006 and 2007 when the unemployment rate dipped below 5 percent. What should happen under such circumstances? As we shall see now, the tight labor market should produce an inflation that eventually eliminates the inflationary gap, although perhaps in a slow and painful way. Let us see how. When equilibrium GDP exceeds potential GDP, jobs are plentiful and labor is in great demand. Firms are likely to have trouble recruiting new workers or even holding onto their old ones as other firms try to lure workers away with higher wages. FI GURE 7 Rising nominal wages add to business costs, which shift the aggregate supply curve to The Elimination of an the left. As the aggregate supply curve moves from S0S0 to S1S1 in Figure 7, the inflationInflationary Gap ary gap shrinks. In other words, inflation eventually erodes the inflationary gap and brings the economy to an equilibrium at potential GDP (point F). Potential There is a straightforward way of looking at the ecoGDP S1 nomics underlying this process. Inflation arises because buyers are demanding more output than the economy can D produce at normal operating rates. To paraphrase an old S0 cliché, there is too much demand chasing too little supply. Such an environment encourages price hikes. Ultimately, rising prices eat away at the purchasing F power of consumers’ wealth, forcing them to cut back on E consumption, as explained in Chapter 25. In addition, exB ports fall and imports rise, as we learned in Chapter 26. Eventually, aggregate quantity demanded is scaled back to S1 the economy’s capacity to produce—graphically, the econD Inflationary omy moves back along curve DD from point E to point F. gap S0 At this point the self-correcting process stops. In brief: If aggregate demand is exceptionally high, the economy may reach a short-run equilibrium above full employment

Real GDP (Y )

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

594

Part 6

The Macroeconomy: Aggregate Supply and Demand

(an inflationary gap). When this occurs, the tight situation in the labor market soon forces nominal wages to rise. Because rising wages increase business costs, prices increase; there is inflation. As higher prices cut into consumer purchasing power and net exports, the inflationary gap begins to close. As the inflationary gap closes, output falls and prices continue to rise. When the gap is finally eliminated, a long-run equilibrium is established with a higher price level and with GDP equal to potential GDP.

This scenario is precisely what some economists believe happened in 2006 and 2007. Because they believed that the U.S. economy had a small inflationary gap in 2006 and 2007, they expected inflation to rise slightly—which it did, before receding again. Remember once again that the self-correcting mechanism takes time because wages and prices do not adjust quickly. Thus, although an inflationary gap sows the seeds of its own destruction, the seeds germinate slowly. So, once again, policy makers may want to speed up the process.

Demand Inflation and Stagflation

Stagflation is inflation that occurs while the economy is growing slowly or having a recession.

Simple as it is, this model of how the economy adjusts to an inflationary gap teaches us a number of important lessons about inflation in the real world. First, Figure 7 reminds us that the real culprit is an excess of aggregate demand relative to potential GDP. The aggregate demand curve is initially so high that it intersects the aggregate supply curve beyond full employment. The resulting intense demand for goods and labor pushes prices and wages higher. Although aggregate demand in excess of potential GDP is not the only possible cause of inflation, it certainly is the cause in our example. Nonetheless, business managers and journalists may blame inflation on rising wages. In a superficial sense, of course, they are right, because higher wages do indeed lead firms to raise product prices, but in a deeper sense they are wrong. Both rising wages and rising prices are symptoms of the same underlying malady: too much aggregate demand. Blaming labor for inflation in such a case is a bit like blaming high doctor bills for making you ill. Second, notice that output falls while prices rise as the economy adjusts from point E to point F in Figure 7. This is our first (but not our last) explanation of the phenomenon of stagflation—the conjunction of inflation and economic stagnation. Specifically: A period of stagflation is part of the normal aftermath of a period of excessive aggregate demand.

It is easy to understand why. When aggregate demand is excessive, the economy will temporarily produce beyond its normal capacity. Labor markets tighten and wages rise. Machinery and raw materials may also become scarce and so start rising in price. Faced with higher costs, business firms quite naturally react by producing less and charging higher prices. That is stagflation.

A U.S. Example The stagflation that follows a period of excessive aggregate demand is, you will note, a rather benign form of the dreaded disease. After all, while output is falling, it nonetheless remains above potential GDP, and unemployment is low. The U.S. economy last experienced such an episode at the end of the 1980s. The long economic expansion of the 1980s brought the unemployment rate down to a 15-year low of 5 percent by March 1989. Almost all economists believed at the time that 5 percent was below the full-employment unemployment rate, that is, that the U.S. economy had an inflationary gap. As the theory suggests, inflation began to accelerate—from 4.4 percent in 1988 to 4.6 percent in 1989 and then to 6.1 percent in 1990. In the meantime, the economy was stagnating. Real GDP growth fell from 3.5 percent during 1989 to 1.8 percent in 1990 and down to 20.5 percent in 1991. Inflation was eating away at the inflationary gap, which had virtually disappeared by mid-1990, when the

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 27

Bringing in the Supply Side: Unemployment and Inflation?

Timing matters in life. The college graduates of 2007 were pretty fortunate. The unemployment rate was a low 4.5 percent in May and June of that year—close to its lowest level in a generation. With employers on the prowl for new hires, starting salaries rose and many graduating seniors had numerous job offers. Things were not nearly that good for the Class of 2009 when it hit the job market just two years later. The U.S. economy was in a deep recession, and job offers were scarce. The unemployment rate in May–June 2009 averaged 9.5 percent. Most companies were less than eager to hire more workers, salary increases were modest, and “perks” were being trimmed. This accident of birth meant that the college grads of 2009 started their working careers in a less advantageous position than their more fortunate brothers and sisters two years earlier. What’s more, recent research suggests that the initial job market advantage of the Class of 2007, compared to the Class of 2009, is likely to be maintained for many years.

SOURCE: © Creatas Images/Jupiterimages

A Tale of Two Graduating Classes: 2007 versus 2009

recession started. Yet inflation remained high through the early months of the recession. The U.S. economy was in a stagflation phase. Our overall conclusion about the economy’s ability to right itself seems to run something like this: The economy does, indeed, have a self-correcting mechanism that tends to eliminate either unemployment or inflation. But this mechanism works slowly and unevenly. In addition, its beneficial effects on either inflation or unemployment are sometimes swamped by strong forces pushing in the opposite direction (such as rapid increases or decreases in aggregate demand). Thus, the self-correcting mechanism is not always reliable.

STAGFLATION FROM A SUPPLY SHOCK We have just discussed the type of stagflation that follows in the wake of an inflationary boom. However, that is not what happened when unemployment and inflation both soared in the 1970s and early 1980s. What caused this more virulent strain of stagflation? Several things, though the principal culprit was rising energy prices. In 1973, the Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC) quadrupled the price of crude oil. American consumers soon found the prices of gasoline and home heating fuels increasing sharply, and U.S. businesses saw an important cost of doing business— energy prices—rising drastically. OPEC struck again in the period 1979–1980, this time doubling the price of oil. Then the same thing happened again, albeit on a smaller scale, when Iraq invaded Kuwait in 1990. More recently, oil prices went on an irregular upward climb from 2002 to 2008 because of the Iraq war, other political issues in the Middle East and elsewhere, problems with refining capacity, and surging energy demand from China. Higher energy prices, we observed earlier, shift the economy’s aggregate supply curve inward in the manner shown in Figure 8. If the aggregate supply curve shifts inward, as it surely did following each of these “oil shocks,” production will decline. To reduce demand to the available supply, prices will have to rise. The result is the worst of both worlds: falling production and rising prices. This conclusion is displayed graphically in Figure 8, which shows an aggregate demand curve, DD, and two aggregate supply curves. When the supply curve shifts inward, the economy’s equilibrium shifts from point E to point A. Thus, output falls while prices

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

595

596

Part 6

The Macroeconomy: Aggregate Supply and Demand

rise, which is precisely our definition of stagflation. In sum:

F I GURE 8 Stagflation from an Adverse Shift in Aggregate Supply

Price Level (2005 = 100)

Stagflation is the typical result of adverse shifts of the aggregate supply curve.

S1 S0

D A 33.6 E

28.1

D S1 S0 4,880

4,917

Real GDP NOTE: Amounts are in billions of 2005 dollars per year.

The numbers used in Figure 8 are meant to indicate what the big energy shock in late 1973 might have done to the U.S. economy. Between 1973 (represented by supply curve S0S0 and point E) and 1975 (represented by supply curve S1S1 and point A), it shows real GDP falling by about 1.1 percent, whereas the price level rises more than 19 percent over the two years. The general lesson to be learned from the U.S. experience with supply shocks is both clear and important: The typical results of an adverse supply shock are lower output and higher inflation. This is one reason why the world economy was plagued by stagflation in the mid-1970s and early 1980s. And it can happen again if another series of supply-reducing events takes place.

APPLYING THE MODEL TO A GROWING ECONOMY You may have noticed that ever since Chapter 22 we have been using the simple aggregate supply and aggregate demand model to determine the equilibrium price level and the equilibrium level of real GDP, as depicted in several graphs in this chapter. In the real world, neither the price level nor real GDP remains constant for long. Instead, both normally rise from one year to the next. The growth process is illustrated in Figure 9, which is a scatter diagram of the U.S. price level and the level of real GDP for every year from 1972 to 2009. The labeled points show the clear upward march of the economy through time—toward higher prices and higher levels of output.

Why Was There No Stagflation in 2006–2008? flexible. However, in the view of most researchers who have studied the question, part of the story is plain old good luck. Naturally, we cannot expect good luck to continue forever. Finally, it can be argued that we did have a little bit of stagflation. In late 2007 and early 2008, growth slowed sharply and inflation rose.

SOURCE: © Creatas Images/Jupiterimages

As noted earlier, oil prices climbed steeply, if irregularly, from early 2002 through mid-2008. Yet this succession of “oil shocks” seems not to have caused much, if any, stagflation in the United States or in other industrial economies. This recent experience stands in sharp contrast to the 1970s and early 1980s. What has been different this time around? In truth, economists do not have a complete answer to this question, and research on it continues. But we do understand a few things. Most straightforwardly, the world has learned to live with less energy (relative to GDP). In the United States and many other countries, for example, the energy content of $1 worth of GDP is now only about half of what it was in the 1970s. That alone cuts the impact of an oil shock in half. In addition, for reasons that are not entirely understood, the United States and other economies seem to have become less volatile since the mid-1980s. Sound macroeconomic policies have probably contributed to the reduction in volatility, and so have a variety of structural changes that have made these economies more

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

597

Bringing in the Supply Side: Unemployment and Inflation?

Chapter 27

120 110

Price Level (GDP deflator) (2005 = 100)

100 90 80 70 60 50 40 30

2009

2008 2007 2005 2006 2001 2003 S 2004 D 1999 2002 1995 1997 2000 1993 1992 1996 1998 1991 1994 S S D D 1986 1988 1989 1990 1984 1987 1983 1985 1982 S D 1981 1980 1979 1977 1978 1975 1976 1974 1973 1972

20 4,000

5,000

6,000

7,000

8,000

9,000

10,000

11,000

12,000

13,000

14,000

Real GDP in Billions of 2005 Dollars

FI GURE 9

SOURCE: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis.

FIGURE 10 Aggregate Supply and Demand Analysis of a Growing Economy S0 S1

Price Level (P ) (2005 = 100)

This upward trend is hardly mysterious, for both the aggregate demand curve and the aggregate supply curve normally shift to the right each year. Aggregate supply grows because more workers join the workforce each year and because investment and technology improve productivity (Chapter 24). Aggregate demand grows because a growing population generates more demand for both consumer and investment goods and because the government increases its purchases (Chapters 25 and 26). We can think of each point in Figure 9 as the intersection of an aggregate supply curve and an aggregate demand curve for that particular year. To help you visualize this idea, the curves for 1984 and 1993 are sketched in the diagram. Figure 10 is a more realistic version of the aggregate supply-and-demand diagram that illustrates how our theoretical model applies to a growing economy. We have chosen the numbers so that the black curves D0D0 and S0S0 roughly represent the year 2005, and the brick-colored curves D1D1 and S1S1 roughly represent 2006—except that we use nice round numbers to facilitate computations. Thus, the equilibrium in 2005 was at point A, with a real GDP of $12,620 billion (in 2005 dollars) and a price level of 100. A year later, D1 the equilibrium was at point B, with real GDP at $13,000 billion and the price level at 103. The blue arrow in the diagram shows how equilibrium moved from D0 B 103 2005 to 2006. It points upward and to the right, meaning that both prices and output increased. In this case, the economy A 100 grew by 3 percent and prices also rose about 3 percent, which is close to what actually happened in the United States S0 over that year.

The Price Level and Real GDP Output in the United States, 1972–2009

D1

S1

Demand-Side Fluctuations Let us now use our theoretical model to rewrite history. Suppose that aggregate

D0 12,620 13,000 Real GDP (Y ) in Billions of 2005 Dollars

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

598

The Macroeconomy: Aggregate Supply and Demand

Part 6

D2 S0 S1 C

Price Level (P ) (2005 = 100)

106 D2 D0 A 100 S0 S1 D0 12,620 13,250 Real GDP (Y ) in Billions of 2005 Dollars

FIGURE 11 The Effects of Faster Growth of Aggregate Demand

demand grew faster than it actually did between 2005 and 2006. What difference would this have made to the performance of the U.S. economy? Figure 11 provides answers. Here the black demand curve D0D0 is exactly the same as in the previous diagram, as are the two supply curves, indicating a given rate of aggregate supply growth. But the brick-colored demand curve D2D2 lies farther to the right than the demand curve D1D1 in Figure 10. Equilibrium is at point A in 2005 and point C in 2006. Comparing point C in Figure 11 with point B in Figure 10, you can see that both output and prices would have increased more over the year—that is, the economy would have experienced faster growth and more inflation. This is generally what happens when the growth rate of aggregate demand speeds up.

For any given growth rate of aggregate supply, a faster growth rate of aggregate demand will lead to more inflation and faster growth of real output.

Figure 12 illustrates the opposite case. Here we imagine that the aggregate demand curve shifted out less than in Figure 10. That is, the brick-colored demand curve D3D3 in Figure 12 lies to the left of the demand curve D1D1 in Figure 10. The consequence, we see, is that the shift of the economy’s equilibrium from 2005 to 2006 (from point A to point E) would have entailed less inflation and slower growth of real output than actually took place. Again, that is generally the case when aggregate demand grows more slowly. For any given growth rate of aggregate supply, a slower growth rate of aggregate demand will lead to less inflation and slower growth of real output.

Putting these two findings together gives us a clear prediction: If fluctuations in the economy’s real growth rate from year to year arise primarily from variations in the rate at which aggregate demand increases, then the data should show the most rapid inflation occurring when output grows most rapidly and the slowest inflation occurring when output grows most slowly.

FIGURE 12 The Effects of Slower Growth of Aggregate Demand

S0 D3 S1

Price Level (P ) (2005 = 100)

D0

A

100.5 100

Is it true? For the most part, yes. Our brief review of U.S. economic history back in Chapter 22 found that most episodes of high inflation came with rapid growth. But not all. Some surges of inflation resulted from the kinds of supply shocks we have considered in this chapter.

E

Supply-Side Fluctuations S0

D3

S1 D0 12,620 12,800 Real GDP (Y ) in Billions of 2005 Dollars

As an historical example, let’s return to the events of 1973 to 1975 that were depicted in Figure 8. But now let’s add in something we ignored there: While the aggregate supply curve was shifting inward because of the oil shock, the aggregate demand was shifting outward.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

599

Bringing in the Supply Side: Unemployment and Inflation?

Chapter 27

FIGURE 13 Stagflation from an Adverse Supply Shock

Price Level (P ) (2005 = 100)

In Figure 13, the black aggregate demand curve D0D0 and aggregate S1 supply curve S0S0 represent the economic situation in 1973. EquiD1 librium was at point E, with a price B 33.6 level of 28.1 (based on 2005 = 100) S0 D0 and real output of $4,917 billion. D1 By 1975, the aggregate demand E 28.1 curve had shifted out to the posiS1 tion indicated by the brick-colored D0 curve D1D1, but the aggregate supply curve had shifted inward from S0 S0S0 to the brick-colored curve S1S1. The equilibrium for 1975 (point B in the figure) therefore 4,880 4,917 wound up to the left of the equilibReal GDP (Y ) in Billions of 2005 Dollars rium point for 1973 (point E in the figure). Real output declined slightly (although less than in Figure 8) and prices—led by energy costs—rose rapidly (more than in Figure 8). What about the opposite case? Suppose the economy experiences a favorable supply shock, as it did in the late 1990s, so that the aggregate supply curve shifts outward at an unusually rapid rate. Figure 14 depicts the consequences. The aggregate demand curve shifts out from D0D0 to D1D1 as usual, but the aggregate supply curve shifts all the way out to S1S1. (The dotted line indicates what would happen in a “normal” year.) So the economy’s equilibrium winds up at point B rather than at point C. Compared to C, point B represents faster economic growth (B is to the right of C) and lower inflation (B is lower than C). In brief, the economy wins on both fronts: inflation falls while GDP grows rapidly, as happened in the late 1990s. Combining these two cases, we conclude that If fluctuations in economic activity emanate mainly from the supply side, higher rates of inflation will be associated with lower rates of economic growth.

FIGURE 14 S0

D1 D0

Nor mal growth of aggregate supply S1

The Effects of a Favorable Supply Shock

Price Level (P )

C A

Effect of favorable supply shock

B

D1

S0 S1

D0 Real GDP (Y )

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

600

Part 6

The Macroeconomy: Aggregate Supply and Demand

PUZZLE RESOLVED:

EXPLAINING STAGFLATION

What we have learned in this chapter helps us to understand why the U.S. economy performed so poorly in the 1970s and early 1980s, when both unemployment and inflation rose together. The OPEC cartel first flexed its muscles in 1973–1974, when it quadrupled the price of oil, thereby precipitating the first bout of serious stagflation in the United States and other oil-importing nations. Then OPEC struck again in 1979–1980, this time doubling the price of oil, and stagflation returned. Unlucky? Yes. But mysterious? No. What was happening was that the economy’s aggregate supply curve was shifted inward by the rising price of energy, rather than moving outward from one year to the next, as it normally does. Unfavorable supply shocks tend to push unemployment and inflation up at the same time. It was mainly unfavorable supply shocks that accounted for the stunningly poor economic performance of the 1970s and early 1980s.3

A ROLE FOR STABILIZATION POLICY Chapter 25 emphasized the volatility of investment spending, and Chapter 26 noted that changes in investment have multiplier effects on aggregate demand. This chapter took the next step by showing how shifts in the aggregate demand curve cause fluctuations in both real GDP and prices—fluctuations that are widely decried as undesirable. It also suggested that the economy’s self-correcting mechanism works, but slowly, thereby leaving room for government stabilization policy to improve the workings of the free market. Can the government really accomplish this goal? If so, how? These are some of the important questions for Part 7.

| SUMMARY | 1. The economy’s aggregate supply curve relates the quantity of goods and services that will be supplied to the price level. It normally slopes upward to the right because the costs of labor and other inputs remain relatively fixed in the short run, meaning that higher selling prices make input costs relatively cheaper and therefore encourage greater production. 2. The position of the aggregate supply curve can be shifted by changes in money wage rates, prices of other inputs, technology, or quantities or qualities of labor and capital. 3. The equilibrium price level and the equilibrium level of real GDP are jointly determined by the intersection of the economy’s aggregate supply and aggregate demand schedules. 4. Among the reasons why the oversimplified multiplier formula is wrong is the fact that it ignores the inflation that is caused by an increase in aggregate demand. Such

inflation decreases the multiplier by reducing both consumer spending and net exports. 5. The equilibrium of aggregate supply and demand can come at full employment, below full employment (a recessionary gap), or above full employment (an inflationary gap). 6. The economy has a self-correcting mechanism that erodes a recessionary gap. Specifically, a weak labor market reduces wage increases and, in extreme cases, may even drive wages down. Lower wages shift the aggregate supply curve outward, but it happens very slowly. 7. If an inflationary gap occurs, the economy has a similar mechanism that erodes the gap through a process of inflation. Unusually strong job prospects push wages up, which shifts the aggregate supply curve to the left and reduces the inflationary gap.

As we mentioned in the box on page 596, questions have been raised, and only partially answered, about why stagflation did not return in the 2006–2008 period.

3

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 27

601

Bringing in the Supply Side: Unemployment and Inflation?

11. Things reversed in 1997–1998, when falling oil prices and rising productivity shifted the aggregate supply curve out more rapidly than usual, thereby boosting real growth and reducing inflation simultaneously.

8. One consequence of this self-correcting mechanism is that, if a surge in aggregate demand opens up an inflationary gap, the economy’s subsequent natural adjustment will lead to a period of stagflation—that is, a period in which prices are rising while output is falling.

12. Inflation can be caused either by rapid growth of aggregate demand or by sluggish growth of aggregate supply. When fluctuations in economic activity emanate from the demand side, prices will rise rapidly when real output grows rapidly. However, when fluctuations in economic activity emanate from the supply side, output will grow slowly when prices rise rapidly.

9. An inward shift of the aggregate supply curve will cause output to fall while prices rise—that is, it will produce stagflation. Among the events that have caused such a shift are abrupt increases in the price of foreign oil. 10. Adverse supply shifts like this plagued the U.S. economy when oil prices skyrocketed in 1973–1974, in 1979–1980, and again in 1990, leading to stagflation each time.

| KEY TERMS | aggregate supply curve

584

inflationary gap

equilibrium of real GDP and the price level 587 inflation and the multiplier

productivity

589

self-correcting mechanism

586

recessionary gap

stagflation

594

(2)

(3)

(4)

Aggregate Demand When Investment Is $240 $3,860 3,830 3,800 3,770 3,740 3,710

Aggregate Demand When Investment Is $260 $4,060 4,030 4,000 3,970 3,940 3,910

Aggregate Supply $3,660 3,730 3,800 3,870 3,940 4,010

593

589

588

| TEST YOURSELF | 1. In an economy with the following aggregate demand and aggregate supply schedules, find the equilibrium levels of real output and the price level. Graph your solution. If full employment comes at $2,800 billion, is there an inflationary or a recessionary gap? Aggregate Quantity Demanded $3,200 3,100 3,000 2,900 2,800

Price Level 90 95 100 105 110

Aggregate Quantity Supplied $2,750 2,900 3,000 3,050 3,075

NOTE: Amounts are in billions of dollars.

2. Suppose a worker receives a wage of $20 per hour. Compute the real wage (money wage deflated by the price index) corresponding to each of the following possible price levels: 85, 95, 100, 110, 120. What do you notice about the relationship between the real wage and the price level? Relate your finding to the slope of the aggregate supply curve. 3. Add the following aggregate supply and demand schedules to the example in Test Yourself Question 2 of Chapter 26 (page 576) to see how inflation affects the multiplier:

(1)

Price Level 90 95 100 105 110 115

Draw these schedules on a piece of graph paper. a. Notice that the difference between columns (2) and (3), which show the aggregate demand schedule at two different levels of investment, is always $200. Discuss how this constant gap of $200 relates to your answer in the previous chapter. b. Find the equilibrium GDP and the equilibrium price level both before and after the increase in investment. What is the value of the multiplier? Compare that to the multiplier you found in Test Yourself Question 2 of Chapter 26. 4. Use an aggregate supply-and-demand diagram to show that multiplier effects are smaller when the aggregate supply curve is steeper. Which case gives rise to more inflation—the steep aggregate supply curve or the flat one? What happens to the multiplier if the aggregate supply curve is vertical?

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

602

Part 6

The Macroeconomy: Aggregate Supply and Demand

| DISCUSSION QUESTIONS | 1. Explain why a decrease in the price of foreign oil shifts the aggregate supply curve outward to the right. What are the consequences of such a shift? 2. Comment on the following statement: “Inflationary and recessionary gaps are nothing to worry about because the economy has a built-in mechanism that cures either type of gap automatically.”

4. Why do you think wages tend to be rigid in the downward direction? 5. Explain in words why rising prices reduce the multiplier effect of an autonomous increase in aggregate demand.

3. Give two different explanations of how the economy can suffer from stagflation.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Part

Fiscal and Monetary Policy

I

n Part 6, we constructed a framework for understanding the macroeconomy. The basic theory came in three parts. We started with the determinants of the long-run growth rate of potential GDP in Chapter 24, added some analysis of short-run fluctuations in aggregate demand in Chapters 25 and 26, and finally considered short-run fluctuations in aggregate supply in Chapter 27. Part 7 uses that framework to consider a variety of public policy issues—the sorts of things that make headlines in the newspapers and on television. At several points in earlier chapters, beginning with our list of Ideas for Beyond the Final Exam in Chapter 1, we suggested that the government may be able to manage aggregate demand by using its fiscal and monetary policies. Chapters 28–30 pick up and build on that suggestion. You will learn how the government tries to promote rapid growth and low unemployment while simultaneously limiting inflation—and why its efforts do not always succeed. Then, in Chapters 31–33, we turn explicitly to a number of important controversies related to the government’s stabilization policy. How should the Federal Reserve do its job? Why is it considered so important to reduce the budget deficit? Is there a tradeoff between inflation and unemployment? By the end of Part 7, you will be in an excellent position to understand some of the most important debates over national economic policy—not only today but also in the years to come.

C H A P T E R S 28 | Managing Aggregate

31 | The Debate over Monetary

29 | Money and the Banking

32 | Budget Deficits in the Short

30 | Managing Aggregate

33 | The Trade-Off between

Demand: Fiscal Policy System

Demand: Monetary Policy

and Fiscal Policy and Long Run

Inflation and Unemployment

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Managing Aggregate Demand: Fiscal Policy Next, let us turn to the problems of our fiscal policy. Here the myths are legion and the truth hard to find. JOHN F. KENNEDY

I

n the model of the economy we constructed in Part 6, the government played a rather passive role. It did some spending and collected taxes, but that was about it. We concluded that such an economy has only a weak tendency to move toward an equilibrium with high employment and low inflation. Furthermore, we hinted that well-designed government policies might enhance that tendency and improve the economy’s performance. It is now time to expand on that hint—and to learn about some of the difficulties that must be overcome if stabilization policy is to succeed. We begin in this chapter with fiscal policy, which was employed in 2008, 2009, and again in 2010 to shorten the Great Recession and speed up the recovery. The next three chapters take up the government’s other main tool for managing aggregate demand, monetary policy.

The government’s fiscal policy is its plan for spending and taxation. It is designed to steer aggregate demand in some desired direction.

C O N T E N T S ISSUE: THE GREAT FISCAL STIMULUS DEBATE OF 2009–2010

INCOME TAXES AND THE CONSUMPTION SCHEDULE THE MULTIPLIER REVISITED The Tax Multiplier Income Taxes and the Multiplier Automatic Stabilizers Government Transfer Payments

ISSUE REVISITED: THE 2009–2010

STIMULUS DEBATE

PLANNING EXPANSIONARY FISCAL POLICY PLANNING CONTRACTIONARY FISCAL POLICY THE CHOICE BETWEEN SPENDING POLICY AND TAX POLICY ISSUE REDUX: DEMOCRATS VERSUS

REPUBLICANS

ISSUE: THE PARTISAN DEBATE ONCE MORE Toward an Assessment of Supply-Side Economics

| APPENDIX A | Graphical Treatment of Taxes and Fiscal Policy Multipliers for Tax Policy

| APPENDIX B | Algebraic Treatment of Taxes and Fiscal Policy

SOME HARSH REALITIES THE IDEA BEHIND SUPPLY-SIDE TAX CUTS Some Flies in the Ointment

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

606

Part 7

Fiscal and Monetary Policy

ISSUE:

THE GREAT FISCAL STIMULUS DEBATE OF 2009–2010

When President Barack Obama assumed office in January 2009, the U.S. economy was sliding downhill fast. One of the new president’s first actions was to ask Congress to pass a large fiscal stimulus bill (eventually, $787 billion) consisting of a combination of tax cuts, new federal spending, and substantial aid to state and local governments. The aim of the Recovery Act was clear: to increase aggregate demand and, thereby, to moderate the economic decline and speed up the recovery. It was precisely the sort of fiscal policy response that we will study in this chapter. The Recovery Act was controversial—and highly partisan—from the start. It passed Congress in February with almost no Republican support, and many Republicans have been clamoring for its repeal ever since. They objected on several grounds: that the bill had too much spending and not enough tax cuts, that it would increase the federal budget deficit, and that it would not even give the economy a boost. Democrats countered that new government spending would affect the economy sooner and more surely than some of the tax cuts advocated by Republicans, and that larger deficits, although undesirable per se, were part of the price we had to pay to prevent “Great Depression 2.0.” They also asked: How in the world could this much government spending not stimulate the economy? Thus the great fiscal stimulus debate of 2009, which continues into 2010, revolved around three concepts that we will study in this chapter: • The multiplier effects of tax cuts versus higher government spending • The multiplier effects of different types of tax cuts • The incentive effects of tax cuts

SOURCE: Image copyright Frontpage, 2009. Used under license from Shutterstock.com

By the end of the chapter, you will be in a much better position to form your own opinion on this important, and ongoing, public policy issue.

INCOME TAXES AND THE CONSUMPTION SCHEDULE To understand how taxes affect equilibrium gross domestic product (GDP), we begin by recalling that taxes (T) are subtracted from gross domestic product (Y) to obtain disposable income (DI): DI 5 Y 2 T

and that disposable income, not GDP, is the amount actually available to consumers and is therefore the principal determinant of consumer spending (C). Thus, at any given level of Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

607

Managing Aggregate Demand: Fiscal Policy

GDP, if taxes rise, disposable income falls—and hence so does consumption. What we have just described in words is summarized graphically in Figure 1. Any increase in taxes shifts the consumption schedule downward, and any tax reduction shifts the consumption schedule upward.

Of course, if the C schedule moves up or down, so does the C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM) schedule. And we know from Chapter 26 that such a shift will have a multiplier effect on aggregate demand. So it follows that:

Tax Cut C

Real Consumer Spending

Chapter 28

An increase or decrease in taxes will have a mutiplier effect on equilibrium GDP on the demand side. Tax reductions increase equilibrium GDP, and tax increases reduce it.

Tax Increase

Real GDP

So far, this analysis just echoes our previous analysis of the multiplier effects of government spending, but there is one important difference. Government purchases of goods and services add to total spending directly—through the G component of C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM). Taxes reduce total spending only indirectly—by lowering disposable income and thus reducing the C component of C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM). As we will now see, that little detail turns out to be important.

FI GURE 1 How Tax Policy Shifts the Consumption Schedule

THE MULTIPLIER REVISITED To understand why, let us return to the example used in Chapter 26, in which we learned that the multiplier works through a chain of spending and respending, as one person’s expenditure becomes another’s income. In the example, the spending chain was initiated by Microhard’s decision to spend an additional $1 million on investment. With a marginal propensity to consume (MPC) of 0.75, the complete multiplier chain was

$1,000,000 1 $750,000 1 $562,500 1 $421,875 1 . . . . 5 $1,000,000 (1 1 0.75 1 (0.75)2 1 (0.75)3 1 . . .) 5 $1,000,000 3 4 5 $4,000,000. Thus, each dollar originally spent by Microhard eventually produced $4 in additional spending.

The Tax Multiplier Now suppose the initiating event was a $1 million tax cut instead. As we just noted, a tax cut affects spending only indirectly. By adding $1 million to disposable income, it increases consumer spending by $750,000 (assuming that the MPC is 0.75). Thereafter, the chain of spending and respending proceeds exactly as before, to yield:

$750,000 1 $562,500 1 $421,875 1 . . . . 5 $750,000 (1 1 0.75 1 (0.75)2 1 . . .) 5 $750,000 3 4 5 $3,000,000. Notice that the mutiplier effect of each dollar of tax cut is now three, not four. The reason is straightforward. Each new dollar of additional autonomous spending—regardless of whether it is C or I or G—has a multiplier of four, but each dollar of tax cut creates only 75 cents of new consumer spending. Applying the basic expenditure multiplier of four to the 75 cents of first-round spending leads to a multiplier of three for each dollar of tax cut. This numerical example illustrates a general result:1 1 You may notice that the tax multiplier of three is the spending multiplier of four times the marginal propensity to consume, which is 0.75. See appendix B for an algebraic explanation.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

608

Fiscal and Monetary Policy

Part 7

The multiplier for changes in taxes is smaller than the multiplier for changes in government purchases because not every dollar of tax cut is spent.

Income Taxes and the Multiplier This is not the only way in which taxes force us to modify the multiplier analysis of Chapter 26. If the volume of taxes collected depends on GDP—which, of course, it does in reality—there is another way. To understand this new wrinkle, return again to our Microhard example, but now assume that the government levies a 20 percent income tax—meaning that individuals pay 20 cents in taxes for each $1 of income they receive. Now when Microhard spends $1 million on salaries, its workers receive only $800,000 in after-tax (that is, disposable) income. The rest goes to the government in taxes. If workers spend 75 percent of the $800,000 (because the MPC is 0.75), spending in the next round will be only $600,000. Notice that this is only 60 percent of the original expenditure, not 75 percent—as was the case before. Thus, the multiplier chain for each original dollar of spending shrinks from

1 1 0.75 1 (0.75)2 1 (0.75)3 1 . . . 5

1 1 5 54 1 2 0.75 0.25

in Chapter 26’s example to

1 1 0.6 1 (0.6)2 1 (0.6)3 1 . . . 5

1 1 5 5 2.5 1 2 0.6 0.4

now. This is clearly a large reduction in the multiplier. Although this is just a numerical example, the two appendixes to this chapter show that the basic finding is quite general: The multiplier is reduced by an income tax because an income tax reduces the fraction of each dollar of GDP that consumers actually receive and spend.

We thus have a third reason why the oversimplified multiplier formula of Chapter 26 exaggerates the size of the multiplier: It ignores income taxes. REASONS WHY THE OVERSIMPLIFIED FORMULA OVERSTATES THE MULTIPLIER

F I GURE 2 The Multiplier in the Presence of an Income Tax

1. It ignores variable imports, which reduce the size of the multiplier. 2. It ignores price-level changes, which reduce the multiplier. 3. It ignores income taxes, which also reduce the size of the multiplier.

45

C + I + G1 + (X – IM ) Real Expenditure

E1 C + I + G0 + (X – IM )

$400 billion E0

6,000

NOTE: Figures are in billions of dollars per year.

7,000 Real GDP

8,000

The last of these three reasons is the most important one in practice. This conclusion about the multiplier is shown graphically in Figure 2, which can usefully be compared to Figure 10 of Chapter 26 (page 570). Here we draw our C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM) schedules with a slope of 0.6, reflecting an MPC of 0.75 and a tax rate of 20 percent, rather than the 0.75 slope we used in Chapter 26. Figure 2 then illustrates the effect of a $400 billion increase in government purchases of goods and services, which shifts the total expenditure schedule from C 1 I 1 G0 1 (X 2 IM) to C 1 I 1 G1 1 (X 2 IM). Equilibrium moves from point E0 to point E1—a GDP increase from Y 5 $6,000 billion to Y 5 $7,000 billion. Thus, if we ignore for the moment any increases in the price level (which would further reduce the multiplier), a $400-billion

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 28

609

Managing Aggregate Demand: Fiscal Policy

increment in government spending leads to a $1,000-billion increment in GDP. So, when a 20 percent income tax is included in our model, the multiplier is only $1,000/$400 5 2.5, as we concluded above. We now have noted two different ways in which taxes modify the multiplier analysis: • Tax changes have a smaller multiplier effect than spending changes by government or others. • An income tax reduces the multipliers for both tax changes and changes in spending.

Automatic Stabilizers The size of the multiplier may seem to be a rather abstract notion with little practical importance, but that is not so. Fluctuations in one or another of the components of total spending—C, I, G, or (X 2 IM)—occur all the time. Some come unexpectedly; some are even difficult to explain after the fact. We know from Chapter 26 that any such fluctuation will move GDP up or down by a multiplied amount. Thus, if the multiplier is smaller, GDP will be less sensitive to such shocks—that is, the economy will be less volatile. Features of the economy that reduce its sensitivity to shocks are called automatic stabilizers. The most obvious example is the one we have just been discussing: the personal income tax. The income tax acts as a shock absorber because it makes disposable income, and thus consumer spending, less sensitive to fluctuations in GDP. As we have just seen, when GDP rises, disposable income (DI) rises less because part of the increase in GDP is siphoned off by the U.S. Treasury. This leakage helps limit any increase in consumption spending. When GDP falls, DI falls less sharply because part of the loss is absorbed by the Treasury rather than by consumers. So consumption does not drop as much as it otherwise might. Thus, the much-maligned personal income tax is one of the main features of our modern economy that helps ensure against a repeat performance of the Great Depression. Our economy has other automatic stabilizers as well. For example, Chapter 23 discussed the U.S. system of unemployment insurance. This program also serves as an automatic stabilizer. When GDP drops and people lose their jobs, unemployment benefits prevent disposable incomes from falling as dramatically as earnings. As a result, unemployed workers can maintain their spending better, and consumption fluctuates less than employment does. The list could continue, but the basic principle remains the same: Each automatic stabilizer serves, in one way or another, as a shock absorber, thereby lowering the multiplier. And each does so quickly, without the need for any decision maker to take action. In a word, they work automatically. A dramatic example arose when the U.S. economy sagged in fiscal years 2008 and 2009. The budget deficit naturally rose sharply as tax receipts came in far lower than had been expected. There was much consternation over the rising deficit, but most economists viewed it as a good thing in the short run: The automatic stabilizers were propping up spending, as they should.

An automatic stabilizer is a feature of the economy that reduces its sensitivity to shocks, such as sharp increases or decreases in spending.

Government Transfer Payments To complete our discussion of multipliers for fiscal policy, let us now turn to the last major fiscal tool: government transfer payments. Transfers, as you will remember, are payments to individuals that are not compensation for any direct contribution to production. How are transfers treated in our models of income determination—like purchases of goods and services (G) or like taxes (T)? The answer to this question follows readily from the circular flow diagram on page 540 or the accounting identity on page 541. The important thing to understand about transfer payments is that they intervene between gross domestic product (Y) and disposable income (DI) in precisely the opposite way from income taxes. They add to earned income rather than subtract from it. Specifically, starting with the wages, interest, rents, and profits that constitute national income, we subtract income taxes to calculate disposable income. We do so because these taxes represent the portion of incomes that consumers earn but never receive. Then we Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

610

Part 7

Fiscal and Monetary Policy

must add transfer payments because they represent sources of income that are received although they were not earned in the process of production. Thus: Transfer payments function basically as negative taxes.

As you may recall from Chapter 25, we use the symbol T to denote taxes minus transfers. Thus, giving consumers $1 in the form of transfer payments is treated in the 45° line diagram in the same way as a $1 decrease in taxes.

ISSUE REVISITED:

THE 2009–2010 STIMULUS DEBATE

What we have learned already has some bearing on the partisan debate between Democrats and Republicans over the 2009 fiscal stimulus package. Remember, one of the main bones of contention was that Republicans wanted more tax cuts and less spending. We have just learned that the multiplier for T is smaller than the multiplier for G. That means that removing some government spending from the stimulus package and replacing it with more tax cuts would probably have weakened the overall impact on aggregate demand. So does that mean the Democrats were right? Well, not quite. Our simple analysis so far has focused solely on the effects of fiscal stimulus on aggregate demand; it leaves out any possible incentive effects of tax cuts on aggregate supply. It is precisely these incentive effects, Republicans argue, that tip the scales in favor of tax cuts. We will return to that question later in this chapter.

PLANNING EXPANSIONARY FISCAL POLICY We will have more to say about the stimulus debate later, but first imagine that you were a member of the U.S. Congress trying to decide whether to use fiscal policy to stimulate the economy in 2009—and, if so, by how much. Suppose the economy would have had a GDP of $6,000 billion if the government simply reenacted the previous year’s budget. Suppose further that your goal was to achieve a fully employed labor force and that staff economists told you that a GDP of approximately $7,000 billion was needed to reach this target. Finally, to keep the calculations simple, imagine that the price level was fixed. What sort of budget would you have voted for? This chapter has taught us that the government has three ways to raise GDP by $1,000 billion. Congress can close the recessionary gap between actual and potential GDP by

SOURCE: © R. J. Matson, Roll Call

• raising government purchases • reducing taxes • increasing transfer payments Figure 3 illustrates the problem, and its cure, through higher government spending, on our 45° line diagram. Figure 3(a) shows the equilibrium of the economy if no changes are made in the budget. With an expenditure multiplier of 2.5, you can figure out that an additional $400 billion of government spending would be needed to push GDP up by $1,000 billion and eliminate the gap ($400 3 2.5 5 $1,000). So you might vote to raise G by $400 billion, hoping to move the C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM) line in Figure 3(a) up to the position indicated in Figure 3(b), thereby achieving full employment. Or you might prefer to achieve this fiscal stimulus by lowering taxes. Or you might opt for more generous transfer payments. The point is that a variety of budgets are capable of increasing GDP by $1,000 billion. Figure 3 applies equally well to any of them. President George W. Bush favored tax cuts, which is the tool the U.S government relied on in 2001, especially after the September 11 terrorist attacks. Encouraging consumers to spend their tax cuts became a national priority. (See the cartoon to the left.)

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

611

Managing Aggregate Demand: Fiscal Policy

Chapter 28

FI GURE 3

E

Potential GDP

45°

C + I + G0 + (X – IM )

Real Expenditure

Real Expenditure

Potential GDP

45°

Fiscal Policy to Eliminate a Recessionary Gap

F C + I + G1 + (X – IM )

C + I + G0 + (X – IM )

Recessionary gap

5,000

6,000 7,000 Real GDP (a)

5,000

6,000 7,000 Real GDP (b)

NOTE: Figures are in billions of dollars per year.

PLANNING CONTRACTIONARY FISCAL POLICY The preceding example assumed that the basic problem of fiscal policy is to close a recessionary gap, as was surely the case in 2009. A decade earlier, in 1999, most economists believed that the major macroeconomic problem in the United States was just the opposite: real GDP exceeded potential GDP, producing an inflationary gap. And some people believed that an inflationary gap emerged once again in 2006 and 2007, when the unemployment rate dropped to around 4.5 percent. In such cases, government would wish to adopt more restrictive fiscal policies to reduce aggregate demand. It does not take much imagination to run our previous analysis in reverse. If an inflationary gap would arise from a continuation of current budget policies, contractionary fiscal policy tools can eliminate it. By cutting spending, raising taxes, or by a combination of the two, the government can pull the C 1 G 1 I 1 (X 2 IM) schedule down to a noninflationary position and achieve an equilibrium at full employment. Notice the difference between this way of eliminating an inflationary gap and the natural self-correcting mechanism that we discussed in the last chapter. There we observed that, if the economy were left to its own devices, a cumulative but self-limiting process of inflation would eventually eliminate the inflationary gap and return the economy to full employment. Here we see that we need not put the economy through the inflationary wringer. Instead, a restrictive fiscal policy can avoid inflation by limiting aggregate demand to the level that the economy can produce at full employment.

THE CHOICE BETWEEN SPENDING POLICY AND TAX POLICY In principle, fiscal policy can nudge the economy in the desired direction equally well by changing government spending or by changing taxes. For example, if the government wants to expand the economy, it can raise G or lower T. Either policy would shift the total expenditure schedule upward, as depicted in Figure 3(b), thereby raising equilibrium GDP on the demand side. In terms of our aggregate demand-and-supply diagram, either policy shifts the aggregate demand curve outward, as illustrated in the shift from D0D0 to D1D1 in Figure 4. As a result, the economy’s equilibrium moves from point E to point A; both real GDP and the price level rise. As this diagram points out, Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

612

Part 7

Fiscal and Monetary Policy

Any combination of higher spending and lower taxes that produces the same aggregate demand curve leads to the same increases in real GDP and prices.

F I GURE 4 Expansionary Fiscal Policy

D1

Price Level

D0 A Rise in price level

S

E

Rise in real GDP

SOURCE: From The Wall Street Journal— Permission, Cartoon Features Syndicate

Real GDP

“Free gifts to every kid in the world? Are you a Keynesian or something?”

How, then, do policy makers decide whether to raise spending or to cut taxes? The answer depends mainly on how large a pubS lic sector they want—a major issue in the long-running debate in the United States over the proper size of government. The small-government point of view, typically advocated by conservatives, says that we are foolish to rely on the public sector to do what private individuals and businesses can do better. Conservatives believe that the growth of government interferes too much in our everyday lives, thereby curtailing our freedom. Those who hold this view can argue for tax cuts when macroeconomic considerations call for expansionary fiscal policy, as President George W. Bush did, and for lower public D1 spending when contractionary policy is required. An opposing opinion, expressed more often by liberals, holds D0 that something is amiss when a country as wealthy as the United States has such an impoverished public sector. In this view, America’s most pressing needs are not for more fast food and video games but, rather, for better schools, better transportation infrastructure, and health insurance for all of our citizens—all priorities of President Obama. People on this side of the debate believe that we should increase spending when the economy needs stimulus and pay for these improved public services by increasing taxes when it is necessary to rein in the economy. It is important not to confuse the fiscal stabilization issue with the “biggovernment” issue. In fact, Individuals favoring a smaller public sector can advocate an active fiscal policy just as well as those who favor a larger public sector. Advocates of bigger government should seek to expand demand (when appropriate) through higher government spending and to contract demand (when appropriate) through tax increases. Advocates of smaller government should seek to expand demand by cutting taxes and to reduce demand by cutting expenditures.

Indeed, our two most conservative recent presidents, Ronald Reagan and George W. Bush, each pursued activist fiscal policies, as has the more liberal President Obama.

ISSUE REDUX:

DEMOCRATS VERSUS REPUBLICANS

Although both parties wanted to stimulate the economy in 2009, the choice between tax cuts and more government spending played a central role in the economic debate over the fiscal stimulus package. The bill that the Democrats passed consisted, very roughly, of one-third tax cuts, one-third federal spending, and one-third aid to state and local governments. Clearly, that made government “bigger.” Republicans objected to those proportions. They wanted more tax cuts and less spending—a “smaller” government—and, on those grounds, voted against the bill.

SOME HARSH REALITIES The mechanics outlined so far in this chapter make the fiscal policy planner’s job look deceptively simple. The elementary diagrams make it appear that policy makers can drive GDP to any level they please simply by manipulating spending and tax programs. It seems they should be able to hit the full-employment bull’s-eye every time. In fact, a

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 28

Managing Aggregate Demand: Fiscal Policy

better analogy is to a poor rifleman shooting through dense fog at an erratically moving target with an inaccurate gun and slow-moving bullets. The target is moving because, in the real world, the investment, net exports, and consumption schedules constantly shift about as expectations, technology, events abroad, and other factors change. For all of these reasons and others, the policies decided on today, which will take effect at some future date, may no longer be appropriate by the time that future date rolls around. The second misleading feature of our diagrams (the “inaccurate gun”) is that we do not know multipliers as precisely as in our numerical examples. Although our best guess may be that a $20 billion increase in government purchases will raise GDP by $30 billion (a multiplier of 1.5), the actual outcome may be as little as $20 billion or as much as $40 billion. It is therefore impossible to “fine-tune” every little wobble out of the economy’s growth path. Economic science is simply not that precise. A third complication is that our target—full-employment GDP—may be only dimly visible, as if through a fog. For example, when the unemployment rate hovered around 4.5 percent for parts of 2006 and 2007, there was a vigorous debate over whether the U.S. economy was above or below full employment. Now, with unemployment over 9 percent full employment is a far-off target. A fourth complication is that the fiscal policy “bullets” travel slowly: Tax and spending policies affect aggregate demand only after some time elapses. Consumer spending, for example, may take months to react to an income-tax cut. Because of these time lags, fiscal policy decisions must be based on forecasts of the future state of the economy. And forecasts are not always accurate. The combination of long lags and poor forecasts may occasionally leave the government fighting the last recession just as the new inflation gets under way. And, finally, the people aiming the fiscal “rifle” are politicians, not economic technicians. Sometimes political considerations lead to policies that deviate markedly from what textbook economics would suggest. Even when they do not, the wheels of Congress grind slowly. In addition to all of these operational problems, legislators trying to decide whether to push the unemployment rate lower would like to know the answers to two further questions. First, since either higher spending or lower taxes will increase the government’s budget deficit, what are the long-run costs of running large budget deficits? This is a question we will take up in depth in Chapter 32. Second, how large is the inflationary cost likely to be? As we know, an expansionary fiscal policy that reduces a recessionary gap by increasing aggregate demand will lower unemployment. As Figure 4 reminds us, it also tends to be inflationary. This undesirable side effect may make the government hesitant to use fiscal policy to combat recessions. Is there a way out of this dilemma? Can we pursue the battle against unemployment without aggravating inflation? For over 30 years now, a small but influential minority of economists, journalists, and politicians have argued that we can. They call their approach “supply-side economics.” The idea helped sweep Ronald Reagan to smashing electoral victories in 1980 and 1984 and was revived under President George W. Bush. Just what is supply-side economics?

THE IDEA BEHIND SUPPLY-SIDE TAX CUTS The central idea of supply-side economics is that certain types of tax cuts increase aggregate supply. For example, taxes can be cut in ways that raise the rewards for working, saving, and investing. Then, if people actually respond to these incentives, such tax cuts will increase the total supplies of labor and capital in the economy, thereby increasing aggregate supply. Figure 5 illustrates the idea on an aggregate supply-and-demand diagram. If policy measures can shift the economy’s aggregate supply to position S1S1, then prices will be lower and output higher than if the aggregate supply curve remained at S0S0. Policy makers will have reduced inflation and raised real output at the same time—as shown by point B in the figure. The trade-off between inflation and unemployment will have been defeated, which is the goal of supply-side economics.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

613

614

Part 7

Fiscal and Monetary Policy

What sorts of policies do supply-siders advocate? Here is a sample of their long list of recommended tax cuts:

F I GURE 5 The Goal of SupplySide Tax Cuts

Lower Personal Income-Tax Rates Sharp cuts in personal S0 S1

Price Level

D

A B

taxes were the cornerstone of the economic strategy of George W. Bush, just as they had been for Ronald Reagan 20 years earlier. Starting in 2001, tax rates on individuals were reduced in stages, and in several ways. The four upper tax bracket rates, which were 39.6 percent, 36 percent, 31 percent, and 28 percent when President Bush assumed office, were reduced to 35 percent, 33 percent, 28 percent, and 25 percent, respectively. (President Obama now wants to raise the upper-bracket rates back.) In addition, some very low income taxpayers saw their tax rate fall from 15 percent to 10 percent. Lower tax rates, supply-siders argue, augment the supplies of both labor and capital.

S0

Reduce Taxes on Income from Savings One extreme form of this proposal would simply exempt from taxation all income Real GDP from interest and dividends. Because income must be either consumed or saved, doing this would, in effect, change our present personal income tax into a tax on consumer spending. Several such proposals for radical tax reform have been considered in Washington over the years, but never adopted. However, Congress did reduce the tax rate on dividends to just 15 percent in 2003. D

S1

Reduce Taxes on Capital Gains When an investor sells an asset for a profit, that profit is called a capital gain. Supply-siders argue that the government can encourage more investment by taxing capital gains at lower rates than ordinary income. This proposal was acted upon in 2003, when the top rate on capital gains was cut to 15 percent. In 2010, President Obama proposed eliminating capital gains taxes on small businesses.

Reduce the Corporate Income Tax By reducing the tax burden on corporations, proponents argue, the government can provide both greater investment incentives (by raising the profitability of investment) and more investable funds (by letting companies keep more of their earnings).

F IGURE 6 A Successful SupplySide Tax Reduction

D1

Price Level

D0

E

Let us suppose, for the moment, that a successful supply-side tax cut is enacted. Because both aggregate demand and aggregate supply increase simultaneously, the economy may be able to avoid the inflationary consequences of an expansionary fiscal policy shown in Figure 4. Figure 6 illustrates this conclusion. The two aggregate demand curves and the initial aggregate supply curve S0S0 carry over directly from Figure 4. Now we have introduced an additional supply curve, S1 S1 , to reflect the successful supply–side tax cut depicted in Figure 5. The equilibrium point for the economy moves from E to C, whereas with a convenS0 tional demand-side tax cut it would have moved from E to A. As compared with point A, which reflects only the demand-side S1 effects of a tax cut, output is higher and prices are lower at point C. A good deal, you say. And indeed it is. The supply-side arA gument is extremely attractive in principle. The question is: C Does it work in practice? Can we actually do what is depicted in Figure 6? Let us consider some of the difficulties. D1

S0

S1 Real GDP

D0

Some Flies in the Ointment Critics of supply-side economics rarely question its goals or the basic idea that lower taxes improve incentives. They argue, instead, that supply-siders exaggerate the beneficial effects of

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 28

615

Managing Aggregate Demand: Fiscal Policy

tax cuts and ignore some undesirable side effects. Here is a brief rundown of some of their main objections.

Small Magnitude of Supply-Side Effects The first objection is that supply-siders are simply too optimistic: No one really knows how to do what Figure 5 shows. Although it is easy, for example, to design tax incentives that make saving more attractive financially, people may not actually respond to these incentives. In fact, most of the statistical evidence suggests that we should not expect much from tax incentives for saving. As the economist Charles Schultze once quipped: “There’s nothing wrong with supply-side economics that division by 10 couldn’t cure.” Demand-Side Effects The second objection is that supply-

A More Pessimistic View of Supply-Side Tax Cuts

D1

siders ignore the effects of tax cuts on aggregate demand. If you cut personal taxes, for example, individuals may possibly work more, but they will certainly spend more.

S0 S1

D0

Price Level

The joint implications of these two objections appear in Figure 7. This figure depicts a small outward shift of the aggregate supply curve (which reflects the first objection) and a large outward shift of the aggregate demand curve (which reflects the second objection). The result is that the economy’s equilibrium moves from point E (the intersection of S0S0 and D0D0) to point C (the intersection of S1S1 and D1D1). Prices rise as output expands. The outcome differs only a little from the straight “demand-side” fiscal stimulus depicted in Figure 4.

FI GURE 7

C E

D1 S0 S1

D0

Real GDP Problems with Timing Investment incentives are the most promising type of supply-side tax cuts, but the benefits from greater investment do not arrive by overnight mail. In particular, the expenditures on investment goods almost certainly come before any expansion of capacity. Thus, supply-side tax cuts have their primary short-run effects on aggregate demand. Effects on aggregate supply come later.

Effects on Income Distribution The preceding objections all pertain to the likely effects of supply-side policies on aggregate supply and demand. However, a different problem bears mentioning: Most supply-side initiatives increase income inequality. Indeed, some tilt toward the rich is an almost inescapable corollary of supply-side logic. The basic aim of supply-side economics is to increase the incentives for working and investing—that is, to increase the gap between the rewards of those who succeed in the economic game (by working hard, investing well, or just plain being lucky) and those who fail. It can hardly be surprising, therefore, that supply-side policies tend to increase economic inequality.

Losses of Tax Revenue You can hardly help noticing that most of the policies suggested by supply-siders involve cutting one tax or another. Thus supply-side tax cuts are bound to raise the government budget deficit. This problem proved to be the Achilles’ heel of supply-side economics in the United States in the 1980s. The Reagan tax cuts left in their wake a legacy of budget deficits that took 15 years to overcome. Opponents argue that President George W. Bush’s tax cuts put us in a similar position: The tax cuts used up the budget surplus and turned it into a large deficit. That is one main reason why President Obama wants to repeal many of the Bush tax cuts.

ISSUE:

THE PARTISAN DEBATE ONCE MORE

Several items on the preceding list have played prominent roles in the continuing debate over fiscal stimulus in 2009 and 2010. Many Democrats argue that the supply-side effects of many Republican-proposed tax cuts are small and uncertain and that, at any rate, the U.S. economy’s real problem is too little demand, not too little supply. Many Republicans counter that business tax incentives are the best way to spur real, lasting job creation and that the fiscal multiplier is small, or even zero. Implicitly, they believe more in supply-side effects than demand-side effects.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

616

Part 7

Fiscal and Monetary Policy

Supply-Side Economics and Presidential Elections the tax cuts permanent features of the code. Obama, of course, won the election. So which approach do American voters prefer? They appear to be fickle! But one thing is clear: The debate over fiscal policy played a major role in each of the last eight presidential elections.

SOURCES: (a) © AP Images (b) © AP Images/Greg Wahl-Stevens; (c) © Wally McNamee/CORBIS; (d) © AP Images / J. Scott Applewhite (e) © AP Images/Rick Bowmer

As we have mentioned, Ronald Reagan won landslide victories in 1980 and 1984 by running on a supply-side platform. In 1992, candidate Bill Clinton attacked supply-side economics as “trickledown economics,” arguing that it had failed. He emphasized two of the drawbacks of such a fiscal policy: the effects on income inequality and on the budget deficit. The voters apparently agreed with him. The hallmark of Clintonomics was, first, reducing the budget deficit that Clinton had inherited from the first President George Bush, and second, building up a large surplus. This policy succeeded—for a while. The huge budget deficit turned into a large surplus, the economy boomed, and Clinton, like Reagan before him, was reelected easily. Then, in the 2000 presidential election, the voters once again switched their allegiance. During that campaign, Democratic candidate Al Gore promised to continue the “fiscal responsibility” of the Clinton years, whereas Republican candidate George W. Bush echoed Reagan by offering large tax cuts. Bush won in what was virtually a dead heat. Then, in 2004, John Kerry ran against the incumbent George Bush on what amounted to a promise to roll back some of the Bush tax cuts and return to Clintonomics. Bush won again. In 2008, the very same issue was on the agenda again. Barack Obama wanted to repeal most of the Bush tax cuts because, he argued, the government needs the tax revenue. John McCain wanted to make

Toward an Assessment of Supply-Side Economics On balance, most economists have reached the following conclusions about supply-side tax initiatives: 1. The likely effectiveness of supply-side tax cuts depends on what kinds of taxes are cut. Tax reductions aimed at stimulating business investment are likely to pack more punch than tax reductions aimed at getting people to work longer hours or to save more. 2. Such tax cuts probably will increase aggregate supply much more slowly than they increase aggregate demand. Thus, supply-side policies should not be regarded as a substitute for short-run stabilization policy, but, rather, as a way to promote (slightly) faster economic growth in the long run. 3. Demand-side effects of supply-side tax cuts are likely to overwhelm supply-side effects in the short run. 4. Supply-side tax cuts are likely to widen income inequalities. 5. Supply-side tax cuts are almost certain to lead to larger budget deficits.

Some people will look over this list and decide in favor of supply-side tax cuts; others, perusing the same facts, will reach the opposite conclusion. We cannot say that either group is wrong because, like almost every economic policy, supply-side economics has its pros and cons and involves value judgments that color people’s conclusions. Why, then, have so many economists and politicians reacted so negatively to supplyside economics over the years? The main reason seems to be that the claims made by the most ardent supply-siders were clearly excessive. Naturally, these claims proved wrong, but showing that wild claims are wild does not eliminate the kernel of truth in supply-side

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Managing Aggregate Demand: Fiscal Policy

Chapter 28

617

economics: Reductions in marginal tax rates do improve economic incentives. Any specific supply-side tax cut must be judged on its individual merits.

| SUMMARY | 1. The government’s fiscal policy is its plan for managing aggregate demand through its spending and taxing programs. This policy is made jointly by the president and Congress. 2. Because consumer spending (C) depends on disposable income (DI), and DI is GDP minus taxes, any change in taxes will shift the consumption schedule on a 45° line diagram. Such shifts in the consumption schedule have multiplier effects on GDP.

gaps can be cured by raising G or cutting T. Inflationary gaps can be cured by cutting G or raising T. 8. Active stabilization policy can be carried out either by means that tend to expand the size of government (by raising either G or T when appropriate) or by means that reduce the size of government (by reducing either G or T when appropriate). 9. Expansionary fiscal policy can mitigate recessions, but it also raises the budget deficit.

3. The multiplier for changes in taxes is smaller than the multiplier for changes in government purchases because each $1 of tax cuts leads to less than $1 of increased consumer spending.

10. Expansionary fiscal policy also normally exacts a cost in terms of higher inflation. This last dilemma has led to a great deal of interest in “supply-side” tax cuts designed to stimulate aggregate supply.

4. An income tax reduces the size of the multiplier.

11. Supply-side tax cuts aim to push the economy’s aggregate supply curve outward to the right. When successful, they can expand the economy and reduce inflation at the same time—a highly desirable outcome.

5. Because an income tax reduces the multiplier, it reduces the economy’s sensitivity to shocks. It is therefore considered an automatic stabilizer. 6. Government transfer payments are like negative taxes, rather than like government purchases of goods and services, because they influence total spending only indirectly through their effect on consumption. 7. If the multipliers were known precisely, it would be possible to plan a variety of fiscal policies to eliminate either a recessionary gap or an inflationary gap. Recessionary

12. Critics point out at least five serious problems with supply-side tax cuts: They also stimulate aggregate demand; the beneficial effects on aggregate supply may be small; the demand-side effects occur before the supplyside effects; they make the income distribution more unequal; and large tax cuts lead to large budget deficits.

| KEY TERMS | automatic stabilizer

609

fiscal policy

605

| TEST YOURSELF | 1. Consider an economy in which tax collections are always $400 and in which the four components of aggregate demand are as follows: GDP Taxes $1,360 $400 1,480 400 1,600 400 1,720 400 1,840 400

DI $960 1,080 1,200 1,320 1,440

C $720 810 900 990 1,080

I $200 200 200 200 200

G (X 2 IM) $500 $30 500 30 500 30 500 30 500 30

Find the equilibrium of this economy graphically. What is the marginal propensity to consume? What is the multiplier? What would happen to equilibrium GDP if government purchases were reduced by $60 and the price level remained unchanged? 2. Consider an economy similar to that in the preceding question in which investment is also $200, government purchases are also $500, net exports are also $30, and the price level is also fixed. But taxes now vary with income

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

618

Part 7

Fiscal and Monetary Policy

and, as a result, the consumption schedule looks like the following: GDP $1,360 1,480 1,600 1,720 1,840

Taxes $320 360 400 440 480

DI $1,040 1,120 1,200 1,280 1,360

C $810 870 930 990 1,050

Find the equilibrium graphically. What is the marginal propensity to consume? What is the tax rate? Use your diagram to show the effect of a decrease of $60 in government purchases. What is the multiplier? Compare this answer to your answer to Test Yourself Question 1. What do you conclude?

3. Return to the hypothetical economy in Test Yourself Question 1, and now suppose that both taxes and government purchases are increased by $120. Find the new equilibrium under the assumption that consumer spending continues to be exactly three-quarters of disposable income (as it is in Test Yourself Question 1). 4. Suppose you are put in charge of fiscal policy for the economy described in Test Yourself Question 1. There is an inflationary gap, and you want to reduce income by $120. What specific actions can you take to achieve this goal? 5. Now put yourself in charge of the economy in Test Yourself Question 2, and suppose that full employment comes at a GDP of $1,840. How can you push income up to that level?

| DISCUSSION QUESTIONS | 1. The federal budget for national defense increased substantially to pay for the Iraq and Afghanistan wars. How would GDP in the United States have been affected if this higher defense spending led to a. larger budget deficits?

5. (More difficult) Advocates of lower taxes on capital gains argue that this type of tax cut will raise aggregate supply by spurring business investment. Compare the effects on investment, aggregate supply, and tax revenues of three different ways to cut the capital gains tax:

b. less spending elsewhere in the budget, so that total government purchases remained the same?

a. Reduce capital gains taxes on all investments, including those that were made before tax rates were cut.

2. Explain why G has the same multiplier as I, but taxes have a different multiplier.

b. Reduce capital gains taxes only on investments made after tax rates are cut.

3. If the government decides that aggregate demand is excessive and is causing inflation, what options are open to it? What if the government decides that aggregate demand is too weak instead?

c. Reduce capital gains taxes only on certain types of investments, such as corporate stocks and bonds. Which of the three options seems most desirable to you? Why?

4. Which of the proposed supply-side tax cuts appeals to you most? Draw up a list of arguments for and against enacting such a cut right now.

| APPENDIX A | Graphical Treatment of Taxes and Fiscal Policy Most of the taxes collected by the U.S. government— indeed, by all national governments—rise and fall with GDP. In some cases, the reason is obvious: Personal and corporate income-tax collections, for example, depend on how much income there is to be taxed. Sales tax receipts depend on GDP because consumer spending is higher when GDP is higher. However, other types of tax receipts—such as property taxes— do not vary with GDP. We call the first kind of tax variable taxes and the second kind fixed taxes.

This distinction is important because it governs how the consumption schedule shifts in response to a tax change. If a fixed tax is increased, disposable income falls by the same amount regardless of the level of GDP. Hence, the decline in consumer spending is the same at every income level. In other words, the C schedule shifts downward in a parallel manner, as was depicted in Figure 1. Many tax policies actually change disposable income by larger amounts when incomes are higher. That is

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 28

true, for example, whenever Congress alters the tax rates imposed by the personal income tax, as it did in 2001 and 2003. Because higher tax rates decrease disposable income more when GDP is higher, the C schedule shifts down more sharply at higher income levels than at lower ones, as depicted in Figure 8. The same relationships apply for tax decreases, as the upward shift in the figure shows. FIGU R E 8 How Variable Taxes Shift the Consumption Schedule

Real Consumer Spending

Variable tax cut

C

Variable tax increase

Real GDP

619

Managing Aggregate Demand: Fiscal Policy

We can easily understand why. Column (1) of Table 1 shows alternative values of GDP ranging from $4.5 trillion to $7.5 trillion. Column (2) then indicates that taxes are always one-fifth of this amount. Column (3) subtracts column (2) from column (1) to arrive at disposable income (DI). Column (4) then gives the amount of consumer spending corresponding to each level of DI. The schedule relating C to Y, which we need for our 45° line diagram, is therefore found in columns (1) and (4). TABLE 1 The Effects of an Income Tax on the Consumption Schedule

(1) Gross Domestic Product

(2)

Taxes

$4,500 5,000 5,500 6,000 6,500 7,000 7,500

$ 900 1,000 1,100 1,200 1,300 1,400 1,500

(3) (4) Disposable Income (GDP minus taxes) Consumption $3,600 4,000 4,400 4,800 5,200 5,600 6,000

$3,000 3,300 3,600 3,900 4,200 4,500 4,800

NOTE: Figures are in billions of dollars per year.

FIGU R E 9 The Consumption Schedule with Fixed versus Variable Taxes

Real Consumer Spending

C1 C2

Real GDP

Figure 9 illustrates the second reason why the distinction between fixed and variable taxes is important. This diagram shows two different consumption lines. C1 is the consumption schedule used in previous chapters; it reflects the assumption that tax collections are the same regardless of GDP. C2 depicts a more realistic case in which the government collects taxes equal to 20 percent of GDP. Notice that C2 is flatter than C1. This is no accident. In fact, as pointed out in the chapter: Variable taxes such as the income tax flatten the consumption schedule in a 45° line diagram.

Notice that each $500-billion increase in GDP in Table 1 leads to a $300-billion rise in consumer spending. Thus, the slope of line C2 in Figure 9 is $300/ $500, or 0.60, as we observed in the chapter. In our earlier example in Chapter 26, consumption rose by $300 billion each time GDP increased $400 billion— making the slope $300/$400, or 0.75. (See the steeper line C1 in Figure 9.) Table 2 compares the two cases explicitly. In the Chapter 26 example, taxes were fixed at $1,200 billion and each $400-billion rise in Y led to a $300-billion rise in C—as in the left-hand panel of Table 2. But now, with taxes variable (equal to 20 percent of GDP), each $500-billion increment to Y gives rise to a $300-billion increase in C—as in the righthand panel of Table 2. TABLE 2 The Relationship between Consumption and GDP

With Fixed Taxes (T 5 $1,200) (from Table 1, Chapter 26) Y C

With a 20 Percent Income Tax (from Table 1) Y C

$4,800 $3,000 5,200 3,300 5,600 3,600 6,000 3,900 6,400 4,200 6,800 4,500 7,200 4,800 Line C1 in Figure 9

$4,500 $3,000 5,000 3,300 5,500 3,600 6,000 3,900 6,500 4,200 7,000 4,500 7,500 4,800 Line C2 in Figure 9

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

620

Part 7

Fiscal and Monetary Policy

Real Expenditure

Government purchases of goods and services add to These differences sound terribly mechanical, but total spending directly through the G component of the economic reasoning behind them is vital to underC 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM). Higher taxes reduce total spendstanding tax policies. When taxes are fixed, as in line ing indirectly by lowering disposable income and thus C1, each additional dollar of GDP raises disposable inreducing the C component of C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM). On come (DI) by $1. Consumer spending then rises by balance, then, the government’s actions may raise or $1 times the marginal propensity to consume (MPC), lower the equilibrium level of GDP, depending on how which is 0.75 in our example. Hence, each additional much spending and taxing it does. dollar of GDP leads to 75 cents more spending. When taxes vary with income, each addiFIGURE 10 tional dollar of GDP raises DI by less than $1 Income Determination with a Variable Income Tax because the government takes a share in taxes. In our example, taxes are 20 percent of GDP, 8,000 45° so each additional $1 of GDP generates just 80 cents more DI. With an MPC of 0.75, then, C + I + G + (X – IM ) 7,000 spending rises by only 60 cents (75 percent of 80 cents) each time GDP rises by $1. Thus, the E slope of line C 2 in Figure 9 is only 0.60, in6,000 stead of 0.75. Table 3 and Figure 10 take the next step by 5,000 replacing the old consumption schedule with this new one in both the tabular presentation 4,000 of income determination and the 45o line diagram. We see immediately that the equilib3,000 rium level of GDP is at point E. Here gross domestic product is $6,000 billion, consumption is $3,900 billion, investment is $900 billion, net 4,000 6,000 8,000 exports are 2$100 billion, and government Real GDP purchases are $1,300 billion. As we know from previous chapters, full employment may NOTE: Figures are in billions of dollars per year. occur above or below Y 5 $6,000 billion. If it is below this level, an inflationary gap arises. Prices will probably start to rise, pulling the expenditure schedule down and reducing equilibrium GDP. If it is above this MULTIPLIERS FOR TAX POLICY level, a recessionary gap results, and history suggests that prices will fall only slowly. In the interim, the Now let us turn our attention, as in the chapter, to economy will suffer a period of high unemployment. multipliers for tax changes. They are more complicated than multipliers for spending because they work TABLE 3 indirectly via consumption. For this reason, we restrict Total Expenditure Schedule with a 20 Percent Income Tax ourselves to the multiplier for fixed taxes, leaving the (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) more complicated case of variable taxes to more adGross Total vanced courses. Tax multipliers must be worked out in Domestic Government Expenditures two steps: Product Consumption Investment Purchases Net Exports C 1 I 1 G 1

Y

C

$4,500 $3,000 5,000 3,300 5,500 3,600 6,000 3,900 6,500 4,200 7,000 4,500 7,500 4,800

I

G

(X 2 IM)

(X 2 IM)

$900 900 900 900 900 900 900

$1,300 1,300 1,300 1,300 1,300 1,300 1,300

2$100 2100 2100 2100 2100 2100 2100

$5,100 5,400 5,700 6,000 6,300 6,600 6,900

In short, once we adjust the expenditure schedule for variable taxes, the determination of national income proceeds exactly as before. The effects of government spending and taxation, therefore, are fairly straightforward and can be summarized as follows:

1. Figure out how much any proposed or actual changes in the tax law will affect consumer spending. 2. Enter this vertical shift of the consumption schedule in the 45° line diagram and see how it affects output. To create a simple and familiar numerical example, suppose income taxes fall by a fixed amount at each level of GDP—say, by $400 billion. Step 1 instructs us to multiply the $400-billion tax cut by the marginal propensity to consume (MPC), which is 0.75, to get $300 billion as the increase in consumer spending—that is, as the vertical shift of the consumption schedule.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

621

Managing Aggregate Demand: Fiscal Policy

Next, Step 2 instructs us to multiply this $300billion increase in consumption by the multiplier— which is 2.5 in our example—giving $750 billion as the rise in GDP. Figure 11 verifies that this result is correct by depicting a $300-billion upward shift of the consumption function in the 45° line diagram and noting that GDP does indeed rise by $750 billion as a consequence—from $6,000 billion to $6,750 billion. Notice that the $400-billion tax cut raises GDP by $750 billion, whereas the multiplier effect of the $400billion increase in government purchases depicted in the chapter in Figure 2 raised GDP by $1,000 billion. This is a specific numerical example of something we learned in the chapter. Because some of the change in disposable income affects saving rather than spending, a dollar of tax cut does not pack as much punch as a dollar of G. That is why we multiplied the $400-billion change in taxes by 0.75 to get the $300-billion shift of the C schedule shown in Figure 11.

FIGURE 11 The Multiplier for a Reduction in Fixed Taxes 45° C1 + I + G + (X – IM )

Real Expenditure

Chapter 28

C0 + I + G + (X – IM )

$300 billion

6,000 Real GDP

6,750

| SUMMARY | 1. Precisely how a tax change affects the consumption schedule depends on whether fixed taxes or variable taxes are changed.

3. Because tax changes affect C only indirectly, the multiplier for a change in T is smaller than the multiplier for a change in G.

2. Shifts of the consumption function caused by tax policy are subject to the same multiplier as autonomous shifts in G, I, or X 2 IM.

4. The government’s net effect on aggregate demand—and hence on equilibrium output and prices—depends on whether the expansionary effects of its spending are greater or smaller than the contractionary effects of its taxes.

| KEY TERMS | fixed taxes 619

variable taxes

619

| TEST YOURSELF | 1. Which of the following is considered a fixed tax and which a variable tax? a. The gasoline tax

spending and taxes by $100 billion. What should happen to equilibrium GDP on the demand side? 3. (More difficult) Suppose real GDP is $10,000 billion and the basic expenditure multiplier is two. If two tax changes are made at the same time:

b. The corporate income tax c. The estate tax

a. fixed taxes are raised by $100 billion,

d. The payroll tax 2. In a certain economy, the multiplier for government purchases is 2 and the multiplier for changes in fixed taxes is 1.5. The government then proposes to raise both

b. the income-tax rate is reduced from 20 percent to 18 percent, will equilibrium GDP on the demand side rise or fall?

| DISCUSSION QUESTIONS | 1. When the income-tax rate declines, as it did in the United States early in this decade, does the multiplier go up or down? Explain why.

2. Discuss the pros and cons of having a higher or lower multiplier.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

622

Part 7

Fiscal and Monetary Policy

| APPENDIX B | Algebraic Treatment of Taxes and Fiscal Policy In this appendix, we explain the simple algebra behind the fiscal policy multipliers discussed in the chapter. In so doing, we deal only with a simplified case in which prices do not change. Although it is possible to work out the corresponding algebra for the more realistic aggregate demand-and-supply analysis with variable prices, the analysis is rather complicated and is best left to more advanced courses. We start with the example used both in the chapter and in appendix A. The government spends $1,300 billion on goods and services (G 5 1,300) and levies an income tax equal to 20 percent of GDP. So, if the symbol T denotes tax receipts,

T 5 0.20Y Because the consumption function we have been working with is

C 5 300 1 0.75DI where DI is disposable income, and because disposable income and GDP are related by the accounting identity

DI 5 Y 2 T it follows that the C schedule used in the 45° line diagram is described by the following algebraic equation:

C 5 300 1 0.75(Y 2 T) 5 300 1 0.75(Y 2 0.20Y) 5 300 1 0.75(0.80Y) 5 300 1 0.60Y We can now apply the equilibrium condition:

Y 5 C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM) Because investment in this example is I 5 900 and net exports are 2100, substituting for C, I, G, and (X 2 IM) into this equation gives:

Y 5 300 1 0.60Y 1 900 1 1,300 2 100 0.40Y 5 2,400 Y 5 6,000 This is all there is to finding equilibrium GDP in an economy with a government. To find the multiplier for government spending, increase G by one and solve the problem again:

Y 5 C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM) Y 5 300 1 0.60Y 1 900 1 1,301 2 100 0.40Y 5 2,401 Y 5 6,002.5

Thus, the multiplier is 6,002.5 2 6,000 5 2.5, as stated in the text. To find the multiplier for an increase in fixed taxes, change the tax schedule as follows:

T 5 0.20Y 1 1 Disposable income is then

DI 5 Y 2 T 5 Y 2 (0.20Y 1 1) 5 0.80Y 2 1 so the consumption function is

C 5 300 1 0.75DI 5 300 1 0.75(0.80Y 2 1) 5 299.25 1 0.60Y Solving for equilibrium GDP as usual gives:

Y 5 C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM) Y 5 299.25 1 0.60Y 1 900 1 1,300 2 100 0.40Y 5 2,399.25 Y 5 5,998.125 So a $1 increase in fixed taxes lowers Y by $1.875. The tax multiplier is 21.875, which is 75 percent of 22.5. Now let us proceed to a more general solution, using symbols rather than specific numbers. The equations of the model are as follows: Y 5 C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM)

(1)

is the usual equilibrium condition. C 5 a 1 bDI

(2)

is the same consumption function we used in appendix A of Chapter 26. DI 5 Y 2 T

(3)

is the accounting identity relating disposable income to GDP. T 5 T0 1 tY

(4)

is the tax function, where T0 represents fixed taxes (which are zero in our numerical example) and t represents the tax rate (which is 0.20 in the example). Finally, I, G, and (X 2 IM) are just fixed numbers. We begin the solution by substituting Equations (3) and (4) into Equation (2) to derive the consumption schedule relating C to Y:

C 5 a 1 bDI C 5 a 1 b(Y 2 T) C 5 a 1 b(Y 2 T0 2 tY) C 5 a 2 bT0 1 b(1 2 t)Y

(5)

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Managing Aggregate Demand: Fiscal Policy

Chapter 28

Notice that a change in fixed taxes (T0) shifts the intercept of the C schedule, whereas a change in the tax rate (t) changes its slope, as explained in appendix A. Next, substitute Equation (5) into Equation (1) to find equilibrium GDP:

Y 5 C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM) Y 5 a 2 bT0 1 b(1 2 t)Y 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM) [1 2 b(1 2 t)] Y 5 a 2 bT0 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM)

In Chapter 26 (page 572), we noted that if there were no income tax (t 5 0), a realistic value for b (the marginal propensity to consume) would yield a multiplier of 20, which is much bigger than the true multiplier. Now that we have added taxes to the model, our multiplier formula produces much more realistic numbers. Approximate values for these parameters for the U.S. economy are b 5 0.95 and t 5 1⁄3. The multiplier formula then gives

1 1 2 0.95 1 1 2 13 2 1 1 5 5 2.73 5 1 2 0.633 0.367

Multiplier 5

or Y5

a 2 bT0 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM) 1 2 b(1 2 t)

(6)

Equation (6) shows us that the multiplier for G, I, a, or (X 2 IM) is Multiplier 5

1 . 1 2 b(1 2 t)

Y5

a 2 bT0 1 I 1 G 1 1 X 2 IM 2 1 1 1 2 b 11 2 t2

Subtracting Equation (6) from this expression gives the change in Y stemming from a one-unit change in G, I, or a:

Change in Y 5

which is much closer to its actual estimated value— between 1.5 and 2. Finally, we can see from Equation (6) that the multiplier for a change in fixed taxes (T0) is Tax Multiplier 5

To see that this is in fact the multiplier, raise any of G, I, a, or (X 2 IM) by one unit. In each case, Equation (6) would be changed to read:

623

2b 1 2 b1 2 t

For the example considered in the text and earlier in this appendix, b 5 0.75 and t 5 0.20, so the formula gives

2 0.75 2 0.75 5 1 2 0.75 1 1 2 0.20 2 1 2 0.75 1 0.80 2 2 0.75 2 0.75 5 5 5 2 1.875 1 2 0.60 0.40 According to these figures, each $1 increase in T0 reduces Y by $1.875.

1 1 2 b 11 2 t2

| TEST YOURSELF | 1. Consider an economy described by the following set of equations:

C 5 120 1 0.80DI I 5 320 G 5 480 (X 2 IM) 5 280 T 5 200 1 0.25Y Find the equilibrium level of GDP. Next, find the multipliers for government purchases and for fixed taxes. If full employment comes at Y 5 1,800, what are some policies that would move GDP to that level? 2. This question is a variant of the previous problem that approaches things in the way that a fiscal policy plan-

ner might. In an economy whose consumption function and tax function are as given in Test Yourself Question 1, with investment fixed at 320 and net exports fixed at 280, find the value of G that would make GDP equal to 1,800. 3. You are given the following information about an economy:

C 5 0.90DI I 5 100 G 5 540 (X 2 IM) 5 240 T 5 2 1⁄3 Y

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

624

Part 7

Fiscal and Monetary Policy

a. Find equilibrium GDP and the budget deficit. b. Suppose the government, unhappy with the budget deficit, decides to cut government spending by precisely the amount of the deficit you just found. What actually happens to GDP and the budget deficit, and why?

4. (More difficult) In the economy considered in Test Yourself Question 3, suppose the government, seeing that it has not wiped out the deficit, keeps cutting G until it succeeds in balancing the budget. What level of GDP will then prevail?

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Money and the Banking System [Money] is a machine for doing quickly and commodiously what would be done, though less quickly and commodiously, without it. JOHN STUART M I LL

T

he circular flow diagrams of earlier chapters showed a “financial system” in the upper-left corner. (Look back, for example, at Figure 1 of Chapter 26 on page 561.) Saving flowed into this system and investment flowed out. Something obviously goes on inside the financial system to channel the saving back into investment, and it is time we learned just what this something is. There is another, equally important, reason for studying the financial system. The government exercises significant control over aggregate demand by manipulating monetary policy as well as fiscal policy. Indeed, most observers nowadays see monetary policy as the more important stabilization tool, and the Federal Reserve took extraordinary actions to stimulate the economy in 2008 and 2009. To understand how monetary policy works (the subject of Chapters 30 and 31), we must first acquire some understanding of the banking and financial system. By the end of this chapter, you will have that understanding.

C O N T E N T S ISSUE: WHY ARE BANKS SO HEAVILY REGULATED?

Other Definitions of the Money Supply

BANKS AND MONEY CREATION

THE NATURE OF MONEY

THE BANKING SYSTEM

Barter versus Monetary Exchange The Conceptual Definition of Money What Serves as Money?

How Banking Began Principles of Bank Management: Profits versus Safety Bank Regulation

The Limits to Money Creation by a Single Bank Multiple Money Creation by a Series of Banks The Process in Reverse: Multiple Contractions of the Money Supply

HOW THE QUANTITY OF MONEY IS MEASURED M1 M2

THE ORIGINS OF THE MONEY SUPPLY How Bankers Keep Books

WHY THE MONEY-CREATION FORMULA IS OVERSIMPLIFIED THE NEED FOR MONETARY POLICY

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

626

Part 7

Fiscal and Monetary Policy

ISSUE:

WHY ARE BANKS SO HEAVILY REGULATED?

Banking has long been one of the most heavily regulated industries in America, but the pendulum of bank regulation has swung back and forth. In the late 1970s and early 1980s, the United States eased several restrictions on interest rates and permissible bank activities. Then, after a number of banks and savings institutions went bankrupt in the 1980s, Congress and the bank regulatory agencies cracked down with stiffer regulation and much closer scrutiny. Later, the pendulum swung back in the deregulatory direction, with two landmark banking laws passed in the 1990s. Most restrictions on banking across state lines were lifted in 1994, and the once-strict separation of banking from insurance and investment banking was more or less ended in 1999. More recently, the mortgage meltdown that began in 2007 has raised new questions about what further regulations might be needed. Many have been proposed. In brief, we have spent decades wrestling with the question: How much bank regulation is enough—or too much? To answer this question intelligently, we must first address a more basic one: Why are banks so heavily regulated in the first place? A first reason is something we will learn in the next chapter: that the major “output” of the banking industry—the nation’s money supply—is an important determinant of aggregate demand. Bank managers are paid to do what is best for their stockholders. Although as we will see, what is best for bank stockholders may not always be best for the economy as a whole. Consequently, the government does not allow bankers to determine the money supply and interest rates strictly on profit considerations. A second reason for the extensive web of bank regulation is concern for the safety of depositors. In a free-enterprise system, new businesses are born and die every day; and no one other than the people immediately involved takes much notice. When a firm goes bankrupt, stockholders lose money and employees may lose their jobs. However, except for the case of very large firms, that is about all that happens. Banking is different. If banks were treated like other firms, depositors would lose money whenever one went bankrupt. That outcome is bad enough by itself, but the real danger emerges in the case of a run on a bank. When depositors get nervous about the security of their money, they may all rush to cash in their accounts. For reasons we will learn in this chapter, most banks could not survive such a “run” and would be forced to shut their doors. Worse yet, this disease is highly contagious. If one family hears that their neighbors just lost their life savings because their bank went broke, they are likely to rush to their own bank to withdraw their funds. In fact, fear of contagion is precisely what prompted British bank regulators to act in September 2007 when Northern Rock, a bank specializing in home mortgages, experienced a highly publicized run. (See the box “It’s Not Such a Wonderful Life”.) They first guaranteed all deposits in Northern Rock and later extended the guarantee to all British banks.1 Without modern forms of bank regulation, therefore, one bank failure might lead to another. Indeed, bank failures were common throughout most of U.S. history. (See Figure 1(a).) But since the 1930s, bank failures have been less common—until recently. (See Figure 1(b), and notice the sharply different scales.) And they have rarely been precipitated by runs because the government has taken steps to ensure that such an infectious disease will not spread. It has done so in several ways that we will mention in this chapter.

A run on a bank occurs when many depositors withdraw cash from their accounts all at once.

THE NATURE OF MONEY Money is so much a part of our daily existence that we take it for granted and fail to appreciate all that it accomplishes. But money is in no sense “natural.” Like the wheel, it had to be invented.

The United Kingdom did not then have a deposit insurance system comparable to the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC) in the United States. 1

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

2,200

627

Money and the Banking System

Chapter 29

FDIC established

2,000

1,600 1,400 1,200 1,000 800 600 400

Great Depression begins

Number of Bank Failures

SOURCE: Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation.

Number of Bank Failures

1,800

200 160 120 80 40 0 1945

1955

1965

1975

1985 (b)

1995

2000

2005

2009

200 0 1915 1920 1925 1930 1935 1940 1945 Year (a)

The most obvious way to trade commodities is not by using money, but by barter—a system in which people exchange one good directly for another. And the best way to appreciate what monetary exchange accomplishes is to imagine a world without it.

Barter versus Monetary Exchange Under a system of direct barter, if Farmer Jones grows corn and has a craving for peanuts, he has to find a peanut farmer, say, Farmer Smith, with a taste for corn. If he finds such a person (a situation called the double coincidence of wants), the two farmers make the trade. If that sounds easy, try to imagine how busy Farmer Jones would be if he had to repeat the sequence for everything he consumed in a week. For the most part, the desired double coincidences of wants are more likely to turn out to be double wants of coincidence. (See the accompanying cartoon.) Jones gets no peanuts and Smith gets no corn. Worse yet, with so much time spent looking for trading partners, Jones would have far less time to grow corn. In brief:

FIGURE 1 Bank Failures in the United States, 1915–2009

Barter is a system of exchange in which people directly trade one good for another, without using money as an intermediate step.

SOURCE: By permission of Johnny Hart and Creators Syndicate, Inc.

Money greases the wheels of exchange and thus makes the whole economy more productive.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

628

Part 7

Fiscal and Monetary Policy

Dealing by Wheeling on Yap

Yap, Micronesia—On this tiny South Pacific Island . . . the currency is as solid as a rock. In fact, it is rock. Limestone to be precise. For nearly 2,000 years the Yapese have used large stone wheels to pay for major purchases, such as land, canoes and permission to marry. Yap is a U.S. trust territory, and the dollar is used in grocery stores and gas stations. But reliance on stone money . . . continues. Buying property with stones is “much easier than buying it with U.S. dollars,” says John Chodad, who recently purchased a building lot with a 30-inch stone wheel. “We don’t know the value of the U.S. dollar.” Stone wheels don’t make good pocket money, so for small transactions, Yapese use other forms of currency, such as beer. . . .

Besides stone wheels and beer, the Yapese sometimes spend gaw, consisting of necklaces of stone beads strung together around a whale’s tooth. They also can buy things with yar, a currency made from large seashells. But these are small change. The people of Yap have been using stone money ever since a Yapese warrior named Anagumang first brought the huge stones over from limestone caverns on neighboring Palau, some 1,500 to 2,000 years ago. Inspired by the moon, he fashioned the stone into large circles. The rest is history. . . . By custom, the stones are worthless when broken. You never hear people on Yap musing about wanting a piece of the rock. SOURCE: University of Pennsylvania Museum (58–21338)

Primitive forms of money still exist in some remote places, as this extract from an old newspaper article shows.

SOURCE: Excerpted from Art Pine, ”Hard Assets, or Why a Loan in Yap Is Hard to Roll Over,” The Wall Street Journal, March 29, 1984, p. B1. Reprinted by permission of The Wall Street Journal. Copyright © 1984 Dow Jones & Company, Inc. All Rights Reserved Worldwide.

Under a monetary system, Farmer Jones gives up his corn for money. He does so not because he wants the money per se, but because of what that money can buy. Now he simply needs to locate a peanut farmer who wants money. And what peanut farmer does not? For these reasons, monetary exchange replaced barter at a very early stage of human civilization, and only extreme circumstances, such as massive wars and runaway inflations, have been able to bring barter (temporarily) back.

The Conceptual Definition of Money Money is the standard object used in exchanging goods and services. In short, money is the medium of exchange. The medium of exchange is the object or objects used to buy and sell other items such as goods and services. The unit of account is the standard unit for quoting prices. A store of value is an item used to store wealth from one point in time to another.

Under monetary exchange, people trade money for goods when they purchase something, and they trade goods for money when they sell something, but they do not trade goods directly for other goods. This practice defines money’s principal role as the medium of exchange. Once money has become accepted as the medium of exchange, whatever serves as money is bound to serve other functions as well. For one, it will inevitably become the unit of account—that is, the standard unit for quoting prices. Thus, if inhabitants of an idyllic tropical island use coconuts as money, they would be foolish to quote prices in terms of seashells. Money also may come to be used as a store of value. If Farmer Jones’s corn sales bring him more cash than he wants to spend right away, he may find it convenient to store the difference temporarily in the form of money. He knows that money can be sold easily for goods and services at a later date, whereas land, gold, and other stores of value might not be. Of course, if inflation is substantial, he may decide to forgo the convenience of money and store his wealth in some other form rather than see its purchasing power eroded. So money’s role as a store of value is far from inevitable. Because money may not always serve as a store of value, and because other commodities may act as stores of value, we will not include the store-of-value function as part of our conceptual definition of money. Instead, we simply label as “money” whatever serves as the medium of exchange.

What Serves as Money? Anthropologists and historians can testify that a bewildering variety of objects have served as money in different times and places. Cattle, stones, candy bars, cigarettes, woodpecker Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

629

Money and the Banking System

Chapter 29

Over the last few years, the U.S. Treasury has replaced much of America’s paper money with new notes designed to be much more difficult to counterfeit. Several of the new anticounterfeiting features are visible to the naked eye. By inspecting one of the new $20 bills—the ones with the big picture of Andrew Jackson that looks like it’s been through a washing machine—you can easily see several of them. (Others are harder to detect.) Most obvious are the various shades of coloration, including the silver blue eagle to Jackson’s left. Next, hold the bill up to a light, with Jackson facing you. Near the left edge, you will find some small type set vertically, rather than horizontally. If your eyesight is good, you will be able to read what it says. If you were a counterfeiter, you would find this line devilishly difficult to duplicate. Third, twist the bill and see how the gold numeral “20” in the lower-right corner glistens and changes color. An optical illusion? No, a clever way to make life hard on counterfeiters.

SOURCE: © AP Images

Remaking America’s Paper Money

scalps, porpoise teeth, and giraffe tails provide a few of the more colorful examples. (For another example, see the box “Dealing by Wheeling on Yap” on the previous page.) In primitive or less organized societies, the commodities that served as money generally held value in themselves. If not used as money, cattle could be slaughtered for food, cigarettes could be smoked, and so on. Such commodity money generally runs into several severe difficulties. To be useful as a medium of exchange, a commodity must be easily divisible—which makes cattle a poor choice. It must also be of uniform, or at least readily identifiable, quality so that inferior substitutes are easy to recognize. This shortcoming may be why woodpecker scalps never achieved great popularity. The medium of exchange must also be storable and durable, which presents a serious problem for candybar money. Finally, because people will carry and store commodity money, it is helpful if the item is compact—that is, if it has high value per unit of volume and weight. All of these traits make it natural that gold and silver have circulated as money since the first coins were struck about 2,500 years ago. Because they have high value in nonmonetary uses, a lot of purchasing power can be carried without too much weight. Pieces of gold are also storable, divisible (with a little trouble), and of identifiable quality (with a little more trouble). The same characteristics suggest that paper would make an even better money. The Chinese invented paper money in the eleventh century, and Marco Polo brought the idea to Europe. Because we can print any number on it that we please, we can make paper money as divisible as we like. People can also carry a large value of paper money in a lightweight and compact form. Paper is easy to store and, with a little cleverness, we can make counterfeiting challenging, though never impossible. (See the box “Remaking America’s Paper Money” above.) Paper cannot, however, serve as commodity money because its value per square inch in alternative uses is so low. A paper currency that is repudiated by its issuer can, perhaps, be used as wallpaper or to wrap fish, but these uses will surely represent only a small fraction of the paper’s value as money.2 Contrary to the popular expression, such a currency

Commodity money is an object in use as a medium of exchange that also has a substantial value in alternative (nonmonetary) uses.

The first paper money issued by the U.S. federal government, the Continental dollar, was essentially repudiated. (Actually, the new government of the United States redeemed the Continentals for 1 cent on the dollar in the 1790s.) This event gave rise to the derisive expression, “It’s not worth a Continental.”

2

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

630

Part 7

Fiscal and Monetary Policy

Fiat money is money that is decreed as such by the government. It is of little value as a commodity, but it maintains its value as a medium of exchange because people have faith that the issuer will stand behind the pieces of printed paper and limit their production.

literally is worth the paper it is printed on—which is to say that it is not worth much. Thus, paper money is always fiat money. Money in the contemporary United States is almost entirely fiat money. Look at a dollar bill. Next to George Washington’s picture it states: “This note is legal tender for all debts, public and private.” Nowhere on the certificate is there a promise, stated or implied, that the U.S. government will exchange it for anything else. A dollar bill is convertible into, say, four quarters or ten dimes—but not into gold, chocolate, or any other commodity. Why do people hold these pieces of paper? Because they know that others are willing to accept them for things of intrinsic value—food, rent, shoes, and so on. If this confidence ever evaporated, dollar bills would cease serving as a medium of exchange and, given that they make ugly wallpaper, would become virtually worthless. Don’t panic. This series of events is hardly likely to occur. Our current monetary system has evolved over hundreds of years, during which commodity money was first replaced by full-bodied paper money—paper certificates that were backed by gold or silver of equal value held in the issuer’s vaults. Then the full-bodied paper money was replaced by certificates that were only partially backed by gold and silver. Finally, we arrived at our present system, in which paper money has no “backing” whatsoever. Like hesitant swimmers who first dip their toes, then their legs, then their whole body into a cold swimming pool, we have “tested the water” at each step of the way—and found it to our liking. It is unlikely that we will ever take a step back in the other direction.

HOW THE QUANTITY OF MONEY IS MEASURED Because the amount of money in circulation is important for the determination of national product and the price level, the government must know how much money there is. Thus we must devise some measure of the money supply. Our conceptual definition of money as the medium of exchange raises difficult questions about just which items to include and which items to exclude when we count up the money supply. Such questions have long made the statistical definition of money a subject of dispute. In fact, the U.S. government has several official definitions of the money supply, two of which we will meet shortly. Some components are obvious. All of our coins and paper money—the small change of our economic system—clearly should count as money. But we cannot stop there if we want to include the main vehicle for making payments in our society, for the lion’s share of our nation’s payments are made neither in metal nor in paper money, but by check. Checking deposits are actually no more than bookkeeping entries in bank ledgers. Many people think of checks as a convenient way to pass coins or dollar bills to someone else, but that is not so. For example, when you pay the grocer $50 by check, dollar bills rarely change hands. Instead, that check normally travels back to your bank, where $50 is deducted from the bookkeeping entry that records your account and $50 is added to the bookkeeping entry for your grocer’s account. (If you and the grocer hold accounts at different banks, more books get involved, but still no coins or bills will likely move.) The volume of money held in the form of checkable deposits far exceeds the volume of currency.

M1 So it seems imperative to include checkable deposits in any useful definition of the money supply. Unfortunately, this is not an easy task nowadays, because of the wide variety of ways to transfer money by check. Traditional checking accounts in commercial banks are the most familiar vehicle, but many people can also write checks on their savings accounts, on their deposits at credit unions, on their mutual funds, on their accounts with stockbrokers, and so on. One popular definition of the money supply draws the line early and includes only coins, paper money, traveler’s checks, conventional checking accounts, and certain other checkable deposits in banks and savings institutions. In the official U.S. statistics, this Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 29

631

Money and the Banking System

narrowly defined concept of money is called M1. The upper part of Figure 2 shows the composition of M1 as of December 2009.

FIGURE 2 Two Definitions of the Money Supply, December 2009

M2

Currency outside banks $867 billion

Checking deposits in commercial banks $442 billion

SOURCE: Federal Reserve

Other types of accounts allow withdrawals by check, so they are also candidates for inclusion in the money supply. Most notably, money market deposit accounts allow their owners to write only a few checks per month but pay market-determined interest rates. Consumers have Other found these accounts attractive, and balances in them now exceed all checkable the checkable deposits included in M1. deposits $384 billion In addition, many mutual fund organizations and brokerage houses offer money market mutual funds. These funds sell shares and M1 = $1,693 billion use the proceeds to purchase a variety of short-term securities. The important point for our purposes is that owners of shares in money market mutual funds can withdraw their funds by writing checks. Thus, depositors can use their holdings of fund shares just like checkM1 ing accounts. $1,693 billion Finally, although you cannot write a check on a savings account, modern banking procedures have blurred the distinction between Savings checking balances and savings balances. For example, most banks deposits $6,017 billion these days offer convenient electronic transfers of funds from one account to another, by telephone, Internet, or by pushing a button on an automatic teller machine (ATM). Consequently, savings balances Money market can become checkable almost instantly. For this reason, savings acmutual funds $814 billion counts are included—along with money market deposit accounts and M2 = $8,524 billion money market mutual fund shares—in the broader definition of the money supply known as M2. The composition of M2 as of December 2009 is shown in the lower part of Figure 2. You can see that savings deposits predominate, dwarfing M1. Figure 2 illustrates that our money supply comes not only from banks but also from savings institutions, brokerage houses, and mutual fund organizations. Even so, banks still play a predominant role.

Other Definitions of the Money Supply Some economists do not want to stop counting at M2; they prefer still broader definitions of money (M3, and so on), which include more types of bank deposits and other closely related assets. The inescapable problem, however, is that there is no obvious place to stop, no clear line of demarcation between those assets that are money and those that are merely close substitutes for money—so-called near moneys. If we define an asset’s liquidity as the ease with which its holder can convert it into cash, there is a spectrum of assets of varying degrees of liquidity. Everything in M1 is completely liquid, the money market fund shares and passbook savings accounts included in M2 are a bit less so, and so on, until we encounter items such as short-term government bonds, which, while still quite liquid, would not be included in anyone’s definition of the money supply. Any number of different Ms can be defined—and have been—by drawing the line in different places. And yet more complexities arise. For example, credit cards clearly serve as a medium of exchange. Should they be included in the money supply? Of course, you say. But how much money does your credit card represent? Is it the amount you currently owe on the card, which may be zero? Or is it your entire line of credit, even though you may never use it all? Neither choice seems sensible. Furthermore, you will probably wind up writing a check (which is included in M1) to pay your credit card bill. These are two reasons why economists have so far ignored credit cards in their definitions of money. 3

This amount includes travelers’ checks and NOW (negotiable order of withdrawal) accounts.

The narrowly defined money supply, usually abbreviated M1, is the sum of all coins and paper money in circulation, plus certain checkable deposit balances at banks and savings institutions.3 The broadly defined money supply, usually abbreviated M2, is the sum of all coins and paper money in circulation, plus all types of checking account balances, plus most forms of savings account balances, plus shares in money market mutual funds. Near moneys are liquid assets that are close substitutes for money. An asset’s liquidity refers to the ease with which it can be converted into cash.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

632

Part 7

Fiscal and Monetary Policy

We could mention further complexities, but an introductory course in economics is not the place to get bogged down in complex definitional issues. So we will simply adhere to the convention that: “Money” consists only of coins, paper money, and checkable deposits.

THE BANKING SYSTEM Now that we have defined money and seen how to measure it, we turn our attention to the principal creators of money—the banks. Banking is a complicated business—and getting more so. If you go further in your study of economics, you will probably learn more about the operations of banks. For present purposes, a few simple principles will suffice. Let’s start at the beginning.

How Banking Began

Fractional reserve banking is a system under which bankers keep as reserves only a fraction of the funds they hold on deposit.

When Adam and Eve left the Garden of Eden, they did not encounter an ATM. Banking had to be invented. With a little imagination, we can see how the first banks must have begun. When money was made of gold or other metals, it was inconvenient for consumers and merchants to carry it around and weigh and assay its purity every time they made a transaction. So the practice developed of leaving gold in a goldsmith’s safe storage facilities and carrying in its place a receipt stating that John Doe did indeed own five ounces of gold. When people began trading goods and services for the goldsmiths’ receipts, rather than for the gold itself, the receipts became an early form of paper money. At this stage, paper money was fully backed by gold. Gradually, however, the goldsmiths began to notice that the amount of gold they were actually required to pay out in a day was but a small fraction of the total gold they had stored in their warehouses. Then one day some enterprising goldsmith hit upon a momentous idea that must have made him fabulously wealthy. His thinking probably ran something like this: “I have 2,000 ounces of gold stored away in my vault, for which I collect storage fees from my customers. I am never called upon to pay out more than 100 ounces on a single day. What harm could it do if I lent out, say, half the gold I now have? I’ll still have more than enough to pay off any depositors who come in for withdrawals, so no one will ever know the difference. And I could earn 30 additional ounces of gold each year in interest on the loans I make (at 3 percent interest on 1,000 ounces). With this profit, I could lower my service charges to depositors and so attract still more deposits. I think I’ll do it.” With this resolution, the modern system of fractional reserve banking was born. This system has three features that are crucially important to this chapter.

Bank Profitability By getting deposits at zero interest and lending some of them out at positive interest rates, goldsmiths made profits. The history of banking as a profitmaking industry was begun and has continued to this date. Banks, like other enterprises, are in business to earn profits.

Bank Discretion over the Money Supply When goldsmiths decided to keep only fractions of their total deposits on reserve and lend out the balance, they acquired the ability to create money. As long as they kept 100 percent reserves, each gold certificate represented exactly 1 ounce of gold. So whether people decided to carry their gold or leave it with their goldsmiths did not affect the money supply, which was set by the volume of gold. With the advent of fractional reserve banking, however, new paper certificates appeared whenever goldsmiths lent out some of the gold they held on deposit. The loans, in effect, created new money. In this way, the total amount of money came to depend on

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Money and the Banking System

Chapter 29

633

the amount of gold that each goldsmith felt compelled to keep in his vault. For any given volume of gold on deposit, the lower the reserves the goldsmiths kept, the more loans they could make, and therefore the more money would circulate. Although we no longer use gold to back our money, this principle remains true today. Bankers’ decisions on how much to hold in reserves influence the supply of money. A substantial part of the rationale for modern monetary policy is, as we have mentioned, that profit-seeking bankers might not create the amount of money that is best for society. For example, when bankers got scared in the financial crisis of 2008–2009, they started holding vastly more reserves. Had the Federal Reserve not intervened, the money supply would have contracted violently.

Exposure to Runs A goldsmith who kept 100 percent reserves never had to worry about a run on his vault. Even if all his depositors showed up at the door at once, he could always convert their paper receipts back into gold. As soon as the first goldsmith decided to get by with only fractional reserves, the possibility of a run on the vault became a real concern. If that first goldsmith who lent out half his gold had found 51 percent of his customers at his door one unlucky day, he would have had a lot of explaining to do. Similar problems have worried bankers for centuries. The danger of a run on the bank has induced bankers to keep prudent reserves and to lend out money carefully. Runs on banks are, for the most part, a relic of the past. You may have seen the famous bank-run scene in Frank Capra’s 1946 movie classic It’s a Wonderful Life, with Jimmy Stewart playing a young banker named George Bailey. But you’ve probably never seen an actual bank run. In September 2007, however, quite a few people in England did see one when depositors “ran” Northern Rock, a large mortgage bank. (See the box “It’s Not Such a Wonderful Life” below.) As we observed earlier, avoiding bank runs is one of the main rationales for bank regulation. They have not happened in the United States, despite many recent bank failures.

It’s Not Such a Wonderful Life The subprime mortgage crisis that started in 2007 (described in greater detail later on page 635) quickly spread beyond the borders of the United States. One of its victims was a large British mortgage lender called Northern Rock. In mid-September 2007, rumors that the bank was in trouble precipitated the first bank run in England since the nineteenth century. Here is the scene as described in the online version of The Times (of London) on September 14, 2007:

SOURCE: © AP Images/Andrew Milligan/PA

Long queues formed outside branches of Northern Rock today as anxious customers waited to withdraw savings after the bank was forced to seek an emergency bailout from the Bank of England. Savers went in person to Northern Rock’s branches to withdraw their money, after facing difficulties contacting the bank on the phone or via the internet. William Gough, 75, arriving at a Northern Rock branch in Central London this morning, said he did not believe the bank’s assurances that his savings were safe and intended to withdraw his funds. “. . . At the time I put the money in I wouldn’t have imagined something like this would happen,” Mr Gough said while joining the back of a 40-strong queue. Customers queued for up to an hour and, as news of the Bank of England bailout spread, the throng inside the branch was so dense that some struggled to open the door. Gary Diamond beat the crowd by arriving early. “I came down here to withdraw my funds because I’m concerned that Northern Rock are not still going to be in existence,” he said after closing his accounts. He added that there was a danger

that if others followed suit it could worsen Northern Rock’s position. “But I don’t want to be the mug left without my savings,” he said. [Other] customers said they were not concerned about the stability of the bank but had been forced to act over fears of a bank run. Paul De Lamare, a 46-year-old consultant, said: “. . . I don’t think the Bank of England would allow anything to happen. But I’m just trying to avoid getting caught short, so I’ve taken out cash.”

SOURCE: Joe Bolger and Marcus Leroux, “Northern Rock Savers Rush to Empty Accounts”, Times Online, September 14, 2007.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

634

Part 7

Fiscal and Monetary Policy

Principles of Bank Management: Profits versus Safety Bankers have a reputation for conservatism in politics, dress, and business affairs—the latter now somewhat tarnished. From what has been said so far, the economic rationale for this conservatism should be clear. Checking deposits are pure fiat money. Years ago, these deposits were “backed” by nothing more than a particular bank’s promise to convert them into currency on demand. If people lost trust in a bank, it was doomed. Thus, bankers have traditionally relied on a reputation for prudence, which they achieved in two principal ways. First, they maintained a sufficiently generous level of reserves to minimize their vulnerability to runs. Second, they were cautious in making loans and investments, because large losses on their loans could undermine their depositors’ confidence. It is important to realize that banking under a system of fractional reserves is an inherently risky business that is rendered safe only by cautious and prudent management. America’s long history of bank failures (see Figure 1), as well as recent events, bear sober testimony to the fact that many bankers were neither cautious nor prudent. Why not? Because caution is not the route to high profits. Bank profits are maximized by keeping reserves as low as possible and by making at least some loans to borrowers with questionable credit standing who will pay higher interest rates. Many such loans were made in the last decade. The art of bank management is to strike the appropriate balance between the lure of profits and the need for safety. If a banker errs by being too stodgy, his bank will earn inadequate profits. If he errs by taking unwarranted risks, his bank may not survive at all.

Bank Regulation Governments in virtually every society have decided that profit-minded bankers will not necessarily strike the balance between profits and safety exactly where society wants it. So they have constructed a web of regulations designed to ensure depositors’ safety and to control the money supply.

Deposit Insurance

Deposit insurance is a system that guarantees that depositors will not lose money even if their bank goes bankrupt.

Moral hazard is the idea that people insured against the consequences of risk will engage in riskier behaviors.

The principal innovation that guarantees the safety of bank deposits is deposit insurance. Today, most U.S. bank deposits are insured against loss by the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC)—an agency of the federal government. If your bank belongs to the FDIC, as almost all do, your account is insured for up to $250,000 regardless of what happens to the bank. Thus, although bank failures may spell disaster for the bank’s stockholders, they do not create concern for many depositors. Deposit insurance eliminates the motive for customers to rush to their bank just because they hear some bad news about the bank’s finances. Many observers give this innovation much of the credit for the pronounced decline in bank failures after the FDIC was established in 1933— which is apparent in Figure 1. Despite this achievement, some critics of FDIC insurance worry that depositors who are freed from any risk of loss from a failing bank will not bother to shop around for safer banks. This problem is an example of what is called moral hazard. The general idea that, when people are well insured against a particular risk, they will put little effort into making sure that the risk does not occur. (Example: A business with good fire insurance may not install an expensive sprinkler system.) In this context, some of the FDIC’s critics argue that high levels of deposit insurance actually make the banking system less safe.

Bank Supervision Partly for this reason, the government takes several steps to see that banks do not get into financial trouble. For one thing, various regulatory authorities conduct periodic bank examinations to keep tabs on the financial conditions and business practices of the banks under their purview. After a rash of bank failures in the late 1980s and early 1990s (visible in Figure 1(b)), U.S. bank supervision was tightened by legislation that permits the authorities to intervene early in the affairs of financially troubled banks. Further regulations may be on their way in reaction to the recent bank crisis. Other laws and regulations limit the kinds and quantities of assets in which banks may invest. For example, banks are permitted to own only limited amounts of common stock. Both of these forms of regulation, and others, are clearly aimed at keeping banks safe. That said, there is no such thing as perfect safety, as the subprime mortgage debacle illustrated (see the box on the next page). Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 29

635

Money and the Banking System

What Happened to the Subprime Mortgage Market? Federal Reserve stepped in to quell the panic by lending massively to banks and then cutting interest rates. The medicine helped a bit, but losses from the housing downturn continued, banks contracted and some failed, and credit became harder to obtain. By early 2008, the economy was in recession.

SOURCE: © AP Images/Reed Saxon

One valuable, but also somewhat risky, innovation in American banking during the past decade was the rapid expansion of so-called subprime mortgages, meaning loans to prospective homeowners with less-than-stellar credit histories. Often, these borrowers were low-income and poorly educated people. Naturally, bankers expected higher default rates on subprime loans than on prime loans, and so they charged higher interest rates to compensate for expected future losses. That was all perfectly sound banking practice. But a few things went wrong, especially in 2005 and 2006. For one thing, subprime loans started to be made with little or no evidence that the homeowners had enough regular income (for example, a large-enough paycheck) to meet their monthly payments. That is not sound banking practice. Second, many subprime loans carried “adjustable rates,” which in practice meant that the monthly mortgage payment could skyrocket after, say, two years. That created a ticking time bomb that should have raised serious questions about affordability of the mortgages—but apparently did not. Third, about half of these risky loans were not made by regulated banks at all, but rather by mortgage brokers—who were not regulated by the federal government and who sometimes followed unscrupulous sales practices. Finally, the general euphoria over housing (the housing “bubble”) led many people to believe that all these dangers would be papered over by ever-rising home prices. When house prices stopped rising so fast in 2005–2006, the game of musical chairs ended abruptly. Default rates on subprime mortgages soared. Then, in 2007, the subprime market virtually shut down, precipitating a near panic in financial markets in the United States and around the world. In the United States, the

Reserve Requirements A final type of regulation also has some bearing on safety but is motivated primarily by the government’s desire to control the money supply. We have seen that the amount of money any bank will issue depends on the amount of reserves it elects to keep. For this reason, most banks are subject by law to minimum required reserves. Although banks may (and sometimes do) keep reserves in excess of these legal minimums, they may not keep less. This regulation places an upper limit on the money supply. The rest of this chapter is concerned with the details of this mechanism, at least as it operates in normal times.

Required reserves are the minimum amount of reserves (in cash or the equivalent) required by law. Normally, required reserves are proportional to the volume of deposits.

THE ORIGINS OF THE MONEY SUPPLY Our objective is to understand how the money supply is determined. Before we can fully understand the process by which money is “created,” we must acquire at least a nodding acquaintance with the mechanics of modern banking.

How Bankers Keep Books The first thing to know is how to distinguish assets from liabilities. An asset of a bank is something of value that the bank owns. This “thing” may be a physical object, such as the bank building or a computer, or it may be a piece of paper, such as an IOU signed by a customer to whom the bank has made a loan (e.g., a mortgage). A liability of a bank is something of value that the bank owes. Most bank liabilities take the form of bookkeeping entries. For example, if you have an account in the Main Street Bank, your bank balance is a liability of the bank. (It is, of course, an asset to you.) There is an easy test for whether some piece of paper or bookkeeping entry is a bank’s asset or liability. Ask yourself a simple question: If this paper were converted into cash, would the bank receive the cash (if so, it is an asset) or pay it out (if so, it is a liability)?

An asset of an individual or business firm is an item of value that the individual or firm owns. A liability of an individual or business firm is an item of value that the individual or firm owes. Many liabilities are known as debts.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

636

Part 7

Fiscal and Monetary Policy

A balance sheet is an accounting statement listing the values of all assets on the left side and the values of all liabilities and net worth on the right side. Net worth is the value of all assets minus the value of all liabilities.

This test makes it clear that loans to customers are assets of the bank (when a loan is repaid, the bank collects), whereas customers’ deposits are bank liabilities (when a deposit is cashed in, the bank pays). Of course, things are just the opposite to the bank’s customers: The loans are liabilities and the deposits are assets. When accountants draw up a complete list of all the bank’s assets and liabilities, the resulting document is called the bank’s balance sheet. Typically, the value of all the bank’s assets exceeds the value of all its liabilities. (On the rare occasions when this is not so, the bank is in serious trouble.) In what sense, then, do balance sheets “balance”? They balance because accountants have invented the concept of net worth to balance the books. Specifically, they define the net worth of a bank to be the difference between the value of all its assets and the value of all its liabilities. Thus, by definition, when accountants add net worth to liabilities, the sum they get must be equal to the value of the bank’s assets: Assets = Liabilities + Net worth

Table 1 illustrates this point with the balance sheet of a fictitious bank, Bank-a-Mythica, whose finances are extremely simple. On December 31, 2007, it had only two kinds of assets (listed on the left side of the balance sheet)—$1 million in cash reserves and $4.5 million in outstanding loans to its customers, that is, in customers’ IOUs. And it had only one type of liability (listed on the right side)—$5 million in checking deposits. The difference between total assets ($5.5 million) and total liabilities ($5.0 million) was the bank’s net worth ($500,000), also shown on the right side of the balance sheet. TABLE 1 Balance Sheet of Bank-a-Mythica, December 31, 2007

Assets Assets Reserves Loans outstanding Total Addendum: Bank Reserves Actual reserves Required reserves Excess reserves

Liabilities and Net Worth $1,000,000 $4,500,000 $5,500,000 $1,000,000 21,000,000 0

Liabilities Checking deposits

$5,000,000

Net Worth Stockholders’ equity

22$500,000

Total

$5,500,000

BANKS AND MONEY CREATION

Deposit creation refers to the process by which a fractional reserve banking system turns $1 of bank reserves into several dollars of bank deposits.

Excess reserves are any reserves held in excess of the legal minimum.

Let us now turn to the process of deposit creation. Many bankers will deny that they have any ability to “create” money. The phrase itself has a suspiciously hocus-pocus sound to it. The protesting bankers are not quite right. Although any individual bank’s ability to create money is severely limited, the banking system as a whole can achieve much more than the sum of its parts. Through the modern alchemy of deposit creation, it can turn one dollar into many dollars. To understand this important process, we had better proceed step-by-step, beginning with the case of a single bank, our hypothetical Bank-a-Mythica.

The Limits to Money Creation by a Single Bank According to the balance sheet in Table 1, Bank-a-Mythica holds cash reserves of $1 million, equal to 20 percent of its $5 million in deposits. Assume that this is the reserve ratio prescribed by law and that the bank strives to keep its reserves down to the legal minimum; that is, it strives to keep its excess reserves at zero. Now let us suppose that on January 2, 2008, an eccentric widower comes into Bank-aMythica and deposits $100,000 in cash in his checking account. The bank now has $100,000 more in cash reserves and $100,000 more in checking deposits. Because deposits are up by $100,000, required reserves rise by only $20,000, leaving $80,000 in excess reserves. Table 2 illustrates the effects of this transaction on Bank-a-Mythica’s balance sheet. Tables such as

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Money and the Banking System

Chapter 29

TABLE 2 Changes in Bank-a-Mythica’s Balance Sheet, January 2, 2008

Assets Reserves

Liabilities +$100,000

Checking deposits

+$100,000

Addendum: Changes in Reserves Actual reserves +$100,000 Required reserves +$ 20,000 Excess reserves +$ 80,000

this one, which show changes in balance sheets rather than the balance sheets themselves, will help us follow the money-creation process.4 Bank-a-Mythica is unlikely to be happy with the situation illustrated in Table 2, for it is holding $80,000 in excess reserves on which it earns no interest. So as soon as possible, it will lend out the extra $80,000—let us say to Hard-Pressed Construction Company. This loan leads to the balance sheet changes shown in Table 3: Bank-a-Mythica’s loans rise by $80,000 while its holdings of cash reserves fall by $80,000. TABLE 3 Changes in Bank-a-Mythica’s Balance Sheet, January 3–6, 2008

Assets

Liabilities

Loans outstanding Reserves

+$80,000 –$80,000

Addendum: Changes Actual reserves Required reserves Excess reserves

in Reserves –$80,000 No change –$80,000

No change

By combining Tables 2 and 3, we arrive at Table 4, which summarizes the bank’s transactions for the week. Reserves are up $20,000, loans are up $80,000, and, now that the bank has had a chance to adjust to the inflow of deposits, it no longer holds excess reserves. Looking at Table 4 and keeping in mind our specific definition of money, it appears at first that the chairman of Bank-a-Mythica is right when he claims not to have engaged in the nefarious-sounding practice of “money creation.” All that happened was that, in exchange for the $100,000 in cash it received, the bank issued the widower a checking balance of $100,000. This transaction does not change M1; it merely converts one form of money (currency) into another (checking deposits). TABLE 4 Changes in Bank-a-Mythica’s Balance Sheet, January 2–6, 2008

Assets Reserves Loans outstanding

Liabilities +$20,000 +$80,000

Checking deposits

+$100,000

Addendum: Changes in Reserves Actual reserves +$20,000 Required reserves +$20,000 Excess reserves No change

In all such tables, which are called T accounts, the two sides of the ledger must balance. This balance is required because changes in assets and changes in liabilities must be equal if the balance sheet is to balance both before and after the transaction.

4

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

637

638

Part 7

Fiscal and Monetary Policy

But wait. What happened to the $100,000 in cash that the eccentric man brought to the bank? The table shows that Bank-a-Mythica retained $20,000 in its vault. Because this currency is no longer in circulation, it no longer counts in the official money supply, M1. (Notice that Figure 2 included only “currency outside banks.”) The other $80,000, which the bank lent out, is still in circulation. It is held by Hard-Pressed Construction Company, which probably will redeposit it in some other bank. Even before this new deposit is made, the original $100,000 in cash has supported an increase in the money supply. There is now $100,000 in checking deposits and $80,000 of cash in circulation, making a total of $180,000—whereas prior to the original deposit there was only the $100,000 in cash. The money-creation process has begun.

Multiple Money Creation by a Series of Banks By tracing the $80,000 in cash, we can see how the process of money creation gathers momentum. Suppose that Hard-Pressed Construction Company, which banks across town at the First National Bank, deposits the $80,000 in its bank account. First National’s reserves increase by $80,000. Because its deposits rise by $80,000, its required reserves increase by 20 percent of this amount, or $16,000. If First National Bank behaves like Bank-a-Mythica, it will lend out the $64,000 of excess reserves. Table 5 shows the effects of these events on First National Bank’s balance sheet. (We do not show the preliminary steps corresponding to Tables 2 and 3 separately.) At this stage in the chain, the original $100,000 in cash has led to $180,000 in deposits—$100,000 at Bank-a-Mythica and $80,000 at First National Bank—and $64,000 in cash, which is still in circulation (in the hands of the recipient of First National’s loan—Al’s Auto Shop). Thus, instead of the original $100,000, a total of $244,000 worth of money ($180,000 in checking deposits plus $64,000 in cash) has been created. TABL E 5 Changes in First National Bank’s Balance Sheet

Assets Reserves Loans outstanding

Liabilities 1$16,000 1$64,000

Checking deposits +$80,000

Addendum: Changes in Reserves Actual reserves 1$16,000 Required reserves 1$16,000 Excess reserves No change

To coin a phrase, the bucks do not stop there. Al’s Auto Shop will presumably deposit the proceeds from its loan into its own account at Second National Bank, leading to the balance sheet adjustments shown in Table 6 when Second National makes an additional loan of $51,200 rather than hold on to excess reserves. You can see how the money creation process continues. TABL E 6 Changes in Second National Bank’s Balance Sheet

Assets Reserves Loans outstanding

Liabilities 1$12,800 1$51,200

Checking deposits +$64,000

Addendum: Changes in Reserves Actual reserves 1$12,800 Required reserves 1$12,800 Excess reserves No change

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

639

Money and the Banking System

Chapter 29

Figure 3 summarizes the balance sheet changes of the first five banks in the chain (from Bank-a-Mythica through the Fourth National Bank) graphically, based on the assumptions that (1) each bank holds exactly the 20 percent required reserves, and (2) each loan recipient redeposits the proceeds in the next bank. But the chain does not end there. The Main Street Movie Theatre, which received the $32,768 loan from the Fourth National Bank, deposits these funds into the Fifth National Bank. Fifth National has to keep only 20 percent of this deposit, or $6,553.60, on reserve and will lend out the balance. And so the chain continues. Where does it all end? The running sums on the right side of Figure 3 show what eventually happens to the entire banking system. The initial deposit of $100,000 in cash is ultimately absorbed in bank reserves (column 1), leading to a total of $500,000 in new deposits (column 2) and $400,000 in new loans (column 3). The money supply rises by $400,000 because the nonbank public eventually holds $100,000 less in currency and $500,000 more in checking deposits. As we see, there really is some hocus-pocus. Somehow, an initial deposit of $100,000 leads to $500,000 in new bank deposits—a multiple expansion of $5 for every original dollar—and a net increase of $400,000 in the money supply. We need to understand why this is so, but first let us verify that the calculations in Figure 3 are correct. If you look carefully at the numbers, you will see that each column forms a geometric progression; specifically, each entry is equal to exactly 80 percent of the entry before it. Recall that in our discussion of the multiplier in Chapter 26 we learned how to sum an infinite

FI GUR E 3

Running Sums (1) Reserves

$80,000 lent out

SOURCE: This schematic diagram was suggested to us by Dr. Ivan K. Cohen, whom we thank.

$64,000 lent out

$180,000

$51,200 lent out

$244,000

$40,960 lent out

$295,200

$32,768 lent out

And so on . . .

$236,160

$59,040

$336,160

$40,960 deposit $8,192 on reserve

$195,200

$48,800

$51,200 deposit $10,240 on reserve

$144,000

$36,000

$64,000 deposit $12,800 on reserve

The Chain of Multiple Deposit Creation

$80,000

$20,000

$80,000 deposit $16,000 on reserve

(3) Loans

$100,000

$100,000 deposit $20,000 on reserve

(2) Deposits

$67,232

• • • • • • $100,000 $500,000

$268,928

• • • $400,000

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

640

Part 7

Fiscal and Monetary Policy

geometric progression, which is just what each of these chains is. In particular, if the common ratio is R, the sum of an infinite geometric progression is:

1 1 R 1 R2 1 R3 1 . . . 5

1 12R

By applying this formula to the chain of checking deposits in Figure 3, we get:

$100,000 1 $80,000 1 $64,000 1 $51,200 1 . . . 5 $100,000 3 ( 1 1 0.80 1 0.64 1 0.512 1 . . . ) 5 $100,000 3 ( 1 1 0.80 1 0.802 1 0.803 1 . . . ) $100,000 1 5 5 $500,000 5 $100,000 3 1 2 0.80 0.20 Proceeding similarly, we can verify that the new loans sum to $400,000 and that the new required reserves sum to $100,000. (Check these figures as exercises.) Thus the numbers at the bottom of Figure 3 are correct. Let us, therefore, think through the logic behind them. The chain of deposit creation ends only when there are no more excess reserves to be loaned out—that is, when the entire $100,000 in cash is tied up in required reserves. That explains why the last entry in column (1) of Figure 3 must be $100,000. With a reserve ratio of 20 percent, excess reserves disappear only when checking deposits expand by $500,000—which is the last entry in column (2). Finally, because balance sheets must balance, the sum of all newly created assets (reserves plus loans) must equal the sum of all newly created liabilities ($500,000 in deposits). That leaves $400,000 for new loans—which is the last entry in column (3). More generally, if the reserve ratio is some number m (rather than the one-fifth in our example), each dollar of deposits requires only a fraction m of a dollar in reserves. The common ratio in the preceding formula is, therefore, R 5 1 2 m, and deposits must expand by 1/m for each dollar of new reserves that are injected into the system. This suggests the general formula for multiple money creation when the required reserve ratio is some number m: OVERSIMPLIFIED MONEY MULTIPLIER FORMULA The money multiplier is the ratio of newly created bank deposits to new reserves.

If the required reserve ratio is some fraction, m, the banking system as a whole can convert each $1 of reserves into $1/m in new money. That is, the so-called money multiplier is given by: Change in money supply = (1/m) 3 Change in reserves

Although this formula correctly describes what happens in our example, it leaves out an important detail. The initial deposit of $100,000 in cash at Bank-a-Mythica constitutes $100,000 in new reserves (see Table 2). Applying a multiplier of 1/m 5 1/0.20 5 5 to this $100,000, we conclude that bank deposits will rise by $500,000—which is just what happens. Remember that the process started when the eccentric widower took $100,000 in cash and deposited it in his bank account. Thus the public’s holdings of money—which includes both checking deposits and cash—increase by only $400,000 in this case: There is $500,000 more in deposits, but $100,000 less in cash.

The Process in Reverse: Multiple Contractions of the Money Supply Let us now briefly consider how this deposit-creation mechanism operates in reverse—as a system of deposit destruction. In particular, suppose that our eccentric widower returned to Bank-a-Mythica to withdraw $100,000 from his checking account and return it to his mattress, where it rightfully belongs. Bank-a-Mythica’s required reserves would fall by $20,000 as a result of this transaction (20 percent of $100,000), but its actual reserves would fall by $100,000. The bank would be $80,000 short, as indicated in Table 7(a).

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 29

641

Money and the Banking System

TABLE 7 Changes in the Balance Sheet of Bank-a-Mythica

(a)

(b)

Assets

Liabilities Checking deposits

2$100,000

Reserves

2$100,000

Addendum: Changes in Reserves Actual reserves 2$100,000 Required reserves 2$20,000 Excess reserves 2$80,000

Assets

Liabilities

Reserves 1$80,000 Loans outstanding 2$80,000 Addendum: Changes in Reserves Actual reserves 1$80,000 Required reserves No Change Excess reserves 1$80,000

No Change

How would the bank react to this discrepancy? As some of its outstanding loans are routinely paid off, it will cease granting new ones until it has accumulated the necessary $80,000 in required reserves. The data for Bank-a-Mythica’s contraction are shown in Table 7(b), assuming that borrowers pay off their loans in cash.5 Where did the borrowers get this money? Probably by making withdrawals from other banks. In this case, assume that the funds came from First National Bank, which loses $80,000 in deposits and $80,000 in reserves. It finds itself short some $64,000 in reserves, as shown in Table 8(a), and therefore must reduce its loan commitments by $64,000, as in Table 8(b). This reaction, of course, causes some other bank to suffer a loss of reserves and deposits of $64,000, and the whole process repeats just as it did in the case of deposit expansion. TABLE 8 Changes in the Balance Sheet of First National Bank

(a)

(b)

Assets Reserves

Liabilities 2$80,000

Addendum: Changes in Reserves Actual reserves 2$80,000 Required reserves 2$16,000 Excess reserves 2$64,000

Checking deposits

2$80,000

Assets

Liabilities

Reserves 1$64,000 Loans outstanding 2$64,000 Addendum: Changes in Reserves Actual reserves 1$64,000 Required reserves No Change Excess reserves 1$64,000

No Change

After the entire banking system had become involved, the picture would be just as shown in Figure 3, except that all the numbers would have minus signs in front of them. Deposits would shrink by $500,000, loans would fall by $400,000, bank reserves would be reduced by $100,000, and the M1 money supply would fall by $400,000. As suggested by 5 In reality, the borrowers would probably pay with checks drawn on other banks. Bank-a-Mythica would then cash these checks to acquire the reserves.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

642

Part 7

Fiscal and Monetary Policy

our money multiplier formula with m 5 0.20, the decline in the bank deposit component of the money supply is 1/0.20 5 5 times as large as the decline in reserves. One of the authors of this book was a student in Cambridge, Massachusetts, during the height of the radical student movement of the late 1960s. One day a pamphlet appeared urging citizens to withdraw all funds from their checking accounts on a prescribed date, hold them in cash for a week, and then redeposit them. This act, the circular argued, would wreak havoc upon the capitalist system. Obviously, some of these radicals were well schooled in modern money mechanics, for the argument was basically correct. The tremendous multiple contraction of the banking system and subsequent multiple expansion that a successful campaign of this sort could have caused might have seriously disrupted the local financial system. History records that the appeal met with little success. Apparently, checking account withdrawals are not the stuff of which revolutions are made.

WHY THE MONEY-CREATION FORMULA IS OVERSIMPLIFIED So far, our discussion of the process of money creation has seemed rather mechanical. If everything proceeds according to formula, each $1 in new reserves injected into the banking system leads to a $1/m increase in new deposits. In reality, things are not this simple. Just as in the case of the expenditure multiplier, the oversimplified money multiplier is accurate only under very particular circumstances. These circumstances require that 1. Every recipient of cash must redeposit the cash into another bank rather than hold it. 2. Every bank must hold reserves no larger than the legal minimum. The “chain” diagram in Figure 3 can teach us what happens if either of these assumptions is violated. Suppose first that the business firms and individuals who receive bank loans decide to redeposit only a fraction of the proceeds into their bank accounts, holding the rest in cash. Then, for example, the first $80,000 loan would lead to a deposit of less than $80,000— and similarly down the chain. The whole chain of deposit creation would therefore be reduced. Thus: If individuals and business firms decide to hold more cash, the multiple expansion of bank deposits will be curtailed because fewer dollars of cash will be available for use as reserves to support checking deposits. Consequently, the money supply will be smaller.

The basic idea here is simple. Each $1 of cash held inside a bank can support several dollars (specifically, $1/m) of money. Each $1 of cash held outside the banking system is exactly $1 of money; it supports no deposits. Hence, any time cash moves from inside the banking system into the hands of a household or a business, the money supply will decline. And any time cash enters the banking system, the money supply will rise. Next, suppose bank managers become more conservative or that the outlook for loan repayments worsens because of a recession, which is what happened in a major way in 2008–2009. In such an environment, banks might decide to keep more reserves than the legal requirement and lend out less than the amounts assumed in Figure 3. If this happens, banks further down the chain receive smaller deposits and, once again, the chain of deposit creation is curtailed. Thus: If banks wish to keep excess reserves, the multiple expansion of bank deposits will be limited. A given amount of cash will support a smaller supply of money than would be the case if banks held no excess reserves.

The latter problem arose—in magnified form—in the United States after September 2008, when the collapse of Lehman Brothers set off a financial panic. Banks clung to reserves as if they were life preservers, and excess reserves exploded from a mere $2 billion just before Lehman to an astonishing $767 billion by December. (At this writing, they stand at over $1 trillion.) In consequence, although total bank reserves rose by about 1,670 percent between August and December 2008, the M1 money supply rose only 14 percent. Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 29

Money and the Banking System

643

THE NEED FOR MONETARY POLICY If we pursue these two points a bit farther, we will see why the government must regulate the money supply in an effort to maintain economic stability. We have just suggested that banks prefer to keep excess reserves when they do not foresee profitable and secure opportunities to make loans. This scenario is most likely to arise when business conditions are depressed. At such times, the propensity of banks to hold excess reserves can turn the deposit-creation process into one of deposit destruction, as happened recently in the United States and elsewhere. In addition, if depositors become nervous, they may decide to hold on to more cash. Thus: During a recession, profit-oriented banks would be prone to reduce the money supply by increasing their excess reserves and declining to lend to less creditworthy applicants—if the government did not intervene. As we will learn in subsequent chapters, the money supply is an important influence on aggregate demand, so such a contraction of the money supply would aggravate the recession.

This is precisely what happened—with a vengeance—during the Great Depression of the 1930s. Although total bank reserves grew, the money supply contracted violently because banks preferred to hold excess reserves rather than make loans that might not be repaid. And something similar has been happening in recent years: The supply of reserves has expanded much more rapidly than the money supply because nervous bankers have been holding on to their excess reserves. But this time, the Federal Reserve kept the money supply growing by using policy tools we will describe in the next chapter. By contrast, banks want to squeeze the maximum money supply possible out of any given amount of cash reserves by keeping their reserves at the bare minimum when the demand for bank loans is buoyant, profits are high, and secure investment opportunities abound. This reduced incentive to hold excess reserves in prosperous times means that During an economic boom, profit-oriented banks will likely make the money supply expand, adding undesirable momentum to the booming economy and paving the way for inflation. The authorities must intervene to prevent this rapid money growth.

Regulation of the money supply, then, is necessary because profit-oriented bankers might otherwise provide the economy with a money supply that dances to and amplifies the tune of the business cycle. Precisely how the authorities control the money supply is the subject of the next chapter.

| SUMMARY | 1. It is more efficient to exchange goods and services by using money as a medium of exchange than by bartering them directly. 2. In addition to being the medium of exchange, whatever serves as money is likely to become the standard unit of account and a popular store of value. 3. Throughout history, all sorts of items have served as money. Commodity money gave way to full-bodied paper money (certificates backed 100 percent by some commodity, such as gold), which in turn gave way to partially backed paper money. Nowadays, our paper money has no commodity backing whatsoever; it is pure fiat money. 4. One popular definition of the U.S. money supply is M1, which includes coins, paper money, and several types of checking deposits. Most economists prefer the M2 definition, which adds to M1 other types of checkable accounts and most savings deposits. Much of M2 is held

outside of banks by investment houses, credit unions, and other financial institutions. 5. Under our modern system of fractional reserve banking, banks keep cash reserves equal to only a fraction of their total deposit liabilities. This practice is the key to their profitability, because the remaining funds can be loaned out at interest. It also leaves banks potentially vulnerable to runs. 6. Because of this vulnerability, bank managers are generally conservative in their investment strategies. They also keep a prudent level of reserves. Even so, the government keeps a watchful eye over banking practices. 7. Before 1933, bank failures were common in the United States. They declined sharply when deposit insurance was instituted. 8. Because it holds only fractional reserves, the banking system as a whole can create several dollars of deposits for each dollar of reserves it receives. Under

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

644

Part 7

Fiscal and Monetary Policy

certain assumptions, the ratio of new bank deposits to new reserves will be $1/m, where m is the required reserve ratio. 9. The same process works in reverse, as a system of money destruction, when cash is withdrawn from the banking system.

10. Because banks and individuals may want to hold more cash when the economy is shaky, the money supply would probably contract under such circumstances if the government did not intervene. Similarly, the money supply would probably expand rapidly in boom times if it were unregulated.

| KEY TERMS | asset

635

fiat money

balance sheet 636 barter

627

liability

commodity money deposit creation deposit insurance

630

fractional reserve banking 629

636 634

632

635

liquidity

moral hazard

634

near moneys

631

net worth

631

636

required reserves

M1 631

run on a bank

M2 631

store of value

excess reserves 636

medium of exchange

Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC) 634

money

628

unit of account

635

626 628 628

628

money multiplier

640

| TEST YOURSELF | 1. Suppose banks keep no excess reserves and no individuals or firms hold on to cash. If someone suddenly discovers $12 million in buried treasure and deposits it in a bank, explain what will happen to the money supply if the required reserve ratio is 10 percent.

b. Sam finds a $100 bill on the sidewalk and deposits it into his checking account.

2. How would your answer to Test Yourself Question 1 differ if the reserve ratio were 25 percent? If the reserve ratio were 100 percent?

4. For each of the transactions listed in Test Yourself Question 3, what will be the ultimate effect on the money supply if the required reserve ratio is one-eighth (12.5 percent)? Assume that the oversimplified money multiplier formula applies.

3. Use tables such as Tables 2 and 3 to illustrate what happens to bank balance sheets when each of the following transactions occurs:

c. Mary Q. Contrary withdraws $500 in cash from her account at Hometown Bank, carries it to the city, and deposits it into her account at Big City Bank.

a. You withdraw $100 from your checking account to buy concert tickets.

| DISCUSSION QUESTIONS | 1. If ours were a barter economy, how would you pay your tuition bill? What if your college did not want the goods or services you offered in payment? 2. How is “money” defined, both conceptually and in practice? Does the U.S. money supply consist of commodity money, full-bodied paper money, or fiat money? 3. What is fractional reserve banking, and why is it the key to bank profits? (Hint: What opportunities to make profits would banks lose if reserve requirements were 100 percent?) Why does fractional reserve banking give bankers discretion over how large the money supply will be? Why does it make banks potentially vulnerable to runs? 4. Since 2008 a rash of bank failures has occurred in the United States. Explain why these failures did not lead to runs on banks.

5. Each year during the Christmas shopping season, consumers and stores increase their holdings of cash. Explain how this development could lead to a multiple contraction of the money supply. (As a matter of fact, the authorities prevent this contraction from occurring by methods explained in the next chapter.) 6. Excess reserves make a bank less vulnerable to runs. Why, then, don’t bankers like to hold excess reserves? What circumstances might persuade them that it would be advisable to hold excess reserves? 7. If the government takes over a failed bank with liabilities (mostly deposits) of $2 billion, pays off the depositors, and sells the assets for $1.5 billion, where does the missing $500 million come from? Why?

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Managing Aggregate Demand: Monetary Policy Victorians heard with grave attention that the Bank Rate had been raised. They did not know what it meant. But they knew that it was an act of extreme wisdom. JOHN KENNETH GAL BR AI TH

A

rmed with our understanding of the rudiments of banking, we are now ready to bring money and interest rates into our model of income determination and the price level. Up to now, we have taken investment (I) to be a fixed number, but this is a poor assumption. Not only is investment highly variable but it also depends on interest rates—which are, in turn, heavily influenced by monetary policy. The main task of this chapter is to explain how monetary policy affects interest rates, investment, and aggregate demand. By the end of the chapter, we will have constructed a complete macroeconomic model, which we will use in subsequent chapters to investigate a variety of important policy issues—and to understand better what has happened since 2007.

Monetary policy refers to actions that the Federal Reserve System takes to change interest rates and the money supply. It is aimed at affecting the economy.

C O N T E N T S ISSUE: JUST WHY IS BEN BERNANKE SO IMPORTANT?

MONEY AND INCOME: THE IMPORTANT DIFFERENCE AMERICA’S CENTRAL BANK: THE FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM Origins and Structure Central Bank Independence

IMPLEMENTING MONETARY POLICY: OPEN-MARKET OPERATIONS

The Market for Bank Reserves The Mechanics of an Open-Market Operation Open-Market Operations, Bond Prices, and Interest Rates

MONEY AND THE PRICE LEVEL IN THE KEYNESIAN MODEL

OTHER METHODS OF MONETARY CONTROL

UNCONVENTIONAL MONETARY POLICY

Lending to Banks Changing Reserve Requirements

FROM MODELS TO POLICY DEBATES

Application: Why the Aggregate Demand Curve Slopes Downward

HOW MONETARY POLICY WORKS Investment and Interest Rates Monetary Policy and Total Expenditure

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

646

Part 7

Fiscal and Monetary Policy

ISSUE:

JUST WHY IS BEN BERNANKE SO IMPORTANT?

The financial crisis had been simmering below the surface for a while. But when it burst into the open in August 2007, every eye in the financial world, it seemed, turned to Ben Bernanke, who had been installed as chairman of the Federal Reserve Board just 18 months earlier. Why? Because many observers see the Federal Reserve chairman as the most powerful person in the economic world. Bernanke is a brilliant but unassuming economist who taught for many years at Princeton University. Now when he speaks, though, people in financial markets around the world dote on his remarks with an intensity that was once reserved for utterances from behind the Kremlin walls. The reason for all the attention is that, in the view of many economists, the Federal Reserve’s decisions on interest rates are the single most important influence on aggregate demand—and hence on economic growth, unemployment, and inflation. And the financial crisis made people worried about the health of the economy. Bernanke heads America’s central bank, the Federal Reserve System. The “Fed,” as it is called, is a bank—but a very special kind of bank. Its customers are banks rather than individuals, and it performs some of the same services for them as your bank performs for you. Although Image not available due to copyright restrictions it makes enormous profits, profit is not its goal. Instead, the Fed tries to manage interest rates according to what it perceives to be the national interest. This chapter will teach you how the Fed does its job and why its decisions affect our economy so profoundly. In brief, it will teach you why people listen so intently whenever Ben Bernanke speaks.

MONEY AND INCOME: THE IMPORTANT DIFFERENCE First we must get some terminology straight. The words money and income are used almost interchangeably in common parlance. Here, however, we must be more precise. Money is a snapshot concept. It answers questions such as “How much money do you have right now?” or “How much money did you have at 3:32 P.M. on Friday, November 5?” To answer these questions, you would add up the cash you are (or were) carrying and whatever checkable balances you have (or had), and answer something like: “I have $126.33,” or “On Friday, November 5, at 3:32 P.M., I had $31.43.” Income, by contrast, is more like a motion picture; it comes to you over a period of time. If you are asked, “What is your income?”, you must respond by saying “$1,000 per week,” or “$4,000 per month,” or “$50,000 per year,” or something like that. Notice that a unit of time is attached to each of these responses. If you just answer, “My income is $45,000,” without indicating whether it is per week, per month, or per year, no one will understand what you mean. That the two concepts are very different is easy to see. A typical American family has an income of about $45,000 per year, but its money holdings at any point in time (using the M1 definition) may be less than $2,000. Similarly, at the national level, nominal GDP at the end of 2009 was around $14.5 trillion, whereas the money stock (M1) was under $1.7 trillion. Although money and income are different, they are certainly related. This chapter focuses on that relationship. Specifically, we will look at how interest rates and the stock of money in existence at any moment of time influences the rate at which people earn income—that is, how monetary policy affects GDP. Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 30

647

Managing Aggregate Demand: Monetary Policy

AMERICA’S CENTRAL BANK: THE FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM When Congress established the Federal Reserve System in 1914, the United States joined the company of most other advanced industrial nations. Until then, the United States, distrustful of centralized economic power, was almost the only important nation without a central bank. The Bank of England, for example, dates back to 1694.

Origins and Structure

A central bank is a bank for banks. The United States’ central bank is the Federal Reserve System.

SOURCE: © The New Yorker Collection 1998, Peter Steiner from cartoonbank.com. All Rights Reserved.

It was painful experiences with economic reality, not the power of economic logic, that provided the impetus to establish a central bank for the United States. Four severe banking panics between 1873 and 1907, in which many banks failed, convinced legislators and bankers alike that a central bank that would regulate credit conditions was not a luxury but a necessity. The 1907 crisis led Congress to study the shortcomings of the banking system and, eventually, to establish the Federal Reserve System. Although the basic ideas of central banking came from Europe, the United States made some changes when it imported the idea, making the Federal Reserve System a uniquely American institution.1 Because of the vastness of our country, the extraordinarily large number of commercial banks, and our tradition of shared state-federal responsibilities, Congress decided that the United States should have not one central bank but twelve. Technically, each Federal Reserve Bank is a corporation; its stockholders are its member banks. But your bank, if it is a member of the system, does not enjoy the privileges normally accorded to stockholders: It receives only a token share of the Federal Reserve’s immense profits (the bulk is turned over to the U.S. Treasury), and it has virtually no say in corporate decisions. In fact, the private banks are more like customers of the Fed than owners. Who, then, controls the Fed? Most of the power resides in the seven-member Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System in Washington, and especially in its chairman. The governors are appointed by the president of the United States, with the advice and consent of the Senate, for fourteen-year terms. The president also designates one of the members to serve a four-year term as chairman of the board and thus to be “I’m sorry, sir, but I don’t believe you know us well enough the most powerful central banker in the world. to call us the Fed.” The Federal Reserve is independent of the rest of the government. As long as it stays within the authority granted to it by Congress, it alone has responsibility for determining the nation’s monetary policy. The power of appointment, however, gives the president some long-run influence over Federal Reserve policy. For example, it was President George W. Bush in 2006 who selected Ben Bernanke, a former adviser, to be the Fed’s next chairman. Four years later, President Barack Obama decided to keep Bernanke in office. Closely allied with the Board of Governors is the powerful Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC), which meets eight times a year in Washington. For reasons to be explained shortly, FOMC decisions largely determine short-term interest rates and the size of the U.S. money supply. This twelve-member committee consists of the seven governors of the Federal Reserve System, the president of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York, and, on a rotating basis, four of the other eleven district bank presidents.2 Ironically, when the European Central Bank was established in 1999, its structure was patterned on that of the Federal Reserve.

1

Alan Blinder was the vice chairman of the Federal Reserve Board, and thus a member of the Federal Open Market Committee, from 1994 to 1996.

2

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

648

Part 7

Fiscal and Monetary Policy

A Meeting of the Federal Open Market Committee secretary to call the roll. Only the twelve voting members answer, saying yes or no. Negative votes are rare, for the FOMC tries to operate by consensus and a dissent is considered a loud objection. The meeting adjourns, and at precisely 2:15 P.M. a Fed spokesman announces the decision to the public. Within minutes, financial markets around the world react.

SOURCE: Courtesy of the Federal Reserve Board

Meetings of the Federal Open Market Committee are serious and formal affairs. All nineteen members—seven governors and twelve reserve bank presidents—sit around a mammoth table in the Fed’s cavernous but austere board room. A limited number of top Fed staffers join them at and around the table, for access to FOMC meetings is strictly controlled. At precisely 9 A.M.—for punctuality is a high virtue at the Fed— the doors are closed and the chairman calls the meeting to order. No press is allowed and, unlike most important Washington meetings, nothing said there will leak. Secrecy is another high virtue at the Fed. After hearing a few routine staff reports, the chairman calls on each of the members in turn to give their views of the current economic situation. District bank presidents offer insights into their local economies, and all members comment on the outlook for the national economy. Committee members also offer their views on what changes in monetary policy, if any, are appropriate. Disagreements are raised, but voices are not, for politeness is another virtue. Strikingly, in this most political of cities, politics is almost never mentioned. Once he has heard from all the others, the chairman summarizes the discussion, offers his own views of the economic situation and of the policy options, and recommends a course of action. Most members normally agree with the chairman, though some note differences of opinion. Then the chairman asks the

Central Bank Independence Central bank independence refers to the central bank’s ability to make decisions without political interference.

For decades a debate raged, both in the United States and in other countries, over the pros and cons of central bank independence. Proponents of central bank independence argued that it enables the central bank to take the long view and to make monetary policy decisions on objective, technical criteria—thus keeping monetary policy out of the “political thicket.” Without this independence, they argued, politicians with short time horizons might try to force the central bank to expand the money supply too rapidly, especially before elections, thereby contributing to chronic inflation and undermining faith in the country’s financial system. They pointed to historical evidence showing that countries with more independent central banks have, on average, experienced lower inflation. Opponents of this view countered that there is something profoundly undemocratic about letting a group of unelected bankers and economists make decisions that affect every citizen’s well-being. Monetary policy, they argued, should be formulated by the elected representatives of the people, as is fiscal policy. The high inflation of the 1970s and early 1980s helped resolve this issue by convincing many governments around the world that an independent central bank was essential to controlling inflation. Thus, one country after another has made its central bank independent over the past 20 to 25 years. For example, the Maastricht Treaty (1992), which committed members of the European Union to both low inflation and a single currency (the euro), required each member state to make its central bank independent. All did so, even though several have still not joined the monetary union. Japan also decided to make its central bank independent in 1998. In Latin America, several formerly high-inflation

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 30

649

Managing Aggregate Demand: Monetary Policy

countries like Brazil and Mexico found that giving their central banks more independence helped them control inflation. And some of the formerly socialist countries of Europe, finding themselves saddled with high inflation and “unsound” currencies, made their central banks more independent for similar reasons. Thus, for practical purposes, the debate over central bank independence is now all but over. The new debate is over how to hold such independent and powerful institutions accountable to the political authorities and to the broad public. For example, most central banks have now abandoned their former traditions of secrecy and have become far more open to public scrutiny. Some, the “inflation targeters,” even announce specific numerical targets for inflation, thereby making it easy for outside observers to judge the central bank’s success or failure. The Federal Reserve does not do this explicitly, but it reveals enough information in its long-run forecast that people pretty much know its inflation target.

IMPLEMENTING MONETARY POLICY: OPEN-MARKET OPERATIONS When it wants to change interest rates, the Fed normally relies on open-market operations, which is the tool it relied upon first when it lowered interest rates in response to the financial crisis in 2007 and 2008. Open-market operations either give banks more reserves or take reserves away from them, thereby triggering the sort of multiple expansion or contraction of the money supply described in the previous chapter. How does this process work? If the Federal Open Market Committee decides to lower interest rates, it can bring them down by providing banks with more reserves. Specifically, the Federal Reserve System would normally purchase a particular kind of short-term U.S. government security called a Treasury bill from any individual or bank that wished to sell them, paying with newly created bank reserves. To see how this open-market operation affects interest rates, we must understand how the market for bank reserves, which is depicted in Figure 1, works.

Open-market operations refer to the Fed’s purchase or sale of government securities through transactions in the open market.

FI GURE 1 The Market for Bank Reserves

The Market for Bank Reserves

Interest Rate

The main sources of supply and demand in the market on which S D bank reserves are traded are straightforward. On the supply side, the Fed decides how many dollars of reserves to provide. Thus the label on the supply curve in Figure 1 indicates that the For given position of the supply curve depends on Federal Reserve policy. The Fed policy E Fed’s decision on the quantity of bank reserves is the essence of monetary policy, and we are about to consider how the Fed For given Y makes that decision. and P On the demand side of the market, the main reason why banks hold reserves under normal circumstances is something we learned in the previous chapter: Government regulations require them to do so. In Chapter 29, we used the symbol m to D denote the required reserve ratio (which is 0.1 in the United S States). So if the volume of transaction deposits is D, the demand for required reserves is simply m 3 D. The demand for reserves Quantity of Bank Reserves thus reflects the demand for transactions deposits in banks. The demand for bank deposits depends on many factors, but the principal determinant is the dollar value of transactions. After all, people and businesses hold bank deposits in order to conduct transactions. Real GDP (Y) is typically used as a convenient indicator of the number of transactions, and the price level (P) is a natural measure of the average price per transaction. So the volume of bank deposits, D, and therefore the demand for bank reserves, depends on both Y and P—as indicated by the label on the demand curve in Figure 1.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

650

Part 7

Fiscal and Monetary Policy

Interest Rate

There is more to the story, however, for we have not yet explained why the the demand curve DD slopes down and the supply curve SS slopes up. The interest rate measured along The federal funds rate is the vertical axis of Figure 1 is called the federal funds rate. It is the rate that applies when the interest rates that banks banks borrow and lend reserves to one another. When you hear on the evening news that pay and receive when they “the Federal Reserve today cut interest rates by 1⁄4 of a point,” it is the federal funds rate that borrow reserves from one the reporter is talking about. another. Now where does this borrowing and lending come from? As we mentioned in the previous chapter, banks sometimes find themselves with either insufficient or excess reserves. Normally, neither situation leaves bankers happy. Keeping actual reserves below the required level is not allowed. Holding reserves in excess of requirements is perfectly legal, but since reserves pay little interest, a bank can put excess reserves to better use by lending them out rather than keeping them idle.3 So banks have developed an active market in which those with excess reserves lend them to those with reserve deficiencies. These F I GURE 2 bank-to-bank loans provide an additional source of both supply and demand—and one The Effects of an Openthat (unlike required reserves) is interest sensitive. Market Purchase Any bank that wants to borrow reserves must pay the federal funds rate for the privilege. Naturally, as the funds rate rises, borrowing looks more expensive and so fewer reserves are deS0 S1 D manded. In a word, the demand curve for reserves (DD) slopes downward. Similarly, the supply curve for reserves (SS) slopes upward because lending reserves becomes more attractive as the federal funds rate rises. The equilibrium federal funds rate is established, as usual, at E point E in Figure 1—where the demand and supply curves cross. Now suppose the Federal Reserve wants to push the federal funds A rate down. It can provide additional reserves to the market by purchasing Treasury bills (often abbreviated as T-bills) from banks.4 This open-market purchase would shift the supply curve of bank reserves outward, from S0S0 to S1S1, in Figure 2. Equilibrium would therefore shift from point E to point A, which, as the diagram D S0 S1 shows, implies a lower interest rate and more bank reserves. That is precisely what the Fed does when it wants to reduce interest rates.5 Quantity of Bank Reserves

The Mechanics of an Open-Market Operation The bookkeeping behind such an open-market purchase is illustrated by Table 1, which imagines that the Fed purchases $100 million worth of T-bills from commercial banks. When the Fed buys the securities, the ownership of the T-bills shifts from the banks to the Fed—as indicated by the black arrows in Table 1. Next, the Fed makes payment by giving the banks $100 million in new reserves, that is, by adding $100 million to the bookkeeping entries that represent the banks’ accounts at the Fed—called “bank reserves” in the table. These reserves, shown in blue in the table, are liabilities of the Fed and assets of the banks. You may be wondering where the Fed gets the money to pay for the securities. It could pay in cash, but it normally does not. Instead, it manufactures the funds out of thin air or, more literally, by punching a keyboard. Specifically, the Fed pays the banks by adding the appropriate sums to the reserve accounts that the banks maintain at the Fed. Balances held in these accounts constitute bank reserves, just like cash in bank vaults. Although this process of adding to bookkeeping entries at the Federal Reserve is sometimes referred to as “printing money,” the Fed does not literally run any printing presses. Instead, it simply The interest rate on excess reserves was zero until a change in law in October 2008. It is not important that banks be the buyers. Test Yourself Question 3 at the end of the chapter shows that the effect on bank reserves and the money supply is the same if bank customers purchase the securities.

3 4

There are many interest rates in the economy, but normally they all tend to move up and down together. So, in a first course in economics, we traditionally do not distinguish one interest rate from another. The period since late 2007 has been anything but normal, however. At times, different interest rates actually moved in opposite directions—which is highly unusual. For more on this, see Chapter 37.

5

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 30

651

Managing Aggregate Demand: Monetary Policy

TA BLE 1 Effects of an Open-Market Purchase of Securities on the Balance Sheets of Banks and the Fed

Banks Assets Reserves 1 $100 million U.S. government securities 2 $100 million Addendum: Changes in Reserves Actual reserves 1 $100 million Required reserves No Change Excess reserves 1 $100 million

Federal Reserve System Liabilities

Assets

Liabilities

U.S. government securities 1 $100 million

Bank reserves 1 $100 million

Banks get reserves Fed gets securities

trades its IOUs for an existing asset (a T-bill). Unlike other IOUs, the Fed’s IOUs constitute bank reserves and thus can support a multiple expansion of the money supply just as cash does. Let’s see how this works. It is clear from Table 1 that bank deposits have not increased at all—yet. So, required reserves are unchanged by the open-market operation, but actual reserves are increased by $100 million. If the banks held only their required reserves initially, they now have $100 million in excess reserves. As banks rid themselves of these excess reserves by making more loans, a multiple expansion of the banking system is set in motion—as described in the previous chapter. It is not difficult for the Fed to estimate the ultimate increase in the money supply that will result from its actions. As we learned in the previous chapter, each dollar of newly created bank reserves can support up to 1/m dollars of checking deposits, if m is the required reserve ratio. In the example in the last chapter, m 5 0.20; hence, $100 million in new reserves would support $100 million 4 0.2 5 $500 million in new money. However, estimating the ultimate monetary expansion is a far cry from knowing it with certainty. We know from the previous chapter that the oversimplified money multiplier formula is predicated on two assumptions: that people will want to hold no more cash, and that banks will want to hold no more excess reserves, as the monetary expansion proceeds. In practice, these assumptions are unlikely to be literally true. And recently, the second assumption (no excess reserves) has been spectacularly false. So to predict the eventual effect of its action on the money supply, the Fed must estimate both the amount that firms and individuals will add to their currency holdings and the amount that banks will add to their excess reserves. Neither of these can be estimated with precision. In summary: When the Federal Reserve wants lower interest rates, it purchases U.S. government securities in the open market. It pays for these securities by creating new bank reserves, which lead to a multiple expansion of the money supply. Because of fluctuations in people’s desires to hold cash and banks’ desires to hold excess reserves, the Fed cannot predict the consequences of these actions for the money supply with perfect accuracy. But the Fed can always put the federal funds rate where it wants by buying just the right volume of securities.6

For this reason, in this and subsequent chapters, we will simply proceed as if the Fed controls the federal funds rate directly.

Why? Because the federal funds rate is observable in the market every minute and hence need not be estimated. If interest rates do not fall as much as the Fed wants, it can simply purchase more securities. If interest rates fall too much, the Fed can purchase less. Such adjustments can be made very quickly.

6

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

652

Part 7

Fiscal and Monetary Policy

The procedures followed when the FOMC wants to raise interest rates are just the opposite of those we have just explained. In brief, it sells government securities in the open market. This takes reserves away from banks, because banks pay for the securities by drawing down their deposits at the Fed. A multiple contraction of the banking system should ensue. The principles are exactly the same—and so are the uncertainties.

Open-Market Operations, Bond Prices, and Interest Rates The expansionary monetary policy action we have been using as an example began when the Fed bought more Treasury bills. When it goes into the open market to purchase more of these bills, the Federal Reserve naturally drives up their prices. This process is illustrated by Figure 3, which shows an inward shift of the (vertical) supply curve of T-bills available to private investors—from S0S0 to S1S1—indicating that the Fed’s action has taken some of the bills off the private market. With an unchanged (private) demand curve, DD, the price of T-bills rises from P0 to P1 as equilibrium in the market shifts from point A to point B. Rising prices for Treasury bills—or for any other type of bond—translate directly into falling interest rates. Why? The reason is simple arithmetic. Bonds pay a fixed number of dolS1 S0 lars of interest per year. For concreteness, consider a bond that pays $60 each year. If the bond sells for $1,000, bondholders earn a 6 percent return on their investment (the $60 interest payment is 6 percent of $1,000). We therefore say that the interest rate on the bond is 6 percent. Now suppose that the price of the bond rises to $1,200. The annual interest payment is still $60, so B bondholders now earn just 5 percent on their money ($60 is 5 percent of $1,200). The effective interest rate on the bond has fallen A to 5 percent. This relationship between bond prices and interest rates is completely general:

Price of a Treasury Bill

D

P1 P0

D S1

S0

When bond prices rise, interest rates fall because the purchaser of a bond spends more money than before to earn a given number of dollars of interest per year. Similarly, when bond prices fall, interest rates rise.

Quantity of Treasury Bills

F I GURE 3 Open-Market Purchases and Treasury Bill Prices

In fact, the relationship amounts to nothing more than two ways of saying the same thing. Higher interest rates mean lower bond prices; lower interest rates mean higher bond prices.7 Thus Figure 3 is another way to look at the fact that Federal Reserve open-market operations influence interest rates. Specifically: An open-market purchase of Treasury bills by the Fed not only raises the money supply but also drives up T-bill prices and pushes interest rates down. Conversely, an openmarket sale of bills, which reduces the money supply, lowers T-bill prices and raises interest rates.

OTHER METHODS OF MONETARY CONTROL When the Federal Reserve System was first established, its founders did not intend it to pursue an active monetary policy to stabilize the economy. Indeed, the basic ideas of stabilization policy were unknown at the time. Instead, the Fed’s founders viewed it as a means of preventing the supplies of money and credit from drying up during banking panics, as had happened so often in the pre-1914 period.

7

For further discussion and examples, see Test Yourself Question 4 at the end of the chapter.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

653

Managing Aggregate Demand: Monetary Policy

Chapter 30

When the financial panic hit in 2007, more and more investors became attracted to U.S. government bonds as a safe place to park funds. However, an amazing number of investors do not understand even the elementary facts about bond investing—including the relationship between bond prices and interest rates. The Wall Street Journal reported back in November 2001 that “One of the bond basics about which many investors are clueless, for instance, is the fundamental seesaw relationship between interest rates and bond prices. Only 31% of 750 investors participating in the American Century [a mutual fund company] telephone survey knew that when interest rates rise, bond prices generally fall.” * Imagine how many fewer, then, could explain why this is so. * Karen Damato, “Investors Love Their Bond Funds—Too Much?,” The Wall Street Journal, November 9, 2001, p. C1.

SOURCE: © Sidney Harris, www.sciencecartoonsplus.com

You Now Belong to a Distinctive Minority Group

“When interest rates go up, bond prices go down. When interest rates go down, bond prices go up. But please don’t ask me why.”

Lending to Banks One of the principal ways in which Congress intended the Fed to provide such insurance against financial panics was to act as a “lender of last resort.” When risky business prospects made commercial banks hesitant to extend new loans, or when banks were in trouble, the Fed would step in by lending money to the banks, thus inducing them to lend more to their customers. If that sounds familiar, it should, since it is exactly what the Fed and other central banks did beginning in the summer and fall of 2007, when the financial crisis made banks wary of lending. Mammoth amounts of central bank lending to commercial banks helped keep the financial system functioning and eased the panic for a while. Later, in 2008, the Fed actually began a temporary program of lending to securities firms—something it had not done since the 1930s. The mechanics of Federal Reserve lending are illustrated in Table 2. When the Fed makes a loan to a bank in need of reserves, that bank receives a credit in its deposit account at the Fed—$5 million in the example. That $5 million represents newly created reserves. So it expands the supply of reserves just as was shown in Figure 2. Furthermore, because bank deposits, and hence required reserves, have not yet increased, this addition to the supply of bank reserves creates excess reserves, which should lead to an expansion of the money supply. TA BLE 2 Balance Sheet Changes for Borrowing from the Fed

Banks Assets Reserves

1 $5 million

Addendum: Changes in Reserves Actual reserves 1 $5 million Required reserves No Change Excess reserves 1 $5 million

Federal Reserve System Liabilities

Assets

Loan from Loan to Fed 1 $5 million bank

1 $5 million

Liabilities Bank reserves

1 $5 million

Bank borrows $5 million and the proceeds are credited to its reserve account

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

654

Part 7

Fiscal and Monetary Policy

The discount rate is the interest rate the Fed charges on loans that it makes to banks.

Federal Reserve officials can try to influence the amount banks borrow by manipulating the rate of interest charged on these loans, which is known as the discount rate. If the Fed wants banks to have more reserves, it can reduce the interest rate that it charges on loans, thereby tempting banks to borrow more—which is exactly what it did repeatedly in 2007 and 2008. Alternatively, it can soak up reserves by raising its rate and persuading the banks to reduce their borrowings. When it changes its discount rate, the Fed cannot know for sure how banks will react. Sometimes they may respond vigorously to a cut in the rate, borrowing a great deal from the Fed and lending a correspondingly large amount to their customers. At other times they may essentially ignore the change in the discount rate. In fact, when it first cut the discount rate in 2007, the Fed was disappointed in the banks’ meager response because it wanted to add reserves to the system. This episode illustrates a general point: that the link between the discount rate and the volume of bank reserves may be a loose one. Some foreign central banks use their versions of the discount rate actively as the centerpiece of monetary policy. However, in the United States, the Fed normally lends infrequently and in very small amounts. It relies instead on open-market operations to conduct monetary policy. The Fed typically adjusts its discount rate passively, to keep it in line with market interest rates. In a crisis, however, the Fed does use the discount window to supplement and support open-market operations. It has done so massively since 2007.

Changing Reserve Requirements In principle, the Federal Reserve has a third way to conduct monetary policy: varying the minimum required reserve ratio. To see how this works, imagine that banks hold reserves that just match their required minimums. In other words, excess reserves are zero. If the Fed decides that lower interest rates are warranted, it can reduce the required reserve ratio, thereby transforming some previously required reserves into excess reserves. No new reserves are created directly by this action. We know from the previous chapter, though, that such a change will set in motion a multiple expansion of the banking system. Looked at in terms of the market for bank reserves (Figure 1), a reduction in reserve requirements shifts the demand curve inward (because banks no longer need as many reserves), thereby lowering interest rates. Similarly, raising the required reserve ratio will raise interest rates and set off a multiple contraction of the banking system. In point of fact, however, the Fed has not used the reserve ratio as a weapon of monetary control for years. Current law and regulations provide for required reserves equal to 10 percent of transaction deposits—a figure that has not changed since 1992.

HOW MONETARY POLICY WORKS Remembering that monetary policy actions by the Fed are usually open-market operations, the two panels of Figure 4 illustrate the effects of expansionary monetary policy (an open-market purchase) and contractionary monetary policy (an open-market sale). Panel (a) looks just like Figure 2. So expansionary monetary policy actions lower interest rates and contractionary monetary policy actions raise interest rates. But then what happens? To find out, let’s go back to the analysis of earlier chapters, where we learned that aggregate demand is the sum of consumption spending (C), investment spending (I), government purchases of goods and services (G), and net exports (X 2 IM). We know that fiscal policy controls G directly and influences both C and I through the tax laws. We now want to understand how monetary policy affects total spending. Most economists agree that, of the four components of aggregate demand, investment and net exports are the most sensitive to monetary policy. We will study the effects of monetary and fiscal policy on net exports in Chapter 36, after we have learned about international exchange rates. For now, we will assume that net exports are fixed and focus on monetary policy’s influence on investment.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

655

Managing Aggregate Demand: Monetary Policy

Chapter 30

Investment and Interest Rates

S0

D

S1

D

S2

S0

Interest Rate

Interest Rate

Given recent events in the housing B market, it is important to remember that the I in C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM) E E includes both business investment in A new factories and machinery and investment in housing. Because the interest cost of a home mortgage is the major component of the total cost of D D S0 S1 S0 S2 owning a house, fewer families will want to purchase new homes as inBank Reserves Bank Reserves (a) (b) terest rates rise. Thus, higher interest rates will reduce expenditures on Expansionary Monetary Policy Contractionary Monetary Policy housing. Business investment is also sensitive to interest rates, for reasons FI GURE 4 explained in earlier chapters.8 Because the rate of interest that must be paid on borrowings The Effects of is part of the cost of an investment, business executives will find investment prospects less Monetary Policy on attractive as interest rates rise. Therefore, they will spend less. We conclude that Interest Rates Higher interest rates lead to lower investment spending. But investment (I) is a component of total spending, C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM). Therefore, when interest rates rise, total spending falls. In terms of the 45° line diagram of previous chapters, a higher interest rate leads to a lower expenditure schedule. Conversely, a lower interest rate leads to a higher expenditure schedule.

Figure 5 depicts this situation graphically.

Monetary Policy and Total Expenditure

Real Expenditure

The effect of interest rates on spending provides the chief mechanism by which monetary policy affects the macroeconomy. We know from our analysis of the market for bank reserves (Figure 4) that monetary policy can move interest rates up or down. Let us, therefore, trace the impacts of conventional monetary policy, starting there. Suppose the Federal Reserve, worried that the economy might slip into a recession, increases the supply of bank reserves. It would normally do so by purchasing government securities in the open market, thereby shifting the supply schedule for reserves outward—as indicated by the shift from the black line S0S0 to the brick-colored line S1S1 in Figure 4(a). This is essentially what the Fed did in 2007 and 2008. With the demand schedule for bank reserves, DD, temporarily fixed, such a shift in the supply curve has the effect that an increase in supply always has in a free market: It lowers the price, as Figure 4(a) shows. In this case, the relevant price is the rate of interest that must be paid for borrowing reserves, r (the federal funds rate). So r falls. Next, for reasons we have just outlined, investment spending on housing and business equipment Real GDP (I) rises in response to the lower interest rates. But,

8

FI GURE 5 The Effect of Interest Rates on Total Expenditure

45°

C + I + G + (X – IM) (lower interest rate) C + I + G + (X – IM) C + I + G + (X – IM) (higher interest rate)

See, for example, Chapter 24, pages 522–523.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

656

Part 7

Fiscal and Monetary Policy

as we learned in Chapter 26, such an autonomous rise in investment kicks off a multiplier chain of increases in output and employment. This sequence of events summarizes the linkages from the supply of bank reserves to the level of aggregate demand. In brief, monetary policy works as follows: Expansionary monetary policy leads to lower interest rates (r), and these lower interest rates encourage investment (I), which has multiplier effects on aggregate demand.

This process operates equally well in reverse. By contracting bank reserves and the money supply, the central bank can push interest rates up, which is precisely what the Fed did between mid-2004 and August 2006. Higher rates will cause investment spending to fall and pull down aggregate demand via the multiplier mechanism. This, in outline form, is how monetary policy influences the economy in the Keynesian model. Because the chain of causation is fairly long, the following schematic diagram may help clarify it: 1

Real Expenditure

Federal Reserve Policy

5,500

F IGURE 6 The Effect of Expansionary Monetary Policy on Total Expenditure

2 M and r

3 I

4 C + I + G + (X – I M)

GDP

In this causal chain, Link 1 indicates that the Federal Reserve’s open-market operations affect both interest rates and the money supply. Link 2 stands for the effect of interest rates on investment. Link 3 simply notes that investment is one component of total spending. Link 4 is the multiplier, relating an autonomous change in investment to the ultimate change in aggregate demand. To see what economists must study if they are to estimate the effects of monetary policy, let us briefly review what we know 45° about each of these four links. Link 1 is the subject of this chapter. It was deC + I + G + (X – IM ) 1 E1 picted in Figure 4(a), which shows how injections of C + I0 + G + (X – IM ) bank reserves by the Federal Reserve push the interest rate down. Thus, the first thing an economist must know is how sensitive interest rates are to changes in the supply of bank reserves. E0 Link 2 translates the lower interest rate into higher investment spending. To estimate this effect in practice, economists must study the sensitivity of investment to interest rates—a topic we first took up in Chapter 24. Link 3 instructs us to enter the rise in I as an autonomous upward shift of the C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM) 6,000 6,500 7,000 schedule in a 45° line diagram. Figure 6 carries out Real GDP this next step. The expenditure schedule rises from NOTE: Figures are in billions of dollars per year. C 1 I0 1 G 1 (X 2 IM) to C 1 I1 1 G 1 (X 2 IM). Finally, Link 4 applies multiplier analysis to this vertical shift in the expenditure schedule to obtain the eventual increase in real GDP demanded. This change is shown in Figure 6 as a shift in equilibrium from E0 to E1, which raises real GDP by $500 billion in the example. Of course, the size of the multiplier itself must also be estimated. To summarize: The effect of monetary policy on aggregate demand depends on the sensitivity of interest rates to open-market operations, on the responsiveness of investment spending to the rate of interest, and on the size of the basic expenditure multiplier.

MONEY AND THE PRICE LEVEL IN THE KEYNESIAN MODEL Our analysis up to now leaves one important question unanswered: What happens to the price level? To find the answer, we must recall that aggregate demand and aggregate supply jointly determine prices and output. Our analysis of monetary policy so far has shown Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

657

Managing Aggregate Demand: Monetary Policy

Chapter 30

Price Level

us how expansionary monetary policy boosts total spending: It increases the aggregate FI GURE 7 quantity demanded at any given price level. To learn what happens to the price level and to The Inflationary Effects real output, we must consider aggregate supply as well. of Expansionary Monetary Policy Specifically, when considering shifts in aggregate demand caused by fiscal policy in Chapter 28, we noted that an upsurge in total spending normally induces firms to inD1 D0 crease output somewhat and to raise prices somewhat. This is precisely what an upward-sloping aggregate supply curve shows. Whether the responses come more in the form S $500 billion of real output or more in the form of price depends on the slope of the aggregate supply curve (see Figure 7). Exactly B 103 the same analysis of output and price responses applies to monetary policy or, for that matter, to anything that raises E the aggregate demand curve. So we conclude that 100 Expansionary monetary policy causes some inflation under normal circumstances. But exactly how much inflation it causes depends on the slope of the aggregate supply curve.

S D0

The effect of expansionary monetary policy on the price 6,000 level is shown graphically on an aggregate supply and Real GDP demand diagram in Figure 7. In the example depicted in Figure 6, the Fed’s actions lowered interest rates enough to NOTE: GDP figures are in billions of dollars per year. increase aggregate demand (through the multiplier) by $500 billion. We enter this increase as a $500 billion horizontal shift of the aggregate demand curve in Figure 7, from D0D0 to D1D1. The diagram shows that this expansionary monetary policy pushes the economy’s equilibrium from point E to point B—the price level therefore rises from 100 to 103, or 3 percent. The diagram also shows that real GDP rises by only $400 billion, which is less than the $500 billion stimulus to aggregate demand. The reason, as we know from earlier chapters, is that rising prices stifle real aggregate demand. By taking account of the effect of an increase in the money supply on the price level, we have completed our story about the role of monetary policy in the Keynesian model. We can thus expand our schematic diagram of monetary policy as follows: 1 Federal Reserve Policy

2 M and r

3 I

6,400

4 C + I + G + (X – IM)

Y and P

The last link now recognizes that both output and prices normally are affected by changes in interest rates and the money supply.

Application: Why the Aggregate Demand Curve Slopes Downward9 This analysis of the effect of monetary policy on the price level puts us in a better position to understand why higher prices reduce aggregate quantity demanded—that is, why the aggregate demand curve slopes downward. In earlier chapters, we explained this phenomenon in two ways. First, we observed that rising prices reduce the purchasing power of certain assets held by consumers, especially money and government bonds, and that falling real wealth in turn retards consumption spending. Second, we noted that higher domestic prices depress exports and stimulate imports. There is nothing wrong with this analysis; it is just incomplete. Higher prices have another important effect on aggregate demand, through a channel that we are now in a position to understand.

9

This section contains somewhat more difficult material, which can be skipped in shorter courses.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

D1

658

Part 7

D0

Fiscal and Monetary Policy

D1

S

Interest Rate

E1

E0

S

Effect of a higher P

D0

Bank Reserves

F I GURE 8 The Effect of a Higher Price Level on the Market for Bank Reserves

D1

Bank deposits are demanded primarily to conduct transactions. As we noted earlier in this chapter, an increase in the average money cost of each transaction—that is, a rise in the price level— will increase the quantity of deposits demanded, and hence increase the demand for bank reserves. Thus, when spending rises for any reason, the price level will also rise, and more reserves will therefore be demanded at any given interest rate—that is, the demand curve for bank reserves will shift outward to the right, as shown in Figure 8. If the Fed does not increase the supply of reserves, this outward shift of the demand curve will force the cost of borrowing reserves—the federal funds rate—to rise, as Figure 8 makes clear. As we know, increases in interest rates reduce investment and, hence, reduce aggregate demand. This is the main reason why the economy’s aggregate demand curve has a negative slope, meaning that aggregate quantity demanded is lower when prices are higher. In sum:

At higher price levels, the quantity of bank reserves demanded is greater. If the Fed holds the supply schedule fixed, a higher price level must therefore lead to higher interest rates. Because higher interest rates discourage investment, aggregate quantity demanded is lower when the price level is higher—that is, the aggregate demand curve has a negative slope.

UNCONVENTIONAL MONETARY POLICY

SOURCE: © Harley Schwadron / CartoonStock.com

Recent events dramatically point out one major omission from this chapter’s discussion: What happens if the Federal Reserve uses open-market operations to push the federal funds rate all the way down to zero, and yet the economy still needs more stimulus? This topic was never taken up in previous editions of this book because the possibility seemed so remote, but it actually happened in December 2008. Once the funds rate hits zero, the Fed still has a variety of policy weapons to deploy, although the evidence suggests they all have weaker effects than the funds rate. A full explanation of such unconventional monetary policy would require many pages and more advanced material. Here is one simple example: As we have explained, in conventional open-market purchases, the Fed buys Treasury bills, which drives their prices up and their interest rates down. Once the Treasury bill rate gets to zero, it cannot be driven down any further. So one option is for the Fed to purchase other assets—for example, mortgage-backed securities—thereby driving their prices up and their interest rates down. In fact, this is one of the policies the Fed actually pursued in 2009 and 2010—and on a very large scale. (For more on this, see Chapter 37.)

FROM MODELS TO POLICY DEBATES You will no doubt be relieved to hear that we have now provided just about all the technical apparatus we need to analyze stabilization policy. To be sure, you will encounter many graphs in the next few chapters. Most of them, however, repeat diagrams with which you are already familiar. Our attention now turns from building a theory to using that theory to address several important policy issues.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

659

Managing Aggregate Demand: Monetary Policy

Chapter 30

The next three chapters take up a trio of controversial policy debates that surface regularly in the media: the debate over the conduct of stabilization policy (Chapter 31), the continuing debate over budget deficits and the effects of fiscal and monetary policy on growth (Chapter 32), and the controversy over the trade-off between inflation and unemployment (Chapter 33).

| SUMMARY | haps by reducing the interest rate it charges on such loans (the discount rate) or by reducing reserve requirements.

1. A central bank is a bank for banks. 2. The Federal Reserve System is America’s central bank. There are 12 Federal Reserve banks, but most of the power is held by the Board of Governors in Washington and by the Federal Open Market Committee. 3. The Federal Reserve acts independently of the rest of the government. Over the past 20 to 25 years, many countries have decided that central bank independence is a good idea and have moved in this direction. 4. The Fed has three major monetary policy weapons: open-market operations, reserve requirements, and its lending policy to banks. Normally, it relies on openmarket operations but recently it has lent massive amounts to banks. 5. The Fed increases the supply of bank reserves by purchasing government securities in the open market. When it pays banks for such purchases by creating new reserves, the Fed lowers interest rates and induces a multiple expansion of the money supply. Conversely, open-market sales of securities take reserves from banks, raise interest rates, and lead to a contraction of the money supply. 6. When the Fed buys bonds, bond prices rise and interest rates fall. When the Fed sells bonds, bond prices fall and interest rates rise. 7. The Fed can also pursue a more expansionary monetary policy by allowing banks to borrow more reserves, per-

8. None of these weapons, however, gives the Fed perfect control over the money supply in the short run, because it cannot predict perfectly how far the process of deposit creation or destruction will go. The Fed can, however, control the interest rate paid to borrow bank reserves, which is called the federal funds rate, much more tightly. 9. Investment spending (I), including business investment and investment in new homes, is sensitive to interest rates (r). Specifically, I is lower when r is higher. 10. Monetary policy works in the following way in the Keynesian model: Raising the supply of bank reserves leads to lower interest rates; the lower interest rates stimulate investment spending; and this investment stimulus, via the multiplier, then raises aggregate demand. 11. Prices are likely to rise as output rises. The amount of inflation caused by expansionary monetary policy depends on the slope of the aggregate supply curve. Much inflation will occur if the supply curve is steep, but little inflation if it is flat. 12. The main reason why the aggregate demand curve slopes downward is that higher prices increase the demand for bank deposits, and hence for bank reserves. Given a fixed supply of reserves, this higher demand pushes interest rates up, which, in turn, discourages investment.

| KEY TERMS | central bank

647

central bank independence

discount rate 648

654

federal funds rate

monetary policy 650

645

open-market operations

649

| TEST YOURSELF | 1. Suppose there is $120 billion of cash and that half of this cash is held in bank vaults as required reserves (that is, banks hold no excess reserves). How large will the money supply be if the required reserve ratio is 10 percent? 12 1⁄2 percent? 16 2⁄3 percent?

2. Show the balance sheet changes that would take place if the Federal Reserve Bank of New York purchased an office building from Citigroup for a price of $100 million. Compare this effect to the effect of an open-market purchase of securities shown in Table 1. What do you conclude?

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

660

Part 7

Fiscal and Monetary Policy

3. Suppose the Fed purchases $5 billion worth of government bonds from Bill Gates, who banks at the Bank of America in San Francisco. Show the effects on the balance sheets of the Fed, the Bank of America, and Gates. (Hint: Where will the Fed get the $5 billion to pay Gates?) Does it make any difference if the Fed buys bonds from a bank or an individual? 4. Treasury bills have a fixed face value (say, $1,000) and pay interest by selling at a discount. For example, if a one-year bill with a $1,000 face value sells today for $950, it will pay $1,000 2 $950 5 $50 in interest over its life. The interest rate on the bill is therefore $50/$950 5 0.0526, or 5.26 percent. a. Suppose the price of the Treasury bill falls to $925. What happens to the interest rate?

a. Each $1 billion increase in bank reserves reduces the rate of interest by 0.5 percentage point. b. Each 1 percentage point decline in interest rates stimulates $30 billion worth of new investment. c. The expenditure multiplier is two. d. The aggregate supply curve is so flat that prices do not rise noticeably when demand increases. 6. Explain how your answers to Test Yourself Question 5 would differ if each of the assumptions changed. Specifically, what sorts of changes in the assumptions would weaken the effects of monetary policy? 7. (More difficult) Consider an economy in which government purchases, taxes, and net exports are all zero. The consumption function is

C 5 300 1 0.75Y

b. Suppose, instead, that the price rises to $975. What is the interest rate now? c. (More difficult) Now generalize this example. Let P be the price of the bill and r be the interest rate. Develop an algebraic formula expressing r in terms of P. (Hint: The interest earned is $1,000 2 P. What is the percentage interest rate?) Show that this formula illustrates the point made in the text: Higher bond prices mean lower interest rates.

and investment spending (I) depends on the rate of interest (r) in the following way:

I 5 1,000 2 100r Find the equilibrium GDP if the Fed makes the rate of interest (a) 2 percent (r = 0.02), (b) 5 percent, and (c) 10 percent.

5. Explain what a $5 billion increase in bank reserves will do to real GDP under the following assumptions:

| DISCUSSION QUESTIONS | 1. Why does a modern industrial economy need a central bank?

5.25 percent to nearly zero. How did the Fed reduce the federal funds rate? Illustrate your answer on a diagram.

2. What are some reasons behind the worldwide trend toward greater central bank independence? Are there arguments on the other side?

5. Explain why both business investments and purchases of new homes rise when interest rates decline.

3. Explain why the quantity of bank reserves supplied normally is higher and the quantity of bank reserves demanded normally is lower at higher interest rates. 4. From September 2007 through December 2008, the Fed believed that interest rates needed to fall and took steps to reduce them, eventually cutting the federal funds rate from

6. In the early years of this decade, the federal government’s budget deficit rose sharply because of tax cuts and increased spending. If the Federal Reserve wanted to maintain the same level of aggregate demand in the face of large increases in the budget deficit, what should it have done? What would you expect to happen to interest rates?

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

The Debate over Monetary and Fiscal Policy The love of money is the root of all evil. THE NEW TE STA M E N T

Lack of money is the root of all evil. GEORGE BERNARD SHAW

U

p to now, our discussion of stabilization policy has been almost entirely objective and technical. In seeking to understand how the national economy works and how government policies affect it, we have mostly ignored the intense economic and political controversies that surround the actual conduct of monetary and fiscal policy. Chapters 31 through 33 are precisely about these issues. We begin this chapter by introducing an alternative theory of how monetary policy affects the economy, known as monetarism. Although the monetarist and Keynesian theories seem to contradict one another, we will see that the conflict is more apparent than real. However, important differences do arise among economists over the appropriate design and execution of monetary policy. These differences are the central concern of the chapter. We will learn about the continuing debates over the nature of aggregate supply, over the relative virtues of monetary versus fiscal policy, and over whether the Federal Reserve should try to control the money stock or interest rates. As we will see, the resolution of these issues is crucial to the proper conduct of stabilization policy and, indeed, to the decision of whether the government should try to stabilize the economy at all.

C O N T E N T S ISSUE: SHOULD WE FORSAKE STABILIZATION

DEBATE: SHOULD WE RELY ON FISCAL OR MONETARY POLICY?

VELOCITY AND THE QUANTITY THEORY OF MONEY

DEBATE: SHOULD THE FED CONTROL THE MONEY SUPPLY OR INTEREST RATES?

Some Determinants of Velocity Monetarism: The Quantity Theory Modernized

Two Imperfect Alternatives What Has the Fed Actually Done?

FISCAL POLICY, INTEREST RATES, AND VELOCITY

DEBATE: THE SHAPE OF THE AGGREGATE SUPPLY CURVE

Application: The Multiplier Formula Revisited Application: The Government Budget and Investment

DEBATE: SHOULD THE GOVERNMENT INTERVENE?

POLICY?

DIMENSIONS OF THE RULES-VERSUSDISCRETION DEBATE How Fast Does the Economy’s Self-Correcting Mechanism Work? How Long Are the Lags in Stabilization Policy? How Accurate Are Economic Forecasts? The Size of Government Uncertainties Caused by Government Policy A Political Business Cycle?

ISSUE REVISITED: WHAT SHOULD BE DONE?

Lags and the Rules-versus-Discretion Debate

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

662

Part 7

Fiscal and Monetary Policy

ISSUE:

SHOULD WE FORSAKE STABILIZATION POLICY?

We have suggested several times in this book that well-timed changes in fiscal or monetary policy can mitigate fluctuations in inflation and unemployment. For example, when the U.S. economy slumped in the aftermath of the financial crisis, both fiscal policy and monetary policy turned sharply expansionary. Congress cut taxes and raised spending. The Federal Reserve cut interest rates dramatically. These actions might be called “textbook responses” to the recession. They were all consistent with the lessons you have learned in Chapters 28 and 30. But some economists argue that these lessons are best forgotten. In practice, they claim, attempts at macroeconomic stabilization are likely to do more harm than good. Policy makers are therefore best advised to follow fixed rules rather than use their best judgment on a case-by-case basis. Nothing we have said so far leads to this conclusion. We have not yet told the whole story, though. By the end of the chapter you will have encountered several arguments in favor of rules, and so you will be in a better position to make up your own mind.

VELOCITY AND THE QUANTITY THEORY OF MONEY

Velocity indicates the number of times per year that an “average dollar” is spent on goods and services. It is the ratio of nominal gross domestic product (GDP) to the number of dollars in the money stock. That is: Velocity 5

Nominal GDP Money stock

In the previous chapter, we studied the Keynesian view of how monetary policy influences real output and the price level. But another, older model provides a different way to look at these matters. This model, known as the quantity theory of money, will be easy to understand once we introduce one new concept: velocity. In Chapter 29, we learned that because barter is so cumbersome, virtually all economic transactions in advanced economies use money. Thus, if there are $10 trillion worth of transactions in an economy during a particular year, and there is an average money stock of $2 trillion during that year, then each dollar of money must have been used an average of five times during the year. The number five in this example is called the velocity of circulation, or velocity for short, because it indicates the speed at which money circulates. For example, a particular dollar bill might be used to buy a haircut in January; the barber might use it to purchase a sweater in March; the storekeeper might then use it to pay for gasoline in May; the gas station owner could pay it out to a house painter in October; and the painter might spend it on a Christmas present in December. In this way, the same dollar is used five times during the year. If it were used only four times during the year, its velocity would be four, and so on. No one has data on every transaction in the economy. To make velocity an operational concept, economists need a workable measure of the dollar volume of all transactions. As mentioned in the previous chapter, the most popular choice is nominal gross domestic product (GDP), even though it ignores many transactions that use money, such as the huge volume of activity in financial markets. If we accept nominal GDP as our measure of the money value of transactions, we are led to a concrete definition of velocity as the ratio of nominal GDP to the number of dollars in the money stock. Because nominal GDP is the product of real GDP (Y) times the price level (P), we can write this definition in symbols as follows: Velocity 5

The equation of exchange states that the money value of GDP transactions must be equal to the product of the average stock of money times velocity. That is: M3V5P3Y

Nominal GDP P3Y Value of transactions 5 5 Money stock M M

By multiplying both sides of the equation by M, we arrive at an identity called the equation of exchange, which relates the money supply and nominal GDP: Money supply 3 Velocity 5 Nominal GDP

Alternatively, stated in symbols, we have M3V5P3Y

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

663

The Debate over Monetary and Fiscal Policy

Chapter 31

The equation of exchange provides an obvious link between the stock of money, M, and the nominal value of the nation’s output, P 3 Y. This connection is merely a matter of arithmetic, however—not of economics. For example, it does not imply that the Fed can raise nominal GDP by increasing M. Why not? Because V might simultaneously fall enough to prevent the product M 3 V from rising. In other words, if more dollar bills circulated than before, but each bill changed hands more slowly, total spending might not rise. Thus, we need an auxiliary assumption to change the arithmetic identity into an economic theory. The quantity theory of money transforms the equation of exchange from an arithmetic identity into an economic model by assuming that changes in velocity are so minor that velocity can be taken to be virtually constant.

You can see that if V never changed, the equation of exchange would be a marvelously simple model of the determination of nominal GDP—far simpler than the Keynesian model that took us several chapters to develop. To see this, it is convenient to rewrite the equation of exchange in terms of growth rates:

The quantity theory of money assumes that velocity is (approximately) constant. In that case, nominal GDP is proportional to the money stock.

%DM 1 %DV 5 %DP 1 %DY

FI GURE 1 Velocity of Circulation, 1929–2009

3.0

V1

2.5

Velocity (V2)

10.5 10.0 9.5 9.0 8.5 8.0 7.5 7.0 6.5 6.0 5.5 5.0 4.5 4.0 3.5 3.0 2.5 2.0 1.5 1.0 0.5

Velocity (V1)

SOURCE: Constructed by the authors; data from Bureau of Economic Analysis, Federal Reserve Board, and Robert Rasche.

If V was constant, making its percentage change zero, this equation would say, for example, that if the Federal Reserve wanted to make nominal GDP grow by 4.7 percent per year, it need merely raise the money supply by 4.7 percent per year. In such a simple world, economists could use the equation of exchange to predict nominal GDP growth by predicting the growth rate of money. And policy makers could control nominal GDP growth by controlling growth of the money supply. In the real world, things are not so simple because velocity is not a fixed number. But variable velocity does not necessarily destroy the usefulness of the quantity theory. As we explained in Chapter 1, all economic models make assumptions that are at least mildly unrealistic. Without such assumptions, they would not be models at all, just tedious descriptions of reality. The question is really whether the assumption of constant velocity is a useful abstraction from annoying detail or a gross distortion of the facts. Figure 1 sheds some light on this question by showing the behavior of velocity since 1929. Note that the figure includes two different measures of velocity, labeled V1 and V2. Why? Recall from Chapter 29 that we can measure money in several ways, the most popular of which are M1 and M2. Because velocity (V) is simply nominal GDP divided by the money stock (M), we get a different measure of V for each measure of M. Figure 1 shows the velocities of both M1 and M2.

V2

2.0 1.5 1.0 0.5

1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 Year (a)

0.0

1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 Year (b)

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

664

Part 7

Fiscal and Monetary Policy

You will undoubtedly notice the stark difference in the behavior of V1 versus V2. V1 is nowhere near constant; it displays a clear downward trend from 1929 until 1946, a pronounced upward trend until about 1981, and quite erratic behavior since then. V2 is much closer to constant, but closer examination of monthly or quarterly data reveals rather substantial fluctuations in velocity, by either measure. Because velocity is not constant in the short run, predictions of nominal GDP growth based on assuming constant velocity have not fared well, regardless of how M is measured. Therefore, the strict quantity theory of money is not an adequate model of aggregate demand.

Some Determinants of Velocity Because it is abundantly clear that velocity is a variable, not a constant, the equation of exchange is useful as a model of GDP determination only if we can explain movements in velocity. What factors decide whether a dollar will be used to buy goods and services four or five or six times per year? Although numerous factors are relevant, two are important enough to merit discussion here.

Efficiency of the Payments System Money is convenient for conducting transactions, which is why people hold it. However, money has one important disadvantage: Cash pays no interest, and ordinary checking accounts pay very little. Thus, if it were possible to convert interest-bearing assets into money on short notice and at low cost, rational individuals might prefer to use, say, credit cards for most purchases, making periodic transfers to their checking accounts as necessary. That way, the same volume of transactions could be accomplished with lower money balances. By definition, velocity would rise. The incentive to limit cash holdings thus depends on the ease and speed with which it is possible to exchange money for other assets—which is what we mean by the “efficiency of the payments system.” As computerization has speeded up banks’ bookkeeping procedures, as financial innovations have made it possible to transfer funds rapidly between checking accounts and other assets, and as credit cards have come to be used instead of cash, the need to hold money balances has declined and velocity has risen. In practice, improvements in the payments system pose severe practical problems for analysts interested in predicting velocity. A host of financial innovations, beginning in the 1970s and continuing right up to the present day (some of which were mentioned in Chapter 29’s discussion of the definitions of money), have transformed forecasting velocity into a hazardous occupation. In fact, many economists believe the task is impossible and should not even be attempted. Interest Rates A second key determinant of velocity is the rate of interest. The reason is implicit in what we have already said: The higher the rate of interest, the greater the opportunity cost of holding money. Therefore, as interest rates rise, people want to hold smaller cash balances—which means that the existing stock of money circulates faster, and velocity rises. It is this factor that most directly undercuts the usefulness of the quantity theory of money as a guide for monetary policy. In the previous chapter, we learned that expansionary monetary policy, which increases bank reserves and the money supply, also decreases the interest rate. But if interest rates fall, other things being equal, velocity (V) also falls. Thus, when the Fed raises the money supply (M), the product M 3 V should increase by a smaller percentage than does M itself.

Thus, we conclude that Velocity is not a strict constant but depends on such things as the efficiency of the financial system and the rate of interest. Only by studying these determinants of velocity

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 31

665

The Debate over Monetary and Fiscal Policy

can we hope to predict the growth rate of nominal GDP from knowledge of the growth rate of the money supply.

Monetarism: The Quantity Theory Modernized Adherents to a school of thought called monetarism try to do precisely that. Monetarists realize that velocity changes, but they claim that such changes are fairly predictable—certainly in the long run and perhaps even in the short run. As a result, they conclude that the best way to study economic activity is to start with the equation of exchange in growthrate form:

Monetarism is a mode of analysis that uses the equation of exchange to organize and analyze macroeconomic data.

%DM 1 %DV 5 %DP 1 %DY

From here, careful study of the determinants of money growth (which we provided in the previous two chapters) and of changes in velocity (which we just sketched) can be used to predict the growth rate of nominal GDP. Similarly, given an understanding of movements in V, controlling M can give the Fed excellent control over nominal GDP. These ideas are the central tenets of monetarism. The monetarist and Keynesian approaches can be thought of as two competing theories of aggregate demand. Keynesians divide economic knowledge into four neat compartments marked C, I, G, and (X 2 IM) and then add them all up to obtain aggregate demand. In Keynesian analysis, as we have learned, money affects the economy by first affecting interest rates. Monetarists, by contrast, organize their knowledge into two alternative boxes labeled M and V and then multiply the two to obtain aggregate demand. In the monetarist model, the role of money is not necessarily limited to working through interest rates. The bit of arithmetic that multiplies M and V to get P 3 Y is neither more nor less profound than the one that adds up C, I, G, and (X 2 IM) to get Y, and certainly both are correct. The real question is which framework is more useful in practice. That is, which approach works better as a model of aggregate demand? Although there is no generally correct answer for all economies in all periods of time, a glance back at Figure 1 will show you why most economists had abandoned monetarism by the early 1990s. During the 1960s and 1970s, velocity (at least V2) was fairly stable, which helped monetarism win many converts—in the United States and around the world. Since then, however, velocity has behaved so erratically here and in many other countries that there are few monetarists left. Nonetheless, as we will see later in this chapter, some faint echoes of the debate between Keynesians and monetarists can still be heard. Furthermore, few economists doubt that there is a strong long-run relationship between M and P. They just question whether this relationship is useful in the short run. (See the box “Does Money Growth Always Cause Inflation?” on the next page.)

FISCAL POLICY, INTEREST RATES, AND VELOCITY As we learned in the previous chapter, Keynesian economics provides a powerful and important role for monetary policy: An increase in bank reserves and the money supply reduces interest rates, which, in turn, stimulates the demand for investment. But fiscal policy also exerts a powerful influence on interest rates. To see how, think about what happens to real output and the price level following, say, a rise in government spending. We have learned that both real GDP (Y) and the price level (P) rise, so nominal GDP certainly rises. The previous chapter’s analysis of the market for bank reserves taught us that rising prices and/or rising output—by increasing the money volume of transactions—push the demand curve for bank reserves outward to the right. If there is no change in the supply of reserves, the rate of interest must rise. So expansionary fiscal policy raises interest rates.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

666

Part 7

Fiscal and Monetary Policy

P O L I C Y DEB AT E

Does Money Growth Always Cause Inflation?

14

14

80

12

79 81 Inflation Rate

Inflation Rate

2

82

90

89 91 88 87 92 05 06 00 94 93 95 96 04 07 99 03 97 02 2.5 09

5

84 08 85 01

83

Money Growth Rate (a)

10

8 6 4 2

86 98 7.5

79 81

10

8 6

80

12

10

4

The answer appears to be “yes.” The accompanying charts use recent U.S. history as an illustration. In the scatter diagram on the left, each point records both the growth rate of the M2 money supply and the inflation rate (as measured by the Consumer Price Index) for a particular year between 1979 and 2009. Because of the years 1979–1981, there seems to be a weak positive relationship between the two variables. No relationship at all appears for the years 1982–2009. Monetarists often argue that this comparison is unfair because the effect of money supply growth on inflation operates with a lag of perhaps two years. So the right-hand scatter diagram compares inflation with money supply growth two years earlier. It tells essentially the same story. More sophisticated versions of scatter plots like these have led most economists to reject the monetarist claim that inflation and money supply growth are tightly linked.

12.5

82 90 84 89 91 88 08 87 85 93 92 05 06 00 83 96 95 07 01 04 94 03 97 99 86 98 02 2.5

5 09 7.5 10 Money Growth Rate (b)

12.5

SOURCE: Federal Reserve System and Bureau of Labor Statistics.

Monetarists have long claimed that, in the famous words of the late Milton Friedman, “inflation is always and everywhere a monetary phenomenon.” By this statement, Friedman meant that changes in the growth rate of the money supply (%DM) are far and away the principal cause of changes in the inflation rate (%DP)—in all places and at all times. Few economists question the dominant role of rapid money growth in accounting for extremely high rates of inflation. During the German hyperinflation of the 1920s, for example, money was being printed so fast that the printing presses had a difficult time keeping up the pace! But most economists question the words “always and everywhere” in Friedman’s dictum. Aren’t many cases of moderate inflation driven by factors other than the growth rate of the money supply?

NOTE: All figures are in percents.

If the government uses its spending and taxing weapons in the opposite direction, the same process works in reverse. Falling output and (possibly) falling prices shift the demand curve for reserves inward to the left. With a fixed supply curve, equilibrium in the market for bank reserves leads to a lower interest rate. Thus: Monetary policy is not the only type of policy that affects interest rates. Fiscal policy does, too. Specifically, increases in government spending or tax cuts normally push interest rates up, whereas restrictive fiscal policies normally pull interest rates down.

The apparently banal fact that changes in fiscal policy move interest rates up and down has several important consequences. Here are two.

Application: The Multiplier Formula Revisited We have just noted that expansionary fiscal policy raises interest rates. We also know that higher interest rates deter private investment spending. So when the government raises the G component of C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM), one side effect will probably be a reduction in the I component. Consequently, total spending will rise by less than simple multiplier analysis might suggest. The fact that a surge in government demand (G) discourages Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 31

The Debate over Monetary and Fiscal Policy

some private demand (I) provides another reason why the oversimplified multiplier formula of earlier chapters, 1/(1 2 MPC), exaggerates the size of the multiplier: Because a rise in G (or, for that matter, an autonomous rise in any component of total expenditure) pushes interest rates higher, and hence deters some investment spending, the increase in the sum C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM) is smaller than what the oversimplified multiplier formula predicts.

Combining this observation with our previous analysis of the multiplier, we now have the following complete list of REASONS WHY THE OVERSIMPLIFIED FORMULA OVERSTATES THE MULTIPLIER 1. It ignores variable imports, which reduce the size of the multiplier. 2. It ignores price-level changes, which reduce the size of the multiplier. 3. It ignores the income tax, which reduces the size of the multiplier. 4. It ignores the rising interest rates that accompany any autonomous increase in spending, which also reduce the size of the multiplier.

With so many reasons, it is no wonder that the actual multiplier, which is estimated to be less than two for the U.S. economy, is so much less than the oversimplified formula suggests.

Application: The Government Budget and Investment One major argument for reducing the government’s budget deficit is that lower deficits should lead to higher levels of private investment spending. We can now understand why. To reduce its budget deficit, the government must engage in contractionary fiscal policies: lower spending or higher taxes. As we have now just learned, any such measure should reduce real interest rates. These lower real interest rates should spur investment spending. This simple insight—that lower budget deficits should lead to more private investment—will play a major role in the next chapter.

DEBATE: SHOULD WE RELY ON FISCAL OR MONETARY POLICY? The Keynesian and monetarist approaches are like two different languages, but it is well known that language influences attitudes in subtle ways. For example, the Keynesian language biases things toward thinking first about fiscal policy simply because G is a part of C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM). By contrast, the monetarist approach, working through the equation of exchange, M 3 V 5 P 3 Y, puts the spotlight on M. In fact, years ago economists engaged in a spirited debate in which extreme monetarists claimed that fiscal policy was futile, whereas extreme Keynesians argued that monetary policy was useless. Today, such arguments are rarely heard. Instead of arguing over which type of policy is more powerful, economists nowadays debate which type of medicine—fiscal or monetary—works faster. Until now, we have ignored questions of timing and pretended that the authorities noticed the need for stabilization policy instantly, decided on a course of action right away, and administered the appropriate medicine at once. In reality, each of these steps takes time. First, delays in data collection mean that the most recent data describe the state of the economy a few months ago. Second, one of the prices of democracy is that the government often takes a distressingly long time to decide what should be done, to muster the necessary political support, and to put its decisions into effect. Finally, our $14 trillion economy is a bit like a sleeping elephant that reacts rather sluggishly to moderate fiscal and monetary prods. As it turns out, these lags in stabilization policy, as they are called, play a pivotal role in the choice between fiscal and monetary policy. Here’s why. The main policy tool for manipulating consumer spending (C) is the personal income tax, and Chapter 25 documented why the fiscal policy planner can feel fairly confident that each $1 of tax reduction will lead to about 90 to 95 cents of additional spending eventually. But not all of this extra spending happens at once. Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

667

668

Part 7

Fiscal and Monetary Policy

First, consumers must learn about the tax change. Then they may need to be convinced that the change is permanent. Finally, there is simple force of habit: Households need time to adjust their spending habits when circumstances change. For all these reasons, consumers may increase their spending by only 30 to 50 cents for each $1 of additional income within the first few months after a tax cut. Only gradually will they raise their spending up to about 90 to 95 cents for each additional dollar of income. Lags are much longer for investment (I), which provides the main vehicle by which monetary policy affects aggregate demand. Planning for capacity expansion in a large corporation is a long, drawn-out process. Ideas must be submitted and approved, plans must be drawn up, funding acquired, orders for machinery or contracts for new construction placed. And most of this activity occurs before any appreciable amount of money is spent. Economists have found that much of the response of investment to changes in either interest rates or tax provisions takes several years to develop. The fact that C responds more quickly than I has important implications for the choice among alternative stabilization policies. The reason is that the most common varieties of fiscal policy either affect aggregate demand directly—because G is a component of C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM)—or work through consumption with a relatively short lag, whereas monetary policy primarily affects investment. Therefore: Conventional types of fiscal policy actions, such as changes in G or in personal taxes, probably affect aggregate demand much more promptly than do monetary policy actions.

So is fiscal policy therefore a superior stabilization tool? Not necessarily. The lags we have just described, which are beyond policy makers’ control, are not the only ones affecting the timing of stabilization policy. Additional lags stem from the behavior of the policy makers themselves. We refer here to the delays that occur while policy makers study the state of the economy, contemplate which steps they should take, and put their decisions into effect. Here monetary policy has a huge advantage. The Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) meets eight times each year, and more often if necessary. So monetary policy decisions are made frequently. And once the Fed decides on a course of action, it executes its plan immediately by buying or selling Treasury bills in the open market. In contrast, federal budgeting procedures operate on an annual budget cycle. Except in unusual cases, major fiscal policy initiatives can occur only at the time of the annual budget. In principle, tax laws can be changed at any time. However, the wheels of Congress normally grind slowly and are often gummed up by partisan politics. For these reasons, it may take many months for Congress to change fiscal policy. That said, Congress has proven three times in this decade that it can act very quickly in a perceived emergency. First in 2001, then again in 2008, and then dramatically in 2009, both houses rapidly passed, and the president signed, fiscal stimulus bills that put checks into the hands of consumers when the economy was threatened by recession—even though, in the second case, the White House and Congress were controlled by different parties. This recent experience now has many observers rethinking the old conventional wisdom, which held that: Policy lags are normally much shorter for monetary policy than for fiscal policy.

Could it be that this is no longer true? So where does the combined effect of expenditure lags and policy lags leave us? With nothing very conclusive, we are afraid. In practice, however, most students of stabilization policy have come to believe that the unwieldy and often partisan nature of our political system make active use of fiscal policy for stabilization purposes quite difficult. Monetary policy, they claim, is the only realistic game in town and therefore must bear most of the burden of stabilization policy.

DEBATE: SHOULD THE FED CONTROL THE MONEY SUPPLY OR INTEREST RATES? Another major controversy that raged for decades focused on how the Federal Reserve should conduct monetary policy. Most economists argued that the Fed should use its open-market operations to control the rate of interest (r), which is how we have portrayed Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 31

The Debate over Monetary and Fiscal Policy

669

Interest Rate

normal monetary policy up to now. But others, especially S M1 10% M0 monetarists, insisted that the Fed should concentrate on W 9 controlling bank reserves or some measure of the money supply (M) instead. This debate echoes even today in 8 For given Europe, where the European Central Bank (ECB), unlike Fed policy A 7 the Fed, claims to pay considerable attention to the growth of the money supply. (Many skeptics doubt that 6 it actually does so, however.) Z 5 To understand the nature of this debate, we must first Money E demand understand why the Fed cannot control both M and r at 4 shifts out the same time. Figure 2 will help us see why. It looks just 3 like Figure 8 of the previous chapter (on page 658), except that the horizontal axis now measures the money supply 2 instead of bank reserves. The switch from reserves to 1 D1 money is justified by something we learned in earlier D0 M chapters: that the money supply is “built up” from the 0 830 840 850 Fed’s supply of bank reserves via the process of multiple Money Supply (in billions of dollars) expansion.1 As you will recall, this process leads to an approximately proportional relationship between the two— FI GURE 2 meaning that if bank reserves go up by X percent, then 2 The Federal Reserve’s the money supply rises by approximately X percent, too. Because M is basically proporPolicy Dilemma tional to bank reserves, anything we can analyze in the market for reserves can be analyzed in just the same way in the market for money—which is the market depicted in Figure 2. The diagram shows an initial equilibrium in the money market at point E, where money demand curve M0D0 crosses money supply curve MS. Here the interest rate is r 5 5 percent and the money stock is M 5 $830 billion. We assume that these are the Fed’s targets: It wants to keep the money supply and interest rates just where they are. If the demand curve for money holds still, everything works out fine. But suppose the demand for money is not so obliging. Suppose, instead, that the demand curve shifts outward to the position indicated by the brick-colored line M1D1 in Figure 2. We learned in the previous chapter that such a shift might occur because output increases or because prices rise, thereby increasing the volume of transactions. Or it might happen simply because people decide to hold more bank deposits. Whatever the reason, once the shift occurs, the Fed can no longer achieve both previous targets. If the Fed does nothing, the outward shift of the demand curve will push up both the quantity of money (M) and the rate of interest (r). Figure 2 depicts these changes as the move from point E to point A. In the example, if the demand curve for money shifts outward from M0D0 to M1D1, and monetary policy does not change (leaving the supply curve unchanged), the money stock rises to $840 billion and the interest rate rises to 7 percent. Now suppose the Fed is targeting the money supply and is unwilling to let M rise. In that case, it must use contractionary open-market operations to prevent M from rising. In so doing, it will push r up even higher, as point W in Figure 2 shows. After the demand curve for money shifts outward, point E is no longer attainable. The Fed must instead choose from among the points on the brick-colored line M1D1, and point W is the point on this line that keeps the money supply at $830 billion. To hold M at $830 billion, the Fed must reduce bank reserves just enough to pull the money supply curve inward so that it passes through point W. (Pencil this shift in for yourself on the diagram.) But the interest rate will then skyrocket to 9 percent. Alternatively, if the Federal Reserve is pursuing an interest rate target, it might decide that the rise in r must be avoided. In this case, the Fed would be forced to engage in expansionary open-market operations to prevent the outward shift of the demand curve for money If you need to review this process, turn back to Chapter 29, especially pages 636–642. For further details on this proportionality relationship, including some numerical examples, see Test Yourself Question 5 at the end of this chapter. The proportionality between bank reserves and the money supply applies to non-crisis times, when banks do not want to hold excess reserves. As mentioned previously, during the financial crisis, the Fed had to raise bank reserves by huge amounts in order to produce modest growth of the money supply. 1 2

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

670

Part 7

Fiscal and Monetary Policy

from pushing r up. In terms of Figure 2, the interest rate can be held at 5 percent by adding just enough bank reserves to shift the money supply curve outward so that it passes through point Z. However, doing this will push the money supply up to $850 billion. (Again, try penciling in the required shift of the money supply curve.) To summarize this discussion: When the demand curve for money shifts outward, the Fed must tolerate a rise in interest rates, a rise in the money stock, or both. It cannot control both the supply of money and the interest rate. If it tries to keep M steady, then r will rise even more. Conversely, if it tries to stabilize r, then M will rise even more.

Two Imperfect Alternatives For years, economists debated how a central bank should deal with its inability to control both the money supply and the rate of interest. Should it adhere rigidly to a target growth path for bank reserves and the money supply, regardless of the consequences for interest rates—which is the monetarist policy? Should it hold interest rates steady, even if that requires sharp gyrations in reserves and the money stock—which is roughly what the Fed does now? Or is some middle ground more appropriate? Let us first explore the issues and then consider what has actually been done. The main problem with imposing rigid targets on the supply of money is that the demand for money does not cooperate by growing smoothly and predictably from month to month; instead it dances around quite a bit in the short run. This variability presents the recommendation to control the money supply with two problems: 1. It is almost impossible to achieve. Because the volume of money in existence depends on both the demand and the supply curves, keeping M on target in the face of significant fluctuations in the demand for money requires exceptional dexterity. 2. For reasons just explained, rigid adherence to money-stock targets might lead to wide fluctuations in interest rates, which could create an unsettled atmosphere for business decisions. Powerful objections can also be raised against exclusive concentration on interest rate movements. Because increases in output and prices shift the demand schedule for money outward (as shown in Figure 2), a central bank determined to keep interest rates from rising would have to expand the money supply in response. Conversely, when GDP sagged, it would have to contract the money supply to keep rates from falling. Thus, interest rate pegging would make the money supply expand in boom times and contract in recessions, with potentially grave consequences for the stability of the economy. Ironically, this is precisely the sort of monetary behavior the Federal Reserve System was designed to prevent. Hence, if the Fed is to control interest rates, it had better formulate flexible targets, not fixed ones.

What Has the Fed Actually Done? For most of post–World War II history, the predominant view held that the interest rate was much the more important of the two targets. The rationale was that gyrating interest rates could cause abrupt and unsettling changes in investment spending, which in turn would make the entire economy fluctuate. Stabilizing interest rates was therefore believed to be the best way to stabilize GDP. If doing so required fluctuations in the money supply, so be it. Consequently, the Fed focused on interest rates and paid little attention to the money supply—which is more or less the Fed’s view today as well. During the 1960s, however, this prevailing view came under withering attack from Milton Friedman and other monetarists. These economists argued that the Fed’s obsession with stabilizing interest rates actually destabilized the economy by making the money supply fluctuate too much. For this reason, they urged the Fed to stop worrying so much about fluctuations in interest rates and, instead, make the money supply grow at a constant rate from month to month and year to year.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 31

The Debate over Monetary and Fiscal Policy

Percent

Monetarism made important inroads at the Fed during the inflationary 1970s, especially in October 21 20 1979 when then-Chairman Paul Volcker announced a 19 major change in the conduct of monetary policy. 18 Henceforth, he asserted, the Fed would stick more 17 16 closely to its target for money-stock growth regardless 15 of the implications for interest rates. Interest rates Bank prime rate 14 would go wherever supply and demand took them. 13 12 According to our analysis, this change in policy 11 should have led to wider fluctuations in interest rates— 10 and it did. Unfortunately, the Fed also ran into some 9 bad luck. The ensuing three years were marked by un8 7 usually severe gyrations in the demand for money, so 3-month Treasury bills 6 the ups and downs of interest rates were even more ex5 0 treme than anyone had expected. Figure 3 shows just 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 how volatile interest rates were between late 1979 and Year late 1982. As you might imagine, this erratic performance provoked some heavy criticism of the Fed. Then, in October 1982, Chairman Volcker announced FI GURE 3 that the Fed was temporarily abandoning its attempts to stick to a target growth path for The Behavior of the money supply. Although he did not say so, his announcement presumably meant that Interest Rates, 1979–1985 the Fed went back to paying more attention to interest rates. As you can see in Figure 3, interest rates did become much more stable after the change in policy. Most observers think this greater stability was no coincidence. After 1982, the Fed gradually distanced itself from the proposition that the money supply should grow at a constant rate. Finally, in 1993, then-Chairman Alan Greenspan officially confirmed what many people already knew: that the Fed was no longer using the various Ms to guide policy. He strongly hinted that the Fed was targeting interest rates, especially real interest rates, instead—a hint that has been repeated many times since then. In truth, the Fed had little choice. The demand curve for money behaved so erratically and so unpredictably in the 1980s and 1990s that stabilizing the money stock was probably impossible and certainly undesirable. And at least so far, the Fed has shown little interest in returning to the Ms.

DEBATE: THE SHAPE OF THE AGGREGATE SUPPLY CURVE Another lively debate over stabilization policy revolves around the shape of the economy’s aggregate supply curve. Many economists think of the aggregate supply curve as quite flat, as in Figure 4(a), so that large increases in output can be achieved with little inflation. Other economists envision the supply curve as steep, as shown in Figure 4(b), so that prices respond strongly to changes in output. The differences for public policy are substantial. If the aggregate supply curve is flat, expansionary fiscal or monetary policy that raises the aggregate demand curve can buy large gains in real GDP at low cost in terms of inflation. In Figure 5(a), stimulation of demand pushes the aggregate demand curve outward from D0D0 to D1D1, thereby moving the economy’s equilibrium from point E to point A. The substantial rise in output ($400 billion in the diagram) is accompanied by only a pinch of inflation (1 percent). So the antirecession policy is quite successful. Conversely, when the supply curve is flat, a restrictive stabilization policy is not a very effective way to bring inflation down. Instead, it serves mainly to reduce real output, as Figure 5(b) shows. Here a leftward shift of the aggregate demand curve from D0D0 to D2D2 moves equilibrium from point E to point B, lowering real GDP by $400 billion but cutting the price level by merely 1 percent. Fighting inflation by contracting aggregate demand is obviously quite costly in this example.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

671

672

Part 7

Fiscal and Monetary Policy

F I GURE 4 S

Flat aggregate supply curve

Price Level

Price Level

Alternative Views of the Aggregate Supply Curve

S

Steep aggregate supply curve

S S

Real GDP (b)

Real GDP (a)

D1

D0 D2

A

Price Level

Price Level

D0

S

101 Rise in price

E

100 99

101 E

S

100 Fall in price

B

99

S

S D0 Rise in output 6,000

6,400

D1

D2 Fall in output 5,600

D0

6,000

Real GDP

Real GDP

(a) Expansionary Policy

(b) Contractionary Policy

NOTE: Real GDP in billions of dollars per year.

F I GURE 5 Stabilization Policy with a Flat Aggregate Supply Curve

Things are just the reverse if the aggregate supply curve is steep. In that case, expansionary fiscal or monetary policies will cause a good deal of inflation without boosting real GDP much. This situation is depicted in Figure 6(a), in which expansionary policies shift the aggregate demand curve outward from D0D0 to D1D1, thereby moving the economy’s equilibrium from E to A. Output rises by only $100 billion but prices shoot up 10 percent. Similarly, contractionary policy is an effective way to bring down the price level without much sacrifice of output, as shown by the shift from E to B in Figure 6(b). Here it takes only a $100 billion loss of output (from $6,000 billion to $5,900 billion) to “buy” 10 percent less inflation. Thus, as we can see, deciding whether the aggregate supply curve is steep or flat is clearly of fundamental importance to the proper conduct of stabilization policy. If the supply curve is flat, stabilization policy is much more effective at combating recession than inflation. If the supply curve is steep, precisely the reverse is true. Why does the argument persist? Why can’t economists just measure the slope of the aggregate supply curve and stop arguing? The answer is that supply conditions in the real

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

673

The Debate over Monetary and Fiscal Policy

Chapter 31

D1

S

S

D0

D0 A 110 Rise in price

E

D1

100

90

D0 S

Price Level

Price Level

110

D2

E

100 Fall in price

B

90

Rise in output 6,000 6,100 Real GDP

(a) Expansionary Policy

D0 S

Fall in output

D2

5,900 6,000 Real GDP (b) Contractionary Policy

FI GURE 6

NOTE: Real GDP in billions of dollars per year.

world are far more complicated than our simple diagrams suggest. Some industries may have flat supply curves, whereas others have steep ones. For reasons explained in Chapter 27, supply curves shift over time. And, unlike laboratory scientists, economists cannot perform controlled experiments that would reveal the shape of the aggregate supply curve directly. Instead, they must use statistical inference to make educated guesses. Although empirical research continues, our understanding of aggregate supply remains less settled than our understanding of aggregate demand. Nevertheless, many economists believe that the outline of a consensus view has emerged. This view holds that the steepness of the aggregate supply schedule depends on the time period under consideration. In the short run, the aggregate supply curve is quite flat, making Figure 5 the more relevant picture of reality. Over short time periods, therefore, fluctuations in aggregate demand have large effects on output but only minor effects on prices. In the long run, however, the aggregate supply curve becomes quite steep, perhaps even vertical. In that case, Figure 6 is a better representation of reality, so that changes in demand affect mainly prices, not output.3 The implication is that

Stabilization Policy with a Steep Aggregate Supply Curve

Any change in aggregate demand will have most of its effect on output in the short run but on prices in the long run.

We have yet to consider what may be the most fundamental and controversial debate of all—the issue posed at the beginning of the chapter. Is it likely that government policy can successfully stabilize the economy? Or are even well-intentioned efforts likely to do more harm than good? This controversy has raged for several decades. In part, the debate is political or philosophical. Liberal economists tend to be more intervention-minded and hence more favorably disposed toward an activist stabilization policy. Conservative economists are more inclined to keep the government’s hands off

SOURCE: From The Wall Street Journal. Reprinted with the permission of Cartoon Features Syndicate

DEBATE: SHOULD THE GOVERNMENT INTERVENE?

“Daddy’s not mad at you, dear— Daddy’s mad at the Fed.”

The reasoning behind the view that the aggregate supply curve is flat in the short run but steep in the long run will be developed in Chapter 33. 3

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

674

Part 7

Fiscal and Monetary Policy

The Fed Fights Recession Federal Funds Rate, 2007–2010

6 5 4 3 2

Year

SOURCE: Federal Reserve

Jan. 2010

Oct. 2009

Jul. 2009

Apr. 2009

Jan. 2009

Oct. 2008

Jul. 2008

Apr. 2008

Jan. 2008

Oct. 2007

Jul. 2007

0

Apr. 2007

1 Jan. 2007

Percentage Points

When things first started to deteriorate in the financial markets in the summer of 2007, the federal funds rate was sitting at 5.25 percent. Sensing trouble, the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) began to cut interest rates in September 2007. It moved slowly at first; by year-end, the funds rate was at 4.25 percent. Only in late January 2008 did the FOMC become alarmed about the potential macroeconomic fallout from the financial crisis, and then it began cutting rates aggressively—dropping the funds rate from 4.25 percent to 2 percent in about three months. The Fed then sat with its 2 percent funds rate for over five months, watching both financial developments and the deteriorating economy. Then the Lehman Brothers catastrophe happened in mid-September. A few weeks later, the Fed sprang into action again, cutting the funds rate from 2 percent to its current 0–0.25 percent range on December 16, 2008. Shortly thereafter, it declared that the super-low federal funds rate would remain in effect “for an extended period.” And indeed it has.

the economy and hence advise adhering to fixed rules. Such political differences are not surprising. But more than ideology propels the debate. We need to understand the economics. Critics of stabilization policy point to the lags and uncertainties that surround the operation of both fiscal and monetary policies—lags and uncertainties that we have stressed repeatedly in this and earlier chapters. Will the Fed’s actions have the desired effects on the money supply? What will these actions do to interest rates and spending? Can fiscal policy actions be taken promptly? How large is the expenditure multiplier? The list could go on and on. These skeptics look at this formidable catalog of difficulties, add a dash of skepticism about our ability to forecast the future, and worry that stabilization policy may fail. They therefore advise the authorities to pursue passive policies rather than active ones— adhering to fixed rules that, although incapable of ironing out every bump and wiggle in the economy’s growth path, will at least keep it roughly on track. Advocates of active stabilization policies admit that perfection is unattainable. However, they are much more optimistic about the prospects for success, and they are much less optimistic about how smoothly the economy would grow in the absence of demand management. They therefore advocate discretionary increases in government spending (or decreases in taxes) and lower interest rates when the economy has a recessionary gap—and the reverse when the economy has an inflationary gap. Such policies, they believe, will help keep the economy closer to its full-employment growth path. Each side can point to evidence that buttresses its own view. Activists look back with pride at the tax cut of 1964 and the sustained period of economic growth that it ushered in. They also point to the tax cut of 1975 (which was quickly enacted at just about the trough of a severe recession) and the even speedier fiscal stimulus packages enacted after 9/11, again in February 2008, and then again in February 2009. Advocates of using discretionary monetary policy extol the Federal Reserve’s switch to “easy money” in 1982, its expert steering of the economy between 1992 and 2000, and its quick responses to the threats to the economy after 9/11 and the financial panic in August 2007. Advocates of rules remind us of the government’s refusal to curb runaway demand during the 1966–1968 Vietnam buildup, its overexpansion of the economy in 1972, and the monetary overkill that Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 31

675

The Debate over Monetary and Fiscal Policy

helped bring on the sharp recession of 1981–1982. Some also argue that the Fed helped fuel the housing “bubble” by holding interest rates too low in 2003–2005. The historical record of fiscal and monetary policy is far from glorious. Although the authorities have sometimes taken appropriate and timely actions to stabilize the economy, at other times they clearly either took inappropriate steps or did nothing at all. The question of whether the government should adopt passive rules or attempt an activist stabilization policy therefore merits a closer look. As we shall see, the lags in the effects of policy discussed earlier in this chapter play a pivotal role in the debate.

Lags and the Rules-versus-Discretion Debate Potential GDP E

Actual and Potential GDP

Lags lead to a fundamental difficulty for stabilization policy—a difficulty so formidable that it has prompted some economists to conclude that attempts to stabilize economic activity are likely to do more harm than good. To see why, refer to Figure 7, which charts the behavior of both actual and potential GDP over the course of a business cycle in a hypothetical economy with no stabilization policy. At point A, the economy begins to slip into a recession and does not recover to full employment until point D. Then, between points D and E, it overshoots potential GDP and enters an inflationary boom. The argument in favor of stabilization policy runs something A B like this: Policy makers recognize that the recession is a serious problem at point B, and they take appropriate actions very soon. These actions have their major effects around point C and therefore limit both the depth and the length of the recession. But suppose the lags are really longer and less predictable than those just described. Suppose, for example, that actions do not come until point C and that stimulative policies do not have their major effects until after point D. Then policy will be of little help during the recession and will actually do harm by overstimulating the economy during the ensuing boom. Thus:

D Actual GDP

C

Time

FI GURE 7 A Typical Business Cycle

In the presence of long lags, attempts at stabilizing the economy may actually succeed in destabilizing it.

For this reason, some economists argue that we are better off leaving the economy alone and relying on its natural self-corrective forces to cure recessions and inflations. Instead of embarking on periodic programs of monetary and fiscal stimulus or restraint, they advise policy makers to stick to fixed rules that ignore current economic events. For monetary policy, we have already mentioned the monetarist policy rule: The Fed should keep the money supply growing at a constant rate. For fiscal policy, proponents of rules often recommend that the government resist the temptation to manage aggregate demand actively and rely instead on the economy’s automatic stabilizers, which we discussed in Chapter 28 (see page 609).

DIMENSIONS OF THE RULES-VERSUS-DISCRETION DEBATE Are the critics right? Should we forget about discretionary policy and put the economy on autopilot—relying on automatic stabilizers and the economy’s natural, self-correcting mechanisms? As usual, the answer depends on many factors.

How Fast Does the Economy’s Self-Correcting Mechanism Work? In Chapter 27, we emphasized that the economy has a self-correcting mechanism. If that self-correcting mechanism is fast and efficient, so that recessions and inflations will disappear quickly by themselves, the case for policy intervention is weak. Indeed, if such Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

676

Part 7

Fiscal and Monetary Policy

problems typically last only a short time, then lags in discretionary stabilization policy might mean that the medicine has its major effects only after the disease has run its course. In terms of Figure 7, this is a case in which point D comes very close to point A. In fact, a distinct minority of economists used precisely this reasoning to argue against a fiscal stimulus after the September 11, 2001, terrorist attacks and again after the financial panic of 2007–2008. But few made this argument once the 2007–2009 recession deepened. Although extreme advocates of rules argue that this is indeed what happens, most economists agree that the economy’s self-correcting mechanism is slow and not terribly reliable, even when supplemented by the automatic stabilizers. On this count, then, a point is scored for discretionary policy.

How Long Are the Lags in Stabilization Policy? We just explained why long and unpredictable lags in monetary and fiscal policy make it hard for stabilization policy to do much good. Short, reliable lags point in just the opposite direction. Thus advocates of fixed rules emphasize the length of lags, whereas proponents of discretion tend to discount them. Who is right depends on the circumstances. Sometimes policy makers take action promptly, and the economy receives at least some stimulus from expansionary policy within a year after slipping into a recession. The tax reductions and sharp cuts in interest rates that followed both the 9/11 tragedy and the financial crisis of 2007–2008 are the most recent examples. Although far from perfect, the effects of such timely actions were certainly felt soon enough to do some good. However, as we have seen, very slow policy responses may actually prove destabilizing. Because history offers examples of each type, we can draw no general conclusion.

How Accurate Are Economic Forecasts? One way to compress the policy-making lag dramatically is to forecast economic events accurately. If we could see a recession coming a full year ahead of time (which we certainly cannot do), even a rather sluggish policy response would still be timely. In terms of Figure 7, this would be a case in which the recession is predicted well before point A. Over the years, economists in universities, government agencies, and private businesses have developed a number of techniques to assist them in predicting what the economy will do. Unfortunately, none of these methods is terribly accurate. To give a rough idea of magnitudes, forecasts of either the inflation rate or the real GDP growth rate for the year ahead typically err by 6 3⁄4 to 1 percentage point. In a bad year for forecasters, errors of 2 or 3 percentage points occur. Is this forecasting record good enough? That depends on how the forecasts are used. It is certainly not good enough to support so-called fine-tuning—that is, attempts to keep the economy always within a hair’s breadth of full employment. But it probably is good enough for policy makers interested in using discretionary stabilization policy to close persistent and sizable gaps between actual and potential GDP, such as those of recent years.

The Size of Government One bogus argument sometimes heard is that active fiscal policy must inevitably lead to a growing public sector. Because proponents of fixed rules tend also to be opponents of big government, they view this growth as undesirable. Of course, others think that a larger public sector is just what society needs. This argument, however, is completely beside the point because, as we pointed out in Chapter 28: One’s opinion about the proper size of government should have nothing to do with one’s view on stabilization policy. For example, President George W. Bush was as conservative as they come and, at least rhetorically, he was devoted to shrinking the size of the public sector.4 But his tax-cutting initiatives in 2001–2003 constituted an extremely In fact, the size of the federal government expanded rapidly during his presidency, in part because of national security concerns, but also because of domestic spending.

4

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 31

The Debate over Monetary and Fiscal Policy

677

activist fiscal policy to spur economic growth. Furthermore, most stabilization policy these days consists of monetary policy, which neither increases nor decreases the size of government.

Uncertainties Caused by Government Policy Advocates of rules are on stronger ground when they argue that frequent changes in tax laws, government spending programs, or monetary conditions make it difficult for firms and consumers to formulate and carry out rational plans. They argue that the authorities can provide a more stable environment for the private sector by adhering to fixed rules so that businesses and consumers know exactly what to expect. No one disputes that a more stable environment is better for private planning. However, supporters of discretionary policy emphasize that stability in the economy is more important than stability in the government budget (or in Federal Reserve operations). The whole idea of stabilization policy is to prevent gyrations in the pace of economic activity by causing timely gyrations in the government budget (or in monetary policy). Which atmosphere is better for business, they ask: one in which fiscal and monetary rules keep things peaceful on Capitol Hill and at the Federal Reserve while recessions and inflations wrack the economy, or one in which government changes its policy abruptly on occasion but the economy grows more smoothly? They think the answer is self-evident. The question, of course, is whether stabilization policy can succeed in practice.

A Political Business Cycle? A final argument put forth by advocates of rules is political rather than economic. Fiscal policy decisions are made by elected politicians: the president and members of Congress. When elections are on the horizon (and for members of the House of Representatives, they always

Between Rules and Discretion interest rate in proportion to any excess of inflation above 2 percent (which is the Fed’s presumed inflation goal). No central bank uses the Taylor rule as a mechanical rule; nor did Taylor intend it that way. But many central banks around the world, including the Fed, find the Taylor rule useful as a benchmark to guide their decision making—thus blending, once again, features of both rules and discretion.

SOURCE: © David Devins/newscast

In recent years, a number of economists and policy makers have sought a middle ground between saddling monetary policy makers with rigid rules and giving them complete discretion, as the Federal Reserve has in the United States. One such approach is called “inflation targeting.” As practiced in the United Kingdom, for example, inflation targeting starts when an elected official (the Chancellor of the Exchequer, who is roughly equivalent to the U.S. Secretary of the Treasury) chooses a numerical target for the inflation rate—currently, this target is 2 percent for consumer prices. The United Kingdom’s central bank, the Bank of England, is then bound by law to try to reach this target. In that sense, the system functions somewhat like a rule. However, monetary policy makers are given complete discretion as to how they go about trying to achieve this goal. Neither the Chancellor nor Parliament interferes with day-to-day monetary policy decisions. The Federal Reserve’s current chairman, Ben Bernanke, was a big advocate of inflation targeting when he was a professor at Princeton University. But the Fed has not adopted it officially. Another approach is called the “Taylor rule,” after Professor John Taylor of Stanford University. More than a decade ago, Taylor noticed that the Fed’s interest rate decisions during the chairmanship of Alan Greenspan could be described by a simple algebraic equation. This equation, now called the Taylor rule, starts with a 2 percent real interest rate, and then instructs the Fed to lower the rate of interest in proportion to any recessionary gap and to raise the

The Bank of England’s Monetary Policy Committee

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

678

Part 7

Fiscal and Monetary Policy

are), these politicians may be as concerned with keeping their jobs as with doing what is right for the economy. This situation leaves fiscal policy subject to “political manipulation”— lawmakers may take inappropriate actions to attain short-run political goals. A system of purely automatic stabilization, its proponents argue, would eliminate this peril. It is certainly possible that politicians could deliberately cause economic instability to help their own reelection. Indeed, some observers of these “political business cycles” have claimed that several American presidents have taken full advantage of the opportunity. Furthermore, even without any insidious intent, politicians may take the wrong actions for perfectly honorable reasons. Decisions in the political arena are never clearcut, and it certainly is easy to find examples of grievous errors in the history of U.S. fiscal policy. Taken as a whole, then, the political argument against discretionary fiscal policy seems to have a great deal of merit. But what are we to do about it? It is unrealistic to believe that fiscal decisions could or should be made by a group of objective and nonpartisan technicians. Tax and budget policies require inherently political decisions that, in a democracy, should be made by elected officials. This fact may seem worrisome in view of the possibilities for political chicanery, but it should not bother us any more (or any less) than similar maneuvering in other areas of policy making. After all, the same problem besets international relations, national defense, formulation and enforcement of the law, and so on. Politicians make all these decisions for us, subject only to sporadic accountability at elections. Is there really any reason why fiscal decisions should be different? Monetary policy is different. Because Congress was concerned that elected officials focused on the short run would pursue inflationary monetary policies, it long ago gave day-to-day decision-making authority over monetary policy to the unelected technocrats at the Federal Reserve. Politics influences monetary policy only indirectly: The Fed must report to Congress, and the president has the power to appoint Federal Reserve governors whose views are to his liking. For the most part, however, the Fed is apolitical.

A Nobel Prize for the Rules-versus-Discretion Debate

SOURCE: © Sven Nackstrand/AFP/Getty Images

In 2004, the economists Finn Kydland and Edward Prescott were awarded the Nobel Prize for a fascinating contribution to the rules-versus-discretion debate. They called attention to a general problem that they labeled “time inconsistency,” and their analysis of this problem led them to conclude that the Fed should follow a rule. A close-to-home example will illustrate the basic time inconsistency problem. Suppose your instructor announces in September that a final exam will be given in December. The main purpose of the exam is to ensure that students study and learn the course materials, and the exam itself creates both work for the faculty and stress for the students. So, when December rolls around, it may seem “optimal” to call off the exam at the last moment. Of course, if that happened regularly, students

would soon stop studying for exams. So actually giving the exam is the better long-run policy. One way to solve this time inconsistency problem is to adopt a simple rule stating that announced exams will always be given, rather than allowing individual faculty members to cancel exams at their discretion. Kydland and Prescott argued that monetary policy makers face a similar time inconsistency problem. They first announce a stern anti-inflation policy (analogous to giving an exam). But then, when the moment of truth (December) arrives, they may relent because they don’t want to cause unemployment (all that work and stress). Their suggested solution: The Fed and other central banks should adopt rules that remove period-by-period discretion.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

The Debate over Monetary and Fiscal Policy

Chapter 31

ISSUE REVISITED:

679

WHAT SHOULD BE DONE?

So where do we come out on the question posed at the start of this chapter? On balance, is it better to pursue the best discretionary policy we can, knowing full well that we will never achieve perfection? Or is it wiser to rely on fixed rules and the automatic stabilizers? In weighing the pros and cons, your basic view of the economy is crucial. Some economists believe that the economy, if left unmanaged, would generate a series of ups and downs that would be difficult to predict, but that it would correct each of them by itself in a relatively short time. They conclude that, because of long lags and poor forecasts, our ability to anticipate whether the economy will need stimulus or restraint by the time policy actions have their effects is quite limited. Consequently, they advocate fixed rules. Other economists liken the economy to a giant glacier with a great deal of inertia. Under this view, if we observe an inflationary or recessionary gap today, it will likely still be there a year or two from now because the self-correcting mechanism works slowly. In such a world, accurate forecasting is not imperative, even if policy lags are long. If we base policy on a forecast of a 4 percent gap between actual and potential GDP a year from now, and the gap turns out to be only 2 percent, we still will have done the right thing despite the inaccurate forecast. Holders of this view of the economy tend to support discretionary policy, especially during deep slumps like the present one. There is certainly no consensus on this issue, either among economists or politicians. After all, the question touches on political ideology as well as economics, and liberals often look to government to solve social problems, whereas conservatives consistently point out that many efforts of government fail despite the best intentions. A prudent view of the matter might be that The case for active discretionary policy is strong when the economy has a serious deficiency or excess of aggregate demand. However, advocates of fixed rules are right that it is unwise to try to iron out every little wiggle in the growth path of GDP.

One thing seems certain: The rules-versus-discretion debate is likely to go on for quite some time.

| SUMMARY | 1. Velocity (V) is the ratio of nominal GDP to the stock of money (M). It indicates how quickly money circulates.

trast, monetary policy operates mainly on investment, I, which responds slowly to changes in interest rates.

2. One important determinant of velocity is the rate of interest (r). At higher interest rates, people find it less attractive to hold money because money pays zero or little interest. Thus, when r rises, money circulates faster, and V rises.

6. However, the policy-making lag normally is much longer for fiscal policy than for monetary policy. Hence, when the two lags are combined, it is not clear which type of policy acts more quickly.

3. Monetarism is a type of analysis that focuses attention on velocity and the money supply (M). Although monetarists realize that V is not constant, they believe that it is predictable enough to make it a useful tool for policy analysis and forecasting.

7. Because it cannot control the demand curve for money, the Federal Reserve cannot control both M and r. If the demand for money changes, the Fed must decide whether it wants to hold M steady, hold r steady, or adopt a compromise position.

4. Because it increases the volume of transactions, and hence increases the demands for bank deposits and therefore bank reserves, expansionary fiscal policy pushes interest rates higher. Higher interest rates reduce the multiplier by deterring some types of spending, especially investment.

8. Monetarists emphasize the importance of stabilizing the growth path of the money supply, whereas the predominant Keynesian view puts more emphasis on keeping interest rates on target.

5. Because fiscal policy actions affect aggregate demand either directly through G or indirectly through C, the expenditure lags between fiscal actions and their effects on aggregate demand are probably fairly short. By con-

9. In practice, the Fed has changed its views on this issue several times. For decades, it attached primary importance to interest rates. Between 1979 and 1982, it stressed its commitment to stable growth of the money supply. But, since then, the focus has clearly returned to interest rates.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

680

Part 7

Fiscal and Monetary Policy

10. When the aggregate supply curve is very flat, changes in aggregate demand will have large effects on the nation’s real output but small effects on the price level. Under those circumstances, stabilization policy works well as an antirecession device, but it has little power to combat inflation. 11. When the aggregate supply curve is steep, changes in aggregate demand have small effects on real output but large effects on the price level. In such a case, stabilization policy can do much to fight inflation but is not a very effective way to cure unemployment. 12. The aggregate supply curve is likely to be relatively flat in the short run but relatively steep in the long run. Hence, stabilization policy affects mainly output in the short run but mainly prices in the long run.

13. When the lags in the operation of fiscal and monetary policy are long and unpredictable, attempts to stabilize economic activity may actually destabilize it. 14. Some economists believe that our imperfect knowledge of the channels through which stabilization policy works, the long lags involved, and the inaccuracy of forecasts make it unlikely that discretionary stabilization policy can succeed. 15. Other economists recognize these difficulties but do not believe they are quite as serious. They also place much less faith in the economy’s ability to cure recessions and inflations on its own. They therefore think that discretionary policy is not only advisable, but essential. 16. Stabilizing the economy by fiscal policy need not imply a tendency toward “big government.”

| KEY TERMS | equation of exchange

662

lags in stabilization policy

monetarism 667

665

velocity

quantity theory of money

662

663

| TEST YOURSELF | 1. How much money by the M1 definition (cash plus checking account balances) do you typically have at any particular moment? Divide this amount into your total income over the past 12 months to obtain your own personal velocity. Are you typical of the nation as a whole? 2. The following table provides data on nominal gross domestic product and the money supply (M1 definition) in recent selected years. Compute velocity in each year. Can you see any trend? How does it compare with the trend that prevailed from 1975 to 1995?

Year 2004 2005 2006 2007

End-of-Year Money Supply (M1) $1,376 1,375 1,367 1,364

Nominal GDP $11,686 12,434 13,195 13,841

NOTE: Amounts are in billions.

3. Use a supply-and-demand diagram similar to Figure 2 to show the choices open to the Fed following an unexpected decline in the demand for money. If the Fed is following a monetarist policy, what will happen to the rate of interest? 4. Which of the following events would strengthen the argument for the use of discretionary policy, and which would strengthen the argument for rules? a. Structural changes make the economy’s self-correcting mechanism work more quickly and reliably than before.

b. New statistical methods are found that improve the accuracy of economic forecasts. c. A Republican president is elected when there is an overwhelmingly Democratic Congress. Congress and the president differ sharply on what should be done about the national economy. 5. (More difficult) The money supply (M) is the sum of bank deposits (D) plus currency in the hands of the public (call that C). Suppose the required reserve ratio is 20 percent and the Fed provides $50 billion in bank reserves (R 5 $50 billion). a. First assume that people hold no currency (C 5 0). How large will the money supply (M) be? If the Fed increases bank reserves to R 5 $60 billion, how large will M be then? b. Next, assume that people hold 20 cents worth of currency for each dollar of bank deposits; that is, C 5 0.2D. Define the monetary base (B) as the sum of reserves (R) plus currency (C): B 5 R 1 C. If the Fed now creates $50 billion worth of monetary base, how large will M be? (Hint: You will need a little bit of algebra to figure this out. Remember that the $50 billion monetary base is divided between two purposes: bank reserves and currency.) Now, if the Fed increases the monetary base to B 5 $60 billion, how large will M be? c. What do you notice about the relationship between M and B?

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 31

The Debate over Monetary and Fiscal Policy

681

| DISCUSSION QUESTIONS | 1. Use the concept of opportunity cost to explain why velocity is higher at higher interest rates. 2. How does monetarism differ from the quantity theory of money? 3. Given the behavior of velocity shown in Figure 1, would it make more sense for the Federal Reserve to formulate targets for M1 or M2? 4. Distinguish between the expenditure lag and the policy lag in stabilization policy. Does monetary or fiscal policy have the shorter expenditure lag? What about the policy lag? 5. Explain why their contrasting views on the shape of the aggregate supply curve lead some economists to argue much more strongly for stabilization policies to fight unemployment and other economists to argue much more strongly for stabilization policies to fight inflation.

6. Explain why lags make it possible that policy actions intended to stabilize the economy will actually destabilize it. 7. Many observers think that the Federal Reserve succeeded in using deft applications of monetary policy to “fine-tune” the U.S. economy into the full-employment zone in the 1990s without worsening inflation. Use the data on money supply, interest rates, real GDP, unemployment, and the price level given on the inside back cover of this book to evaluate this claim. 8. During the year 2008, U.S. economic performance deteriorated sharply. Can this decline be blamed on inferior monetary or fiscal policy? (You may want to ask your instructor about this question.)

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Budget Deficits in the Short and Long Run Blessed are the young, for they shall inherit the national debt. HERBERT HO OVER

M

onetary policy and fiscal policy are typically thought of as tools for short-run economic stabilization—that is, as ways to combat either inflation or unemployment. Debates over the Federal Reserve’s next interest-rate decision, or over this year’s federal budget, are normally dominated by short-run considerations such as: Does the economy need to be stimulated or restrained right now? But the monetary and fiscal choices the government makes today also have profound effects on our economy’s ability to produce goods and services in the future. We began Part 6 by emphasizing long-run growth, and especially the role of capital formation (see Chapters 23 and 24). But for most of Part 7, we have been preoccupied with the shorter-run issues of inflation, unemployment, and recession. This chapter integrates the two perspectives by considering both the long-run and short-run implications of fiscal and monetary policy decisions. What difference does it make if we stimulate (or restrain) the economy with fiscal or monetary policy? Should we strive to balance the budget? What are the economic virtues and vices of large budget deficits, both now and in the future?

C O N T E N T S ISSUE: IS THE FEDERAL GOVERNMENT BUDGET

INTERPRETING THE BUDGET DEFICIT OR SURPLUS

DEBT, INTEREST RATES, AND CROWDING OUT

SHOULD THE BUDGET ALWAYS BE BALANCED? THE SHORT RUN

The Structural Deficit or Surplus On-Budget versus Off-Budget Surpluses Conclusion: What Happened after 1981— and after 2001?

The Bottom Line

DEFICIT TOO LARGE?

The Importance of the Policy Mix

SURPLUSES AND DEFICITS: THE LONG RUN DEFICITS AND DEBT: TERMINOLOGY AND FACTS Some Facts about the National Debt

WHY IS THE NATIONAL DEBT CONSIDERED A BURDEN? BUDGET DEFICITS AND INFLATION The Monetization Issue

THE MAIN BURDEN OF THE NATIONAL DEBT: SLOWER GROWTH ISSUE REVISITED: IS THE BUDGET DEFICIT

TOO LARGE?

THE ECONOMICS AND POLITICS OF THE U.S. BUDGET DEFICIT

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

684

Part 7

Fiscal and Monetary Policy

ISSUE:

IS THE FEDERAL GOVERNMENT BUDGET DEFICIT TOO LARGE?

During 2008 and especially 2009, the federal budget deficit soared—partly because the weak economy reduced tax receipts, and partly because of extraordinary spending to fight the financial crisis and the recession. The deficit, which was $161 billion in fiscal year 2007, rose to $459 billion in fiscal 2008, and then to an amazing $1.413 trillion in fiscal 2009. So it was perhaps not surprising that the federal budget deficit became both a huge economic issue and a major political hot potato in 2009–2010. The Obama administration’s February 2010 budget promised smaller deficits—but not just yet. Many Republican (and some Democratic) critics argued that we should not wait that long. The president responded by, among other things, creating a bipartisan commission to report back by year-end on how best to reduce the deficit. Yet other voices, both economists and politicians, warned against reducing the budget deficit too hastily while the economy was still so weak. Either raising taxes or cutting spending while the economy was struggling to lift itself off the canvas was dangerous, they argued. Doing so could send us back into recession. Which side was right? Is it important to shrink the budget deficit quickly? Or should we be more patient, delaying any tax hikes and expenditure cuts for later? Putting the politics aside, by the end of this chapter you will be in an excellent position to make up your own mind on this important public policy issue.

SHOULD THE BUDGET ALWAYS BE BALANCED? THE SHORT RUN Americans have long been attracted by the idea of balancing the government budget year after year—so much so that a constitutional amendment to require a balanced budget has been proposed and debated many times. Let us begin our examination of the virtues and vices of a balanced budget by reviewing the basic principles of fiscal policy that we have learned so far (especially in Chapter 28). These principles certainly do not imply that we should always maintain a balanced budget, much as that notion may appeal to our intuitive sense of prudent financial management. Rather, they instruct fiscal policy makers to focus on balancing aggregate supply and aggregate demand. They therefore point to the desirability of budget deficits when private demand, C 1 I 1 (X 2 IM), is weak and of budget surpluses when private demand is strong. The budget should be balanced, according to these principles, only when C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM) under a balanced-budget policy approximately equals potential GDP. This situation may sometimes prevail, but it will not necessarily be the norm. The reason why a balanced budget is not always advisable should be clear from our earlier discussion of stabilization policy. Consider the fiscal policy that the federal government would follow if its goal were to maintain a balanced budget every year, as most of the 50 states do. Suppose the budget was initially balanced and private spending sagged for some reason, as it did in 2007–2008. The multiplier would pull GDP down. Because personal and corporate tax receipts fall sharply when GDP declines, the budget would automatically swing into the red. To restore budget balance, the government would then have to cut spending or raise taxes—exactly the opposite of the appropriate fiscal policy response to a recessionary gap, and exactly the opposite of what the federal government actually did. Thus: Attempts to balance the budget during recessions—as was done, say, during the Great Depression—will prolong and deepen slumps.

This is precisely what many observers were worried might happen in the United States, the United Kingdom, and many other countries if fiscal stimulus was withdrawn too soon in 2010. And there were vigorous debates over this issue in many countries. The argument,

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 32

Budget Deficits in the Short and Long Run

to be sure, was over when, not whether deficits should be reduced. Everyone agreed that deficits needed to be smaller eventually. This problem arises in both directions. Budget balancing also can lead to inappropriate fiscal policy under boom conditions. If rising tax receipts induce a budget-balancing government to spend more or to cut taxes, then fiscal policy will “boom the boom”—with unfortunate inflationary consequences.

The Importance of the Policy Mix Actually, the issue is even more complicated than we have indicated so far. As we know, fiscal policy is not the only way for the government to affect aggregate demand. It also can influence aggregate demand through its monetary policy. For this reason, The appropriate fiscal policy depends, among other things, on the current stance of monetary policy. Although a balanced budget may be appropriate under one monetary policy, a deficit or a surplus may be appropriate under another monetary policy.

Price Level

An example will illustrate the point. Suppose Congress and the president believe that the aggregate supply and demand curves will intersect approximately at full employment if the budget is balanced. Then a balanced budget would seem to be the appropriate fiscal policy. Now suppose monetary policy turns contractionary, pulling the aggregate demand curve FI GURE 1 inward to the left, as shown by the brick-colored arrow in Figure 1, and thereby creating a The Interaction of recessionary gap. If the fiscal authorities wish to restore GDP to its original level, they must Monetary and Fiscal shift the aggregate demand curve back to its original position, Policy D0D0, as indicated by the blue arrow. To do so, they must either raise spending or cut taxes, thereby opening up a budget deficit. Potential GDP Thus, the tightening of monetary policy changes the appropriate fiscal policy from a balanced budget to a deficit, because both D0 monetary and fiscal policies affect aggregate demand. Effect of S monetary By the same token, a given target for aggregate demand impolicy plies that any change in fiscal policy will alter the appropriate monetary policy. For example, we can reinterpret Figure 1 as inD1 dicating the effects of increasing the budget deficit by raising A government spending or cutting taxes (the blue arrow). Then, Effect of fiscal policy if the Fed wants real GDP to remain at Y1, it must raise interest B rates enough to restore the aggregate demand curve to D1D1. It is precisely the preferred mix of policy—a smaller budget D0 deficit balanced by easier money—that the U.S. government managed to engineer with great success in the 1990s. Congress S D1 raised taxes and cut spending, which reduced aggregate demand, but the Federal Reserve pursued a sufficiently expanY1 Y0 sionary policy to return this “lost” aggregate demand to the Real GDP economy by keeping interest rates low. So we should not expect a balanced budget to be the norm. How, then, can we tell whether any particular deficit is too large or too small? From the discussion so far, it would appear that the answer depends on the strength of privatesector aggregate demand and the stance of monetary policy, but those are not the only considerations.

SURPLUSES AND DEFICITS: THE LONG RUN One implication of what we have just said is that various combinations of fiscal and monetary policy can lead to the same level of aggregate demand, and hence to the same real GDP and price level, in the short run. For example, the government could reduce

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

685

686

Part 7

Fiscal and Monetary Policy

aggregate demand by raising taxes, but the Fed could make up for it by cutting interest rates. Or the reverse could happen: The government could cut taxes while the Fed raises interest rates, leaving aggregate demand unchanged. The long-run consequences of these alternative mixes of monetary and fiscal policy may be quite different, however. In previous chapters, we learned that more expansionary fiscal policy (tax cuts or higher government spending) and tighter money should produce higher real interest rates and therefore lower investment. Thus, such a policy mix should shift the composition of total expenditure, C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM), toward more G, more C (from tax cuts), and less I.1 The expected result is less capital formation, and therefore slower growth of potential GDP. As we shall see shortly, it was precisely that policy mix—large tax cuts and tight money—that the U.S. government inadvertently chose in the early 1980s and, to a lesser extent, in the years 2004–2006. The opposite policy mix—tighter budgets and looser monetary policy—should produce the opposite outcomes: lower real interest rates, more investment, and hence faster growth of potential GDP. That was the direction U.S. macroeconomic policy took in the 1990s—with excellent results. Lowering the budget deficit and then turning it into a surplus, economists believe, was an effective way to increase the investment share of GDP, which soared from 12 percent in 1992 to 17 percent in 2000. The general point is The composition of aggregate demand is a major determinant of the rate of economic growth. If a larger fraction of GDP is devoted to investment, the nation’s capital stock will grow faster and the aggregate supply schedule will shift more quickly to the right, accelerating growth.

Growth and Investment in 24 Countries

4% Japan

Ireland 3

2

Portugal

Italy Iceland Finland Turkey Canada Spain Austria Belgium Greece Luxembourg Germany U.K. France Denmark U.S.

Netherlands

Norway

Australia

Sweden Switzerland

1 New Zealand

0

18

20

22

24

26

28

Average Investment as Percent of GDP, 1970–1990

30

32

SOURCE: Economic Report of the President (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office; 1995), p. 28.

F I GURE 2

Average Annual Growth Rate of per Capita Real GDP, 1970–1990

International data likewise show a positive relationship between growth and the share of GDP invested. Figure 2 displays, for a set of 24 countries on four continents, both investment as a share of GDP and growth in per capita output over two decades (the 1970s and 1980s). Countries with higher investment rates clearly experienced higher growth, on average.

1 Assume for the moment that net exports, X 2 IM, are fixed. We will deal with the consequences of fiscal and monetary policy on exports and imports in Chapter 36.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 32

687

Budget Deficits in the Short and Long Run

So it appears that when we ask whether the budget should be in balance, in deficit, or in surplus, we have posed a good but complicated question. Before attempting to answer it, we need to get some facts straight.

DEFICITS AND DEBT: TERMINOLOGY AND FACTS First, some critical terminology. People frequently confuse two terms that have different meanings: budget deficits and the national debt. We must learn to distinguish between the two. The budget deficit is the amount by which the government’s expenditures exceed its receipts during some specified period of time, usually a year. If, instead, receipts exceed expenditures, we have a budget surplus. For example, during fiscal year 2009, the federal government raised $2.1 trillion in revenue and spent $3.5 trillion, resulting in an astonishingly large deficit of $1.4 trillion.2 The national debt, also called the public debt, is the total value of the government’s indebtedness at a moment in time. Thus, for example, the U.S. national debt at the end of fiscal year 2009 was almost $12 trillion. These two concepts—deficit and debt—are closely related because the government accumulates debt by running deficits or reduces its debt by running surpluses. The relationship between the debt and the deficit or surplus can be explained by a simple analogy. As you run water into a bathtub (“run a deficit”), the accumulated volume of water in the tub (“the debt”) rises. Alternatively, if you let water out of the tub (“run a surplus”), the level of the water (“the debt”) falls. Analogously, budget deficits raise the national debt, whereas budget surpluses lower it. However, getting rid of the deficit (shutting off the flow of water) does not eliminate the accumulated debt (drain the tub).

The budget deficit is the amount by which the government’s expenditures exceed its receipts during a specified period of time, usually a year. If receipts exceed expenditures, it is called a budget surplus instead. The national debt is the federal government’s total indebtedness at a moment in time. It is the result of previous budget deficits.

Some Facts about the National Debt Now that we have made this distinction, let us look at the size and nature of the accumulated public debt and then at the annual budget deficit. How large a public debt do we have? How did we get it? Who owes it? Is it growing or shrinking? To begin with the simplest question, the public debt is enormous. At the end of 2009, it amounted to about $40,000 for every man, woman, and child in America. But just over one-third of this outstanding debt was held by agencies of the U.S. government—in other words, one branch of the government owed it to another. If we deduct this portion, the net national debt was about $7.5 trillion, or approximately $25,000 per person. Furthermore, when we compare the debt with the gross domestic product—the volume of goods and services our economy produces in a year—it does not seem so large after all. With a GDP just over $14 trillion in late 2009, the net debt was about 53 percent of the nation’s yearly income. By contrast, many families who own homes owe several years’ worth of income to the banks that granted them mortgages. Many U.S. corporations also owe their bondholders much more than 53 percent of a year’s sales. Before these analogies make you feel too comfortable, we should point out that simple analogies between public and private debt are almost always misleading. For one thing, individuals do not live forever. But the federal government does—or at least we hope so— which increases its capacity to carry debt. On the other hand, a family with a large mortgage debt also owns a home whose value presumably exceeds the mortgage. And a solvent business firm has assets (factories, machinery, inventories, and so forth) that far exceed its outstanding debt in value. Is the same

2 Reminder: The fiscal year of the U.S. government ends on September 30. Thus, fiscal year 2009 ran from October 1, 2008, to September 30, 2009.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Part 7

Fiscal and Monetary Policy

thing true of the U.S. government? No one knows for sure. How much is the White House worth? Or the national parks? And what about military bases, both here and abroad? Because these government assets are not sold on markets, no one really knows their true value. But some people think the value of the government’s assets may be almost as large as the value of its debt. Figure 3 charts the path of the net national debt from 1915 to 2009, expressing each year’s net debt as a fraction of that year’s nominal GDP. Looking at the debt relative to GDP is important for two reasons. First, we must remember that everything grows in a growing economy. Given that private debt has expanded greatly since 1915, it would be surprising indeed if the public debt had not grown as well. In fact, federal debt grew more slowly than did either private debt or GDP for most of the period since World War II. The years from 1980 to about 1994 stand out as an aberration in Figure 3, with the debt-to-GDP ratio climbing sharply. Second, the debt is measured in dollars and, as long as there is any inflation, the amount of purchasing power that each dollar represents declines each year. Dividing the debt by nominal GDP, as is done in Figure 3, adjusts for both real growth and inflation, and so puts the debt numbers in better perspective. Figure 3 shows us how and when the U.S. government acquired all this debt. Notice the sharp increases in the ratio of debt to GDP during World War I, the Great Depression, and especially World War II. Thereafter, you see an unmistakable downward trend until the recession of 1974–1975. In 1945, the national debt was the equivalent of about a year’s worth of GDP. By 1974, this figure had been whittled down to just two months’ worth. Thus, until the 1980s, the U.S. government had acquired most of its debt either to finance wars or during recessions. As we will see later, the cause of the debt is quite germane to the question of whether the debt is a burden. So it is important to remember that Until about 1983, almost all of the U.S. national debt stemmed from financing wars and from the losses of tax revenues that accompany recessions.

Then things changed. From the early 1980s until 1993, the national debt grew faster than nominal GDP, reversing the pattern that had prevailed since 1945. This growth spurt happened without wars and only one recession. By 1993, the debt exceeded five months’ GDP—nearly triple its value in 1974. This development alarmed many economists and public figures. FIGURE 3

1.00 1981–1982 Recession World War II

1981–1984 Tax cuts

0.67

1993 Budget Agreement 2001–2003 Tax cuts

Great Depression 1974–1975 Recession

0.50 World War I

Great Recession

0.33

1915

1925

1935

1945

1955 Year

1965

1975

1985

1995

2009

SOURCE: Constructed by the authors from data in Historical Statistics of the United States and Economic Report of the President.

The U.S. National Debt Relative to GDP, 1915–2009

Ratio of Public Debt to Gross Domestic Product

688

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 32

689

Budget Deficits in the Short and Long Run

At that point, the government took decisive actions to reduce the budget deficit. The ratio of debt to GDP then fell for years. Then President George W. Bush’s large tax cuts reversed the trend for a few years after 2001, and recent events pushed the debt-to-GDP ratio sharply higher.

INTERPRETING THE BUDGET DEFICIT OR SURPLUS We have observed that the federal government ran large budget deficits from the early 1980s until the mid-1990s, and then again in the mid-2000s. As Figure 4 shows, the budget deficit ballooned from $79 billion in fiscal year 1981 to $208 billion by fiscal year 1983— setting a record that was subsequently eclipsed many times. The government managed to turn the budget to surplus during the years 1998 through 2001, but then large deficits reemerged after the Bush tax cuts. All that was dwarfed, however, by what happened starting in 2008. Recent deficits are enormous, even mind-boggling. What do these numbers mean? How should we interpret them?

The Structural Deficit or Surplus First, it is important to understand that the same fiscal program can lead to a deficit or a surplus, depending on the state of the economy. Failure to appreciate this point has led many people to assume that a larger deficit always signifies a more expansionary fiscal policy—which is not the case. Think, for example, about what happens to the budget during a recession. As GDP falls, the government’s major sources of tax revenue—income taxes, corporate taxes, and payroll taxes—all shrink because firms and people pay lower taxes when they earn less. Similarly, some types of government spending, notably transfer payments such as unemployment benefits, rise when GDP falls because more people are out of work. Recall that the deficit is the difference between government expenditures, which are either purchases or transfer payments, and tax receipts: Deficit 5 G 1 Transfers 2 Taxes 5 G 2 (Taxes 2 Transfers) 5 G 2 T

FIGU R E 4 Official Fiscal-Year Budget Deficits, 1981–2009

1400 1200

Federal Budget Deficit

1000 800 600 400

Deficits

200 ’98 ’99 ’00 ’01

0 –200

’81 ’82 ’83 ’84 ’85 ’86 ’87 ’88 ’89 ’90 ’91 ’92 ’93 ’94 ’95 ’96 ’97 Fiscal Year

–400

’02 ’03 ’04 ’05 ’06 ’07 ’08 ’09

Surpluses

–600 –800

NOTE: Amounts are in billions of dollars.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

SOURCE: Economic Report of the President (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office; 2010).

1600

690

Part 7

Fiscal and Monetary Policy

Spending and Tax Receipts

Because a falling GDP leads to higher transfer payments and lower tax receipts, T = Taxes – Transfers

The deficit rises in a recession and falls in a boom, even with no change in fiscal policy.

Figure 5 depicts this relationship between GDP and the budget deficit. The government’s G fiscal program is summarized by the blue and brick-colored lines. The horizontal blue line laDeficit beled G indicates that federal purchases of goods and services are approximately unafB fected by GDP. The rising brick-colored line labeled T (for taxes minus transfers) indicates that taxes rise and transfer payments fall as Y1 Y2 Y3 GDP rises. Notice that the same fiscal policy Gross Domestic Product (that is, the same two lines) leads to a large deficit if GDP is Y1, a balanced budget if GDP F I GURE 5 is Y2, or a surplus if GDP is as high as Y3. Clearly, the deficit itself is not a good measure of The Effect of the the government’s fiscal policy. Economy on the Budget To seek a better measure, economists pay more attention to what is called the structural budget deficit or surplus. This hypothetical measure replaces both the spending and The structural budget taxes in the actual budget by estimates of how much the government would be spending deficit or surplus is the and receiving, given current tax rates and expenditure rules, if the economy were hypothetical deficit or operating at some fixed, high-employment level. For example, if the high-employment surplus we would have under current fiscal policies benchmark in Figure 5 was Y2, although actual GDP was only Y1, the structural deficit if the economy were would be zero even though the actual deficit would be AB. operating near full Because it is based on the spending and taxing the government would be doing at some employment. fixed level of GDP, rather than on actual expenditures and receipts, the structural deficit does not depend on the state of the economy. It changes only when policy changes, not when GDP changes. For that reason, most economists view it as a better measure of the thrust of fiscal policy than the actual deficit. This new concept helps us understand the changing nature of the large budget deficits of the 1980s, the stunning turn to surpluses in the late 1990s, and the amazing swing back to large deficits since 2007. The first two columns of data in Table 1 show both the actual surplus and the structural surplus every other year since 1981. (Most of the numbers are negative, indicating deficits.) Because of recessions in 1983 and 1991, the actual deficit was far larger than the structural deficit in those years. But the difference between the two was negligible in 1987 and 1997, when the economy was near full emTAB LE 1 ployment, and then changed sign (the structural surplus was Alternative Budget Concepts, 1981–2009 smaller than the actual surplus) in 1999 and 2001. Several interesting facts stand out when we compare the Total Structural On-Budget Off-Budget Fiscal Surplus Surplus Surplus Surplus numbers in the first and second columns. First, even though the Year (1) (2) (3) (4) official deficit fell between fiscal 1983 and fiscal 1995, the structural 1981 279 258 274 25 deficit grew slightly—despite years of allegedly tight budgets. It 1983 2208 2124 2208 0 was this trend toward larger structural deficits that alarmed keen 1985 2212 2199 2222 110 students of the federal budget. Second, the sharp swing in the 1987 2150 2138 2168 118 budget deficit from 1993 to 1999 (from a deficit of $255 billion to a 1989 2153 2175 2205 152 surplus of $126 billion) far exceeds the change in the structural 1991 2269 2216 2321 152 1993 2255 2193 2300 145 deficit, which fell by “only” $231 billion. This last number, which is 1995 2164 2138 2226 162 still impressive, is a better indicator of how much fiscal policy 1997 222 228 2103 181 changed during the period. Third, the movement from a moderate1999 1126 138 12 1124 sized structural surplus in 2001 to a large structural deficit in 2001 1128 148 232 1160 2003, due mainly to the Bush tax cuts, was both rapid and huge. 2003 2378 2306 2538 1160 2005 2318 2313 2494 1176 And finally, of course, while the Great Recession opened up a 2007 2161 2162 2344 1182 large gap between the actual and structural deficits ($312 billion), 2009 21,417 21,105 21,554 1137 the structural deficit itself soared as the government spent hundreds of billions of dollars to fight the recession. NOTE: Amounts are in billions of dollars. Surplus

SOURCE: Congressional Budget Office

A

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 32

Budget Deficits in the Short and Long Run

On-Budget versus Off-Budget Surpluses When you read about the budget in the newspapers, you may see references to the “off-budget” surplus or deficit and the “on-budget” surplus or deficit. What do those terms mean? Because Social Security benefits are financed by an earmarked revenue source—the payroll tax—Social Security and a few minor items have traditionally been segregated in the federal fiscal accounts. Specifically, both Social Security expenditures and the payroll tax receipts that finance them are treated as off-budget items, whereas most other expenditures and receipts are classified as on-budget. Thus: Overall budget deficit 5 Off-budget deficit 1 On-budget deficit

Because the Social Security System has been running sizable surpluses in recent years, the difference between the overall and on-budget deficits has been substantial. For example, in fiscal year 2009, the overall budget showed a colossal $1,417 billion deficit (column 1). This was composed of a whopping $1,554 billion on-budget deficit (column 3) less a $137 billion Social Security surplus (column 4). Some people claim that such a large discrepancy must mean that the Social Security surplus is “hiding” the “true” deficit. That’s a matter of semantics. Nothing is really hidden; the facts are as given in Table 1. But you need to interpret the facts correctly. If you are interested in knowing how much the federal government must borrow each year, the total deficit (column 1) gives the number you want.

Conclusion: What Happened after 1981— and after 2001? Table 1 helps us understand the remarkable ups and downs of the federal budget deficit since the early 1980s. Column 1 shows the overall surplus (if positive) or deficit (if negative) every other year from 1981 to 2009, and column 2 shows the corresponding structural surplus. Finally, columns 3 and 4 break the overall surplus into its on-budget and off-budget components. The table tells the following story about the evolution of the budget deficit. The large Reagan tax cuts in the early 1980s ballooned the budget deficit from $79 billion to $212 billion, and more than 100 percent of this deterioration was structural (see column 2). Late in the 1980s, the deficit started rising again—even though Social Security began to run surpluses (see column 4). The overall deficit reached $269 billion in 1991, but then began to shrink. One reason was the burgeoning Social Security surplus, which increased by $115 between 1993 and 2001. The strong economy helped, too. Notice that the actual surplus rose more than the structural surplus. But most of the deficit-reducing “work” was on-budget and structural, as tax increases and expenditure restraint during the Clinton years finally got the budget under control—briefly, as it turned out. During the Bush administration, a combination of large tax cuts, a burst of spending, and weaker economic growth pushed the deficit up to a new record high of $378 billion in fiscal year 2003. But then both the actual and structural deficits receded sharply by 2007. The recession started late in 2007 and the rest, as they say, is history. The depressed economy plus the government’s strong anti-recessionary measures teamed up to produce a stunning $1.4 trillion deficit, a number previously deemed unimaginable.

WHY IS THE NATIONAL DEBT CONSIDERED A BURDEN? Now that we have gained some perspective on the facts, let us consider the charge that budget deficits place intolerable burdens on future generations. Perhaps the most frequently heard reason is that future Americans will be burdened by heavy interest payments, which will necessitate higher taxes. But think about who will receive those interest payments: mostly the future Americans who own the bonds. Thus, one group of future Americans will be making interest payments to another group of future Americans— which cannot be a burden on the nation as a whole.3 3

However, the future taxes that will have to be raised to pay the interest may reduce the efficiency of the economy.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

691

692

Part 7

Fiscal and Monetary Policy

However, there is a future burden to the extent that the debt is held by foreigners. The share of the net U.S. national debt owned by foreign individuals, businesses, and governments has been rising rapidly and is now over 50 percent. Paying interest on this portion of the debt will indeed burden future Americans in a very concrete way: For years to come, a portion of America’s GDP will be sent abroad to pay interest on the debts we incurred in the 1980s, 1990s, and 2000s. For this reason, many thoughtful observers are becoming concerned that the United States is borrowing too much from abroad.4 Thus, we conclude that If the national debt is owned by domestic citizens, future interest payments just transfer funds from one group of Americans to another. But the portion of the national debt owned by foreigners does constitute a burden on the nation as a whole.

Many people also worry that every nation has a limited capacity to borrow, just like every family and every business. If it exceeds this limit, it is in danger of being unable to pay its creditors and may go bankrupt—with calamitous consequences for everyone. For some countries, this concern is indeed valid and serious. Debt crises have done major damage to many countries in Latin America, Asia, and Africa over the years. Early in 2010, Greece was facing a potential debt crisis that could shake Europe. The U.S. government need not worry about defaulting on its debt for one simple reason. The American national debt is an obligation to pay U.S. dollars: Each debt certificate obligates the Treasury to pay the holder so many U.S. dollars on a prescribed date. But think about where those dollars come from. The U.S. government prints them up! So, in the worst case, if the U.S. government had no better way to pay off its creditors, it could always print whatever money it needed to do so. In a word, no nation need default on debts that call for repayment in its own currency.5 However, printing up the necessary money is not an option for countries whose debts call for payment, say, in U.S. dollars, as a number of Southeast Asian countries learned in 1997 and as Argentina learned in 2001. It does not, of course, follow that acquiring more debt through budget deficits is necessarily a good idea for the United States. Sometimes, it is clearly a bad idea. Nonetheless: There is a fundamental difference between nations that borrow in their own currency (such as the United States) and nations that borrow in some other currency (which is often the U.S. dollar). The former need never default on their debts; the latter might have to.

BUDGET DEFICITS AND INFLATION We now turn to the effects of deficits on macroeconomic outcomes. It often is said that deficit spending is a cause of inflation. Let us consider that argument with the aid of Figure 6, which is a standard aggregate supply-and-demand diagram. Initially, equilibrium is at point A, where demand curve D0D0 and supply curve SS intersect. Output is $7,000 billion, and the price index is 100. In the diagram, the aggregate demand and supply curves intersect precisely at potential GDP, indicating that the economy is operating at full employment. Let us also assume that the budget is initially balanced. Suppose the government now raises spending or cuts taxes enough to shift the aggregate demand schedule outward from D0D0 to D1D1. Equilibrium shifts from point A to point B, and the graph shows the price level rising from 100 to 106, or 6 percent. But that is not the end of the story, because point B represents an inflationary gap. We know from previous chapters that inflation will continue until the aggregate supply curve shifts far enough inward that it passes through point C, at which point the inflationary gap is gone. In this example, deficit spending will eventually raise the price level 12 percent. Thus, the cries that budget deficits are inflationary have the ring of truth. How much truth they hold depends on several factors. One is the slope of the aggregate supply curve. We will discuss the linkages between the federal budget deficit and foreign borrowing in greater detail in Chapter 36. 5 However, Russia astounded the financial world in 1998 by defaulting on its ruble-denominated debt. 4

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

D1

Aggregate supply curve shifts inward as wages rise

Potential GDP

S

D0 112 C Price Level

Figure 6 clearly shows that a steep supply curve would lead to more inflation than a flat one. A second factor is the degree of resource utilization. Deficit spending is more inflationary in a fully employed economy (such as that depicted in Figure 6) than in an economy with lots of slack, such as ours today. Finally, we must remember that the Federal Reserve’s monetary policy can always cancel out the potential inflationary effects of deficit spending by pulling the aggregate demand curve back to its original position. Once again, the policy mix is crucial.

693

Budget Deficits in the Short and Long Run

Chapter 32

106 B

100 A

D1 Deficit spending boosts aggregate demand

S D0 $5,000

$6,000

$7,000

$8,000

Real GDP

FI GURE 6

NOTE: Real GDP amounts are in billions of dollars.

The Monetization Issue

The central bank is said to monetize the deficit when it purchases bonds issued by the government.

For given Fed policy

Interest Rate

Will the Federal Reserve always neutralize the expansionary effect of a higher budget deficit? This question brings up another reason why some people worry about the inflationary consequences of deficits. They fear that the Federal Reserve may feel compelled to “monetize” part of the deficit by purchasing some of the newly issued government debt. Let us explain, first, why the Fed might make such purchases and, second, why these purchases are called monetizing the deficit. Deficit spending, we have just noted, normally drives up both real GDP and the price level. As we emphasized in Chapter 30, such an economic expansion shifts the demand curve for bank reserves outward to the right—as depicted by the movement from D0D0 to D1D1 in Figure 7. The diagram shows that, if the Federal Reserve takes no action to shift the supply curve, interest rates will rise as equilibrium moves from point A to point B. Suppose now that the Fed does not want interest rates to rise. What can it do? To prevent the incipient rise in r, it would have to engage in expansionary moneFIGURE 7 tary policy that creates new bank reserves, thereby Fiscal Expansion and Interest Rates shifting the supply curve for reserves outward to the right—as indicated in Figure 8. With the blue supply curve S1S1, equilibrium would be at point C rather D0 than at point B, leaving interest rates unchanged. S D1 Because the Federal Reserve usually pursues expansionary monetary policy by purchasing Treasury bills in the open market, deficit spending might therefore B induce the Fed to buy more government debt. But why is this process called monetizing the deficit? The reason is simple. As we learned in Chapter 29, creating more bank reserves generally leads, via the A multiple expansion process, to an increase in the money supply. By this indirect route, then, larger budget deficits may lead to a larger money supply. To summarize:

The Inflationary Effects of Deficit Spending

If the Federal Reserve takes no countervailing actions, an expansionary fiscal policy that increases the budget deficit will raise real GDP and prices, thereby raising the demand for bank reserves and

S

D0

Shift in demand for reserves caused by rising Y and P

D1

Quantity of Bank Reserves

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

694

Part 7

Fiscal and Monetary Policy

F I GURE 8 Monetization and Interest Rates

D1

Interest Rate

D0

S0

S1

B Expansionary Fed policy

S0

A

C

S1

D0

Quantity of Bank Reserves

D1

driving up interest rates (Figure 7). If the Fed does not want interest rates to rise, it can engage in expansionary open-market operations; that is, it can purchase more government debt. If the Fed does so, both bank reserves and the money supply will increase (Figure 8). In this case, we say that part of the deficit is monetized.

Monetized deficits are more inflationary than nonmonetized deficits for the simple reason that expansionary monetary and fiscal policies together are more inflationary than expansionary fiscal policy alone. But is this a real worry? Does the Fed actually monetize any substantial portion of the deficit? Normally, it does not. The clearest evidence is the fact that the Fed managed to reduce inflation in the 1980s, and again in the early years of this decade, even as the government ran huge budget deficits. But over the years, monetization of deficits has been a serious cause of inflation in many other countries, ranging from Latin America to Russia, Israel, Zimbabwe, and elsewhere.

DEBT, INTEREST RATES, AND CROWDING OUT So far, we have looked for possible problems that the national debt might cause on the demand side of the economy, but the real worry comes on the supply side. In brief, large budget deficits discourage investment and thereby retard the growth of the nation’s capital stock. The mechanism is easy to understand by presuming (as is generally the case) that the Fed does not engage in any substantial monetization. In that case, we have just seen, budget deficits tend to raise interest rates. We know from earlier chapters, though, that the rate of interest (r) is a major determinant of investment spending (I). In particular, higher r leads to less I. Lower investment today, in turn, means that the nation will have less capital tomorrow—and the size of potential GDP will be smaller. This, according to most economists, is the true sense in which a larger national debt may burden future generations—and, conversely, a smaller national debt may help them: A larger national debt may lead a nation to bequeath less physical capital to future generations. If they inherit less plant and equipment, these generations will be burdened by a smaller productive capacity—a lower potential GDP. By that mechanism, large deficits may retard economic growth. By the same logic, budget surpluses can stimulate capital formation and economic growth. Crowding out occurs when deficit spending by the government forces private investment spending to contract.

Phrasing this point another way explains why this result is often called the crowding out effect. Consider what happens in financial markets when the government engages in deficit spending. When it spends more than it takes in, the government must borrow the rest. It does so by selling bonds, which compete with corporate bonds and other financial instruments for the available supply of funds. As some savers decide to buy government bonds, the funds remaining to invest in private bonds must shrink. Thus, some private borrowers get “crowded out” of the financial markets as the government claims an increasing share of the economy’s total saving. Some critics of deficit spending have taken this lesson to its illogical extreme by arguing that each $1 of government spending crowds out exactly $1 of private spending, leaving “expansionary” fiscal policy with no net effect on total demand. In their view, when G rises, I falls by an equal amount, leaving the total of C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM) unchanged. Under normal circumstances, we would not expect this to occur. Why? First, moderate budget deficits push up interest rates only slightly. Second, private spending is only moderately

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 32

Budget Deficits in the Short and Long Run

695

SOURCE: From The Wall Street Journal— Permission, Cartoon Features Syndicate

sensitive to interest rates. Even at the higher interest rates that government deficits cause, most corporations will continue to borrow to finance their capital investments. Furthermore, in times of economic slack, a counterforce arises that we might call the crowding in effect. Deficit spending presumably quickens the pace of economic activity. That, at least, is its purpose. As the economy expands, businesses find it more profitable Crowding in occurs when to add to their capacity in order to meet the greater consumer demands. Because of this government spending, by induced investment, as we called it in earlier chapters, any increase in G may increase invest- raising real GDP, induces increases in private ment, rather than decrease it as the crowding-out hypothesis predicts. investment spending. The strength of the crowding-in effect depends on how much additional real GDP is stimulated by government spending (that is, on the size of the multiplier) and on how sensitive investment spending is to the improved business opportunities that accompany rapid growth. It is even conceivable that the crowding-in effect could dominate the crowding-out effect in the short run, so that I rises, on balance, when G rises. But how can this be true in view of the crowding-out argument? Certainly, if the government borrows more and the total volume of private saving is fixed, then private industry must borrow less. That’s just arithmetic. The fallacy in the strict crowdingout argument lies in supposing that the economy’s flow of saving is really fixed. If government deficits succeed in raising output, we will have more income and therefore more saving. In that way, both government and industry can borrow more. Which effect dominates—crowding out or crowding in? Crowding out stems from the increases in interest rates caused by deficits, whereas crowding in derives from the faster real economic growth that deficits sometimes produce. In the short run, the crowding-in “Would you mind explaining effect—which results from the outward shift of the aggregate demand curve—is often the again how high interest rates more powerful, especially when the economy is at less than full employment, as it is now. and the national deficit In the long run, however, the supply side dominates because, as we have learned, affect my allowance?” the economy’s self-correcting mechanism pushes actual GDP toward potential GDP. When the economy is approximately at potential, the crowding-out effect takes over: Higher interest rates lead to less investment, causing the capital stock and potential GDP to grow more slowly. Turned on its head, this is the basic long-run argument for reducing the budget deficit: Smaller budget deficits should raise investment and speed up economic growth.

The Bottom Line Let us summarize what we have learned so far about the crowding-out controversy. • The basic argument of the crowding-out hypothesis is sound: Unless the economy

produces enough additional saving, more government borrowing will force out some private borrowers, who are discouraged by the higher interest rates. This process will reduce investment spending and cancel out some of the expansionary effects of higher government spending. • Crowding out is rarely strong enough to cancel out the entire expansionary thrust of

government spending. Some net stimulus to the economy remains. • If deficit spending induces substantial GDP growth, then the crowding-in effect will

lead to more income and more saving—perhaps so much more that private industry can borrow more than it did previously, despite the increase in government borrowing. • The crowding-out effect is likely to dominate in the long run or when the economy is

operating near full employment. The crowding-in effect is likely to dominate in the short run, especially when the economy has a great deal of slack.

THE MAIN BURDEN OF THE NATIONAL DEBT: SLOWER GROWTH This analysis of crowding out versus crowding in helps us understand whether or not the national debt imposes a burden on future generations: When government budget deficits take place in a high-employment economy, the crowding-out effect probably dominates. So deficits exact a toll by leaving a smaller

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

696

Part 7

Fiscal and Monetary Policy

capital stock, and hence lower potential GDP to future generations. However, deficits in an economy with high unemployment may well lead to more investment rather than less. In this case, in which the crowding-in effect dominates, deficit spending increases growth and the new debt is a blessing rather than a burden.

Which case applies to the U.S. national debt? To answer this question, let us go back to the historical facts and recall how we accumulated all that debt prior to the 1980s. The first cause was the financing of wars, especially World War II. Because this debt was contracted in a fully employed economy, it undoubtedly constituted a burden in the formal sense of the term. After all, the bombs, ships, and planes that it financed were used up in the war, not bequeathed as capital to future generations. Yet today’s Americans may not feel terribly burdened by the decisions of those in power in the 1940s, for consider the alternatives. We could have financed the entire war by taxation and thus placed the burden on consumption rather than on investment. But that choice would truly have been ruinous, and probably impossible, given the colossal wartime expenditures. Alternatively, we could have printed money, which would have unleashed an inflation that nobody wanted. Finally, the government could have spent much less money and perhaps not have won the war. Compared to those alternatives, Americans of subsequent generations probably have not felt burdened by the massive deficit spending undertaken in the 1940s. A second major contributor to the national debt prior to 1983 was a series of recessions. But these are precisely the circumstances under which budget deficits might prove to be a blessing rather than a burden. So it was only in the 1980s that we began to have the type of deficits that are truly burdensome—deficits acquired in a fully employed, peacetime economy. This sharp departure from historical norms is what made those budget deficits worrisome. The tax cuts of 1981–1984 blew a large hole in the government budget, and the recession of 1981–1982 ballooned the deficit even further. By the late 1980s, the U.S. economy had recovered to full employment, but a structural deficit of $100–$150 billion per year remained. This persistent deficit was something that had never happened before. Such large structural deficits posed a real threat of crowding out and constituted a serious potential burden on future generations. After a brief interlude of budget surpluses in the late 1990s, large structural deficits reemerged in the early years of this decade, caused by a combination of large tax cuts and rapid spending growth. By 2007, that deficit problem seemed under control. But then came the Great Recession, and the government’s strenuous efforts to contain it, and the budget ballooned to unheard-of heights. Current projections also foresee very large deficits in the future, which worries economists and budget analysts. Let us now summarize our evaluation of the actual burden of the U.S. national debt: • The national debt will not lead the nation into bankruptcy, but it does impose a bur-

den on future generations to the extent that it is sold to foreigners or contracted in a fully employed, peacetime economy. In the latter case, it will reduce the nation’s capital stock. • Under some circumstances, budget deficits are appropriate for stabilization-policy purposes. • Until the 1980s, the actual public debt of the U.S. government was mostly contracted

as a result of wars and recessions—precisely the circumstances under which new debt does not constitute a burden. However, the large deficits of the 1980s and early 2000s were not mainly attributable to recessions, and were therefore worrisome.

ISSUE REVISITED:

IS THE BUDGET DEFICIT TOO LARGE?

We are now in a position to address the issues posed at the beginning of this chapter: Is the federal budget deficit too large? Must it be reduced quickly? To tackle these questions, we need to understand how and why fiscal policy changed, and we need to distinguish between the short-run (demand side) and long-run (supply side) effects of budget deficits. Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 32

Budget Deficits in the Short and Long Run

697

Price Level

Price Level

The deficit was of manageable size in fiscal year 2007, about 1.1 percent of GDP. (See Table 1.) Then the Great Recession happened, and the deficit soared to an amazing $1.417 billion (about 9.3 percent of GDP) by fiscal 2009. In dollar terms, that shattered all records. As a share of GDP, it was the largest deficit this country had seen since World War II. How did this happen? Three main factors contributed. One was the depth of the Great Recession, which was the worst since the 1930s. With GDP so far below potential, it was natural for the budget to swing toward larger deficits—for reasons emphasized in this chapter (see, especially, Figure 5). And it did. We saw in Table 1 that the cyclical component of the deficit rose from essentially zero in 2007 to $312 in 2009. Most of the increase came from lower tax receipts. The second major factor was the extraordinary spending and lending the U.S. government did to limit the financial FIGURE 9 collapse and assist the recovery. The largest and most promiThe Short-Run Effect of Larger Deficits or Smaller nent part of the government’s comprehensive financial rescue Surpluses was the $700 billion Troubled Assets Relief Program (TARP). It was not the only part, though.6 The rescue operations D1 were and remain highly controversial. But no one disD0 putes one fact: They made the budget deficit larger.7 Third came the $800+ billion fiscal stimulus package S that Congress enacted in February 2009, just one month into the new Obama administration. The package consisted B of tax cuts and increased government expenditures designed A to boost aggregate demand and, thereby, to limit the severity of the recession and assist the recovery. The stimulus package was also controversial, but everyone recognizes S that it raised the deficit substantially. Those were the fiscal policies. What were their effects? D1 In the short run, aggregate demand factors dominate ecoD0 nomic performance, and the stimulus from both higher spending and tax cuts provided an expansionary force just Real GDP when the economy needed one. Moving to much larger deficits probably cushioned the recession and sped up the recovery by boosting aggregate demand, as shown in Figure 9. In the long run, output gravitates toward potential GDP, FIGURE 10 no matter what happens to aggregate demand. So aggreThe Long-Run Effect of Larger Deficits or Smaller gate supply eventually rules the roost. And that is where Surpluses the long-run costs of fiscal stimulus emerge. Large budget deficits lead to higher real interest rates and hence to lower Potential levels of private investment. That makes the nation’s capital GDP stock grow more slowly, thereby retarding the growth rate of S1 potential GDP. This slower growth is depicted in Figure 10, which shows budget deficits leading to a potential GDP of D Y1 instead of Y0 in the future. With the same aggregate deS0 mand curve, DD, the result is lower real GDP. So, on balance, were the large fiscal deficits of 2008–2010 apB propriate? Most, but not all, economists would say yes. In those years, the economy clearly needed a lot of short-run stimulus. As the economy recovers, mammoth deficits may start to S1 A crowd out some investment spending. And that, in turn, would slow down the economy’s potential growth in the longD run. For that reason, thoughtful proponents of fiscal stimulus S0 wanted to ensure that any new spending program or tax cut was temporary; and opponents of stimulus wanted to keep the Y1 Y0 package small. But everyone agrees that the U.S. has a longReal GDP run deficit problem that must be addressed. 6 7

For much more detail of the financial crisis and the government’s responses to it, see the last chapter of this book. Some of the government’s money has already been returned, and more will be.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

698

Part 7

Fiscal and Monetary Policy

THE ECONOMICS AND POLITICS OF THE U.S. BUDGET DEFICIT Given what we have learned in this chapter about the theory and facts of budget deficits, we can now address some of the major issues that have been debated in the political arena for years. SOURCE: From The Wall Street Journal—Permission, Cartoon Features Syndicate

1. Have the deficits of the 1980s, 1990s, and 2000s been a problem? In 1981–1982, 1990–1991, and again in 2001, the U.S. economy suffered through recessions. And since late 2007, the economy has been very weak again. Under such circumstances, crowding out is not a serious concern, and actions to close the deficit during or right after these recessions would have threatened the subsequent recoveries. According to the basic principles of fiscal policy, large deficits were appropriate in each case. But in each case, crowding out became a more serious issue as the economy “The ‘Twilight Zone’ will not be recovered toward full employment. Budget deficits should decline under such seen tonight, so that circumstances—as they did in the 1990s and again from 2004 to 2007. Howwe may bring you the followng special on the ever, the deficit did not fall in the 1980s, nor in the period from 2002 to 2004. federal budget.” Instead, the structural deficit rose. Worries about the burden of the national debt, once mostly myths, became all too realistic then, as they will again in a few years. 2. How did we get rid of the deficit in the 1990s? In part, we did it the old-fashioned way: by raising taxes and reducing spending in three not-so-easy steps. There was a contentious but bipartisan budget agreement in 1990, a highly partisan deficitreduction package in 1993 (which passed without a single Republican vote), and a smaller bipartisan budget deal in 1997. Taxing more and spending less constitutes a contractionary fiscal policy that reduces aggregate demand. This effect did not hurt the U.S. economy in the 1990s because fiscal and monetary policies were well coordinated. If fiscal policy turns contractionary to reduce the deficit, monetary policy can turn expansionary to counteract the effects on aggregate demand. In this way, we can hope to shrink the deficit without shrinking the economy. Such a change in the policy mix should also bring down interest rates, because both tighter budgets and easier money tend to have that effect. Indeed, that is just what happened in the 1990s. Interest rates fell, and the Fed made sure that aggregate demand was sufficient to keep the economy growing. In addition, surprisingly rapid economic growth in the late 1990s generated much more tax revenue than anyone thought likely only a few years earlier. And the so-called off-budget surplus also increased. Both of these developments helped the federal budget turn rapidly from deficit into surplus. 3. How did the surplus give way to such large deficits so rapidly in the 2000s? As we have noted, the answer came in three parts under President George W. Bush: recession, tax cuts, and higher levels of spending, especially on national defense and homeland security. It is hardly a mystery that sharply rising expenditures and rapidly falling revenue pushed the budget from the black into the red. Then the budget situation got much worse under President Obama for reasons we have discussed: The economy deteriorated, and the government did what it could—at great expense—to stem the slide. 4. What are the future prospects for the federal budget deficit? In a word, not very good. Beginning in 2011, baby boomers born in the years after 1946 reach the magic age of 65—making them eligible for Medicare and, soon thereafter, for full Social Security benefits. So it is all but certain that federal spending will start to rise sharply. As of now, Congress has not enacted the future tax increases that will be needed to fund these expanding retirement and health-care programs. Nor has it cut the promised benefits. So, if nothing changes, the budget deficit will start to grow again. Economists are not terribly concerned about the gigantic budget deficits of 2009 and 2010, but they are worried about how the U.S. government will pay its bills in 2020, 2030, and 2040. Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Budget Deficits in the Short and Long Run

Chapter 32

699

| SUMMARY | 8. Unless the deficit is substantially monetized, deficit spending forces interest rates higher and discourages private investment spending. This process is called the crowding-out effect. If a great deal of crowding out occurs, then deficits impose a serious burden on future generations by leaving them a smaller capital stock with which to work.

1. Rigid adherence to budget balancing would make the economy less stable, by reducing aggregate demand (via tax increases and reductions in government spending) when private spending is low and by raising aggregate demand when private spending is high. 2. Because both monetary and fiscal policy influence aggregate demand, the appropriate budget deficit or surplus depends on monetary policy. Similarly, the appropriate monetary policy depends on budget policy.

9. Higher government spending (G) may also produce a crowding-in effect. If expansionary fiscal policy succeeds in raising real output (Y), more investment will be induced by the higher Y.

3. The same level of aggregate demand can be generated by more than one mix of fiscal and monetary policy, but the composition of GDP will be different in each case. Larger budget deficits and tighter money tend to produce higher interest rates, a smaller share of investment in GDP, and slower growth. Smaller budget deficits and looser monetary policy lead to a larger investment share and faster growth.

10. Whether crowding out or crowding in dominates largely depends on the time horizon. In the short run, and especially when unemployment is high, crowding in is probably the stronger force, so higher G does not cause lower investment. But, in the long run, the economy will be near full employment, and the proponents of the crowding-out hypothesis will be right: High government spending will mainly displace private investment.

4. One major reason for the large budget deficits of the early 1980s, early 1990s, and now is the fact that the economy operated well below full employment. In those years, the structural deficit, which uses estimates of what the government’s receipts and outlays would be at full employment to correct for business-cycle fluctuations, was much smaller than the official deficit.

11. Larger deficits may spur growth (via aggregate demand) in the short run but deter growth (via aggregate supply and potential GDP) in the long run. 12. Whether or not deficits create a burden depends on how and why the government incurred the deficits in the first place. If the government runs deficits to fight recessions, more investment may be crowded in by rising output than is crowded out by rising interest rates. Deficits contracted to carry on wars certainly impair the future capital stock, although they may not be considered a burden for noneconomic reasons. Because these two cases account for most of the debt the U.S. government contracted until the mid-1980s, that debt cannot reasonably be considered a serious burden. However, some of the deficits since 1984 are more worrisome on this score.

5. The need to make future interest payments on the public debt is a burden only to the extent that the national debt is owned by foreigners. 6. The argument that a large national debt can bankrupt a country like the United States ignores the fact that our national debt consists entirely of obligations to pay U.S. dollars—a currency that the government can raise by increasing taxes or create by printing money. 7. Budget deficits can be inflationary because they expand aggregate demand. They are even more inflationary if they are monetized—that is, if the central bank buys some of the newly issued government debt in the open market.

| KEY TERMS | budget deficit

687

budget surplus crowding in

687

695

crowding out

694

monetizing the deficit national debt

693

structural budget deficit or surplus 690

687

| TEST YOURSELF | 1. Explain the difference between the budget deficit and the national debt. If the deficit gets turned into a surplus, what happens to the debt? 2. Explain in words why the structural budget might show a surplus while the actual budget is in deficit. Illustrate your answer with a diagram like Figure 5.

3. If the Federal Reserve lowers interest rates, what will happen to the government budget deficit? (Hint: What will happen to tax receipts and interest expenses?) If the government wants to offset the effects of the Fed’s actions on aggregate demand, what might it do? How will this action affect the deficit?

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

700

Part 7

Fiscal and Monetary Policy

| DISCUSSION QUESTIONS | 1. Explain how the U.S. government managed to accumulate a debt of $12 trillion. To whom does it owe this debt? Is the debt a burden on future generations?

Fed to lower interest rates. In view of your answer to Test Yourself Question 3, why do you think that might be the case?

2. Comment on the following: “Deficit spending paves the road to ruin. If we keep it up, the whole nation will go bankrupt. Even if things do not go this far, what right have we to burden our children and grandchildren with these debts while we live high on the hog?”

4. Explain the difference between crowding out and crowding in. Given the current state of the economy, which effect would you expect to dominate today?

3. Newspaper reports frequently suggest that the administration (regardless of who is president) is pressuring the

5. Given the current state of the economy, what sort of fiscal-monetary policy mix seems most appropriate to you now? (Note: There is no one correct answer to this question. It is a good question to discuss in class.)

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

The Trade-Off between Inflation and Unemployment We must seek to reduce inflation at a lower cost in lost output and unemployment. JI MMY CA RTE R

I

magine that you were Ben Bernanke, chairman of the Federal Reserve Board, cutting interest rates in 2007 and 2008 in order to boost aggregate demand. Two things you would have liked to know is how much your actions were likely to speed up real GDP growth, and hence reduce unemployment, and how much they were likely to increase inflation—because monetary policy normally moves unemployment and inflation in opposite directions in the short run. This is an idea we first encountered in our list of Ideas for Beyond the Final Exam in Chapter 1. Back then, we noted that there is a bothersome trade-off between inflation and unemployment: High-growth policies that reduce unemployment tend to raise inflation, and slow-growth policies that reduce inflation tend to raise unemployment. We subsequently observed, in Chapter 31, that the trade-off looks rather different in the short run than in the long run because the aggregate supply curve is fairly flat in the short run but quite steep (or vertical) in the long run. A statistical relationship called the Phillips curve seeks to summarize the quantitative dimensions of the trade-off between inflation and unemployment in both the short and long runs. This chapter is about the Phillips curve; that is, it is about one of the things that Chairman Bernanke was wondering in 2007 and 2008.

C O N T E N T S ISSUE: IS THE TRADE-OFF BETWEEN INFLATION AND UNEMPLOYMENT A RELIC OF THE PAST?

DEMAND-SIDE INFLATION VERSUS SUPPLY-SIDE INFLATION: A REVIEW ORIGINS OF THE PHILLIPS CURVE SUPPLY-SIDE INFLATION AND THE COLLAPSE OF THE PHILLIPS CURVE Explaining the Fabulous 1990s

ISSUE RESOLVED: WHY INFLATION AND

UNEMPLOYMENT BOTH DECLINED

WHAT THE PHILLIPS CURVE IS NOT

THE THEORY OF RATIONAL EXPECTATIONS

FIGHTING UNEMPLOYMENT WITH FISCAL AND MONETARY POLICY

What Are Rational Expectations? Rational Expectations and the Trade-Off An Evaluation

WHAT SHOULD BE DONE? The Costs of Inflation and Unemployment The Slope of the Short-Run Phillips Curve The Efficiency of the Economy’s Self-Correcting Mechanism

INFLATIONARY EXPECTATIONS AND THE PHILLIPS CURVE

WHY ECONOMISTS (AND POLITICIANS) DISAGREE THE DILEMMA OF DEMAND MANAGEMENT ATTEMPTS TO REDUCE THE NATURAL RATE OF UNEMPLOYMENT INDEXING

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

702

Part 7

Fiscal and Monetary Policy

ISSUE:

IS THE TRADE-OFF BETWEEN INFLATION AND UNEMPLOYMENT A RELIC OF THE PAST?

In the late 1990s, unemployment in the United States fell to extremely low levels—the lowest in 30 years. Yet, in stark contrast to prior experience, inflation did not rise. In fact, it fell slightly. This pleasant conjunction of events, which was nearly unprecedented in U.S. history, set many people talking about a glorious “New Economy” in which there was no longer any trade-off between inflation and unemployment. The soaring stock market, especially for technology stocks, added to the euphoria. Is the long-feared trade-off really just a memory now? Can the modern economy speed along without fear of rising inflation? Or does faster growth eventually have inflationary consequences? These are questions the Federal Reserve has wrestled with since 2007, and they are the central questions for this chapter. Our answers, in brief, are: no, no, and yes. And we will devote most of this chapter to explaining why.

DEMAND-SIDE INFLATION VERSUS SUPPLY-SIDE INFLATION: A REVIEW

F I GURE 1 Inflation from the Demand Side D1

Price Level

D0

S

Demand-side inflation is a rise in the price level caused by rapid growth of aggregate demand. Supply-side inflation is a rise in the price level caused by slow growth (or decline) of aggregate supply.

We begin by reviewing some of what we learned about inflation in earlier chapters. One major cause of inflation, although certainly not the only one, is rapid growth of aggregate demand. We know that any autonomous increase in spending—whether initiated by consumers, investors, the government, or foreigners—has multiplier effects on aggregate demand. So each additional $1 of C or I or G or (X 2 IM) leads to more than $1 of additional demand. We also know that firms normally find it profitable to supply additional output only at higher prices; that is, the aggregate supply curve slopes upward. Hence, a stimulus to aggregate demand normally pulls up both real output and prices. S Figure 1, which is familiar from earlier chapters, reviews this conclusion. Initially, the economy is at point A, where the aggregate demand curve D0D0 intersects the aggregate supply curve SS. Then something happens to increase spending, B and the aggregate demand curve shifts horizontally to D1D1. A The new equilibrium is at point B, where both prices and output are higher than they were at A. Thus, the economy experiences both inflation and increased output. The slope of the aggregate supply curve measures the amount of inflation that D1 accompanies any specified rise in output and therefore calibrates the trade-off between inflation and economic growth. D0 We also have learned in this book (especially in Chapter 27) Real GDP that inflation does not always originate from the demand side. Anything that retards the growth of aggregate supply— for example, an increase in the price of foreign oil—can shift the economy’s aggregate supply curve inward. This sort of inflation is illustrated in Figure 2, where the aggregate supply curve shifts inward from S0S0 to S1S1, and the economy’s equilibrium consequently moves from point A to point B. Prices rise as output falls. We have stagflation. Thus, although inflation can emanate from either the demand side or the supply side of the economy, a crucial difference arises between the two sources. Demand-side inflation is normally accompanied by rapid growth of real GDP (as in Figure 1), whereas supply-side inflation is normally accompanied by stagnant or even falling GDP (as in Figure 2). This distinction has major practical importance, as we will see in this chapter.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 33

703

The Trade-Off between Inflation and Unemployment

ORIGINS OF THE PHILLIPS CURVE

S1 D0

Price Level

Let us begin by supposing that most economic fluctuations are S0 driven by gyrations in aggregate demand, which is what our brief review of U.S. macroeconomic history in Chapter 21 suggested. In that case, we have just seen that GDP growth and inB flation should rise and fall together. Is this what the data show? We will see shortly, but first let us translate the prediction A into a corresponding statement about the relationship between inflation and unemployment. Faster growth of real outS1 put naturally means faster growth in the number of jobs and, hence, lower unemployment. Conversely, slower growth of S0 real output means slower growth in the number of jobs and, hence, higher unemployment. So we conclude that if business D0 fluctuations emanate from the demand side, unemployment Real GDP and inflation should move in opposite directions. Unemployment should fall when inflation rises high and rise when FI GURE 2 inflation falls. Inflation from the Figure 3 illustrates the idea. The unemployment rate in the United States in 2007 Supply Side averaged 4.6 percent (which we approximate by 5 percent in the figure), and the Consumer Price Index was 2.8 percent higher than in 2006 (which we approximate by 2 percent). Point B in Figure 3 records these two numbers. Had aggregate demand grown faster, inflation would have been higher and unemployment would have been FI GURE 3 lower. To create a concrete example, let us suppose that unemployment would have

If fluctuations in economic activity are caused primarily by variations in the rate at which the aggregate demand curve shifts outward from year to year, then the data should show an inverse relationship between unemployment and inflation.

Origins of the Phillips Curve

3 Inflation Rate

been 4 percent and inflation would have been 3 percent—as shown by point A in Figure 3. By contrast, had aggregate demand grown more slowly than it actually did, unemployment would have been higher and inflation lower. In Figure 3, we suppose that unemployment would have been 6 percent and inflation would have been just 1 percent (point C). This figure displays the principal empirical implication of our theoretical model:

2

1

A

B

C

Now we are ready to look at real data. Do we actually 4% 5% 6% observe such an inverse relationship between inflation Unemployment Rate and unemployment? About 50 years ago, the economist Alban W. Phillips plotted data on unemployment and the rate of change of money wages (not prices) for several exA Phillips curve is a graph tended periods of British history on a series of scatter diagrams, one of which is repro- depicting the rate of duced as Figure 4. He then sketched a curve that seemed to fit the data well. This type unemployment on the of curve, which we now call a Phillips curve, shows that wage inflation normally is horizontal axis and either high when unemployment is low and is low when unemployment is high. So far, so the rate of inflation or the good. These data illustrate the short-run trade-off between inflation and unemploy- rate of change of money wages on the vertical axis. ment, one of our Ideas for Beyond the Final Exam. Phillips curves are more commonly constructed for price inflation; Figure 5 shows a Phillips curves are normally downward-sloping, Phillips-type diagram for the post–World War II United States. This curve also appears to indicating that higher fit the data well. As viewed through the eyes of our theory, these facts suggest that inflation rates are economic fluctuations in Great Britain between 1861 and 1913 and in the United States associated with lower between 1954 and 1969 probably arose primarily from changes in the growth rate of unemployment rates.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Part 7

Fiscal and Monetary Policy

FIGURE 4

10 8 6 4 2 0 –2 –4 1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

9

10

11

Unemployment Rate in Percent

SOURCE: Alban W. Phillips, “The Relation between Unemployment and the Rate of Change of Money Wages in the United Kingdom, 1861–1957,” Economica, New Series, 25 (November 1958).

Rate of Change of Money Wage Rates in Percent per Year

The Original Phillips Curve

FIGURE 5 A Phillips Curve for the United States, 1954–1969

7% 6 Inflation Rate

704

1968 1969

5 4

1966 1956

3

1957

2

1967 1964 1960

1 0

1955 1965

1954 1962 1959

1958 1961

1963 1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

9

10

Unemployment Rate in Percent

aggregate demand. The simple model of demand-side inflation really does seem to describe what happened. During the 1960s and early 1970s, many economists thought of the Phillips curve as a “menu” of choices available to policy makers. In this view, policy makers could opt for low unemployment and high inflation—as in 1969—or for high unemployment and low inflation—as in 1961. The Phillips curve was thought to measure the quantitative tradeoff between inflation and unemployment. And for a number of years it seemed to work. Then something happened. The economy in the 1970s and early 1980s behaved far worse than the historical Phillips curve had led economists to expect. In particular, given the unemployment rates in each of those years, inflation was astonishingly high by past standards. This fact is shown clearly by Figure 6, which simply adds to Figure 5 the data points for 1970 to 1984. So something went badly wrong with the old view of the Phillips curve as a menu for policy choices. But what? There are two major answers to this question, and a full explanation contains elements of each.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 33

705

The Trade-Off between Inflation and Unemployment

SUPPLY-SIDE INFLATION AND THE COLLAPSE OF THE PHILLIPS CURVE 12% 11 10 1974 1980 9 1979 8 Inflation Rate

We begin with the simpler answer, which is that much of the inflation in the years from 1972 to 1982 did not emanate from the demand side at all. Instead, the 1970s and early 1980s were full of adverse “supply shocks”—events such as crop failures in 1972–1973 and oil price increases in 1973–1974 and again in 1979–1980. These events pushed the economy’s aggregate supply curve inward to the left, as was shown in Figure 2. What kind of “Phillips curve” will be generated when economic fluctuations come from the supply side? Figure 2 reminds us that output will decline (or at least grow more slowly) and prices will rise when the economy is hit by an adverse supply shock. Now, in a growing population with more people looking for jobs each year, a stagnant economy that does not generate enough new jobs will suffer a rise in unemployment. Thus inflation and unemployment will rise together:

1973 1978

7

1977 1968

6 1969

5

1982 1984

1955 1965 1954 1957 1962 1967 1959 1958 1964 1961 1960 1963

3 2

0

1971 1972 1976 1970

1966 1956

4

1

If fluctuations in economic activity emanate from the supply side, higher rates of inflation will be associated with higher rates of unemployment, and lower rates of inflation will be associated with lower rates of unemployment.

1981 1975

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

1983

9

10

Unemployment Rate in Percent

The major supply shocks of the 1970s stand out clearly in Figure 6. (Remember—these are real data, not textbook examples.) Food prices soared from 1972 to 1974, and again in 1978. Energy prices skyrocketed in 1973–1974, and again in 1979–1980. Clearly, the inflation and unemployment data generated by the U.S. economy in 1972–1974 and in 1978–1980 are consistent with our model of supply-side inflation. Most economists believe that supply shocks, not demand shocks, dominated the decade from 1972 to 1982.

FI GURE 6 A Phillips Curve for the United States?

Explaining the Fabulous 1990s

Price Level

Now let’s stand this analysis of supply shocks on its head. Suppose the economy experiences FI GURE 7 a favorable supply shock, rather than an adverse one, so that the aggregate supply curve shifts The Effects of a outward at an unusually rapid rate. Any number of factors—such as a drop in oil prices, Favorable Supply Shock bountiful harvests, or exceptionally rapid technological advances—can have this effect. Normal growth S0 D1 Whatever the cause, Figure 7 (which dupliof aggregate supply cates Figure 14 of Chapter 27) depicts the conseS1 D0 quences. The aggregate demand curve shifts outward as usual, but the aggregate supply curve shifts out more than it would in a “normal” year. C So the economy’s equilibrium winds up at point A Effect of favorable B B rather than at point C, meaning that economic supply shock growth is faster (B is to the right of C) and inflation is lower (B is below C). Thus, inflation falls while rapid growth reduces unemployment. Figure 7 more or less characterizes the experiD1 ence of the U.S. economy from 1996 to 1998. Oil S0 prices plummeted, lowering costs to American S1 D0 businesses and households. Stunning advances in technology made computer prices drop even Real GDP more rapidly than usual. And the rising value of

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

706

Part 7

Fiscal and Monetary Policy

the U.S. dollar made imported goods cheaper to Americans.1 Thus, we benefited from a series of favorable supply shocks, and the effects were as depicted in Figure 7. The U.S. economy grew rapidly, and inflation and unemployment fell together.

ISSUE RESOLVED:

WHY INFLATION AND UNEMPLOYMENT BOTH DECLINED

We now have the answer to the question posed at the start of this chapter. We do not need to add anything new or mysterious to explain the marvelous economic performance of the second half of the 1990s. According to the basic macroeconomic theory taught in this book, favorable supply shocks should produce rapid economic growth with falling inflation—which is just what happened. The U.S. economy did so well, in part, because we were so fortunate.

WHAT THE PHILLIPS CURVE IS NOT

F I GURE 8 The Elimination of a Recessionary Gap

Price Level

D

A

S0 S1 S2

So one view of what went wrong with the Phillips curve is that adverse supply shocks dominated the 1970s and early 1980s. But there is another view, one that holds that policy makers misinterpreted the Phillips curve and tried to pick combinations of inflation and unemployment that were simply unsustainable. Specifically, we have learned that the Phillips curve is a statistical relationship between inflation and unemployment that we expect to emerge if business cycle fluctuations arise mainly from changes in the growth of aggregate demand. In the 1970s and 1980s, the curve was widely misinterpreted as depicting a number of alternative equilibrium points from which policy makers could choose. To understand the flaw in this reasoning, let us quickly review an earlier lesson. We know from Chapter 27 that the economy has a self-correcting mechanism that will cure both inflations and recessions eventually, even if the government does nothing. This idea is important in this context because it tells us that many combinations of output and prices cannot be maintained indefinitely. Some will self-destruct. Specifically, if the economy finds itself far from the normal full-employment level of unemployment, forces will be set in motion that tend to erode the inflationary or recessionary gap. Figure 8 depicts the case of a recessionary gap where aggregate supply curve S0S0 intersects aggregate demand curve DD at point A. With equilibrium output well below potential GDP, the economy has unused industrial capacity Potential GDP and unsold output, so inflation will be tame. At the same time, the availability of unemployed workers eager for jobs S0 limits the rate at which labor can push up wage rates. Since S1 wages are the main component of business costs, when they S2 decline (relative to what they would have been without a recession) so do costs. These lower costs, in turn, stimulate greater production. Figure 8 illustrates this process by an B outward shift of the aggregate supply curve—from S0S0 to the brick-colored curve S1S1. C As the figure shows, the outward shift of the aggregate supply curve brought on by the recession pushes equilibrium output up as the economy moves from point A to D point B. Thus, the size of the recessionary gap begins to shrink. This process continues until the aggregate supply Real GDP curve reaches the position indicated by the blue curve S2S2 1

The dollar and imports will be discussed in detail in Chapter 36.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 33

707

The Trade-Off between Inflation and Unemployment

Inflation Rate

in Figure 8. Here wages have fallen enough to eliminate the recessionary gap, and the econf 8% d omy has reached a full-employment equilib7 rium at point C.2 We can relate this sequence of events to our 6 discussion of the origins of the Phillips curve e 5 with the help of Figure 9, which is a hypothetical Phillips curve. Point a in Figure 9 corresponds to 4 point A in Figure 8: It shows the initial recessiona g 3 ary gap with unemployment (assumed to be 6.5 percent) above full employment, which we asc 2 sume to occur at 5 percent. 1 We have just seen that point A in Figure 8— and therefore also point a in Figure 9—is not 3.5 4 4.5 5 5.5 6 6.5 7 sustainable. The economy tends to rid itself of the recessionary gap through the disinflation Unemployment Rate in Percent process just described. The adjustment path from A to C depicted in Figure 8 would appear on our FI GURE 9 Phillips curve diagram as a movement toward less inflation and less unemployment— The Vertical Long-Run something like the blue arrow from point a to point c in Figure 9. Phillips Curve Similarly, points representing inflationary gaps—such as point d in Figure 9—are also not sustainable. They, too, are gradually eliminated by the self-correcting mechanism that we studied in Chapter 27. Wages are forced up by the abnormally low unemployment, which in turn pushes prices higher. Higher prices deter investment spending by forcing up interest rates, and they deter consumer spending by lowering the purchasing power of consumer wealth. The inflationary process continues until the amount people want to buy is brought into line with the amount firms want to sell at normal full employment. During such an adjustment period, unemployment and inflation both rise—as indicated by the blue arrow from point d to point f in Figure 9. Putting these two conclusions together, we see that On a Phillips curve diagram such as Figure 9, neither points corresponding to an inflationary gap (like point d) nor points corresponding to a recessionary gap (like point a) can be maintained indefinitely. Inflationary gaps lead to rising unemployment and rising inflation. Recessionary gaps lead to falling inflation and falling unemployment.

All the points that are sustainable in the long run (such as c, e, and f ), therefore, correspond to the same rate of unemployment, which is therefore called the natural rate of unemployment. The natural rate corresponds to what we have so far been calling the “full-employment” unemployment rate. Thus, the Phillips curve connecting points d, e, and a is not a menu of policy choices at all. Although we can move from a point such as e to a point such as d by stimulating aggregate demand sufficiently, the economy will not be able to remain at d. We cannot keep unemployment at such a low level indefinitely. Instead, policy makers must choose from among points such as c, e, and f, all of which correspond to the same “natural” rate of unemployment. For obvious reasons, the line connecting these points has been dubbed the vertical long-run Phillips curve. It is this vertical Phillips curve, connecting points such as e and f, that represents the true long-run menu of policy choices. We thus conclude: THE TRADE-OFF BETWEEN INFLATION AND UNEMPLOYMENT In the short run, it is possible to “ride up the Phillips curve” toward lower levels of unemployment by stimulating aggregate demand. (See, for example, point d in Figure 9.) Conversely, by restricting the growth of demand, it is possible to “ride down the Phillips curve” toward lower rates of

The economy’s self-correcting mechanism always tends to push the unemployment rate back toward a specific rate of unemployment that we call the natural rate of unemployment. The vertical (long-run) Phillips curve shows the menu of inflation/ unemployment choices available to society in the long run. It is a vertical straight line at the natural rate of unemployment.

IDEAS FOR BEYOND THE FINAL EXAM

2

This simple analysis assumes that the aggregate demand curve does not move during the adjustment period. If it is shifting to the right, the recessionary gap will disappear even faster, but inflation will not slow down as much. (EXERCISE: Construct the diagram for this case by adding a shift of the aggregate demand curve to Figure 8.)

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

708

Part 7

Fiscal and Monetary Policy

inflation (such as point a in Figure 9). Thus, there is a short run trade-off between unemployment and inflation. Stimulating demand will improve the unemployment picture but worsen inflation; restricting demand will lower inflation but aggravate the unemployment problem. However, there is no such trade-off in the long run. The economy’s self-correcting mechanism ensures that unemployment will eventually return to the natural rate no matter what happens to aggregate demand. In the long run, faster growth of demand leads only to higher inflation, not to lower unemployment; and slower growth of demand leads only to lower inflation, not to higher unemployment.

FIGHTING UNEMPLOYMENT WITH FISCAL AND MONETARY POLICY Now let us apply this analysis to a concrete policy problem—one that has often troubled policy makers in the United States and in many other countries. Should the government use its ability to manage aggregate demand through fiscal and monetary policy to combat unemployment? And if so, how? To focus the discussion, we will deal with a recent, realworld example. When the Great Recession started in December 2007, the unemployment rate stood at 5 percent, pretty much in line with estimates of the natural rate of unemployment. We were at something like point e in Figure 9, though with much lower inflation. But then the economy started to weaken, gradually at first, and the unemployment rate crept up—to about 6 percent by the summer of 2008. We were moving down the Phillips curve in the direction of point a in Figure 9. The recession got far worse in the last quarter of 2008 and the first quarter of 2009, with GDP contracting about 3 percent in just six months, and unemployment began to skyrocket—topping 9 percent in May 2009 and reaching a high of 10.1 percent in October. Think of this as being like point a in Figure 9, with a large recessionary gap. Even if fiscal and monetary policy makers did nothing, the economy’s self-correcting mechanism would have gradually eroded the recessionary gap. Both unemployment and inflation would have declined gradually as the economy moved along the blue arrow from point a to point c in Figure 9. Eventually, as the diagram shows, the economy would have returned to its natural rate of unemployment (assumed here to be 5 percent) and inflation would have fallen—in the example, from 3 percent to 2 percent. This eventual outcome is quite satisfactory: Both unemployment and inflation are lower at the end of the adjustment period (point c) than at the beginning (point a). But it may take an agonizingly long time to get there. And American policy makers in 2008 and 2009 did not view patience as a virtue. Rather than keep hands off, the Federal Reserve started cutting interest rates aggressively. Fiscal policy reacted as well, with Congress passing a large fiscal stimulus package. According to the theory we have learned, such a large dose of expansionary fiscal and monetary policy should push the economy up the short-run Phillips curve from a point like a toward a point like e in Figure 9. Compared to simply relying on the self-correcting mechanism, then, the strong policy response presumably will lead to a faster recovery from the 2007–2009 recession—which was certainly the intent of the president, Congress, and the Fed. But Figure 9 points out that it also probably will leave us with a higher inflation rate (5 percent in the figure, lower in reality). This example illustrates the range of choices open to policy makers. They can wait patiently while the economy’s self-correcting mechanism pulls unemployment down to the natural rate—leading to a long-run equilibrium like point c in Figure 9. Or they can rush the process along with expansionary monetary and fiscal policy—and wind up with the same unemployment rate but higher inflation (point e). In what sense, then, do policy makers face a trade-off between inflation and unemployment? The answer, illustrated by this diagram, is The cost of reducing unemployment more rapidly by expansionary fiscal and monetary policies is a permanently higher inflation rate.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 33

The Trade-Off between Inflation and Unemployment

WHAT SHOULD BE DONE? Should the government pay the inflationary costs of fighting unemployment? When the transitory benefit (lower unemployment for a while) is balanced against the permanent cost (higher inflation), have we made a good bargain? We have noted that the U.S. government opted for a strong policy response in 2008–2009. Thus two forces were at work simultaneously: The self-correcting mechanism was pulling the economy toward point c in Figure 9, and expansionary monetary and fiscal policies were pushing it toward point e. The net result was an intermediate path—something like the dotted line leading to point g in Figure 9. As the economy started to return to full employment in 2010, growth resumed and inflation was relatively stable. How do policy makers make decisions like this? Our analysis highlights three critical issues on which the answer depends.

The Costs of Inflation and Unemployment In Chapter 23, we examined the social costs of inflation and unemployment. Many of the benefits of lower unemployment are readily measured in dollars and cents. Basically, we need only estimate how much higher real GDP is each year. However, the costs of the permanently higher inflation rate are more difficult to measure. So there is considerable controversy over the costs and benefits of using demand management to fight unemployment. Economists and political leaders who believe that inflation is extremely costly may deem it unwise to accept the inflationary consequences of reducing unemployment faster. And indeed, a few dissenters in 2007 and 2008 (when the Fed once cut interest rates to fight the recession) were worried about future inflation. Most U.S. policy makers apparently disagreed with that view, however. They decided that fighting unemployment was the higher priority. But things do not always work out that way. In the 1980s and 1990s, European authorities often avoided expansionary stabilization policies, and allowed unemployment to remain high, rather than accept even slightly higher inflation.

The Slope of the Short-Run Phillips Curve The shape of the short-run Phillips curve is also critical. Look back at Figure 9, and imagine that the Phillips curve connecting points a, e, and d was much steeper. In that case, the inflationary costs of using expansionary policy to reduce unemployment would be more substantial. By contrast, if the short-run Phillips curve was much flatter than the one shown in Figure 9, unemployment could be reduced with less inflationary cost.

The Efficiency of the Economy’s Self-Correcting Mechanism We have emphasized that once a recessionary gap opens, the economy’s natural selfcorrecting mechanism will eventually close it—even in the absence of any policy response. The obvious question is: How long must we wait? If the self-correcting mechanism—which works through reductions in wage inflation—is fast and reliable, high unemployment will not last very long. So the costs of waiting will be small. But if wage inflation responds only slowly to unemployment, the costs of waiting may be enormous—which is how things looked to U.S. policy makers in 2008–2010. The efficacy of the self-correcting mechanism is also surrounded by controversy. Most economists believe that the weight of the evidence points to extremely sluggish wage behavior: Wage inflation appears to respond slowly to economic slack. In terms of Figure 9, this lag means that the economy will traverse the path from a to c at an agonizingly slow pace, so that a long period of weak economic activity will be necessary to bring down inflation. A significant minority opinion finds this assessment far too pessimistic. Economists in this group argue that the costs of reducing inflation are not nearly so severe and that

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

709

710

Part 7

Fiscal and Monetary Policy

Inflation Targeting and the Phillips Curve In Chapter 31, we mentioned inflation targeting as a new approach to monetary policy that is gaining adherents in many countries. In practice, inflation targeting requires monetary policy makers to rely heavily on the Phillips curve. Why? Because a central bank with, say, a 2 percent inflation target is obligated to pursue a monetary policy that it believes will drive the inflation rate to 2 percent after, say, a year or two. But how does the central bank know which policy will accomplish this goal?

Knowing the proper policy with certainty is, of course, out of the question. A central bank can use a model similar to the aggregate supply/demand model taught in this book to estimate how its policy choices will affect the unemployment rate, say, this year and next. Then it can use a Phillips curve to estimate how that unemployment path will affect inflation. In fact, that is more or less what inflation-targeting central banks from New Zealand to Norway now do.

the key to a successful anti-inflation policy is how it affects people’s expectations of inflation. To understand this argument, we must first understand why expectations are relevant to the Phillips curve.

INFLATIONARY EXPECTATIONS AND THE PHILLIPS CURVE Recall from Chapter 27 that the main reason the economy’s aggregate supply curve slopes upward—that is, why output increases as the price level rises—is that businesses typically purchase labor and other inputs under long-term contracts that fix input costs in money terms. (The money wage rate is the clearest example.) As long as such contracts are in force, real wages fall as the prices of goods rise. Labor therefore becomes cheaper in real terms, which persuades businesses to expand employment and output. Buying low and selling high is, after all, the route to higher profits. TABLE 1 Table 1 illustrates this general idea in a concrete example. We supMoney and Real Wages under Unexpected pose that workers and firms agree today that the money wage to be Inflation paid a year from now will be $10 per hour. The table then shows the real wage corresponding to each alternative inflation rate. For example, Price Level Wage per Real Wage Inflation 1 Year Hour 1 Year per Hour if inflation is 4 percent, the real wage a year from now will be Rate from Now from Now 1 Year from Now $10.00/1.04 5 $9.62. Clearly, the higher the inflation rate, the higher the 0% 100 $10.00 $10.00 price level at the end of the year and the lower the real wage. 2 102 10.00 9.80 Lower real wages provide an incentive for firms to increase output, 4 104 10.00 9.62 as we have just noted. But lower real wages also impose losses of pur6 106 10.00 9.43 chasing power on workers. Thus, workers are, in some sense, NOTE: Each real wage figure is obtained by dividing the $10 “cheated” by inflation if they sign a contract specifying a fixed money nominal wage by the corresponding price level a year later wage in an inflationary environment. and multiplying by 100. Thus, for example, when the inflation rate is 4 percent, the real wage at the end of the year is Many economists doubt that workers will sign such contracts if ($10.00/104) 3 100 5 $9.62. they can see inflation coming. Wouldn’t it be wiser, these economists ask, to insist on being compensated for the coming inflation? After TABLE 2 all, firms should be willing to offer higher money wages if they exMoney and Real Wages under Expected Inflation pect inflation, because they realize that higher money wages need not imply higher real wages. Expected Expected Real Expected Price Level Wage per Wage per Table 2 illustrates the mechanics of such a deal. For example, if Inflation 1 Year Hour 1 Year Hour 1 Year people expect 4 percent inflation, the contract could stipulate that Rate from Now from Now from Now the wage rate be increased to $10.40 (which is 4 percent more than 0% 100 $10.00 $10.00 $10) at the end of the year. That would keep the real wage at $10 2 102 10.20 10.00 (because $10.40/1.04 5 $10.00), the same as it would be under zero 4 104 10.40 10.00 inflation. The other money wage figures in Table 2 are derived 6 106 10.60 10.00 similarly.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

711

The Trade-Off between Inflation and Unemployment

Chapter 33

If workers and firms behave this way, and if they forecast inflation accurately, then the real wage will remain unchanged as the price level rises. (Notice that, in Table 2, the expected future real wage is $10 per hour regardless of the expected inflation rate.) Prices and wages will go up together. So workers will not lose from inflation, and firms will not gain. Then there is no reason for firms to raise production when the price level rises. In a word, the aggregate supply curve becomes vertical. In general: If workers can see inflation coming, and if they receive compensation for it, inflation does not erode real wages. But if real wages do not fall, firms have no incentives to increase production. In such a case, the economy’s aggregate supply curve will not slope upward, but, rather, will be a vertical line at the level of output corresponding to potential GDP.

Such a curve is shown in Panel (a) of Figure 10. Because a vertical aggregate supply curve leads to a vertical Phillips curve, it follows that even the short-run Phillips curve would be vertical under these circumstances, as in Panel (b) of Figure 10.3 If this analysis is correct, it has profound implications for the costs and benefits of fighting inflation. To see this, refer once again to Figure 9, but now use the graph to depict the strategy of fighting inflation by causing a recession. Suppose we start at point e, with 5 percent inflation. To move to point c (representing 2 percent inflation), the economy must take a long and unpleasant detour through point a. Specifically, contractionary policies must push the economy down the Phillips curve toward point a before the selfcorrecting mechanism takes over and moves the economy from a to c. In words, we must suffer through a recession to reduce inflation. What if even the short-run Phillips curve were vertical rather than downward-sloping? In this case, the unpleasant recessionary detour would not be necessary. Instead, inflation could fall without unemployment rising. The economy could move vertically downward from point e to point c. Does this optimistic analysis describe the real world? Can we really slay the inflationary dragon so painlessly? Not necessarily, for our discussion of expectations so far has made at least one unrealistic assumption: that businesses and workers can predict inflation accurately. Under this assumption, as Table 2 shows, real wages are unaffected by inflation—leaving the aggregate supply curve vertical, even in the short run. Forecasts of inflation are often inaccurate. Suppose workers underestimate inflation. For example, suppose they expect 4 percent inflation but actually get 6 percent. Then

FIGURE 10 A Vertical Aggregate Supply Curve and the Corresponding Vertical Phillips Curve Vertical aggregate supply curve

Inflation Rate

Price Level

S

Vertical short-run Phillips curve

S Real GDP

5 Unemployment Rate

(a)

(b)

Test Yourself Question 1 at the end of the chapter asks you to demonstrate that a vertical aggregate supply curve leads to a vertical Phillips curve.

3

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

712

Part 7

Fiscal and Monetary Policy

real wages will decline by 2 percent. More generally, real wages will fall if workers underestimate inflation at all. The effects of inflation on real wages will be somewhere in between those shown in Tables 1 and 2.4 So firms will retain some incentive to raise production as the price level rises, which means that the aggregate supply curve will retain some upward slope. We thus conclude that The short-run aggregate supply curve is vertical when inflation is predicted accurately but upward-sloping when inflation is underestimated. Thus, only unexpectedly high inflation will raise output, because only unexpected inflation reduces real wages.5 Similarly, only an unexpected decline in inflation will lead to a recession.

Because people often fail to anticipate changes in inflation correctly, this analysis seems to leave our earlier discussion of the Phillips curve almost intact for practical purposes. Indeed, most economists nowadays believe that the Phillips curve slopes downward in the short run but is vertical in the long run.

THE THEORY OF RATIONAL EXPECTATIONS Rational expectations are forecasts that, although not necessarily correct, are the best that can be made given the available data. Rational expectations, therefore, cannot err systematically. If expectations are rational, forecasting errors are pure random numbers.

However, an influential minority of economists disagrees. This group, believers in the hypothesis of rational expectations, insists that the Phillips curve is vertical even in the short run. To understand their point of view, we must first explain rational expectations. Then we will see why rational expectations have such radical implications for the tradeoff between inflation and unemployment.

What Are Rational Expectations? In many economic contexts, people must formulate expectations about what the future will bring. For example, those who invest in the stock market need to forecast the future prices of the stocks they buy and sell. Likewise, as we have just discussed, workers and businesses may want to forecast future prices before agreeing on a money wage. Rational expectations is a controversial hypothesis about how such forecasts are made. As used by economists, a forecast (an “expectation”) of a future variable is considered rational if the forecaster makes optimal use of all relevant information that is available at the time of the forecast. Let us elaborate on the two italicized words in this definition, using as an example a hypothetical stock market investor who has rational expectations. First, proponents of rational expectations recognize that information is limited. An investor interested in Google stock would like to know how much profit the company will make in the coming years. Armed with such information, she could predict the future price of Google stock more accurately. But that information is simply unavailable. The investor’s forecast of the future price of Google shares is not “irrational” just because she cannot foresee the future. On the other hand, if Google stock normally goes down on Fridays and up on Mondays, she should be aware of this fact. Next, we have the word optimal. As used by economists, it means using proper statistical inference to process all the relevant information that is available before making a forecast. In brief, to have rational expectations, your forecasts do not have to be correct, but they cannot have systematic errors that you could avoid by applying better statistical methods. This requirement, although exacting, is not quite as outlandish as it may seem. A good billiards player makes expert use of the laws of physics even without understanding the theory. Similarly, an experienced stock market investor may make good use of information even without formal training in statistics.

4 To make sure you understand why, construct a version of Table 2 based on the assumption that workers expect 4 percent inflation (and hence set next year’s wage at $10.40 per hour), regardless of the actual rate of inflation. If you create this table correctly, it will show that higher inflation leads to lower real wages, as in Table 1. 5 To see this point, compare Tables 1 and 2.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 33

The Trade-Off between Inflation and Unemployment

Rational Expectations and the Trade-Off Let us now see how some economists have used the hypothesis of rational expectations to deny any trade-off between inflation and unemployment—even in the short run. Although they recognize that inflation cannot always be predicted accurately, proponents of rational expectations insist that workers will not make systematic errors. Remember that our argument leading to a sloping short-run Phillips curve tacitly assumed that workers are slow to recognize changes. They thus underestimate inflation when it is rising and overestimate it when it is falling. Many observers see such systematic errors as a realistic description of human behavior. But advocates of rational expectations disagree, claiming that it is fundamentally illogical. Workers, they argue, will always make the best possible forecast of inflation, using all the latest data and the best available economic models. Such forecasts will sometimes be too high and sometimes too low, but they will not err systematically in one direction or the other. Consequently: If expectations are rational, the difference between the actual rate of inflation and the expected rate of inflation (the forecasting error) must be a pure random number, that is: Inflation 2 Expected inflation 5 A random number

Now recall that the argument in the previous section concluded that employment is affected by inflation only to the extent that inflation differs from what was expected. But, under rational expectations, no predictable change in inflation can make the expected rate of inflation deviate from the actual rate of inflation. The difference between the two is simply a random number. Hence, according to the rational expectations hypothesis, unemployment will always remain at the natural rate—except for random, and therefore totally unpredictable, gyrations due to forecasting errors. Thus: If expectations are rational, inflation can be reduced without a period of high unemployment because the short-run Phillips curve, like the long-run Phillips curve, will be vertical.

According to the rational expectations view, the government’s ability to manipulate aggregate demand gives it no ability to influence real output and unemployment because the aggregate supply curve is vertical even in the short run. (To see why, experiment by moving an aggregate demand curve when the aggregate supply curve is vertical, as in Figure 10(a).) The government’s manipulations of aggregate demand are planned ahead and are therefore predictable, and any predictable change in aggregate demand will change the expected rate of inflation. It will therefore leave real wages unaffected. The government can influence output only by making unexpected changes in aggregate demand, but unexpected changes are not easy to engineer if expectations are rational, because people will understand what policy makers are up to. For example, if the authorities typically react to high inflation by reducing aggregate demand, people will soon come to anticipate this reaction. And anticipated reductions in aggregate demand do not cause unexpected changes in inflation.

An Evaluation Believers in rational expectations are optimistic about reducing inflation without losing any output, even in the short run. Are they right? As a piece of pure logic, the rational expectations argument is impeccable. But as is common in the world of economic policy, controversy arises over how well the theoretical idea applies in practice. Although the theory has attracted many adherents, the evidence to date leads most economists to reject the extreme rational expectations position in favor of the view that a trade-off between inflation and unemployment does exist in the short run. Here are some of the reasons.

Contracts May Embody Outdated Expectations Many contracts for labor and other raw materials cover such long periods of time that the expectations on which they were Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

713

714

Part 7

Fiscal and Monetary Policy

based, although perhaps rational at the time, may appear “irrational” from today’s point of view. For example, some three-year labor contracts were drawn up in 1996, when inflation had been running near 3 percent for years. It might have been rational then to expect the 1999 price level to be about 9 percent higher than the 1996 price level, and to have set wages for 1999 accordingly. By 1997, however, inflation had fallen to below 2 percent, and such an expectation would have been plainly irrational. But it might already have been written into contracts. If so, real wages wound up higher than intended, giving firms an incentive to reduce output and therefore employment—even though no one behaved irrationally.

Expectations May Adjust Slowly Many people believe that inflationary expectations do not adapt as quickly to changes in the economic environment as the rational expectations theory assumes. If, for example, the government embarks on an anti-inflation policy, workers may continue to expect high inflation for a while. Thus, they may continue to insist on rapid money wage increases. Then, if inflation actually slows down, real wages will rise faster than anyone expected, and unemployment will result. Such behavior may not be strictly rational, but it may be realistic. When Do Workers Receive Compensation for Inflation? Some observers question whether wage agreements typically compensate workers for expected inflation in advance, as assumed by the rational expectations theory. More typically, they argue, wages catch up to actual inflation after the fact. If so, real wages will be eroded by inflation for a while, as in the conventional view.

What the Facts Show The facts have not been kind to the rational expectations hypothesis. The theory suggests that unemployment should hover around the natural rate most of the time, with random gyrations in one direction or the other. Yet this is not what the data show. The theory also predicts that preannounced (and thus expected) antiinflation programs should be relatively painless. Yet, in practice, fighting inflation has proved very costly in virtually every country. Finally, many direct tests of the rationality of expectations have cast doubt on the hypothesis. For example, survey data on people’s expectations rarely meet the exacting requirements of rationality. All of these problems with rational expectations should not obscure a basic truth. In the long run, the rational expectations view should be more or less correct because people will not cling to incorrect expectations indefinitely. As Abraham Lincoln pointed out with characteristic wisdom, you cannot fool all the people all the time.

WHY ECONOMISTS (AND POLITICIANS) DISAGREE This chapter has now taught us some of the reasons why economists disagree about the proper conduct of stabilization policy. It also helps us understand some of the related political debates. Should the government take strong actions to prevent or reduce inflation? You will say yes if you believe that (1) inflation is more costly than unemployment, (2) the short-run Phillips curve is steep, (3) expectations react quickly, and (4) the economy’s self-correcting mechanism works smoothly and rapidly. These views on the economy tend to be held by believers in rational expectations. You will say no if you believe that (1) unemployment is more costly than inflation, (2) the short-run Phillips curve is flat, (3) expectations react sluggishly, and (4) the selfcorrecting mechanism is slow and unreliable. These views are held by many Keynesian economists, so it is not surprising that they often oppose using recession to fight inflation. The tables turn, however, when the question becomes whether to use demand management to bring a recession to a rapid end. The Keynesian view of the world—that unemployment is costly, that the short-run Phillips curve is flat, that expectations adjust slowly, and that the self-correcting mechanism is unreliable—leads to the conclusion that the

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 33

715

The Trade-Off between Inflation and Unemployment

benefits of fighting unemployment are high and the costs are low. Keynesians are therefore eager to fight recessions. The rational expectations positions on these four issues are precisely the reverse, and so are the policy conclusions.

THE DILEMMA OF DEMAND MANAGEMENT We have seen that policy makers face an unavoidable trade-off. If they stimulate aggregate demand to reduce unemployment, they will aggravate inflation. If they restrict aggregate demand to fight inflation, they will cause higher unemployment. But wait. Early in the chapter we learned that when inflation comes from the supply side, inflation and unemployment are positively correlated: They go up or down together. Does this mean that monetary and fiscal policy makers can escape the trade-off between inflation and unemployment? Unfortunately not. Shifts of the aggregate supply curve can cause inflation and unemployment to rise or fall together, and thus can destroy the statistical Phillips curve relationship. Nevertheless, anything that monetary and fiscal policy can do will make unemployment and inflation move in opposite directions because monetary and fiscal policies influence only the aggregate demand curve, not the aggregate supply curve. Thus, no matter what the source of inflation, and no matter what happens to the Phillips curve, the monetary and fiscal policy authorities still face a disagreeable tradeoff between inflation and unemployment. Many policy makers have failed to understand this principle, which is one of the Ideas we hope you will remember well Beyond the Final Exam.

IDEAS FOR BEYOND THE FINAL EXAM

Naturally, the unpleasant nature of this trade-off has led both economists and public officials to search for a way out of the dilemma. We conclude this chapter by considering some of these ideas—none of which is a panacea.

ATTEMPTS TO REDUCE THE NATURAL RATE OF UNEMPLOYMENT One highly desirable approach—if only we knew how to do it—would be to reduce the natural rate of unemployment. Then we could enjoy lower unemployment without higher inflation. The question is: How? The most promising approaches have to do with education, training, and job placement. The data clearly show that more educated workers are unemployed less frequently than less educated ones are. Vocational training and retraining programs, if successful, help unemployed workers with obsolete skills acquire abilities that are currently in demand. By so doing, they both raise employment and help alleviate upward pressures on wages in jobs where qualified workers are in short supply. Government and private job placement and counseling services play a similar role. Such programs try to match workers to jobs better by funneling information from prospective employers to prospective employees. These ideas sound sensible and promising, but two big problems arise in implementation. First, training and placement programs sometimes look better on paper than in practice. In some cases, people are trained for jobs that do not exist by the time they finish their training—if, indeed, the jobs ever existed. Second, the high cost of these programs restricts the number of workers who can be accommodated, even in successful programs. For this reason, publicly supported job training is done on a very small scale in the United States—much less than in most European countries. Small expenditures can hardly be expected to make a large dent in the natural rate of unemployment. Many observers believe the natural rate of unemployment has fallen in the United States despite these problems. Why? One reason is that work experience has much in common with formal training—workers become more productive by learning on the job. As

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

716

Part 7

Fiscal and Monetary Policy

the American workforce has aged, the average level of work experience has increased, which, according to many economists, has lowered the natural rate of unemployment. (For some other possible reasons, see “Why Did the Natural Rate of Unemployment Fall?”)

INDEXING Indexing refers to provisions in a law or a contract whereby monetary payments are automatically adjusted whenever a specified price index changes. Wage rates, pensions, interest payments on bonds, income taxes, and many other things can be indexed in this way, and have been. Sometimes such contractual provisions are called escalator clauses.

Indexing—which refers to provisions in a law or contract that automatically adjust monetary payments whenever a specific price index changes—presents a very different approach to the inflation-unemployment dilemma. Instead of trying to improve the terms of the trade-off, indexing seeks to reduce the social costs of inflation. The most familiar example of indexing is an escalator clause in a wage agreement. Escalator clauses provide for automatic increases in money wages—without the need for new contract negotiations—whenever the price level rises by more than a specified amount. Such agreements thus act to protect workers partly from inflation. Nowadays, with inflation low and stable, relatively few workers are covered by escalator clauses. They were far more common when inflation was higher. Interest payments on bonds or bank accounts can also be indexed, and the U.S. government began doing so with a small fraction of its bonds in 1997. The most extensive indexing to be found in the United States today, however, appears in government transfer payments. Social Security benefits, for instance, are indexed so that retirees are not victimized by inflation. Some economists believe that the United States should follow the example of several foreign countries and adopt a more widespread indexing system. Why? Because, they argue, it would take most of the sting out of inflation. To see how, let us review some of the social costs of inflation that we enumerated in Chapter 23. One important cost is the capricious redistribution of income caused by unexpected inflation. We saw that borrowers and lenders normally incorporate an inflation premium equal to the expected rate of inflation into the nominal interest rate. Then, if inflation turns out to be higher than expected, the borrower has to pay the lender only the agreed-on nominal interest rate, including the premium for expected inflation; he does not have to compensate the lender for the (higher) actual inflation. Thus, the borrower enjoys a windfall gain and the lender loses out. The opposite happens if inflation turns out to be lower than expected.

Why Did the Natural Rate of Unemployment Fall? In 1995, most economists believed that the natural rate of unemployment in the United States was approximately 6 percent—and certainly not lower than 5.5 percent. If unemployment fell below that critical rate, they said, inflation would start to rise. Experience in the late 1990s belied that view. The unemployment rate dipped below 5.5 percent in the summer of 1996—and kept on falling. By the end of 1998, it was below 4.5 percent. For a few months in 2001, it even dipped below 4 percent. And still there were no signs of rising inflation. One reason for such amazing macroeconomic performance was discussed in this chapter: A series of favorable supply shocks pushed the aggregate supply curve outward at an unusually rapid pace. But it also appears that the natural rate of unemployment fell in the 1990s. Why?

Economists do not have a complete answer to this question, but a few pieces of the puzzle are understood. For one thing, the U.S. working population aged—and mature workers are normally unemployed less often than are young workers. The rise of temporaryhelp agencies and Internet job searching capabilities helped match workers to jobs better. Ironically, record-high levels of incarceration probably reduced unemployment, too, because many of those in jail would otherwise have been unemployed. It is also believed (though difficult to prove) that the weak labor markets of the early 1990s left labor more docile, thereby driving down the unemployment rate consistent with constant inflation. Whatever the reasons, it does appear that the United States can now sustain a lower unemployment than it could, say, 15 years ago.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 33

The Trade-Off between Inflation and Unemployment

717

If interest rates on loans were indexed, none of this would occur. Borrowers and lenders would agree on a fixed real rate of interest, and the borrower would compensate the lender for whatever actual inflation occurred. No one would have to guess what the inflation rate would be.6 A second social cost mentioned in Chapter 23 stems from the fact that our tax system levies taxes on nominal interest and nominal capital gains. As we learned, this flaw in the tax system leads to extremely high effective tax rates in an inflationary environment. But indexing can cure this problem. We need only rewrite the tax code so that only real interest payments and real capital gains are taxed. In the face of all these benefits, why does our economy not employ more indexing? One obvious reason is that inflation has been low for years. Indexing received much more attention years ago, when inflation was much higher. A second reason is that some economists fear that indexing will erode society’s resistance to inflation. With the costs of inflation so markedly reduced, they ask, what will stop governments from inflating more and more? They fear that the answer is: nothing. Voters who stand to lose nothing from inflation are unlikely to pressure their legislators into stopping it. Opponents of indexing worry that a mild inflationary disease could turn into a ravaging epidemic in a highly indexed economy.

| SUMMARY | 1. Inflation can be caused either by rapid growth of aggregate demand or by sluggish growth of aggregate supply.

shape of the short-run Phillips curve, and the speed at which inflationary expectations are adjusted.

2. When fluctuations in economic activity emanate from the demand side, prices will rise rapidly when real output grows rapidly. Because rapid growth means more jobs, unemployment and inflation will be inversely related.

8. If workers expect inflation to occur, and if they demand (and receive) compensation for inflation, output will be independent of the price level. Both the aggregate supply curve and the short-run Phillips curve are vertical in this case.

3. This inverse relationship between unemployment and inflation is called the Phillips curve. In the United States, data for the 1950s and 1960s display a clear Phillips-curve relation, but data for the 1970s and 1980s do not.

9. Errors in predicting inflation will change real wages and therefore the quantity of output that firms wish to supply. Thus, unpredicted movements in the price level will lead to a normal, upward-sloping aggregate supply curve.

4. The Phillips curve is not a menu of long-run policy choices for the economy, because the self-correcting mechanism guarantees that neither an inflationary gap nor a recessionary gap can last indefinitely.

10. According to the rational expectations hypothesis, errors in predicting inflation are purely random. As a consequence, except for some random gyrations, the aggregate supply curve is vertical even in the short run.

5. Because of the self-correcting mechanism, the economy’s true long-run choices lie along a vertical long-run Phillips curve, which shows that the so-called natural rate of unemployment is the only unemployment rate that can persist indefinitely.

11. Many economists reject the rational expectations view. Some deny that expectations are “rational” and believe instead that people tend, for example, to underpredict inflation when it is rising. Others point out that contracts signed years ago may not embody expectations that are “rational” in terms of what we know today.

6. In the short run, the economy can move up or down along its short-run Phillips curve. Temporary reductions in unemployment can be achieved at the cost of higher inflation, and temporary increases in unemployment can be used to fight inflation. This short-run trade-off between inflation and unemployment is one of our Ideas for Beyond the Final Exam. 7. Whether it is advisable to use unemployment to fight inflation depends on four principal factors: the relative social costs of inflation versus unemployment, the efficiency of the economy’s self-correcting mechanism, the

12. When fluctuations in economic activity are caused by shifts of the aggregate supply curve, output will grow slowly (causing unemployment to rise) when inflation rises. Hence, the rates of unemployment and inflation will be positively correlated. Many observers feel that this sort of stagflation is why the Phillips curve collapsed in the 1970s. Similarly, a series of favorable supply shocks help explain the 1990s’ combination of low inflation and strong economic growth.

For example, an indexed loan with a 2 percent real interest rate would require a 5 percent nominal interest payment if inflation were 3 percent, a 7 percent nominal interest payment if inflation were 5 percent, and so on. 6

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

718

Part 7

Fiscal and Monetary Policy

14. Policies that improve the functioning of the labor market—including retraining programs and employment services—can, in principle, lower the natural rate of unemployment. To date, however, the U.S. government has enjoyed only modest success with these measures.

13. Even if inflation is initiated by supply-side problems, so that inflation and unemployment rise together, the monetary and fiscal authorities still face this trade-off: Anything they do to improve unemployment is likely to worsen inflation, and anything they do to reduce inflation is likely to aggravate unemployment. (This is part of one of our Ideas for Beyond the Final Exam.) The reason is that monetary and fiscal policy mainly influence the aggregate demand curve, not the aggregate supply curve.

15. Indexing is another way to approach the trade-off problem. Instead of trying to improve the trade-off, it concentrates on reducing the social costs of inflation. Opponents of indexing worry, however, that the economy’s resistance to inflation may be lowered by indexing.

| KEY TERMS | demand-side inflation indexing

716

natural rate of unemployment 707

702

Phillips curve

703

rational expectations

supply-side inflation 712

self-correcting mechanism

706

702

vertical (long-run) Phillips curve 707

| TEST YOURSELF | 1. Show that if the economy’s aggregate supply curve is vertical, fluctuations in the growth of aggregate demand produce only fluctuations in inflation with no effect on output. 2. Long-term government bonds now pay approximately 4 percent nominal interest. Would you prefer to trade

yours in for an indexed bond that paid a 3 percent real rate of interest? What if the real interest rate offered were 2 percent? What if it were 1 percent? What do your answers to these questions reveal about your personal attitudes toward inflation?

| DISCUSSION QUESTIONS | 1. When inflation and unemployment fell together in the 1990s, some observers claimed that policy makers no longer faced a trade-off between inflation and unemployment. Were they correct? 2. “There is no sense in trying to shorten recessions through fiscal and monetary policy because the effects of these policies on the unemployment rate are sure to be temporary.” Comment on both the truth of this statement and its relevance for policy formulation. 3. Why is it said that decisions on fiscal and monetary policy are, at least in part, political decisions that cannot be made on “objective” economic criteria? 4. What is a Phillips curve? Why did it seem to work so much better in the period from 1954 to 1969 than it did in the 1970s?

5. Explain why expectations of inflation affect the wages that result from labor-management bargaining. 6. What is meant by “rational” expectations? Why does the hypothesis of rational expectations have such stunning implications for economic policy? Would believers in rational expectations want to shorten a recession by expanding aggregate demand? Would they want to fight inflation by reducing aggregate demand? Relate this analysis to your answer to Test Yourself Question 1. 7. It is often said that the Federal Reserve Board typically cares more about inflation and less about unemployment than the administration. If this is true, why might presidents often worry about what the Fed might do to interest rates?

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 33

The Trade-Off between Inflation and Unemployment

8. The year 2007 closed with the unemployment rate around 5 percent, real GDP barely growing, inflation above 2 percent and apparently rising a bit, and the federal budget showing a large deficit.

719

b. Give one or more arguments for engaging in contractionary monetary or fiscal policies under these circumstances. c. Which arguments do you find more persuasive?

a. Give one or more arguments for engaging in expansionary monetary or fiscal policies under these circumstances.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Part

The United States in the World Economy

G



lobalization” became a buzzword in the 1990s—and it remains one today. Some people extol its virtues and view it as something to be encouraged. Others deplore its (real or imagined) costs and seek to stop globalization in its tracks. For example, globalization is often viewed as a threat to the livelihoods of American workers. We will examine several aspects of the globalization debate in Part 8. Love it or hate it, one thing is clear: The United States is thoroughly integrated into a broader world economy. What happens in the United States influences other countries, and events abroad reverberate back here. Trillions of dollars’ worth of goods and services—American software, Chinese toys, Japanese cars—are traded across international borders each year. A vastly larger dollar volume of financial transactions—trade in stocks, bonds, and bank deposits, for example—takes place in the global economy at lightning speed. We have mentioned these subjects before, but Part 8 brings international factors from the wings to center stage. Chapter 34 studies the factors that underlie international trade, and Chapter 35 takes up the determination of exchange rates—the prices at which the world’s currencies are bought and sold. Then Chapter 36 integrates these international influences into our model of the macroeconomy. If you want to understand why so many Americans are worried about international trade, why many thoughtful observers think we need to overhaul the international monetary system, or why there was so much economic turmoil in Southeast Asia, Russia, and Latin America during the last 15 years or so, read these three chapters with care.

C H A P T E R S 34 | International Trade and

Comparative Advantage

36 | Exchange Rates and the Macroeconomy

35 | The International Monetary System: Order or Disorder?

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

International Trade and Comparative Advantage No nation was ever ruined by trade. BENJAM I N FR A N K LI N

E

conomists emphasize international trade as the source of many of the benefits of globalization—a loosely defined term that indicates a closer knitting together of the world’s national economies. Of course, countries have always been linked in various ways. The Vikings, after all, landed in North America—not to mention Christopher Columbus. In recent decades, however, dramatic improvements in transportation, telecommunications, and international relations have drawn the nations of the world ever closer together economically. This process of globalization is often portrayed as something new. In fact, it is not, as the box “Is Globalization Something New?” on the next page points out. Still, it is changing the way the people of the world live. Economic events in other countries affect the United States for both macroeconomic and microeconomic reasons. For example, we learned in Parts 6 and 7 that the level of net exports is an important determinant of a nation’s output and employment. But we did not delve very deeply into the factors that determine a nation’s exports and imports. Chapters 35 and 36 will take up these macroeconomic linkages in greater detail. First, however, this chapter studies some of the microeconomic linkages among nations: How are patterns and prices of world trade determined? How and why do governments often interfere with foreign trade? The central idea of this chapter is one we have encountered before (in Chapters 1 and 3): the principle of comparative advantage.

C O N T E N T S ISSUE: HOW CAN AMERICANS COMPETE WITH

The Graphics of Comparative Advantage Must Specialization Be Complete?

The Infant-Industry Argument Strategic Trade Policy

WHY TRADE?

ISSUE RESOLVED: COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE

CAN CHEAP IMPORTS HURT A COUNTRY?

“CHEAP FOREIGN LABOR”?

Mutual Gains from Trade

EXPOSES THE “CHEAP FOREIGN LABOR” FALLACY

ISSUE: LAST LOOK AT THE “CHEAP FOREIGN

INTERNATIONAL VERSUS INTRANATIONAL TRADE

TARIFFS, QUOTAS, AND OTHER INTERFERENCES WITH TRADE

Political Factors in International Trade The Many Currencies Involved in International Trade Impediments to Mobility of Labor and Capital

Tariffs versus Quotas

| APPENDIX | Supply, Demand, and Pricing in World Trade

WHY INHIBIT TRADE?

How Tariffs and Quotas Work

THE LAW OF COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE The Arithmetic of Comparative Advantage

LABOR” ARGUMENT

Gaining a Price Advantage for Domestic Firms Protecting Particular Industries National Defense and Other Noneconomic Considerations

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

724

Part 8

The United States in the World Economy

Is Globalization Something New? between a Canadian province and an American state is 20 times smaller than domestic trade between two Canadian provinces, after adjusting for distance and income levels. The financial markets are not yet truly integrated either. Despite the newfound popularity of international investing, capital markets were by some measures more integrated at the start of this century than they are now. . . . [And] labour is less mobile than it was in the second half of the 19th century, when some 60m people left Europe for the New World.

Despite much loose talk about the “new” global economy, today’s international economic integration is not unprecedented. The 50 years before the first world war saw large cross-border flows of goods, capital and people. That period of globalisation, like the present one, was driven by reductions in trade barriers and by sharp falls in transport costs, thanks to the development of railways and steamships. The present surge of globalisation is in a way a resumption of that previous trend. . . . Two forces have been driving [globalization]. The first is technology. With the costs of communication and computing falling rapidly, the natural barriers of time and space that separate national markets have been falling too. The cost of a threeminute telephone call between New York and London has fallen from $300 (in 1996 dollars) in 1930 to $1 today . . . The second driving force has been liberalisation. . . . Almost all countries have lowered barriers to trade. . . . [T]he ratio of trade to output . . . has increased sharply in most countries since 1950. But by this measure Britain and France are only slightly more open to trade today than they were in 1913. . . . Product markets are still nowhere near as integrated across borders as they are within nations. Consider the example of SOURCE: “Schools Brief: One World?” from The Economist, October 18, 1997. Copytrade between the United States and Canada, one of the least right © 1997 The Economist Newspaper Ltd. All rights reserved. Reprinted with permission. Further reproduction prohibited. http://www.economist.com. restricted trading borders in the world. On average, trade

ISSUE:

HOW CAN AMERICANS COMPETE WITH “CHEAP FOREIGN LABOR”?

Americans (and the citizens of many other nations) often want their government to limit or prevent import competition. Why? One major reason is the common belief that imports take bread out of American workers’ mouths. According to this view, “cheap foreign labor” steals jobs from Americans and pressures U.S. businesses to lower wages. For many years, attention focused on the phenomenon of manufacturing jobs moving abroad. Lately, there has been a great deal of concern over the “offshoring” of a wide variety of service jobs—ranging from call center operators to lawyers. Such worries were prominently voiced in the 2008 presidential campaign. For example, during the Democratic primaries, Senators Hillary Clinton and Barack Obama competed over who could be more disparaging toward the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA), arguing that competition from cheap Mexican labor had destroyed many good American jobs. Oddly enough, the facts appear to be grossly inconsistent with the theory that trade kills jobs. For one thing, wages in most countries that export to the United States have risen dramatically in recent decades—much faster than wages here. Table 1 shows hourly compensation rates in eight countries on three continents, each expressed as a percentage of hourly compensation in the United States, in 1975 and 2005. Only workers in Mexico lost ground to American workers over this 30-year period. Labor in Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

SOURCE: © AP Images

Few people realize that the industrialized world was, in fact, highly globalized prior to World War I, before the ravages of two world wars and the Great Depression severed many international linkages. Furthermore, as the British magazine The Economist pointed out more than a decade ago, globalization has not gone nearly as far as many people imagine.

725

International Trade and Comparative Advantage

Europe gained substantially on their U.S. counterparts—rising in Britain, for example, from just above half the U.S. standard to above-U.S. levels. And the wage gains in Asia were nothing short of spectacular. Labor compensation in South Korea, for example, soared from just 5 percent of U.S. levels to more than half.1 Yet, while all this was going on, American imports of automobiles from Japan, electronics from Taiwan, and textiles from Korea expanded rapidly. Ironically, then, the United States’ dominant position in the international marketplace deteriorated just as wage levels in Europe and Asia were rising closer to our own. Clearly, something other than exploiting cheap foreign labor must be driving international trade—in contrast to what the “commonsense” view of the matter suggests. In this chapter, we will see precisely what is wrong with this commonsense view.

TABLE 1 Labor Costs in Industrialized Countries as a Percentage of U.S. Labor Costs SOURCE: U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics.

Chapter 34

France United Kingdom Spain Japan South Korea Taiwan Mexico Canada

1975

2005

73% 54 41 48 5 6 24 99

104% 109 75 92 57 27 11 101

NOTE: Data are compensation estimates per hour, converted at exchange rates, and relate to production workers in the manufacturing sector.

WHY TRADE? The earth’s resources are distributed unequally across the planet. Although the United States produces its own coal and wheat, it depends almost entirely on the rest of the world for such basic items as rubber and coffee. Similarly, the Persian Gulf states have little land that is suitable for farming but sit atop huge pools of oil—something we are constantly reminded of by geopolitical events. Because of the seemingly whimsical distribution of the earth’s resources, every nation must trade with others to acquire what it lacks. Even if countries had all the resources they needed, other differences in natural endowments such as climate, terrain, and so on would lead them to engage in trade. Americans could grow their own bananas and coffee in hothouses, albeit with great difficulty. These crops are grown much more efficiently in Honduras and Brazil, though, where the climates are appropriate. The skills of a nation’s labor force also play a role. If New Zealand has a large group of efficient farmers and few workers with industrial experience, whereas the opposite is true in Japan, it makes sense for New Zealand to specialize in agriculture and let Japan concentrate on manufacturing. Finally, a small country that tried to produce every product its citizens want to consume would end up with many industries that are simply too small to utilize modern mass-production techniques or to take advantage of other economies of large-scale operations. For example, some countries operate their own international airlines for reasons that can only be described as political, not economic. To summarize, the main reason why nations trade with one another is to exploit the many advantages of specialization, some of which were discussed in Chapter 3. International trade greatly enhances living standards for all parties involved because: 1. Every country lacks some vital resources that it can get only by trading with others. 2. Each country’s climate, labor force, and other endowments make it a relatively efficient producer of some goods and a relatively inefficient producer of others.

Specialization means that a country devotes its energies and resources to only a small proportion of the world’s productive activities.

3. Specialization permits larger outputs via the advantages of large-scale production.

Mutual Gains from Trade Many people have long believed that one nation gains from trade only at the expense of another. After all, nothing new is produced by the mere act of trading. So if one country gains from a swap, it has been argued for centuries, the other country must necessarily lose. One consequence of this mistaken belief was and continues to be attitudes that call for each country to try to take advantage of its trading partners on the (fallacious) grounds that one nation’s gain must be another’s loss.

1

China would be an even more extreme example, but we lack Chinese data dating back to 1975.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

726

Part 8

The United States in the World Economy

Yet, as Adam Smith emphasized, and as we learned in Chapter 3, both parties must expect to gain something from any voluntary exchange. Otherwise, why would they agree to trade? How can mere exchange of goods leave both parties better off? The answer is that although trade does not increase the total output of goods, it does allow each party to acquire items better suited to its tastes. Suppose Levi has four cookies and nothing to drink, whereas Malcolm has two glasses of milk and nothing to eat. A trade of two of Levi’s cookies for one of Malcolm’s glasses of milk will not increase the total supply of either milk or cookies, but it almost certainly will make both boys better off. By exactly the same logic, both the United States and Mexico must reap gains when Mexicans voluntarily ship their tomatoes to the United States in return for American chemicals. In general, as we emphasized in Chapter 3:

IDEAS FOR BEYOND THE FINAL EXAM

TRADE IS A WIN-WIN SITUATION Both parties must expect to gain from any voluntary exchange. Trade brings about mutual gains by redistributing products so that both parties end up holding more preferred combinations of goods than they held before. This principle, which is one of our Ideas for Beyond the Final Exam, applies to nations just as it does to individuals.

INTERNATIONAL VERSUS INTRANATIONAL TRADE The 50 states of the United States may be the most eloquent testimonial to the large gains that can be realized from specialization and free trade. Florida specializes in growing oranges, Michigan builds cars, California makes software and computers, and New York specializes in finance. All of these states trade freely with one another and, as a result, enjoy great prosperity. Try to imagine how much lower your standard of living would be if you consumed only items produced in your own state. The essential logic behind international trade is no different from that underlying trade among different states; the basic reasons for trade are equally applicable within a country or among countries. Why, then, do we study international trade as a special subject? There are at least three reasons.

Political Factors in International Trade First, domestic trade takes place under a single national government, whereas foreign trade always involves at least two governments. But a nation’s government is normally much less concerned about the welfare of other countries’ citizens than it is about its own. So, for example, the U.S. Constitution prohibits tariffs on trade among states, but it does not prohibit the United States from imposing tariffs on imports from abroad. One major issue in the economic analysis of international trade is the use and misuse of political impediments to international trade.

The Many Currencies Involved in International Trade Second, all trade within the borders of the United States is carried out in U.S. dollars, whereas trade across national borders almost always involves at least two currencies. Rates of exchange between different currencies can and do change. In 1985, it took about 250 Japanese yen to buy a dollar; now it takes fewer than half that many. Variability in exchange rates brings with it a host of complications and policy problems.

Impediments to Mobility of Labor and Capital Third, it is much easier for labor and capital to move about within a country than to move from one nation to another. If jobs are plentiful in California but scarce in Ohio, workers can move freely to follow the job opportunities. Of course, personal costs such as the financial

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 34

727

International Trade and Comparative Advantage

burden of moving and the psychological burden of leaving friends and familiar surroundings may discourage mobility. But such relocations are not inhibited by immigration quotas, by laws restricting the employment of foreigners, or by the need to learn a new language. There are also greater impediments to the transfer of capital across national boundaries than to its movement within a country. For example, many countries have rules limiting foreign ownership. Even the United States limits foreign ownership of broadcast outlets and airlines and, recently, political furors arose when a Chinese company sought to purchase a U.S. oil company and when a Middle Eastern company offered to take over the management of several U.S. ports. Foreign investment is also subject to special political risks, such as the danger of outright expropriation or nationalization after a change in government. Even if nothing as extreme as expropriation occurs, capital invested abroad faces significant risks from exchange rate variations. An investment valued at 250 million yen is worth $2.5 million to American investors when the dollar is worth 100 yen, but it is worth only $1 million when it takes 250 yen to buy a dollar.

THE LAW OF COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE The gains from international specialization and trade are clear and intuitive when one country is better at producing one item and its trading partner is better at producing another. For example, no one finds it surprising that Brazil sells coffee to the United States and the United States exports software to Brazil. We know that coffee can be produced using less labor and other inputs in Brazil than in the United States. Likewise, the United States can produce software at a lower resource cost than can Brazil. In such a situation, we say that Brazil has an absolute advantage in coffee production, and the United States has an absolute advantage in software production. In such cases, it is obvious that both countries can gain by producing the item in which they have an absolute advantage and then trading with one another. What is much less obvious, but equally true, is that these gains from international trade still exist even if one country is more efficient than the other in producing everything. This lesson, the principle of comparative advantage, is one we first encountered in Chapter 3.2 It is, in fact, one of the most important of our Ideas for Beyond the Final Exam, so we repeat it here for convenience. THE SURPRISING PRINCIPLE OF COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE Even if one country is at an absolute disadvantage relative to another country in the production of every good, it still has a comparative advantage in making the good at which it is least inefficient (compared with the other country). The great classical economist David Ricardo (1772–1823) discovered about 200 years ago that two countries can still gain from trade even if one is more efficient than the other in every industry—that is, even if one has an absolute advantage in producing every commodity. In determining the most efficient patterns of production, it is comparative advantage, not absolute advantage, that matters. Thus a country can gain by importing a good even if that good can be produced more efficiently at home. Such imports make sense if they enable the country to specialize in producing goods at which it is even more efficient.

One country is said to have an absolute advantage over another in the production of a particular good if it can produce that good using smaller quantities of resources than can the other country. One country is said to have a comparative advantage over another in the production of a particular good relative to other goods if it produces that good less inefficiently as compared with the other country.

IDEAS FOR BEYOND THE FINAL EXAM

The Arithmetic of Comparative Advantage Let’s see precisely how comparative advantage works using a hypothetical example first suggested in Chapter 3. Table 2 gives a rather exaggerated impression of the trading positions of the United States and Japan a few years ago. We imagine that labor is the only 2

To review, see page 49.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

728

Part 8

The United States in the World Economy

input used to produce computers and television sets in the two countries and that the United States has an absolute advantage in manufacturing both goods. In this example, one year’s worth of labor can produce either 50 computers or 50 TV sets in the United States but only 10 computers or 40 televisions in Japan. In the U.S. In Japan So the United States is the more efficient producer of both goods. Nonetheless, Computers 50 10 as we will now show, it pays for the United States to specialize in producing Televisions 50 40 computers and trade with Japan to get the TV sets it wants. To demonstrate this point, we begin by noting that the United States has a comparative advantage in computers, whereas Japan has a comparative advantage in producing televisions. Specifically, the numbers in Table 2 show that the United States can produce 50 televisions with one year’s labor, whereas Japan can produce only 40, giving the United States a 25 percent efficient edge over Japan. However, the United States is five times as efficient as Japan in producing computers: it can produce 50 per year of labor rather than 10. Because America’s competitive edge is far greater in computers than in televisions, we say that the United States has a comparative advantage in computers. From the Japanese perspective, these same numbers indicate that Japan is only slightly less efficient than the United States in TV production but drastically less efficient in computer production. So Japan’s comparative advantage is in producing televisions. According to Ricardo’s law of comparative advantage, then, the two countries can gain if the United States specializes in producing computers, Japan specializes in producing TVs, and the two countries trade. Let’s verify that this conclusion is true. Suppose Japan transfers TAB LE 3 1,000 years of labor out of the computer industry and into TV Example of the Gains from Trade manufacturing. According to the figures in Table 2, its computer U.S. Japan Total output will fall by 10,000 units, whereas its TV output will rise by 40,000 units. This information is recorded in the middle column of Computers 125,000 210,000 115,000 Televisions 225,000 140,000 115,000 Table 3. Suppose, at the same time, the United States transfers 500 years of labor out of television manufacturing (thereby losing 25,000 TVs) and into computer making (thereby gaining 25,000 computers). Table 3 shows us that these transfers of resources between the two countries increase the world’s production of both outputs. Together, the two countries now have 15,000 additional TVs and 15,000 additional computers—a nice outcome. Was there some sleight of hand here? How did both the United States and Japan gain both computers and TVs? The explanation is that the process we have just described involves more than just a swap of a fixed bundle of commodities, as in our earlier cookiesand-milk example. It also involves a change in the production arrangements. Some of Japan’s inefficient computer production is taken over by more efficient American makers. And some of America’s TV production is taken over by Japanese television companies, which are less inefficient at making TVs than Japanese computer manufacturers are at making computers. In this way, world productivity is increased. The underlying principle is both simple and fundamental: TAB LE 2

Alternative Outputs from One Year of Labor Input

When every country does what it can do best, all countries can benefit because more of every commodity can be produced without increasing the amounts of labor and other resources used.

Where does the United States hold and lack comparative advantage? Among our big export powerhouses are the aerospace industry, agriculture, chemicals, high-tech services, financial services, entertainment, and higher education. We are, of course, huge importers of petroleum, television sets, automobiles, computers, clothing, toys, and much else.

The Graphics of Comparative Advantage The gains from trade also can be illustrated graphically, and doing so helps us understand whether such gains are large or small. The lines US and JN in Figure 1 are closely related to the production possibilities frontiers of the two countries, differing only in that they pretend that each country has the

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 34

International Trade and Comparative Advantage

729

Television Sets (millions)

same amount of labor available.3 In this case, we assume that each has 1 million person-years of labor. For 60 example, Table 2 tells us that for each 1 million years of U labor, the United States can produce 50 million TVs 50 and no computers (point U in Figure 1), 50 million computers and no TVs (point S), or any combination J 40 between (the line US). Similar reasoning leads to line JN for Japan. U.S. production 30 America’s actual production possibilities frontier possibilities frontier would be even higher, relative to Japan’s, than shown in Japanese Figure 1 because the U.S. population is larger. But Fig20 production ure 1 is more useful because it highlights the differences possibilities frontier in efficiency (rather than in mere size), and this is what 10 determines both absolute and comparative advantage. Let’s see how. N S O The fact that line US lies above line JN means that the 60 0 10 20 30 40 50 United States can manufacture more televisions and Computers more computers than Japan with the same amount of (millions) labor. This difference reflects our assumption that the FI GURE 1 United States has an absolute advantage in both Production Possibilities commodities. Frontiers for Two America’s comparative advantage in computer production and Japan’s comparative adCountries (person-years vantage in TV production are shown in a different way: by the relative slopes of the two of labor) lines. Look back to Table 2, which shows that the United States can acquire a computer on its own by giving up one TV. Thus, the opportunity cost of a computer in the United States is one television set. This opportunity cost is depicted graphically by the slope of the U.S. production possibilities frontier in Figure 1, which is OU/OS 5 50/50 5 1. Table 2 also tells us that the opportunity cost of a computer in Japan is four TVs. This relationship is depicted in Figure 1 by the slope of Japan’s production possibilities frontier, which is OJ/ON 5 40/10 5 4. A country’s absolute advantage in production over another country is shown by its having a higher per capita production possibilities frontier. The difference in the comparative advantages between the two countries is shown by the difference in the slopes of their frontiers.

Because opportunity costs differ in the two countries, gains are possible if the two countries specialize and trade with one another. Specifically, it is cheaper, in terms of real resources forgone, for either country to acquire its computers in the United States. By a similar line of reasoning, the opportunity cost of TVs is higher in the United States than in Japan, so it makes sense for both countries to acquire their televisions in Japan.4 Notice that if the slopes of the two production possibilities frontiers, JN and US, were equal, then opportunity costs would be the same in each country. In that case, no potential gains would arise from trade. Gains from trade arise from differences across countries, not from similarities. This is an important point about which people are often confused. It is often argued that two very different countries, such as the United States and Mexico, cannot gain much by trading with one another. The fact is just the opposite: Two very similar countries may gain little from trade. Large gains from trade are most likely when countries are very different.

The pattern is apparent in U.S. trade statistics—with one big exception. Canada, a country very similar to the United States, is our biggest trading partner. But that is mainly because the two nations share a huge and very porous border. However, our next three biggest

3 4

To review the concept of the production possibilities frontier, see Chapter 3. EXERCISE: Provide this line of reasoning.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

730

The United States in the World Economy

Part 8

trading partners, in order, are China, Mexico, and Japan—three countries very different from the United States. How nations divide the gains from trade depends on the prices that emerge from world trade—a complicated topic taken up in the appendix to this chapter. But we already know enough to see that world trade must, in our example, leave a computer costing more than one TV and less than four. Why? Because if a computer bought less than one TV (its opportunity cost in the United States) on the world market, the United States would produce its own TVs rather than buying them from Japan. And if a computer cost more than four TVs (its opportunity cost in Japan), Japan would prefer to produce its own computers rather than buy them from the United States. So we conclude that, if both countries are to trade, the rate of exchange between TVs and computers must end up somewhere between 4:1 and 1:1. Generalizing: If two countries voluntarily trade two goods with one another, the rate of exchange between the goods must fall in between the price ratios that would prevail in the two countries in the absence of trade.

To illustrate the gains from trade in our concrete example, suppose the world price ratio settles at 2:1—meaning that one computer costs as much as two televisions. How much, precisely, do the United States and Japan gain from world trade in this case? Figure 2 helps us visualize the answers. The blue production possibilities frontiers, US in Panel (b) and JN in Panel (a), are the same as in Figure 1. But the United States can do better than line US. Specifically, with a world price ratio of 2:1, the United States can buy two TVs for each computer it gives up, rather than just one (which is the opportunity cost of a computer in the United States). Hence, if the United States produces only computers— point S in Figure 2(b)—and buys its TVs from Japan, America’s consumption possibilities will be as indicated by the brick-colored line that begins at point S and has a slope of two—that is, each computer sold brings the United States two television sets. (It ends at point A because 40 million TV sets is the most that Japan can produce.) Because trade allows the United States to choose a point on AS rather than on US, trade opens up consumption possibilities that were simply not available before (shaded gray in the diagram). F I GURE 2

100

100

90

90

80

80

70

70

60 50 J

40

Japanese consumption possibilities

30

Japanese production possibilities

20 10

Television Sets

Television Sets

The Gains from Trade

60 U

50

A

40

U.S. consumption possibilities

30

U.S. production possibilities

20 10

N 0

10

P 20

S 30

40

50

60

0

10

20

30

40

50

60

Computers

Computers

(a) Japan

(b) United States

NOTE: Quantities are in millions.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 34

International Trade and Comparative Advantage

A similar story applies to Japan. If the Japanese produce only television sets—point J in Figure 2(a)—they can acquire a computer from the United States for every two TVs they give up as they move along the brick-colored line JP (whose slope is two). This result is better than they can achieve on their own, because a sacrifice of two TVs in Japan yields only one-half of a computer. Hence, world trade enlarges Japan’s consumption possibilities from JN to JP. Figure 2 shows graphically that gains from trade arise to the extent that world prices (2:1 in our example) differ from domestic opportunity costs (4:1 and 1:1 in our example). How the two countries share the gains from trade depends on the exact prices that emerge from world trade. As explained in the appendix, that in turn depends on relative supplies and demands in the two countries.

Must Specialization Be Complete? In our simple numerical and graphical examples, international specialization is always complete—for example, the United States makes all the computers and Japan makes all the TV sets. But if you look at the real world, you will find mostly incomplete specialization. For example, the United States is the world’s biggest importer of both petroleum and automobiles, but we also manufacture lots of cars and drill for lots of oil. In fact, we even export some cars. This stark discrepancy between theory and fact might worry you. Is something wrong with the theory of comparative advantage? Actually, there are many reasons why specialization is typically incomplete, despite the validity of the principle of comparative advantage. Two of them are simple enough to merit mentioning right here. First, some countries are just too small to provide the world’s entire output, even when they have a strong comparative advantage in the good in question. In our numerical example, Japan just might not have enough labor and other resources to produce the entire world output of televisions. If so, some TV sets would have to be produced in the United States. Second, you may have noticed that in this chapter we have drawn all the production possibilities frontiers (PPFs) as straight lines, whereas they were always curved in previous chapters. The reason is purely pedagogical: We wanted to create simple examples that lend themselves to numerical solutions. It is undoubtedly more realistic to assume that PPFs are curved. That sort of technology leads to incomplete specialization, which is a complication best left to more advanced courses.

ISSUE RESOLVED:

COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE EXPOSES THE “CHEAP FOREIGN LABOR” FALLACY

The principle of comparative advantage takes us a long way toward understanding the fallacy in the “cheap foreign labor” argument described at the beginning of this chapter. Given the assumed productive efficiency of American labor, and the inefficiency of Japanese labor, we would expect wages to be much higher in the United States. In these circumstances, one might expect American workers to be apprehensive about an agreement to permit open trade between the two countries: “How can we hope to meet the unfair competition of those underpaid Japanese workers?” Japanese laborers might also be concerned: “How can we hope to meet the competition of those Americans, who are so efficient in producing everything?” The principle of comparative advantage shows us that both fears are unjustified. As we have just seen, when trade opens up between Japan and the United States, workers in both countries will be able to earn higher real wages than before because of the increased productivity that comes through specialization. As Figure 2 shows, once trade opens up, Japanese workers should be able to acquire more TVs and more computers than they did before. As a consequence, their living

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

731

732

Part 8

The United States in the World Economy

standards should rise, even though they have been left vulnerable to competition from the super-efficient Americans. Workers in the United States should also end up with more TVs and more computers. So their living standards should also rise, even though they have been exposed to competition from cheap Japanese labor. These higher standards of living, of course, reflect the higher real wages earned because workers become more productive in both countries. The lesson to be learned here is elementary: Nothing helps raise living standards more than a greater abundance of goods.

TARIFFS, QUOTAS, AND OTHER INTERFERENCES WITH TRADE

Mercantilism is a doctrine that holds that exports are good for a country, whereas imports are harmful.

A tariff is a tax on imports.

A quota specifies the maximum amount of a good that is permitted into the country from abroad per unit of time.

Despite the large mutual gains from international trade, nations often interfere with the free movement of goods and services across national borders. In fact, until the rise of the free-trade movement about 200 years ago (with Adam Smith and David Ricardo as its vanguard), it was taken for granted that one of the essential tasks of government was to impede trade, presumably in the national interest. Then, as now, many people argued that the proper aim of government policy was to promote exports and discourage imports, for doing so would increase the amount of money foreigners owed the nation. According to this so-called mercantilist view, a nation’s wealth consists of the amount of gold or other monies at its command. Obviously, governments can pursue such a policy only within certain limits. A country must import vital foodstuffs and critical raw materials that it cannot provide for itself. Moreover, mercantilists ignore a simple piece of arithmetic: It is mathematically impossible for every country to sell more than it buys, because one country’s exports must be some other country’s imports. If everyone competes in this game by cutting imports to the bone, then exports must shrivel up, too. The result is that everyone will be deprived of the mutual gains from trade. Indeed, that is precisely what happens in a trade war. After the protectionist 1930s, the United States moved away from mercantilist policies designed to impede imports and gradually assumed a leading role in promoting free trade. Over the past 60 years, tariffs and other trade barriers have come down dramatically. In 1995, the United States led the world to complete the Uruguay Round of tariff reductions and, just before that, the country joined Canada and Mexico in the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA). The latter caused a political firestorm in the United States in 1993 and 1994, with critic (and 1992 presidential candidate) Ross Perot predicting a “giant sucking sound” as American workers lost their jobs to competition from “cheap Mexican labor.” (Does that argument sound familiar?) Most of the world’s trading nations are now formally engaged in a new multiyear round of trade talks, under guidelines adopted in Doha, Qatar, in 2001. (See the box, “Liberalizing World Trade: The Doha Round.”) Modern governments use three main devices when seeking to control trade: tariffs, quotas, and export subsidies. A tariff is simply a tax on imports. An importer of cars, for example, may be charged $2,000 for each auto brought into the country. Such a tax will, of course, make automobiles more expensive and favor domestic models over imports. It will also raise revenue for the government. In fact, tariffs were a major source of tax revenue for the U.S. government during the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries—and also a major source of political controversy. Nowadays, the United States is a low-tariff country, with only a few notable exceptions. However, many other countries rely on heavy tariffs to protect their industries. Indeed, tariff rates of 100 percent or more are not unknown in some countries. A quota is a legal limit on the amount of a good that may be imported. For example, the government might allow no more than 5 million foreign cars to be imported in a year. In some cases, governments ban the importation of certain goods outright—a quota of zero. The United States now imposes quotas on a smattering of goods, including textiles, meat, and sugar. Most imports, however, are not subject to quotas. By reducing supply,

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

International Trade and Comparative Advantage

733

quotas naturally raise the prices of the goods subject to quotas. For example, sugar is vastly more expensive in the United States than it is elsewhere in the world. An export subsidy is a government payment to an exporter. By reducing the exporter’s costs, such subsidies permit exporters to lower their selling prices and compete more effectively in world trade. Overt export subsidies are minor in the United States. But some foreign governments use them extensively to assist their domestic industries—a practice that provokes bitter complaints from American manufacturers about “unfair competition.” For example, years of heavy government subsidies helped the European Airbus consortium take a sizable share of the world commercial aircraft market away from U.S. manufacturers like Boeing and McDonnell-Douglas—a trend that has lately reversed.

An export subsidy is a payment by the government to exporters to permit them to reduce the selling prices of their goods so they can compete more effectively in foreign markets.

Chapter 34

Tariffs versus Quotas Although both tariffs and quotas reduce international trade and increase the prices of domestically produced goods, there are some important differences between these two ways to protect domestic industries. First, under a quota, profits from the higher price in the importing country usually go into the pockets of the foreign and domestic sellers of the products. Limitations on supply (from abroad) mean (a) that customers in the importing country must pay more for the product and (b) that suppliers, whether foreign or domestic, receive more for every unit they sell. For example, the right to sell sugar in the United States under the tight sugar quota has been extremely valuable for decades. Privileged foreign and domestic firms can make a lot of money from quota rights. By contrast, when trade is restricted by a tariff instead, some of the “profits” go as tax revenues to the government of the importing country. (Domestic producers still benefit, because they are exempt from the tariff.) In this respect, a tariff is certainly a better proposition than a quota for the country that enacts it. Another important distinction between the two measures arises from their different implications for productive efficiency. Because a tariff handicaps all foreign suppliers

Liberalizing World Trade: The Doha Round Doha Round almost collapsed in 2003 and again in 2006 when negotiating sessions got nowhere. In early 2010, there was not much optimism that the contentious agricultural issues could be resolved, leaving many observers doubting that the Doha Round would ever be completed. But no one knows what the future may bring.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

SOURCE: © Patrick Baz/AFP/Getty Images

The time and place were not auspicious: an international gathering in the Persian Gulf just two months after the September 11, 2001, terrorists attacks. Nerves were frayed, security was extremely tight, and memories of a failed trade meeting in Seattle in 1999 lingered on. Yet representatives of more than 140 nations, meeting in Doha, Qatar, in November 2001, managed to agree on the outlines of a new round of comprehensive trade negotiations—one that now appears unlikely to be completed. The so-called Doha Round focuses on bringing down tariffs, subsidies, and other restrictions on world trade in agriculture, services, and a variety of manufactured goods. It also seeks greater protection for intellectual property rights, while making sure that poor countries have access to modern pharmaceuticals at prices they can afford. Reform of the World Trade Organization’s own rules and procedures is also on the agenda. Perhaps most surprisingly, the United States has even promised to consider changes in its antidumping laws, which are used to keep many foreign goods out of U.S. markets. (Dumping is explained at the end of this chapter.) Large-scale trade negotiations such as this one, involving more than 100 countries and many different issues, take years to complete. (The last one, the Uruguay Round, took seven years.) And the

734

Part 8

The United States in the World Economy

equally, it awards sales to those firms and nations that can supply the goods most cheaply—presumably because they are more efficient. A quota, by contrast, necessarily awards its import licenses more or less capriciously—perhaps in proportion to past sales or even based on political favoritism. There is no reason to expect the most efficient suppliers will get the import permits. For example, the U.S. sugar quota was for years suspected of being a major source of corruption in the Caribbean. If a country must inhibit imports, two important reasons support a preference for tariffs over quotas: 1. Some of the revenues resulting from tariffs go to the government of the importing country rather than to foreign and domestic producers. 2. Unlike quotas, tariffs offer special benefits to more efficient exporters.

WHY INHIBIT TRADE? To state that tariffs provide a better way to inhibit international trade than quotas leaves open a far more basic question: Why limit trade in the first place? It has been estimated that trade restrictions cost American consumers more than $70 billion per year in the form of higher prices. Why should they be asked to pay these higher prices? A number of answers have been given. Let’s examine each in turn.

Gaining a Price Advantage for Domestic Firms A tariff forces foreign exporters to sell more cheaply by restricting their market access. If the foreign firms do not cut their prices, they will be unable to sell their goods. So, in effect, a tariff amounts to government intervention to rig prices in favor of domestic producers.5 Not bad, you say. However, this technique works only as long as foreigners accept the tariff exploitation passively—which they rarely do. More often, they retaliate by imposing tariffs or quotas of their own on imports from the country that began the tariff game. Such tit-for-tat behavior can easily lead to a trade war in which everyone loses through the resulting reductions in trade. Something like this, in fact, happened to the world economy in the 1930s, and it helped prolong the worldwide depression. Preventing such trade wars is one main reason why nations that belong to the World Trade Organization (WTO) pledge not to raise tariffs. Tariffs or quotas can benefit particular domestic industries in a country that is able to impose them without fear of retaliation. But when every country uses them, every country is likely to lose in the long run.

Protecting Particular Industries The second, and probably more frequent, reason why countries restrict trade is to protect particular favored industries from foreign competition. If foreigners can produce steel or shoes more cheaply, domestic businesses and unions in these industries are quick to demand protection. And their governments may be quite willing to grant it. The “cheap foreign labor” argument is most likely to be invoked in this context. Protective tariffs and quotas are explicitly designed to rescue firms that are too inefficient to compete with foreign exporters in an open world market. But it is precisely this harsh competition that gives consumers the chief benefits of international specialization: better products at lower prices. So protection comes at a cost.

5

For more details on this, see the appendix to this chapter.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

735

International Trade and Comparative Advantage

Thinking back to our numerical example of comparative advantage, we can well imagine the indignant complaints from Japanese computer makers as the opening of trade with the United States leads to increased imports of American-made computers. At the same time, American TV manufacturers would probably express outrage over the flood of imported TVs from Japan. Yet it is Japanese specialization in televisions and U.S. specialization in computers that enables citizens of both countries to enjoy higher standards of living. If governments interfere with this process, consumers in both countries will lose out. Industries threatened by foreign competition often argue that some form of protection against imports is needed to prevent job losses. For example, the U.S. steel industry has made exactly this argument time and time again since the 1960s—most recently in 2001, when world steel prices plummeted and imports surged. And the U.S. government has usually delivered some protection in response. But basic macroeconomics teaches us that there are better ways to stimulate employTABLE 4 ment, such as raising aggregate demand. Estimated Costs of Protectionism to Consumers A program that limits foreign competition will be more effective at preserving employment in the particular protected industry. However, Industry Cost per Job Saved such job gains typically come at a high cost to consumers and to the Apparel $139,000 economy. Table 4 estimates some of the costs to American consumers of Costume jewelry 97,000 using tariffs and quotas to save jobs in selected industries. In every case, Shipping 415,000 the costs far exceed the annual wages of the workers in the protected Sugar 600,000 Textiles 202,000 industries—ranging as high as $600,000 per job for the sugar quota. Women’s footwear 102,000 Nevertheless, complaints over proposals to reduce tariffs or quotas may be justified unless something is done to ease the cost to individual workers of switching to the product lines that trade makes profitable.

SOURCE: Gary C. Hufbauer and Kimberly Ann Elliott, Measuring the Costs of Protectionism in the United States (Washington, D.C.: Institute for International Economics; January 1994), Table 1.3, pp. 12–13.

Chapter 34

The argument for free trade between countries cannot be considered airtight if governments do not assist the citizens in each country who are harmed whenever patterns of production change drastically—as would happen, for example, if governments suddenly reduced tariff and quota barriers.

Owners of television factories in the United States and of computer factories in Japan may see large investments suddenly rendered unprofitable. Workers in those industries may see their special skills and training devalued in the marketplace. Displaced workers also pay heavy intangible costs—they may need to move to new locations and/or new industries, uprooting their families, losing old friends and neighbors, and so on. Although the majority of citizens undoubtedly gain from free trade, that is no consolation to those who are its victims. To mitigate these problems, the U.S. government follows two basic approaches. First, our trade laws offer temporary protection from sudden surges of imports, on the grounds that unexpected changes in trade patterns do not give businesses and workers enough time to adjust. Second, the government has set up trade adjustment assistance programs to help workers and businesses that lose their jobs or their markets to imports. Firms may be eligible for technical assistance, government loans or loan guarantees, and permission to delay tax payments. Workers may qualify for retraining programs, longer periods of unemployment compensation, and funds to defray moving costs. Each form of assistance is designed to ease the burden on the victims of free trade so that the rest of us can enjoy its considerable benefits.

Trade adjustment assistance provides special unemployment benefits, loans, retraining programs, and other aid to workers and firms that are harmed by foreign competition.

National Defense and Other Noneconomic Considerations A third rationale for trade protection is the need to maintain national defense. For example, even if the United States were not the most efficient producer of aircraft, it might still be rational to produce our own military aircraft so that no foreign government could ever cut off supplies of this strategic product.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

736

Part 8

The United States in the World Economy

How Popular Is Protectionism? Protectionists Free traders 56% 47% Percentage

Since World War II, the world has mainly been moving toward freer trade and away from protection. The people of the world are not convinced that this trend is desirable, though. In what was probably the most comprehensive polling ever conducted on the subject, a Canadian firm asked almost 13,000 people in 22 countries the following question in 1998: “Which of the following two broad approaches do you think would be the best way to improve the economic and employment situation in this country—protecting our local industries by restricting imports, or removing import restrictions to increase our international trade?” The protectionist response narrowly outnumbered the free-trade response by a 47 percent to 42 percent margin. (The rest were undecided.) Protectionist sentiment was much stronger in the United States, however, where the margin was 56 percent to 37 percent. (See the accompanying graph.) That was in 1998. In the United States (and elsewhere), there is clear evidence that protectionist sentiment is actually gaining in popularity. For example, a Wall Street Journal/NBC News poll in 1999 found that 39 percent of Americans believed that trade agreements have helped the United States, whereas 30 percent believed they had hurt. When that same question was asked in 2007, only 28 percent thought trade agreements had helped, whereas 46 percent thought they had hurt.

42% 37%

World

United States

SOURCES: “How Popular Is Protectionism?” The Economist, January 2, 1999; and Grant Aldonas, Robert Lawrence, and Matthew Slaughter, Succeeding in the Global Economy, Financial Services Forum Policy Research, June 2007, p. 10.

The national defense argument is fine as far as it goes, but it poses a clear danger: Even industries with the most peripheral relationship to defense are likely to invoke this argument on their behalf. For instance, for years the U.S. watchmaking industry argued for protection on the grounds that its skilled craftsmen would be invaluable in wartime! Similarly, the United States has occasionally banned either exports to or imports from nations such as Cuba, Iran, and Iraq on political grounds. Such actions may have important economic effects, creating either bonanzas or disasters for particular American industries. But they are justified by politics, not by economics. Noneconomic reasons also explain quotas on importation of whaling products and on the furs of other endangered species.

The Infant-Industry Argument The infant-industry argument for trade protection holds that new industries need to be protected from foreign competition until they develop and flourish.

Yet a fourth common rationale for protectionism is the so-called infant-industry argument, which has been prominent in the United States at least since Alexander Hamilton wrote his Report on Manufactures. Promising new industries often need breathing room to flourish and grow. If we expose these infants to the rigors of international competition too soon, the argument goes, they may never develop to the point where they can survive on their own in the international marketplace. This argument, although valid in certain instances, is less defensible than it seems at first. Protecting an infant industry is justifiable only if the prospective future gains are sufficient to repay the up-front costs of protectionism. But if the industry is likely to be so profitable in the future, why doesn’t private capital rush in to take advantage of the prospective net profits? After all, the annals of business are full of cases in which a new product or a new firm lost money at first but profited handsomely later on. In recent times, Apple, Yahoo!, Google, and eBay all lost money in their early days. The infant-industry argument for protection stands up to scrutiny only if private funds are unavailable for some reason, despite an industry’s glowing profit prospects. Even then

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 34

737

International Trade and Comparative Advantage

it may make more sense to provide a government loan rather than to provide trade protection. In an advanced economy such as ours, with well-developed capital markets to fund new businesses, it is difficult to think of legitimate examples where the infant-industry argument applies. Even if such a case were found, we would have to be careful that the industry not remain in diapers forever. In too many cases, industries are awarded protection when young and, somehow, never mature to the point where protection can be withdrawn. We must be wary of infants that never grow up.

Strategic Trade Policy A stronger argument for (temporary) protection has substantially influenced trade policy in the United States and elsewhere. Proponents of this line of thinking agree that free trade for all is the best system. But they point out that we live in an imperfect world in which many nations refuse to play by the rules of the free-trade game. And they fear that a nation that pursues free trade in a protectionist world is likely to lose out. It therefore makes sense, they argue, to threaten to protect your markets unless other nations agree to open theirs. The United States has followed this strategy in trade negotiations with several countries in recent years. In one prominent case, the U.S. government threatened to impose high tariffs on several European luxury goods unless Europe opened its markets to imported bananas from the Americas. A few years later, the European Union turned the tables, threatening to increase tariffs on a variety of U.S. goods unless we changed a tax provision that amounted to an export subsidy. In each case, a dangerous trade war was narrowly averted when an agreement was struck at the eleventh hour. The strategic argument for protection is a difficult one for economists to counter. Although it recognizes the superiority of free trade, it argues that threatening protectionism is the best way to achieve that end. (See the box “Can Protectionism Save Free Trade?” on the next page.) Such a strategy might work, but it clearly involves great risks. If threats that the United States will turn protectionist induce other countries to scrap their existing protectionist policies, then the gamble will have succeeded. But if the gamble fails, protectionism increases.

The strategic argument for protection holds that a nation may sometimes have to threaten protectionism to induce other countries to drop their own protectionist measures.

CAN CHEAP IMPORTS HURT A COUNTRY? One of the most curious—and illogical—features of the protectionist position is the fear of low import prices. Countries that subsidize their exports are often accused of dumping— of getting rid of their goods at unjustifiably low prices. Economists find this argument strange. As a nation of consumers, we should be indignant when foreigners charge us high prices, not low ones. That commonsense rule guides every consumer’s daily life. Only from the topsy-turvy viewpoint of an industry seeking protection are low prices seen as counter to the public interest. Ultimately, the best interests of any country are served when its imports are as cheap as possible. It would be ideal for the United States if the rest of the world were willing to provide us with goods at no charge. We could then live in luxury at the expense of other countries. However, benefits to the United States as a whole do not necessarily accrue to every single American. If quotas on, say, sugar imports were dropped, American consumers and industries that purchase sugar would gain from lower prices. At the same time, however, owners of sugar fields and their employees would suffer serious losses in the form of lower profits, lower wages, and lost jobs—losses they would fight fiercely to prevent. For this reason, politics often leads to the adoption of protectionist measures that would likely be rejected on strictly economic criteria.

Dumping means selling goods in a foreign market at lower prices than those charged in the home market.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

738

Part 8

The United States in the World Economy

AISSUE:

LAST LOOK AT THE “CHEAP FOREIGN LABOR” ARGUMENT

The preceding discussion reveals the fundamental fallacy in the argument that the United States as a whole should fear cheap foreign labor. The average American worker’s living standard must rise, not fall, if other countries willingly supply their products to us more cheaply. As long as the government’s monetary and fiscal policies succeed in maintaining high levels of employment, we cannot possibly lose by getting world products at bargain prices. Indeed, this is precisely what happened to the U.S. economy in the late 1990s. Even though imports poured in at low prices, unemployment in the United States fell to its lowest rate in a generation. Even in 2007, with a financial crisis and a massive trade deficit equal to 5.1 percent of GDP, the U.S. unemployment rate averaged only 4.6 percent. We must add a few important qualifications, however. First, our macroeconomic policy may not always be effective. If workers displaced by foreign competition cannot find new jobs, they will indeed suffer from international trade. But high unemploy-

Can Protectionism Save Free Trade?

Free trade is economic motherhood. Protectionism is economic evil incarnate. . . . Never should government interfere in the efficiency of international competition. Since childhood, these have been the tenets of my faith. If it meant that certain businesses in this country went belly-up, so be it. . . . If it meant that Americans would be thrown out of work by overseas companies paying coolie wages, that was tough. . . . The thing to keep in mind, I was taught, was the Big Picture and the Long Run. America, the great exporter, had far more to gain than to lose from free trade; attempts to protect inefficient industries here would ultimately cost more American jobs. While playing with my David Ricardo doll and learning nursery rhymes about comparative advantage, I was listening to another laissez-fairy tale: Government’s role in the world of business should be limited to keeping business honest and competitive. In God we antitrusted. Let businesses operate in the free marketplace. Now American businesses are no longer competing with foreign companies. They are competing with foreign governments who help their local businesses. That means the world arena no longer offers a free marketplace; instead, most other governments are pushing a policy that can be called helpfulism. Helpfulism works like this: A government like Japan decides to get behind its baseball-bat industry. It pumps in capital, knocks off marginal operators, finds subtle ways to discourage imports of Louisville Sluggers, and selects target areas for export blitzes. Pretty soon, the favored Japanese companies are driving foreign competitors batty. How do we compete with helpfulism? One way is to complain that it is unfair; that draws a horselaugh. Another way is to demand a “Reagan Round” of trade negotiations under GATT, the Gentlemen’s Agreement To Talk, which is equally laughable.

Yet another way is to join the helpfuls by subsidizing our exports and permitting our companies to try monopolistic tricks abroad not permitted at home. But all that makes us feel guilty, with good reason. The other way to deal with helpfulism is through—here comes the dreadful word—protection. Or, if you prefer a euphemism, retaliation. Or if that is still too severe, reciprocity. Whatever its name, it is a way of saying to the cutthroat cartelists we sweetly call our trading partners: “You have bent the rules out of shape. Change your practices to conform to the agreed-upon rules, or we will export a taste of your own medicine.” A little balance, then, from the free trade theorists. The demand for what the Pentagon used to call “protective reaction” is not demagoguery, not shortsighted, not self-defeating. On the contrary, the overseas pirates of protectionism and exemplars of helpfulism need to be taught the basic lesson in trade, which is: tit for tat.

SOURCE: © David Burnett/Contact Press Images

In this classic column, William Safire shook off his long-standing attachment to free trade and argued eloquently for retaliation against protectionist nations.

SOURCE: William Safire, “Smoot-Hawley Lives,” The New York Times, March 17, 1983. Copyright © 1983 by The New York Times Company. All rights reserved. Used by permission and protected by the Copyright Laws of the United States. The printing, copying, redistribution, or retransmission of the material without express written permission is prohibited.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 34

International Trade and Comparative Advantage

739

ment reflects a shortcoming of the government’s monetary and fiscal policies, not of its international trade policies. That said, it is a huge problem right now, making trade liberalization guide unpopular. Second, we have noted that an abrupt stiffening of foreign competition can hurt U.S. workers by not allowing them adequate time to adapt to the new conditions. If change occurs fairly gradually, workers can be retrained and move into the industries that now require their services. Indeed, if the change is slow enough, normal attrition may suffice. But competition that inflicts its damage overnight is certain to impose real costs on the affected workers—costs that are no less painful for being temporary. That is why our trade laws make provisions for people and industries damaged by import surges. In fact, the economic world is constantly changing. The recent emergence of China, India, and other third-world countries, for example, has created stiff new competition for workers in America and other rich nations—competition they never imagined when they signed up for jobs that may now be imperiled by international trade. The same is true of many workers in service jobs (ranging from call center operators to lawyers) who never dreamed that their jobs might be done electronically from thousands of miles away. It is not irrational, and it is certainly not protectionist, for countries like the United States to use trade adjustment assistance and other tools to cushion the blow for these workers. These are, after all, only qualifications to an overwhelming argument. They call for intelligent monetary and fiscal policies and for transitional assistance to unemployed workers, not for abandonment of free trade. In general, the nation as a whole need not fear competition from cheap foreign labor. In the long run, labor will be “cheap” only where it is not very productive. Wages will be high in countries with high labor productivity, and this high productivity will enable those countries to compete effectively in international trade despite their high wages. It is thus misleading to say that the United States held its own in the international marketplace until recently despite high wages. Rather, it is much more accurate to note that the higher wages of American workers were a result of higher

Unfair Foreign Competition

We are subject to the intolerable competition of a foreign rival, who enjoys, it would seem, such superior facilities for the production of light, that he is enabled to inundate our national market at so exceedingly reduced a price, that, the moment he makes his appearance, he draws off all custom for us; and thus an important branch of French industry, with all its innumerable ramifications, is suddenly reduced to a state of complete stagnation. This rival is no other than the sun. Our petition is, that it would please your honorable body to pass a law whereby shall be directed the shutting up of all windows, dormers, skylights, shutters, curtains, in a word, all openings, holes, chinks, and fissures through which the light of the sun is used to penetrate our dwellings, to the prejudice of the profitable manufactures which we flatter ourselves we have been enabled to bestow upon the country. . . . We foresee your objections, gentlemen; but there is not one that you can oppose to us . . . which is not equally opposed to

your own practice and the principle which guides your policy. . . . Labor and nature concur in different proportions, according to country and climate, in every article of production. . . . If a Lisbon orange can be sold at half the price of a Parisian one, it is because a natural and gratuitous heat does for the one what the other only obtains from an artificial and consequently expensive one. . . . Does it not argue the greatest inconsistency to check as you do the importation of coal, iron, cheese, and goods of foreign manufacture, merely because and even in proportion as their price approaches zero, while at the same time you freely admit, and without limitation, the light of the sun, whose price is during the whole day at zero?

SOURCE: © Culver Pictures

Satire and ridicule are often more persuasive than logic and statistics. Exasperated by the spread of protectionism under the prevailing mercantilist philosophy, the French economist Frédéric Bastiat decided to take the protectionist argument to its illogical conclusion. The fictitious petition of the French candlemakers to the Chamber of Deputies, written in 1845 and excerpted below, has become a classic in the battle for free trade.

SOURCE: Frédéric Bastiat, Economic Sophisms (New York: G. P. Putnam’s Sons, 1922).

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

740

Part 8

The United States in the World Economy

worker productivity, which gave the United States a major competitive edge—an edge we still have, by the way.

Remember, where standards of living are concerned, it is absolute advantage, not comparative advantage, that counts. The country that is most efficient in producing every output can pay its workers more in every industry.

| SUMMARY | 7. Tariffs and quotas aim to protect a country’s industries from foreign competition. Such protection may sometimes be advantageous to that country, but not if foreign countries adopt tariffs and quotas of their own in retaliation.

1. Countries trade for many reasons. Two of the most important are that differences in their natural resources and other inputs create discrepancies in the efficiency with which they can produce different goods, and that specialization offers greater economies of large-scale production.

8. From the point of view of the country that imposes them, tariffs offer at least two advantages over quotas: Some of the gains go to the government rather than to foreign producers, and they provide greater incentive for efficient production.

2. Voluntary trade will generally be advantageous to both parties in an exchange. This concept is one of our Ideas for Beyond the Final Exam. 3. International trade is more complicated than trade within a nation because of political factors, differing national currencies, and impediments to the movement of labor and capital across national borders.

9. When a nation eliminates protection in favor of free trade, some industries and their workers will lose out. Equity then demands that these people and firms be compensated in some way. The U.S. government offers protection from import surges and various forms of trade adjustment assistance to help those workers and industries adapt to the new conditions.

4. Two countries will gain from trade with each other if each nation exports goods in which it has a comparative advantage. Even a country that is inefficient across the board will benefit by exporting the goods in whose production it is least inefficient. This concept is another of the Ideas for Beyond the Final Exam.

10. Several arguments for protectionism can, under the right circumstances, have validity. They include the national defense argument, the infant-industry argument, and the use of trade restrictions for strategic purposes. But each of these arguments is frequently abused.

5. When countries specialize and trade, each can enjoy consumption possibilities that exceed its production possibilities.

11. Dumping will hurt certain domestic producers, but it benefits domestic consumers.

6. The “cheap foreign labor” argument ignores the principle of comparative advantage, which shows that real wages (which determine living standards) can rise in both importing and exporting countries as a result of specialization.

| KEY TERMS | absolute advantage

727

comparative advantage dumping

737

export subsidy

727

infant-industry argument mercantilism quota

733

732

strategic argument for protection 737 tariff

732

specialization

736

725

732

trade adjustment assistance

735

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

International Trade and Comparative Advantage

Chapter 34

741

| TEST YOURSELF | 1. The following table describes the number of yards of cloth and barrels of wine that can be produced with a week’s worth of labor in England and Portugal. Assume that no other inputs are needed.

Cloth Wine

In England 8 yards 2 barrels

In Portugal 12 yards 6 barrels

a. If there is no trade, what is the price of wine in terms of cloth in England? b. If there is no trade, what is the price of wine in terms of cloth in Portugal? c. Suppose each country has 1 million weeks of labor available per year. Draw the production possibilities frontier for each country. d. Which country has an absolute advantage in the production of which good(s)? Which country has a comparative advantage in the production of which good(s)?

f. What can be said about the price at which trade will take place? 2. Suppose that the United States and Mexico are the only two countries in the world and that labor is the only productive input. In the United States, a worker can produce 12 bushels of wheat or 2 barrels of oil in a day. In Mexico, a worker can produce 2 bushels of wheat or 4 barrels of oil per day. a. What will be the price ratio between the two commodities (that is, the price of oil in terms of wheat) in each country if there is no trade? b. If free trade is allowed and there are no transportation costs, which commodity would the United States import? What about Mexico? c. In what range would the price ratio have to fall under free trade? Why? d. Picking one possible post-trade price ratio, show clearly how it is possible for both countries to benefit from free trade.

e. If the countries start trading with each other, which country will specialize and export which good?

| DISCUSSION QUESTIONS | 1. You have a dozen shirts and your roommate has six pairs of shoes worth roughly the same amount of money. You decide to swap six shirts for three pairs of shoes. In financial terms, neither of you gains anything. Explain why you are nevertheless both likely to be better off. 2. In the eighteenth century, some writers argued that one person in a trade could be made better off only by gaining at the expense of the other. Explain the fallacy in this argument. 3. Country A has a cold climate with a short growing season, but a highly skilled labor force (think of Finland). What sorts of products do you think it is likely to produce? What are the characteristics of the countries with which you would expect it to trade? 4. After the removal of a quota on sugar, many U.S. sugar farms go bankrupt. Discuss the pros and cons of removing the quota in the short and long runs. 5. Country A has a mercantilist government that believes it is always best to export more than it imports. As a

consequence, it exports more to Country B every year than it imports from Country B. After 100 years of this arrangement, both countries are destroyed in an earthquake. What were the advantages or disadvantages of the surplus to Country A? To Country B? 6. Under current trade law, the president of the United States must report periodically to Congress on countries engaging in unfair trade practices that inhibit U.S. exports. How would you define an “unfair” trade practice? Suppose Country X exports much more to the United States than it imports, year after year. Does that constitute evidence that Country X’s trade practices are unfair? What would constitute such evidence? 7. Suppose the United States finds Country X guilty of unfair trade practices and penalizes it with import quotas. So U.S. imports from Country X fall. Suppose, further, that Country X does not alter its trade practices in any way. Is the United States better or worse off? What about Country X?

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

742

Part 8

The United States in the World Economy

| APPENDIX | Supply, Demand, and Pricing in World Trade country, for that is how world supply and demand balance.

As noted in the text, price determination in a world market with free trade depends on supply and demand conditions in each of the countries participating in the market. This appendix works out some of the details in a two-country example. When applied to international trade, the usual supplydemand model must deal with (at least) two demand curves: that of the exporting country and that of the importing country. In addition, it may also involve two supply curves, because the importing country may produce part of its own consumption. (For example, the United States, which is the world’s biggest importer of oil, nonetheless produces quite a bit of domestic oil.) Furthermore, equilibrium does not take place at the intersection point of either pair of supply-demand curves. Why? Because if the two countries trade at all, the exporting nation must supply more than it demands while the importing nation must demand more than it supplies. All three of these complications are illustrated in Figure 3, which shows the supply and demand curves of a country that exports wheat in Panel (a) and of a country that imports wheat in Panel (b). For simplicity, we assume that these countries do not deal with anyone else. Where will the two-country wheat market reach equilibrium? Under free trade, the equilibrium price must satisfy two requirements:

2. The price of wheat must be the same in both countries.6

In Figure 3, these two conditions are met at a price of $2.50 per bushel. At that price, the distance AB between what the exporting country produces and what it consumes equals the distance CD between what the importing country consumes and what it produces. This means that the amount the exporting country wants to sell at $2.50 per bushel exactly equals the amount the importing country wants to buy at that price. At any higher price, producers in both countries would want to sell more and consumers in both countries would want to buy less. For example, if the price rose to $3.25 per bushel, the exporter’s quantity supplied would rise from B to F and its quantity demanded would fall from A to E, as shown in Panel (a). As a result, more wheat would be available for export—EF rather than AB. For exactly the same reason, the price increase would cause higher production and lower sales in the importing country, leading to a reduction in imports from CD to GH in Panel (b). But this means that the higher price, $3.25 per bushel, cannot be sustained in a free and competitive international market. With export supply EF far greater than import demand GH, there would be pressure on price to fall back toward the $2.50 equilibrium price.

1. The quantity of wheat exported by one country must equal the quantity of wheat imported by the other

FIGU R E 3

Exporting country’s demand

Exporting country’s supply

E

Price of Wheat per Bushel

Price of Wheat per Bushel

Supply-Demand Equilibrium in the International Wheat Trade

F

$3.25 2.50

A

B Exports

G

H

C

D Imports

Importing country’s supply 0

0

Quantity of Wheat

Importing country’s demand

Quantity of Wheat (b) Importing Country

(a) Exporting Country

To keep things simple, we ignore such details as the costs of shipping wheat from one country to the other. 6

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

743

International Trade and Comparative Advantage

Chapter 34

Similar reasoning shows that no price below $2.50 can be sustained. Thus: In international trade, the equilibrium price is the one that makes the exporting country want to export exactly the amount that the importing country wants to import. Equilibrium will thus occur at a price at which the horizontal distance AB in Figure 3(a) (the excess of the exporter’s quantity supplied over its quantity demanded) is equal to the horizontal distance CD in Figure 3(b) (the excess of the importer’s quantity demanded over its quantity supplied). At this price, the world’s quantity demanded equals the world’s quantity supplied.

HOW TARIFFS AND QUOTAS WORK However, as noted in the text, nations do not always let markets operate freely. Sometimes they intervene with quotas that limit imports or with tariffs that make imports more expensive. Although both tariffs and quotas restrict supplies coming from abroad and drive up prices, they operate slightly differently. A tariff works by raising prices, which in turn reduces the quantity of imports demanded. The sequence associated with a quota is just the reverse—a restriction in supply forces prices to rise. The supply and demand curves in Figure 4 illustrate how tariffs and quotas work. Just as in Figure 3, the equilibrium price of wheat under free trade is $2.50 per bushel (in both countries). At this price, the exporting country produces 125 million bushels— point B in Panel (a)—and consumes 80 million

(point A). So its exports are 45 million bushels—the distance AB. Similarly, the importing country consumes 95 million bushels—point D in Panel (b)—and produces only 50 million (point C), so its imports are also 45 million bushels—the distance CD. Now suppose the government of the importing nation imposes a quota limiting imports to 30 million bushels. The free-trade equilibrium with imports of 45 million bushels is now illegal. Instead, the market must equilibrate at a point where both exports and imports are only 30 million bushels. As Figure 4 indicates, this requirement implies that there must be different prices in the two countries. Imports in Panel (b) will be 30 million bushels—the distance QT—only when the price of wheat in the importing nation is $3.25 per bushel, because only at this price will quantity demanded exceed domestic quantity supplied by 30 million bushels. Similarly, exports in Panel (a) will be 30 million bushels—the distance RS—only when the price in the exporting country is $2.00 per bushel. At this price, quantity supplied exceeds quantity demanded in the exporting country by 30 million bushels. Thus, the quota raises the price in the importing country to $3.25 and lowers the price in the exporting country to $2.00. In general: An import quota on a product normally reduces the volume of that product traded, raises the price in the importing country, and reduces the price in the exporting country.

A tariff can accomplish exactly the same restriction of trade. In our example, a quota of 30 million bushels

FIGURE 4

Exporting country’s supply

Exporting country’s demand A

B

$2.50 2.00

0

R

80 85

S

115 125

Importing country’s supply Price of Wheat per Bushel

Price of Wheat per Bushel

Quotas and Tariffs in International Trade

Q

Importing country’s demand T

$3.25 2.50

0

C

D

50 57.5

87.5 95

Quantity of Wheat

Quantity of Wheat

(a) Exporting Country

(b) Importing Country

NOTE: Quantities are in millions of bushels.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

744

Part 8

The United States in the World Economy

leads to a price that is $1.25 higher in the importing country than in the exporting country ($3.25 versus $2.00). Suppose that, instead of a quota, the importing nation were to impose a $1.25 per bushel tariff. International trade equilibrium would then have to satisfy the following two requirements: 1. The quantity of wheat exported by one country must equal the quantity of wheat imported by the other, just as before. 2. The price that consumers in the importing country pay for wheat must exceed the price that suppliers in the exporting country receive by the amount of the tariff (which is $1.25 in the example).

By consulting the graphs in Figure 4, you can see exactly where these two requirements are met. If the exporter produces at S and consumes at R, while the importer produces at Q and consumes at T, then exports and imports are equal (at 30 million bushels), and the two domestic prices differ by exactly $1.25. (They are $3.25 and $2.00.) But this is exactly the same equilibrium we found under the quota. What we have just discovered is a general result of international trade theory:

Any restriction of imports that is accomplished by a quota normally can also be accomplished by a tariff.

In this case, the tariff corresponding to an import quota of 30 million bushels is $1.25 per bushel. We mentioned in the text that a tariff (or a quota) forces foreign producers to sell more cheaply. Figure 4 shows how this works. Suppose, as in Panel (b), that a $1.25 tariff on wheat raises the price in the importing country from $2.50 to $3.25 per bushel. This higher price drives down imports from an amount represented by the length of the brick-colored line CD to the smaller amount represented by the blue line QT. In the exporting country, this change means an equal reduction in exports, as illustrated by the change from AB to RS in Panel (a). As a result, the price at which the exporting country can sell its wheat is driven down—from $2.50 to $2.00 in the example. Meanwhile, producers in the importing country, which are exempt from the tariff, can charge $3.25 per bushel. Thus, as noted in the text, a tariff (or a quota) can be thought of as a way to “rig” the domestic market in favor of domestic firms.

| SUMMARY | 1. The prices of goods traded between countries are determined by supply and demand, but one must consider explicitly the demand curve and the supply curve of each country involved. Thus, the equilibrium price must make the excess of quantity supplied over quantity demanded in the exporting country equal to the excess of quantity demanded over quantity supplied in the importing country.

2. When trade is restricted, the combinations of prices and quantities in the various countries that are achieved by a quota can also be achieved by a tariff. 3. Tariffs or quotas favor domestic producers over foreign producers.

| TEST YOURSELF | 1. The following table presents the demand and supply curves for microcomputers in Japan and the United States. Quantity Price per Demanded Computer in U.S. 1 90 2 80 3 70 4 60 5 50 6 40

Quantity Supplied in U.S. 30 35 40 45 50 55

Quantity Demanded in Japan 50 40 30 20 10 0

Quantity Supplied in Japan 50 55 60 65 70 75

b. If the United States and Japan do not trade, what are the equilibrium price and quantity in the computer market in the United States? In Japan? c. Now suppose trade is opened up between the two countries. What will be the equilibrium price in the world market for computers? What has happened to the price of computers in the United States? In Japan? d. Which country will export computers? How many? e. When trade opens, what happens to the quantity of computers produced, and therefore employment, in the computer industry in the United States? In Japan? Who benefits and who loses initially from free trade?

NOTE: Price and quantity are in thousands.

a. Draw the demand and supply curves for the United States on one diagram and those for Japan on another one.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

The International Monetary System: Order or Disorder? Cecily, you will read your Political Economy in my absence. The chapter on the Fall of the Rupee you may omit. It is somewhat too sensational. M I S S P RI SM I N O S CAR W I L D E ’ S T HE IMPO RTA NCE O F BEING EA R NEST

M

iss Prism, the Victorian tutor, may have had a better point than she knew. In the summer of 1997, the Indonesian rupiah (not the Indian rupee) fell and economic disaster quickly followed. The International Monetary Fund rushed to the rescue with billions of dollars and pages of advice. But its plan failed, and some say it may even have helped precipitate the bloody riots that led to the fall of the Indonesian government. Like the demure Miss Prism, this chapter does not concentrate on sensational political upheavals. Rather, it focuses on a seemingly mundane topic: how the market determines rates of exchange among different national currencies. Nevertheless, events in Southeast Asia in 1997–1998, in Brazil and Russia in 1998–1999, and in Turkey and Argentina in 2001–2002 have amply demonstrated that dramatic exchange rate movements can have severe human as well as financial consequences. Even in the United States, some people are now worried about the consequences of the declining value of the dollar. This chapter and the next will help you understand why.

C O N T E N T S PUZZLE: WHY HAS THE DOLLAR SAGGED?

WHAT ARE EXCHANGE RATES? EXCHANGE RATE DETERMINATION IN A FREE MARKET Interest Rates and Exchange Rates: The Short Run Economic Activity and Exchange Rates: The Medium Run The Purchasing-Power Parity Theory: The Long Run Market Determination of Exchange Rates: Summary

WHEN GOVERNMENTS FIX EXCHANGE RATES: THE BALANCE OF PAYMENTS

WHY TRY TO FIX EXCHANGE RATES?

A BIT OF HISTORY: THE GOLD STANDARD AND THE BRETTON WOODS SYSTEM

The Role of the IMF The Volatile Dollar The Birth and Adolescence of the Euro

The Classical Gold Standard The Bretton Woods System

ADJUSTMENT MECHANISMS UNDER FIXED EXCHANGE RATES

THE CURRENT “NONSYSTEM”

PUZZLE RESOLVED: WHY THE DOLLAR

ROSE, THEN FELL, THEN ROSE

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

746

Part 8

The United States in the World Economy

PUZZLE:

WHY HAS THE DOLLAR SAGGED?

Many observers speak of “American exceptionalism.” One way in which America differs from other countries is that its media and citizens almost never pay much attention to the international value of its currency. But 2007 proved to be an exception to the exceptionalism. The dollar fell so low against the euro, the British pound, and, especially, the Canadian dollar that—at least for a few days—it grabbed the headlines. The euro flirted with $1.50 (which it later surpassed), the pound topped $2, and the Canadian dollar became more valuable than the U.S. dollar. (Since then, the dollar has gained ground considerably.) These events in foreign currency markets had a lot of people scratching their heads. What caused the dollar to fall so far? Will it fall further? Does the decline signal some deep-seated problem with the U.S. economy? We will learn some of the answers to these and related questions in this chapter. To do that, we first need to understand what determines exchange rates.

WHAT ARE EXCHANGE RATES?

The exchange rate states the price, in terms of one currency, at which another currency can be bought.

A nation’s currency is said to appreciate when exchange rates change so that a unit of its currency can buy more units of foreign currency. A nation’s currency is said to depreciate when exchange rates change so that a unit of its currency can buy fewer units of foreign currency.

We noted in the previous chapter that international trade is more complicated than domestic trade. There are no national borders to be crossed when, say, California lettuce is shipped to Massachusetts. The consumer in Boston pays with dollars, just the currency that the farmer in Modesto wants. If that same farmer ships her lettuce to Japan, however, consumers there will have only Japanese yen with which to pay, rather than the dollars the farmer in California wants. Thus, for international trade to take place, there must be some way to convert one currency into another. The rates at which such conversions are made are called exchange rates. There is an exchange rate between every pair of currencies. For example, one British pound is currently the equivalent of about $1.50. The exchange rate between the pound and the dollar, then, may be expressed as roughly “$1.50 to the pound” (meaning that it costs $1.50 to buy a pound) or about “67 pence to the dollar” (meaning that it costs twothirds of a British pound to buy a dollar). Exchange rates vis-à-vis the United States dollar have changed dramatically over time. In a nutshell, the dollar soared in the period from mid-1980 to early 1985, fell relative to most major currencies from early 1985 until early 1988, and then fluctuated with no clear trend until the spring of 1995. From then until early 2002, the dollar was mostly on the rise. Then, from February 2002 through December 2004, the dollar reversed course and fell steadily. From then until 2007, the dollar was relatively stable, on balance, until early 2007 when, as noted above, it started dropping once again. Since then, it has been stable to rising. This chapter seeks to explain such currency movements. Under our present system, currency rates change frequently. When other currencies become more expensive in terms of dollars, we say that they have appreciated relative to the dollar. Alternatively, we can look at this same event as the dollar buying less foreign currency, meaning that the dollar has depreciated relative to another currency. What is a depreciation to one country must be an appreciation to the other.

For example, if the cost of a pound rises from $1.50 to $2, the cost of a U.S. dollar in terms of pounds simultaneously falls from 67 pence to 50 pence. The United Kingdom has experienced a currency appreciation while the United States has experienced a currency depreciation. In fact, the two mean more or less the same thing. As you may have noticed, these two ways of viewing the exchange rate are reciprocals of one another, that is, 1/1.5 5 0.67 and 1/2 5 0.50. And of course, when a number goes up, its reciprocal goes down. When many currencies are changing in value at the same time, the dollar may be appreciating with respect to one currency but depreciating with respect to another. Table 1 offers a selection of exchange rates prevailing in July 1980, February 1985, June 1995, April

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

747

The International Monetary System: Order or Disorder?

Chapter 35

TABLE 1 Exchange Rates with the U.S. Dollar SOURCE: International Financial Statistics and The Wall Street Journal.

Cost in Dollars Country Australia Canada France Germany Italy Japan Mexico Sweden Switzerland United Kingdom —

Currency

Symbol

July 1980

Feb. 1985

June 1995

April 2002

April 2008

Feb. 2010

dollar dollar franc mark lira yen new peso krona franc pound euro

$ $ FF DM L ¥ $ Kr S.Fr. £ €

$1.16 0.87 0.25 0.57 0.0012 0.0045 44.0† 0.24 0.62 2.37 —

$0.74 0.74 0.10 0.30 0.00049 0.0038 5.0† 0.11 0.36 1.10 —

$0.72 0.73 0.20 0.71 0.0061 0.0118 0.16 0.14 0.86 1.59 —

$0.53 0.63 * * * 0.0076 0.11 0.10 0.60 1.44 0.88

$0.93 $0.89 0.99 0.95 * * * * * * 0.0096 0.0111 0.09 0.08 0.17 0.14 0.98 0.93 1.99 1.54 1.58 1.35

NOTE: Exchange rates are in U.S. dollars per unit of foreign currency. *These

exchange rates were locked together at the start of the euro in January 1999.

†On

January 1, 1993, the peso was redefined so that 1,000 old pesos were equal to 1 new peso. Hence, the numbers 44 and 5 listed for July 1980 and February 1985 were actually 0.044 and 0.005 on the old basis.

2002, April 2008, and February 2010, showing how many dollars or cents it cost at each of those times to buy each unit of foreign currency. Between February 1985 and April 2002, the dollar depreciated sharply relative to the Japanese yen and most European currencies. For example, the British pound rose from $1.10 to $1.44. During that same period, however, the dollar appreciated dramatically relative to the Mexican peso; it bought about 0.2 pesos in 1985 but more than 9 in 2002.1 Since April 2002, the dollar has depreciated against most currencies, and sharply against the euro. Although the terms appreciation and depreciation are used to describe movements of exchange rates in free markets, a different set of terms is employed to describe decreases and increases in currency values that are set by government decree. When an officially set exchange rate is altered so that a unit of a nation’s currency can buy fewer units of foreign currency, we say that a devaluation of that currency has occurred. When the exchange rate is altered so that the currency can buy more units of foreign currency, we say that a revaluation has taken place. We will say more about devaluation and revaluation shortly, but first let’s look at how the free market determines exchange rates.

A devaluation is a reduction in the official value of a currency. A revaluation is an increase in the official value of a currency.

EXCHANGE RATE DETERMINATION IN A FREE MARKET In 1999, 11 European countries adopted a new common currency, the euro. Why does a euro now cost about $1.40 and not $1.20 or $1.60? In a world of floating exchange rates, with no government interferences, the answer would be straightforward. Exchange rates would be determined by the forces of supply and demand, just like the prices of apples, computers, and haircuts. In a leap of abstraction, imagine that the dollar and the euro are the only currencies on earth, so the market need determine only one exchange rate. Figure 1 depicts the determination of this exchange rate at the point (denoted E in the figure) where demand curve DD crosses supply curve SS. At this price ($1.50 per euro), the number of euros demanded is equal to the number of euros supplied.

Floating exchange rates are rates determined in free markets by the law of supply and demand.

In a free market, exchange rates are determined by supply and demand. At a rate below the equilibrium level, the number of euros demanded would exceed the number supplied, and the price of a euro would be bid up. At a rate above the equilibrium level, quantity supplied would exceed quantity demanded, and the price of a euro would fall. Only at the equilibrium exchange rate is there no tendency for the rate to change.

In fact, the dollar bought about 200 pesos in February 1985, but that is because the old peso was replaced by a new peso in January 1993, which moved the decimal point three places.

1

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

748

The United States in the World Economy

Part 8

Price of a Euro (in dollars)

D

S

$1.50

S

F I GURE 1 Determination of Exchange Rates in a Free Market

As usual, supply and demand determine price. However, in this case, we must ask: Where do the supply and demand come from? Why does anyone demand a euro? The answer comes in three parts:

1. International trade in goods and services. This factor was the subject of the previous chapter. If, for example, Jane Doe, an American, wants to buy a new BMW, she will first have to E buy euros with which to pay the car dealer in Munich.2 Thus, Jane’s demand for a European car leads to a demand for European currency. In general, demand for a country’s exports leads to demand for its currency.3 2. Purchases of physical assets such as factories and machinery overD seas. If IBM wants to buy a small French computer manufacturer, the owners will no doubt want to receive euros. So IBM Number of Euros will first have to acquire European currency. In general, direct foreign investment leads to demand for a country’s currency. 3. International trade in financial instruments such as stocks and bonds. If American investors want to purchase Italian stocks, they will first have to acquire the euros that the sellers will insist on for payment. In this way, demand for European financial assets leads to demand for European currency. Thus, demand for a country’s financial assets leads to demand for its currency. In fact, nowadays the volume of international trade in financial assets among the major countries of the world is so large that it swamps the other two sources of demand. Now, where does the supply come from? To answer this question, just turn all of these transactions around. Europeans who want to buy U.S. goods and services, make direct investments in the United States, or purchase U.S. financial assets will have to offer their euros for sale in the foreign-exchange market (which is mainly run through banks) to acquire the needed dollars. To summarize: The demand for a country’s currency is derived from the demands of foreigners for its export goods and services and for its assets—including financial assets, such as stocks and bonds, and real assets, such as factories and machinery. The supply of a country’s currency arises from its imports, and from foreign investment by its own citizens.

To illustrate the usefulness of even this simple supply-and-demand analysis, think about how the exchange rate between the dollar and the euro should change if Europeans become worried about the safety of U.S. assets, as happened briefly during the financial crisis of 2007–2008.4 As European investors reduce their desires to buy U.S. assets, they will supply fewer euros for sale (in order to buy the necessary dollars). In terms of the supply-and-demand diagram in Figure 2, that decreased sale of euros will shift the supply curve inward from the black line S1S1 to the brick-colored line S2S2. Equilibrium would shift from point E to point A, and the exchange rate would rise from $1.50 per euro to $1.70 per euro. Thus, the decreased supply of euros by European citizens would cause the euro to appreciate relative to the dollar—which is just what happened.

EXERCISE Test your understanding of the supply-and-demand analysis of exchange rates by showing why each of the following events would lead to an appreciation of the euro (a depreciation of the dollar) in a free market: 1. American investors are attracted by prospects for profit on the German stock market. 2. A recession in Italy cuts Italian purchases of American goods. 2 Actually, she will not do so because banks generally handle foreign-exchange transactions for consumers. An American bank probably will buy the euros for her. Even so, the effect is exactly the same as if Jane had done it herself. 3 See Discussion Question 2 at the end of this chapter. 4 The dollar subsequently rose again as investors worldwide sought the safety of U.S. Treasury securities.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 35

749

The International Monetary System: Order or Disorder?

3. Interest rates on government bonds rise in France but are stable in the United States. (Hint: Which country’s citizens will be attracted to invest by high interest rates in the other country?)

D A $1.70 Price of a Euro (in dollars)

To say that supply and demand determine exchange rates in a free market is at once to say everything and to say nothing. If we are to understand the reasons why some currencies appreciate whereas others depreciate, we must look into the factors that move the supply and demand curves. Economists believe that the principal determinants of exchange rate movements differ significantly in the short, medium, and long runs. In the next three sections, we turn to the analysis of exchange rate movements over these three “runs,” beginning with the short run.

S1

S2

$1.50 E

D S1

S2

Number of Euros

FI GURE 2

Interest Rates and Exchange Rates: The Short Run Most experts in international finance agree that interest rates and financial flows are the major determinants of exchange rates—certainly in the short run, and probably in the medium run as well. Specifically, one variable that often seems to call the tune in the short run is interest rate differentials. A multitrillion-dollar pool of so-called hot money—owned by banks, investment funds, multinational corporations, and wealthy individuals of all nations—travels rapidly around the globe in search of the highest interest rates. As an example, suppose British government bonds pay a 5 percent rate of interest when yields on equally safe American government securities rise to 7 percent. British investors will be attracted by the higher interest rates in the United States and will offer pounds for sale in order to buy dollars, planning to use those dollars to buy American securities. At the same time, American investors will find it more attractive to keep their money at home, so fewer pounds will be demanded by Americans. When the demand schedule for pounds shifts inward and the supply curve shifts outward, the effect on price is predictable: The pound will depreciate, as Figure 3 shows. In the figure, the supply curve of pounds shifts outward from S1S1 to S2S2 when British investors seek to sell pounds in order to purchase more U.S. securities. At the same time, American investors wish to buy fewer pounds because they no longer desire to invest as much in British securities. Thus, the demand curve shifts inward from D1D1 to D2D2. The result, in our example, is a depreciation of the pound from $1.75 to $1.50. In general:

It is useful to think of interest rate differentials as standing in for the relative returns on all sorts of financial assets in the two countries. In the late 1990s and the early part of this decade, prospective returns on American assets rose well above comparable returns in most other countries—especially those in Europe and Japan. In consequence, foreign capital was attracted here, American capital stayed at home, and the dollar soared—to levels that proved

FI GURE 3 The Effect of a Rise in U.S. Interest Rates

D1

S1

D2 Price of a Pound (in dollars)

Other things equal, countries that offer investors higher rates of return attract more capital than countries that offer lower rates. Thus, a rise in interest rates often will lead to an appreciation of the currency, and a drop in interest rates often will lead to a depreciation.

The Effect of Declining Demand for U.S. Assets on the Exchange Rate

S2 E1

$1.75 E2 $1.50

D1

S1 S2

D2 Number of Pounds

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

750

Part 8

The United States in the World Economy

unsustainable. Similarly, if a nation suffers from capital flight, as Argentina did in 2001, it must offer extremely high interest rates to attract foreign capital. Conversely, when foreign capital “flew” to the safe haven of the United States in 2008–2009, the dollar rose.

Economic Activity and Exchange Rates: The Medium Run

F I GURE 4 The Effect of an Economic Boom Abroad on the Exchange Rate

The medium run is where the theory of exchange rate determination is most unsettled. Economists once reasoned as follows: Because consumer spending increases when income rises and decreases when income falls, the same thing is likely to happen to spending on imported goods. So a country’s imports will rise quickly when its economy booms and rise only slowly when its economy stagnates. For the reasons illustrated in Figure 4, then, a boom in the United States should shift the demand curve for euros outward as Americans seek to acquire more euros to buy more European goods. And that, in turn, should lead to an appreciation of the euro (depreciation of the dollar). In the figure, the euro rises in value from $1.50 to $1.60. However, if Europe was booming at the same time, Europeans would be buying more American exports, which would shift the supply curve of euros outward. (Europeans must offer more euros for sale to get the dollars they want.) On balance, the value of the dollar might rise or fall. It appears that what matters is whether exports are growing faster than imports.

D2 S

Price of a Euro (in dollars)

D1

A country that grows faster than the rest of the world normally finds its imports growing faster than its exports. Thus, its demand curve for foreign currency shifts outward more rapidly than its supply curve. Other things equal, that will make its currency depreciate.

A

$1.60

$1.50

S

This reasoning is sound—so far as it goes. And it leads to the conclusion that a “strong economy” E might produce a “weak currency.” But the three most D2 important words in the preceding paragraph are “other things equal.” Usually, they are not. Specifically, a booming economy will normally offer more D1 attractive prospects to investors than a stagnating one—higher interest rates, rising stock market values, and so on. This difference in prospective Number of Euros investment returns, as we noted earlier, should attract capital and boost its currency value. So there appears to be a kind of tug of war. Thinking only about trade in goods and services leads to the conclusion that faster growth should weaken the currency. Thinking instead about trade in financial assets (such as stocks and bonds) leads to precisely the opposite conclusion: Faster growth should strengthen the currency. Which side wins this tug of war? As we have suggested, it is usually no contest—at least among the major currencies of the world. In the modern world, the evidence seems to say that trade in financial assets is the dominant factor. For example, rapid growth and soaring imports in the United States in the second half of the 1990s accompanied a sharply appreciating dollar as investors from all over the world brought funds to America. We conclude that Stronger economic performance often leads to currency appreciation because it improves prospects for investing in the country.

The Purchasing-Power Parity Theory: The Long Run We come at last to the long run, where an apparently simple principle ought to govern exchange rates. As long as goods can move freely across national borders, exchange rates should eventually adjust so that the same product costs the same amount of money, whether measured in dollars in the United States, euros in Germany, or yen in Japan—except

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 35

The International Monetary System: Order or Disorder?

for differences in transportation costs and the like. This simple statement forms the basis of the major theory of exchange rate determination in the long run: The purchasing-power parity theory of exchange rate determination holds that the exchange rate between any two national currencies adjusts to reflect differences in the price levels in the two countries.

An example will illustrate the basic truth in this theory and also suggest some of its limitations. Suppose German and American steel are identical and that these two nations are the only producers of steel for the world market. Suppose further that steel is the only tradable good that either country produces. Question: If American steel costs $300 per ton and German steel costs 200 euros per ton, what must be the exchange rate between the dollar and the euro? Answer: Because 200 euros and $300 each buy a ton of steel, the two sums of money must be of equal value. Hence, each euro must be worth $1.50. Why? Any higher price for a euro, such as $1.60, would mean that steel would cost $320 per ton (200 euros at $1.60 each) in Germany but only $300 per ton in the United States. In that case, all foreign customers would shop for their steel in the United States—which would increase the demand for dollars and decrease the demand for euros. Similarly, any exchange rate below $1.50 per euro would send all the steel business to Germany, driving the value of the euro up toward its purchasing-power parity level.

EXERCISE Show why an exchange rate of $1.25 per euro is too low to lead to an equilibrium in the international steel market. The purchasing-power parity theory is used to make long-run predictions about the effects of inflation on exchange rates. To continue our example, suppose that steel (and other) prices in the United States rise while prices in Europe remain constant. The purchasing-power parity theory predicts that the euro will appreciate relative to the dollar. It also predicts the amount of the appreciation. After the U.S. inflation, suppose that the price of American steel is $330 per ton, whereas German steel still costs 200 euros per ton. For these two prices to be equivalent, 200 euros must be worth $330, or one euro must be worth $1.65. The euro, therefore, must rise from $1.50 to $1.65. According to the purchasing-power parity theory, differences in domestic inflation rates are a major cause of exchange rate movements. If one country has higher inflation than another, its exchange rate should be depreciating.

For many years, this theory seemed to work tolerably well. Although precise numerical predictions based on purchasing-power parity calculations were never very accurate (see “Purchasing-Power Parity and the Big Mac” on the following page), nations with higher inflation did at least experience depreciating currencies. But in the 1980s and 1990s, even this rule broke down. For example, although the U.S. inflation rate was consistently higher than both Germany’s and Japan’s, the dollar nonetheless rose sharply relative to both the German mark and the Japanese yen from 1980 to 1985. The same thing happened again between 1995 and 2002. Clearly, the theory is missing something. What? Many things, but perhaps the principal failing of the purchasing-power parity theory is, once again, that it focuses too much on trade in goods and services. Financial assets such as stocks and bonds are also traded actively across national borders—and in vastly greater dollar volumes than goods and services. In fact, the astounding daily volume of foreign-exchange transactions exceeds $3 trillion, which is far more than an entire month’s worth of world trade in goods and services. The vast majority of these transactions are financial. If investors decide that, say, U.S. assets are a better bet than Japanese assets, the dollar will rise, even if our inflation rate is well above Japan’s. For this and other reasons, Most economists believe that other factors are much more important than relative price levels for exchange rate determination in the short run. But in the long run, purchasing-power parity plays an important role.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

751

752

Part 8

The United States in the World Economy

Purchasing-Power Parity and the Big Mac

Deviations from Big Mac Purchasing-Power Parity, January 2007

Country United States Norway Great Britain Euro area Canada Mexico Japan Russia China

Big Mac Prices (converted to dollars) $3.22 6.63 3.90 3.82 3.08 2.66 2.31 1.85 1.41

Percent Over (1) or Under (2) Valuation Against Dollar — 1106% 121 119 24 217 228 243 256

By how much? The price in China was just 44 percent of the price in the United States ($1.41/$3.22 5 0.438). So the yuan was 56 percent below its Big Mac parity—and therefore should appreciate. The other numbers in the table have similar interpretations. True Big Mac aficionados may find these data helpful when planning international travel. But can deviations from Big Mac parity predict exchange rate movements? Surprisingly, they can. When economist Robert Cumby studied Big Mac prices and exchange rates in 14 countries over a 10-year period, he found that deviations from hamburger parity were transitory. Their “half-life” was just a year, meaning that 50 percent of the deviation tended to disappear within a year. Thus, the undervalued currencies in the accompanying table would be predicted to appreciate during 2007, whereas the overvalued currencies would be expected to depreciate.

SOURCE: © mediablitzimages (uk) Limited/Alamy

Since 1986, The Economist magazine has been using a well-known international commodity—the Big Mac—to assess the purchasingpower parity theory of exchange rates, or as the magazine once put it, “to make exchange-rate theory more digestible.” Here’s how it works. In theory, the local price of a Big Mac, when translated into U.S. dollars by the exchange rate, should be the same everywhere in the world. The following numbers show that the theory does not work terribly well. For example, although a Big Mac cost an average of $3.22 in the United States in January 2007, it sold for about 11 yuan in China. Using the official exchange rate of 7.77 yuan to the dollar, that amounted to just $1.41. Thus, according to the hamburger parity theory, the yuan was grossly undervalued.

SOURCES: “Big Mac Index” from The Economist, February 1, 2007. Copyright © 2007 The Economist Newspaper Ltd. All rights reserved. Reprinted with permission. Further reproduction prohibited; and Robert Cumby, “Forecasting Exchange Rates and Relative Prices with the Hamburger Standard: Is What You Want What You Get with McParity?” Georgetown University, May 1997.

Market Determination of Exchange Rates: Summary You have probably noticed a theme here: International trade in financial assets certainly dominates short-run exchange rate changes, may dominate medium-run changes, and also influences long-run changes. We can summarize this discussion of exchange rate determination in free markets as follows: 1. We expect to find appreciating currencies in countries that offer investors higher rates of return because these countries will attract capital from all over the world. 2. To some extent, these are the countries that are growing faster than average because strong growth tends to produce attractive investment prospects. However, such fastgrowing countries will also be importing relatively more than other countries, which tends to pull their currencies down. 3. Currency values generally will appreciate in countries with lower inflation rates than the rest of the world’s, because buyers in foreign countries will demand their goods and thus drive up their currencies.

Reversing each of these arguments, we expect to find depreciating currencies in countries with relatively high inflation rates, low interest rates, and poor growth prospects.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 35

The International Monetary System: Order or Disorder?

753

WHEN GOVERNMENTS FIX EXCHANGE RATES: THE BALANCE OF PAYMENTS

Price of a Peso (in dollars)

Many exchange rates today are truly floating, determined by the forces of supply and demand without government interference. Others are not. Furthermore, some people claim that exchange rate fluctuations are so troublesome that the world would be better off with Fixed exchange rates are fixed exchange rates. For these reasons, we turn next to a system of fixed exchange rates, rates set by government decisions and maintained or rates that are set by governments. Naturally, under such a system the exchange rate, being fixed, is not closely by government actions. watched. Instead, international financial specialists focus on a country’s balance of FI GURE 5 payments—a term we must now define—to gauge movements in the supply of and demand for a currency. A Balance of Payments Deficit To understand what the balance of payments is, look at Figure 5, which depicts a situation that might represent, say, Argentina in the winter of S 2001–2002—an overvalued currency. Although the D Balance of supply and demand curves for pesos indicate an payments deficit equilibrium exchange rate of $0.50 to the peso (point E), the Argentine government is holding the 1.00 A B rate at $1. Notice that, at $1 per peso, more people supply pesos than demand them. In the example, suppliers offer to sell 8 billion pesos per year, but E purchasers want to buy only 4 billion. This gap 0.50 between the 8 billion pesos that some people wish to sell and the 4 billion pesos that others wish to buy is what we mean by Argentina’s balance of payments deficit—4 billion pesos (or $4 billion) D S per year in this hypothetical case. It appears as 4 8 the horizontal distance between points A and B in Billions of Pesos per Year Figure 5. How can governments flout market forces in this way? Because sales and purchases on any market must be equal, the excess of quan- The balance of payments tity supplied over quantity demanded—or 4 billion pesos per year in this example— deficit is the amount by must be bought by the Argentine government. To purchase these pesos, it must give up which the quantity supplied of a country’s currency (per some of the foreign currency that it holds as reserves. Thus, the Central Bank of year) exceeds the quantity Argentina would be losing about $4 billion in reserves per year as the cost of keeping demanded. Balance of the peso at $1. payments deficits arise Naturally, this situation cannot persist forever, as the reserves eventually will run out. whenever the exchange rate This is the fatal flaw of a fixed exchange rate system. Once speculators become convinced is pegged at an artificially that the exchange rate can be held for only a short while longer, they will sell the currency high level. in massive amounts rather than hold on to money whose value they expect to fall. That is precisely what began to happen to Argentina in 2001. Lacking sufficient reserves, the Argentine government succumbed to market forces and let the peso float in early 2002. It promptly depreciated. For an example of the reverse case, a severely undervalued currency, we can look at contemporary China. Figure 6 depicts demand and supply curves for Chinese yuan that intersect at an equilibrium price of 15 cents per yuan (point E in the diagram). Yet, in the example, we suppose that the Chinese authorities are holding the rate at 12 cents. At The balance of payments this rate, the quantity of yuan demanded (1,000 billion) greatly exceeds the quantity surplus is the amount by supplied (600 billion). The difference is China’s balance of payments surplus, shown by which the quantity demanded of a country’s the horizontal distance AB. China can keep the rate at 12 cents only by selling all the additional yuan that foreign- currency (per year) exceeds the quantity supplied. ers want to buy—400 billion yuan per year in this example. In return, the country must Balance of payments buy the equivalent amount of U.S. dollars ($48 billion). All of this activity serves to in- surpluses arise whenever crease China’s reserves of U.S. dollars. But notice one important difference between this the exchange rate is pegged case and the overvalued peso: at an artificially low level.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

754

Part 8

The United States in the World Economy

S

D

The accumulation of reserves rarely will force a central bank to revalue in the way that losses of reserves can force a devaluation.

Thus China has been keeping its currency undervalued and accumulating huge dollar reserves for years. This asymmetry is a clear weakness in a fixed exA B change rate system. In principle, an exchange rate disequilibrium can be cured either by a devaluation Balance of payments surplus by the country with a balance of payments deficit or by an upward revaluation by the country with a balD ance of payments surplus. In practice, though, only deficit countries are forced to act. Why do surplus countries refuse to revalue? One 600 1,000 reason is often a stubborn refusal to recognize some Billions of Yuan per Year basic economic realities. They tend to view the disequilibrium as a problem only for the deficit countries and, therefore, believe that the deficit countries should take the corrective steps. This view, of course, is nonsense in a worldwide system of fixed exchange rates. Some currencies are overvalued because some other currencies are undervalued. In fact, the two statements mean exactly the same thing. The other reason why surplus countries resist upward revaluations is that such actions would make their products more expensive to foreigners and thus cut into their export sales. This, in fact, is the main reason why China maintains an undervalued currency despite the protestations of many other nations. China’s leaders believe that vibrant export industries are the key to growth and development. The balance of payments comes in two main parts. The current account totes up exports and imports of goods and services, cross-border payments of interest and dividends, and cross-border gifts. It is close, both conceptually and numerically, to what we have called net exports (X 2 IM) in previous chapters. The United States has been running extremely large current account deficits for years. The current account represents only one part of our balance of payments, for it leaves out all purchases and sales of assets. Purchases of U.S. assets by foreigners bring foreign currency to the United States, and purchases of foreign assets cost us foreign currency. Netting the capital flows in each direction gives us our surplus or deficit on capital account. In recent years, this part of our balance of payments has registered persistently large surpluses as foreigners have acquired massive amounts of U.S. assets. In what sense, then, does the overall balance of payments balance? There are two possibilities. If the exchange rate is floating, all private transactions—current account plus capital account—must add up to zero because dollars purchased equals dollars sold. But if, instead, the exchange rate is fixed, as shown in Figures 5 and 6, the two accounts need not balance one another. Government purchases or sales of foreign currency make up the surplus or deficit in the overall balance of payments.

Price of a Yuan (in dollars)

E

$0.15

0.12

S

F I GURE 6 A Balance of Payments Surplus

The current account balance includes international purchases and sales of goods and services, cross-border interest and dividend payments, and cross-border gifts to and from both private individuals and governments. It is approximately the same as net exports. The capital account balance includes purchases and sales of financial assets to and from citizens and companies of other countries.

A BIT OF HISTORY: THE GOLD STANDARD AND THE BRETTON WOODS SYSTEM It is difficult to find examples of strictly fixed exchange rates in the historical record. About the only time exchange rates were truly fixed was under the old gold standard, at least when it was practiced in its ideal form.5 5 As a matter of fact, although the gold standard lasted (on and off) for hundreds of years, it was rarely practiced in its ideal form. Except for a brief period of fixed exchange rates in the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries, governments periodically adjusted exchange rates even under the gold standard.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

The International Monetary System: Order or Disorder?

755

Under the gold standard, governments maintained fixed exchange rates by an automatic equilibrating mechanism that went something like this: All currencies were defined in terms of gold; indeed, some were actually made of gold. When a nation ran a balance of payments deficit, it had to sell gold to finance the deficit. Because the domestic money supply was based on gold, losing gold to foreigners meant that the money supply fell automatically, thus raising interest rates. Those higher interest rates attracted foreign capital. At the same time, this restrictive “monetary policy” pulled down output and prices, which discouraged imports and encouraged exports. The balance of payments problem quickly rectified itself. This automatic adjustment process meant, however, that under the gold standard no nation had control of its domestic monetary policy. An analogous problem arises in any system of fixed exchange rates, regardless of whether it makes use of gold:

The gold standard is a way to fix exchange rates by defining each participating currency in terms of gold and allowing holders of each participating currency to convert that currency into gold.

Chapter 35

The Classical Gold Standard

Under fixed exchange rates, monetary policy must be dedicated to pegging the exchange rate. It cannot, therefore, be used to manage aggregate demand.

The gold standard posed one other serious difficulty: The world’s commerce was at the mercy of gold discoveries. Major gold finds would mean higher prices and booming economic conditions, through the standard monetary-policy mechanisms that we studied in earlier chapters. But when the supply of gold failed to keep pace with growth of the world economy, prices had to fall in the long run and employment had to fall in the short run.

The Bretton Woods System The gold standard collapsed for good amid the financial chaos of the Great Depression of the 1930s and World War II. Without it, the world struggled through a serious breakdown in international trade. As the war drew to a close, representatives of the industrial nations, including John Maynard Keynes of Great Britain, met at a hotel in Bretton Woods, New Hampshire, to devise a stable monetary environment that would enable world trade to resume. Because the United States held the lion’s share of the world’s reserves at the time, these officials naturally turned to the dollar as the basis for the new international economic order. The Bretton Woods agreements reestablished fixed exchange rates based on the free convertibility of the U.S. dollar into gold. The United States agreed to buy or sell gold to maintain the $35 per ounce price that President Franklin Roosevelt had established in 1933. The other signatory nations, which had almost no gold in any case, agreed to buy and sell dollars to maintain their exchange rates at agreed-upon levels. The Bretton Woods system succeeded in refixing exchange rates and restoring world trade—two notable achievements. But it also displayed the flaws of any fixed exchange rate system. Changes in exchange rates were permitted only as a last resort—which, in practice, came to mean that the country had a chronic deficit in the balance of payments of sizable proportions. Such nations were allowed to devalue their currencies relative to the dollar. So the system was not really one of fixed exchange rates but, rather, one in which rates were “fixed until further notice.” Because devaluations came only after a long run of balance of payments deficits had depleted the country’s reserves, these devaluations often could be clearly foreseen and normally had to be large. Speculators therefore saw glowing opportunities for profit and would “attack” weak currencies with waves of selling. A second problem arose from the asymmetry mentioned earlier: Deficit nations could be forced to devalue, whereas surplus nations could resist upward revaluations. Because the value of the U.S. dollar was fixed in terms of gold, the United States was the one nation in the world that had no way to devalue its currency. The only way the dollar could fall was if the surplus nations would revalue their currencies upward. They did not adjust frequently enough, though, so the United States developed an overvalued currency and chronic balance of payments deficits. The overvalued dollar finally destroyed the Bretton Woods system in 1971, when President Richard Nixon unilaterally ended the game by announcing that the United States would no longer buy or sell gold at $35 per ounce. Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

756

Part 8

The United States in the World Economy

ADJUSTMENT MECHANISMS UNDER FIXED EXCHANGE RATES Under the Bretton Woods system, devaluation was viewed as a last resort, to be used only after other methods of adjusting to payments imbalances had failed. What were these other methods? We encountered most of them in our earlier discussion of exchange rate determination in free markets. Any factor that increases the demand for, say, Argentine pesos or that reduces the supply will push the value of the peso upward—if it is free to adjust. But if the exchange rate is pegged, the balance of payments deficit will shrink instead. (Try this for yourself using Figure 5.) Recalling our earlier discussion of the factors that underlie the demand and supply curves, we see that one way a nation can shrink its balance of payments deficit is to reduce its aggregate demand, thereby discouraging imports and cutting down its demand for foreign currency. Another is to lower its rate of inflation, thereby encouraging exports and discouraging imports. Finally, it can raise its interest rates to attract more foreign capital. In other words, deficit nations are expected to follow restrictive monetary and fiscal policies voluntarily, just as they would have done automatically under the classical gold standard. However, just as under the gold standard, this medicine is often unpalatable. A surplus nation could, of course, take the opposite measures: pursuing expansionary monetary and fiscal policies to increase economic growth and lower interest rates. By increasing the supply of the country’s currency and reducing the demand for it, such actions would reduce that nation’s balance of payments surplus. But surplus countries often do not relish the inflation that accompanies expansionary policies, and so, once again, they leave the burden of adjustment to the deficit nations. The general point about fixed exchange rates is that Under a system of fixed exchange rates, a country’s government loses some control over its domestic economy. Sometimes balance of payments considerations may force it to contract its economy in order to cut down its demand for foreign currency, even though domestic needs call for expansion. At other times, the domestic economy may need to be reined in, but balance of payments considerations suggest expansion.

That was certainly the case in Argentina in 2002, when interest rates soared to attract foreign capital and the government pursued contractionary fiscal policies to curb the country’s appetite for imports. Both contributed to a long and deep recession. Argentina took the bitter medicine needed to defend its fixed exchange rate for quite a while. However, high unemployment eventually led to riots in the streets, toppled the government, and persuaded the Argentine authorities to abandon the fixed exchange rate.

SOURCE: © The New Yorker Collection 1971, Ed Fisher from cartoonbank.com. All Rights Reserved.

WHY TRY TO FIX EXCHANGE RATES?

“Then it’s agreed. Until the dollar firms up, we let the clamshell float.”

In view of these and other problems with fixed exchange rates, why did the international financial community work so hard to maintain them for so many years? And why do some nations today still fix their exchange rates? The answer is that floating exchange rates also pose problems. Chief among these worries is the possibility that freely floating rates might prove to be highly variable rates, thereby adding an unwanted element of risk to foreign trade. For example, if the exchange rate is $1.50 to the euro, then a Parisian dress priced at 400 euros will cost $600. Should the euro appreciate to $1.75, that same dress would cost $700. An American department store thinking of buying the dress may need to place its order far in advance and will want to know the cost in dollars. It may be worried about the possibility that the value of the euro will rise, making the dress cost more than $600. And such worries might inhibit trade. There are two responses to this concern. First, freely floating rates might prove to be fairly stable in practice. Prices of most ordinary goods and services, for example,

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 35

The International Monetary System: Order or Disorder?

are determined by supply and demand in free markets and do not fluctuate unduly. Unfortunately, experience since 1973 has dashed this hope. Exchange rates have proved to be extremely volatile, which is why some observers now favor greater fixity in exchange rates. A second possibility is that speculators might relieve business firms of exchange rate risks—for a fee, of course. Consider the department store example. If each euro costs $1.50 today, the department store manager can assure herself of paying exactly $600 for the dress several months from now by arranging for a speculator to deliver 400 euros to her at $1.50 per euro on the day she needs them. If the euro appreciates in the interim, the speculator, not the department store, will take the financial beating. Of course, if the euro depreciates, the speculator will pocket the profits. Thus, speculators play an important role in a system of floating exchange rates. The widespread fears that speculative activity in free markets will lead to wild gyrations in prices, although occasionally valid, are often unfounded. The reason is simple. To make profits, international currency speculators must buy a currency when its value is low (thus helping to support the currency by pushing up its demand curve) and sell it when its value is high (thus holding down the price by adding to the supply curve). This means that successful speculators must come into the market as buyers when demand is weak (or when supply is strong) and come in as sellers when demand is strong (or supply is scant). In doing so, they help limit price fluctuations. Looked at the other way around, speculators can destabilize prices only if they are systematically willing to lose money.6

Notice the stark—and ironic—contrast to the system of fixed exchange rates in which speculation often leads to wild “runs” on currencies that are on the verge of devaluation— as happened in Mexico in 1995, several Southeast Asian countries in 1997–1998, Brazil in 1999, and Argentina in 2001. Speculative activity, which may well be destabilizing under fixed rates, is more likely to be stabilizing under floating rates.7 We do not mean to imply that speculation makes floating rates trouble-free. At the very least, speculators will demand a fee for their services—a fee that adds to the costs of trading across national borders. In addition, speculators will not assume all exchange rate risks. For example, few contracts on foreign currencies last more than, say, a year or two. Thus, a business cannot easily protect itself from exchange rate changes over periods of many years. Finally, speculative markets can and do get carried away from time to time, moving currency rates in ways that are difficult to understand, that frustrate the intentions of governments, and that devastate some people—as happened in Mexico in 1995 and in Southeast Asia in 1997. Despite all of these problems, international trade has flourished under floating exchange rates. So perhaps exchange rate risk is not as burdensome as some people think.

THE CURRENT “NONSYSTEM” The international financial system today is an eclectic blend of fixed and floating exchange rates, with no grand organizing principle. Indeed, it is so diverse that it is often called a “nonsystem.” Some currencies are still pegged in the old Bretton Woods manner. The most prominent example is probably China, which for years maintained a fixed value for its currency (the yuan) by standing ready to buy or sell U.S. dollars as necessary. Over the years, the pegging policy required the Chinese to buy dollars steadily and in large volume. So China has acquired over $2 trillion in foreign currency reserves.

See Test Yourself Question 4 at the end of the chapter. After their respective currency crises in 1995 and 1999, both Mexico and Brazil floated their currencies. Each weathered the subsequent international financial storms rather nicely. But Argentina, with its fixed exchange rate, struggled. 6 7

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

757

758

Part 8

The United States in the World Economy

A few small countries, such as Panama and Ecuador, have taken the more extreme step of actually adopting the U.S. dollar as their domestic currencies. Other nations tie their currencies to a hypothetical “basket” of several foreign currencies, rather than to just one. More nations, however, let their exchange rates float, although not always freely. Such floating rates change slightly on a day-to-day basis, and market forces determine the basic trends, up or down. But governments do not hesitate to intervene to moderate exchange movements whenever they feel such actions are appropriate. Typically, interventions are aimed at ironing out what are deemed to be transitory fluctuations, but sometimes central banks oppose basic exchange rate trends. For example, the Federal Reserve and other central banks sold dollars aggressively in 1985 to push the dollar down and then bought dollars in 1994 and 1995 to push the dollar up. As we will discuss in the next chapter, the Japanese acquired hundreds of billions of dollars earlier in this decade trying to prevent the yen from floating up too much. The terms dirty float or managed float have been coined to describe this mongrel system.

The Role of the IMF The International Monetary Fund (IMF), which was established at Bretton Woods in 1944, examines the economies of all its member nations on a regular basis. When a country runs into serious financial difficulties, it may turn to the Fund for financial assistance. The IMF typically provides loans, but with many strings attached. For example, if the country has a large current account deficit—as is normally the case when countries come to the IMF— the Fund will typically insist on contractionary fiscal and monetary policies to curb the country’s appetite for imports. Often, this mandate spells recession. During the 1990s, the IMF found itself at the epicenter of a series of very visible economic crises: in Mexico in 1995, in Southeast Asia in 1997, in Russia in 1998, and in Brazil in 1999. In 2001, Turkey and Argentina ran into trouble and appealed to the IMF for help. Although each case was different, they shared some common elements. Most of these crises were precipitated by the collapse of a fixed exchange rate pegged to the U.S. dollar. In each case, the currency plummeted, with ruinous consequences. Questions were raised about the country’s ability to pay its bills. In each case, the IMF arrived on the scene with lots of money and lots of advice, determined to stave off default. In the end, each country suffered through a severe recession—or worse. The IMF’s increased visibility naturally brought it increased criticism. Some critics complained that the Fund set excessively strict conditions on its client states, requiring them, for example, to cut their government budgets and raise interest rates during recessions—which made bad economic situations even worse. Other critics worried that the Fund was serving as a bill collector for banks and other financial institutions from the United States and other rich countries. Because the banks loaned money irresponsibly, these critics argued, they deserved to lose some of it. By bailing them out of their losses, the IMF simply encouraged more reckless behavior in the future. Numerous suggestions for reform were offered, but few were adopted. Then the debate over the IMF went quiet for several years, for a very simple reason: The world economy improved, and most of the nations that formerly needed IMF help no longer required it. The prominence of the IMF faded remarkably—but, as it turned out, temporarily. When the Great Recession went global in late 2008, a long list of countries clamored for IMF assistance. Now the IMFs procedures are under scrutiny once again.

The Volatile Dollar As mentioned earlier, floating exchange rates have proven to be volatile exchange rates. No currency illustrates this point better than the U.S. dollar (see Figure 7). As Table 1 showed, in July 1980 a U.S. dollar bought less than 2 German marks, about 4 French francs, and about 830 Italian lire. Then it started rising like a rocket (see Figure 7). By the time it peaked in February 1985, the mighty dollar could buy more than 3 German marks,

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

759

The International Monetary System: Order or Disorder?

Chapter 35

FI GURE 7 The Ups and Downs of the Dollar

Exchange Rate

SOURCE: Federal Reserve System.

140 120 100 80 60 0 1974

1978

1982

1986

1990

1994

1998

2002

2006

2010

Years

NOTE: Exchange rate relative to major currencies, March 1973 5 100.

about 10 French francs, and more than 2,000 Italian lire. Such major currency changes affect world trade dramatically. The rising dollar was a blessing to Americans who traveled abroad or who bought foreign goods—because foreign prices, when translated to dollars by the exchange rate, looked cheap to Americans.8 But the arithmetic worked just the other way around for U.S. firms seeking to sell their goods abroad; foreign buyers found everything American very expensive.9 It was no surprise, therefore, that as the dollar climbed our exports fell, our imports rose, and many of our leading manufacturing industries were decimated by foreign competition. An expensive currency, Americans came to learn, is a mixed blessing. From early 1985 until early 1988, the value of the dollar fell even faster than it had risen. The cheaper dollar curbed American appetites for imports and alleviated the plight of our export industries, many of which boomed. However, rising prices for imported goods and foreign vacations were a source of consternation to many American consumers. Over the following seven years, the overall value of the dollar did not change very much—although there was a small downward drift. Then, in the spring of 1995, the dollar began another sizable ascent which lasted until early 2002. After that, as we noted earlier in this chapter, the dollar fell for about two years and then was pretty stable until 2007–2008, when it tumbled again before righting itself. All in all, the behavior of the dollar has been anything but boring. Fortunes have been made and lost speculating on what it will do next.

The Birth and Adolescence of the Euro As noted earlier, floating exchange rates are no panacea. One particular problem confronted the members of the European Union (EU). As part of their long-range goal to create a unified market like that of the United States, they perceived a need to establish a single currency for all member countries—a monetary union. The process of convergence to a single currency took place in steps, more or less as prescribed by the Treaty of Maastricht (1992), over a period of years. Member nations encountered a number of obstacles along the way. But to the surprise of many skeptics, all such obstacles were overcome, and the euro became a reality on schedule. Electronic and checking transactions in 11 EU nations were denominated in euros rather than in national currencies in 1999, euro coins and paper money were introduced successfully in 2002, and

8 EXERCISE: How much does a 100-euro hotel room in Paris cost in dollars when the euro is worth $1.25? $1? 80 cents? 9 EXERCISE: How much does a $55 American camera cost a German consumer when the euro is worth $1.20? $1? 80 cents?

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Part 8

The United States in the World Economy

the number of participating countries has since risen in stages to 16. All of these transformations went remarkably smoothly. That said, the euro did not spring into life as a fully grown adult. In its earlier years, there were still plenty of doubters. And perhaps for that reason, the new European currency, which made its debut at $1.18 in January 1999, fell to a low point of $0.83 in October 2000—a stunning 30 percent decline in less than two years. After that, however, the euro climbed in value relative to the dollar for years, reaching a high near $1.60 in 2008, before falling again. The establishment of the euro was a great economic experiment that marked a giant step beyond merely fixing exchange rates. A government can end a fixed exchange rate regime at any time. And, as we have seen, speculators sometimes break fixed exchange rates even when governments want to maintain them. But the single European currency was created by an international treaty and is more or less invulnerable to speculative attack because it abolished exchange rates among the participating nations. Just as there has long been no exchange rate between New York and New Jersey, now there is no exchange rate between Germany and France. Monetary unions may create other problems, but exchange rate instability is not one of them. Instead, some countries like Greece are experiencing trouble keeping up with the rest.

PUZZLE RESOLVED:

WHY THE DOLLAR ROSE, THEN FELL, THEN ROSE

What we have learned in this chapter helps us understand what brought the dollar down between 2002 and 2004, and then again in 2007 and 2008. The story actually begins well before that. During the Great Boom of the late 1990s, the United States was the place to invest. Funds poured in from all over the world to purchase American stocks, American bonds, and even American companies—especially in the information technology field. Yahoo! was indeed a fitting name for the age. As we have learned in this chapter, the rising demand for U.S. assets should have bid up the price of U.S. currency—and it did (see Figure 7 again). But the soaring dollar sowed the seeds of its own destruction. Two of its major effects were (a) to make U.S. goods and services look much more expensive to potential buyers abroad and (b) to make foreign goods look much cheaper to Americans. So our imports grew much faster than our exports. In brief, we developed a huge current account deficit (which is roughly exports minus imports) to match our large capital account surplus. The Internet bubble, of course, started to burst in 2000, pulling the stock market down with it. Then the September 11, 2001, terrorist attacks raised doubts about the strength of the U.S. economy. For these and other reasons, foreign investors apparently began to question the wisdom of holding so “His mood is pegged to the dollar” many American assets. With the U.S. current account still deeply in the red, and the foreign demand for U.S. capital sagging, there was only one way for the (freely floating) dollar to go: down. And so it did. The early stages of the financial crisis continued this trend, and the dollar sank to new lows in 2008. The crisis was, after all, made in America. Then, something surprising happened: The dollar actually rose sharply from July 2008 until March 2009. Why? We have learned the reason in this chapter. When the financial crisis reached its most acute stages, investors all over the world sought the safety of U.S. assets, especially U.S. Treasury debt. SOURCE: © The New Yorker Collection, 2002 Mick Stevens from cartoonbank.com. All rights reserved.

760

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 35

761

The International Monetary System: Order or Disorder?

| SUMMARY | 1. Exchange rates state the value of one currency in terms of other currencies and thus translate one country’s prices into the currencies of other nations. Exchange rates therefore influence patterns of world trade.

supplied. In the first case, the country is suffering from a balance of payments deficit because of its overvalued currency. In the second case, an undervalued currency has given it a balance of payments surplus.

2. If governments do not interfere by buying or selling their currencies, exchange rates will be determined in free markets by the usual laws of supply and demand. Such a system is said to be based on floating exchange rates.

9. The gold standard was a system of fixed exchange rates in which the value of every nation’s currency was fixed in terms of gold. This system created problems because nations could not control their own money supplies and because the world could not control the total supply of gold.

3. Demand for a nation’s currency is derived from foreigners’ desires to purchase that country’s goods and services or to invest in its assets. Under floating rates, anything that increases the demand for a nation’s currency will cause its exchange rate to appreciate.

10. After World War II, the gold standard was replaced by the Bretton Woods system, in which exchange rates were fixed in terms of U.S. dollars and the dollar was in turn tied to gold. This system broke up in 1971, when the dollar became chronically overvalued.

4. Supply of a nation’s currency is derived from the desire of that country’s citizens to purchase foreign goods and services or to invest in foreign assets. Under floating rates, anything that increases the supply of a nation’s currency will cause its exchange rate to depreciate.

11. Since 1971, the world has moved toward a system of relatively free exchange rates, but with plenty of exceptions. We now have a thoroughly mixed system of “dirty” or “managed” floating, which continues to evolve and adapt.

5. Purchasing-power parity plays a major role in longrun exchange rate movements. The purchasing-power parity theory states that relative price levels in any two countries determine the exchange rate between their currencies. Therefore, countries with relatively low inflation rates normally will have appreciating currencies.

12. Floating rates are not without their problems. For example, importers and exporters justifiably worry about fluctuations in exchange rates. 13. Under floating exchange rates, investors who speculate on international currency values provide a valuable service by assuming the risks of those who do not wish to speculate. Normally, speculators stabilize rather than destabilize exchange rates, because that is how they make profits.

6. Over shorter periods, however, purchasing-power parity has little influence over exchange rate movements. The pace of economic activity and, especially, the level of interest rates exert greater influences.

14. The value of the U.S. dollar has been volatile. It rose dramatically from 1980 to 1985, making our imports cheaper and our exports more expensive. From 1985 to 1988, the dollar tumbled, which had precisely the reverse effects. Then the dollar climbed again between 1995 and 2002, leading once again to a large trade imbalance. From 2002 to 2004, and then again in 2007–2008, the dollar fell further, before recovering in 2008–2010.

7. Capital movements are typically the dominant factor in determining exchange rates in the short and medium runs. A nation that offers international investors higher interest rates, or better prospective returns on investments, will typically see its currency appreciate. 8. An exchange rate can be fixed at a nonequilibrium level if the government is willing and able to mop up any excess of quantity supplied over quantity demanded or provide any excess of quantity demanded over quantity

15. The European Union has established a single currency, the euro, for most of its member nations.

| KEY TERMS | appreciation

746

depreciation

balance of payments deficit and surplus 753

devaluation

Bretton Woods system

exchange rate

capital account current account

754 754

755

746

gold standard

747

dirty or managed float

758

746

fixed exchange rates

753

floating exchange rates

747

755

International Monetary Fund (IMF) 758 purchasing-power parity theory 751 revaluation

747

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

762

Part 8

The United States in the World Economy

| TEST YOURSELF | 1. Use supply and demand diagrams to analyze the effect of the following actions on the exchange rate between the dollar and the yen: a. Japan opens its domestic markets to more foreign competition. b. Investors come to believe that values on the Tokyo stock market will fall. c. The Federal Reserve cuts interest rates in the United States. d. The U.S. government, to help settle the problems of the Middle East, gives huge amounts of foreign aid to Israel and her Arab neighbors. e. The United States has a recession while Japan booms. f. Inflation in the United States exceeds that in Japan. 2. For each of the following transactions, indicate how it would affect the U.S. balance of payments if exchange rates were fixed:

a. You spent the summer traveling in Europe. b. Your uncle in Canada sent you $20 as a birthday present. c. You bought a new Honda, made in Japan. d. You bought a new Honda, made in Ohio. e. You sold some stock you own on the Tokyo Stock Exchange. 3. Suppose each of the transactions listed in Test Yourself Question 2 was done by many Americans. Indicate how each would affect the international value of the dollar if exchange rates were floating. 4. We learned in this chapter that successful speculators buy a currency when demand is weak and sell it when demand is strong. Use supply and demand diagrams for two different periods (one with weak demand, the other with strong demand) to show why this activity will limit price fluctuations.

| DISCUSSION QUESTIONS | 1. What items do you own or routinely consume that are produced abroad? From what countries do these items come? Suppose Americans decided to buy fewer of these things. How would that affect the exchange rates between the dollar and these currencies? 2. If the dollar appreciates relative to the euro, will the German camera you have wanted become more or less expensive? What effect do you imagine this change will have on American demand for German cameras? Does the American demand curve for euros, therefore, slope upward or downward? Explain. 3. During the first half of the 1980s, inflation in (West) Germany was consistently lower than that in the United States. What, then, does the purchasing-power parity theory predict should have happened to the exchange rate between the mark and the dollar between 1980 and 1985? (Look at Table 1 to see what actually happened.) 4. How are the problems of a country faced with a balance of payments deficit similar to those posed by a government regulation that holds the price of milk above the equilibrium level? (Hint: Think of each in terms of a supply-demand diagram.)

6. Explain why the members of the Bretton Woods conference in 1944 wanted to establish a system of fixed exchange rates. What flaw led to the ultimate breakdown of the system in 1971? 7. Suppose you want to reserve a hotel room in London for the coming summer but are worried that the value of the pound may rise between now and then, making the room too expensive for your budget. Explain how a speculator could relieve you of this worry. (Don’t actually try it—speculators deal only in very large sums!) 8. In 2003 and 2004, market forces raised the international value of the Japanese yen. Why do you think the government of Japan was unhappy about this currency appreciation? (Hint: Japan was trying to emerge from a recession at the time.) If they wanted to stop the yen’s appreciation, what actions could the Bank of Japan (Japan’s central bank) and the Federal Reserve have taken? Why might the central banks have failed in this attempt?

5. Under the old gold standard, what do you think happened to world prices when a huge gold strike occurred in California in 1849? What do you think happened when the world went without any important new gold strikes for 20 years or so?

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Exchange Rates and the Macroeconomy No man is an island, entire of itself. JOHN D ONNE

O

ne prominent aspect of globalization is that economic events that originate in one country reverberate quickly around the globe, sometimes at the speed of electricity. A stunning example arose in 2007, after the housing boom ended in the United States. A number of so-called subprime mortgages (meaning mortgages granted to people with questionable credit) started to go bad. As the trickle of defaults turned into a flood, it triggered a worldwide financial crisis when several financial businesses in—of all places—France and Germany ran into serious trouble. Why there? It turned out that these institutions, thousands of miles away, had invested heavily in U.S. subprime mortgages. It is indeed a small world. This was just one example of a general phenomenon. Fluctuations in foreign growth, inflation, and interest rates profoundly affect the U.S. economy, and economic events that originate in our country reverberate around the globe. Anyone who ignores these international linkages cannot hope to understand how the modern world economy works. The macroeconomic model we developed in earlier chapters does a bit of that, but not enough because it ignores such crucial influences as exchange rates and international financial movements. The previous chapter showed how major macroeconomic variables such as gross domestic product (GDP), prices, and interest rates affect exchange rates. In this chapter, we complete the circle by studying how changes in the exchange rate affect the domestic economy. Then we bring international capital flows into the picture and learn how monetary and fiscal policy work in an open economy. In particular, we build a model suitable for a large open economy with substantial capital flows and a floating exchange rate—in short, a model meant to resemble the contemporary United States, which is indeed not “an island, entire of itself.”

An open economy is one that trades with other nations in goods and services, and perhaps also trades in financial assets.

C O N T E N T S ISSUE: SHOULD THE U.S. GOVERNMENT TRY TO STOP THE DOLLAR FROM FALLING?

FISCAL AND MONETARY POLICIES IN AN OPEN ECONOMY

INTERNATIONAL TRADE, EXCHANGE RATES, AND AGGREGATE DEMAND

Fiscal Policy Revisited Monetary Policy Revisited

Relative Prices, Exports, and Imports The Effects of Changes in Exchange Rates

INTERNATIONAL ASPECTS OF DEFICIT REDUCTION

AGGREGATE SUPPLY IN AN OPEN ECONOMY

The Loose Link between the Budget Deficit and the Trade Deficit

THE MACROECONOMIC EFFECTS OF EXCHANGE RATES Interest Rates and International Capital Flows

SHOULD WE WORRY ABOUT THE TRADE DEFICIT?

ON CURING THE TRADE DEFICIT Change the Mix of Fiscal and Monetary Policy More Rapid Economic Growth Abroad Raise Domestic Saving or Reduce Domestic Investment Protectionism

CONCLUSION: NO NATION IS AN ISLAND ISSUE REVISITED: SHOULD THE UNITED STATES LET THE DOLLAR FALL?

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

764

Part 8

The United States in the World Economy

ISSUE:

SHOULD THE U.S. GOVERNMENT TRY TO STOP THE DOLLAR FROM FALLING?

For years before it actually started happening, economists predicted that America’s huge trade deficits would eventually drive the international value of the U.S. dollar down. In early 2002, this prophecy finally started to come true. However, the dollar declined only for about two years, before stabilizing at the end of 2004. Then, after a two-year hiatus, dollar depreciation resumed in 2007 and into 2008, when the greenback tumbled sharply. This time the dollar’s weakness even grabbed the headlines—a rare event in our country. People looked on in amazement as the British pound topped $2, the euro soared above $1.50, and the Canadian dollar became worth more than the U.S. dollar for the first time since the 1970s. (Since then the dollar has gained ground again.) Some observers were alarmed by the falling dollar. They urged the United States government to fight the dollar’s decline. Both European and Japanese businesspeople complained that they were losing export markets to the Americans, which was damaging European and Japanese growth. But there was also a bright side: The massive U.S. trade deficit at last started to shrink. Weighing the pros and cons, the U.S. government decided that currency values should remain “flexible,” that is, determined in world markets by the forces of supply and demand that we studied in the previous chapter. It refused to intervene to try to stop the dollar from falling. Who was right? We will examine this question as the chapter progresses.

INTERNATIONAL TRADE, EXCHANGE RATES, AND AGGREGATE DEMAND

F I GURE 1 The Effects of Higher Net Exports

D1

We know from earlier chapters that a country’s net exports, X 2 IM, are one component of its aggregate demand, C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM). It follows that an autonomous increase in exports or decrease in imports has a multiplier effect on the economy, just like an increase in consumption, investment, or government purchases.1 Figure 1 depicts this conclusion on an aggregate demand-and-supply diagram. A rise in net exports shifts the aggregate demand curve outward to the right, pushing equilibrium from point A to point B. Both GDP and the price level therefore rise. What forces might make net exports increase? One factor mentioned in Chapter 25 was a rise in foreign incomes. If foreign economies boom, their citizens are likely to spend more on a wide variety of products, some of which will be American exports. Thus, Figure 1 illustrates the effect on the U.S. economy of more rapid growth in foreign countries. By like reasoning, a recession abroad would reduce U.S. exports and shift the U.S. aggregate demand curve inward. Thus, as we learned in Chapter 26: S

D0

Booms or recessions in one country tend to be transmitted to other countries through international trade in goods and services.

Price Level

B

D1

A

D0

S

Real GDP

This phenomenon was illustrated painfully in 2009 when the worldwide recession led to a collapse of exports in virtually every country, thereby magnifying the reduction in global aggregate demand. A second important determinant of net exports was mentioned in Chapter 25, but not discussed in depth there: the relative prices of foreign and domestic goods. The idea is a simple application of the law of demand. Namely, if the prices of the goods of Country X rise, people everywhere will tend to buy fewer of them—and

Chapter 26's appendix showed that international trade lowers the numerical value of the multiplier. Autonomous changes in C, I, G, and (X 2 IM) all have the same multiplier.

1

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 36

Exchange Rates and the Macroeconomy

765

more of the goods of Country Y. As we will see next, this simple idea holds the key to understanding how exchange rates affect international trade.

Relative Prices, Exports, and Imports First assume—just for this short section—that exchange rates are fixed. Think about what happens if the prices of American goods fall while, say, Japanese prices are constant. With U.S. products now less expensive relative to Japanese products, both Japanese and American consumers will buy more American goods and fewer Japanese goods. That means America’s exports will rise and its imports will fall, thus adding to aggregate demand in the United States. Conversely, a rise in American prices (relative to Japanese prices) will decrease U.S. net exports and aggregate demand. Thus: A fall in the relative prices of a country’s exports tends to increase that country’s net exports and, thereby, to raise its real GDP. Analogously, a rise in the relative prices of a country’s exports will decrease that country’s net exports and GDP.

Precisely the same logic applies to changes in Japanese prices. If Japanese prices rise, Americans will export more to and import less from Japan. So X 2 IM in the United States will rise, boosting GDP here. Figure 1 applies to this case without change. By similar reasoning, falling Japanese prices decrease U.S. net exports and depress our economy. Thus: Price increases for foreign products raise a country’s net exports and hence its GDP. Price decreases for foreign products have the opposite effects.

The Effects of Changes in Exchange Rates From here, it is simple to figure out how changes in exchange rates affect a country’s net exports, because currency appreciations or depreciations change international relative prices. Recall that the basic role of an exchange rate is to convert one country’s prices into another country’s TABLE 1 currency. Table 1 uses two examples of U.S.–Japanese Exchange Rates and Home Currency Prices trade to remind us of this role. Suppose the dollar de¥30,000 Japanese $1,000 U.S. preciates from 120 yen to 100 yen. From the American TV Set Home Computer consumer’s viewpoint, a television set that costs Exchange Price in Price in Price in Price in ¥30,000 in Japan goes up in price from $250 (that is, Rate Japan the U.S. the U.S. Japan 30,000/120) to $300 (that is, 30,000/100). To Americans, $1 5 120 yen ¥30,000 $250 $1,000 ¥120,000 it is as if Japanese manufacturers raised TV prices by 1 5 100 yen 30,000 300 1,000 100,000 20 percent. Naturally, Americans will react by purchasing fewer Japanese products, so American imports decline. Now consider the implications for Japanese consumers interested in buying American personal computers that cost $1,000. When the dollar falls from 120 yen to 100 yen, they see the price of these computers falling from ¥120,000 to ¥100,000. To them, it is as if American producers had offered a 16.7 percent markdown. Under such circumstances, we expect U.S. sales to the Japanese to rise, so U.S. exports should increase. Putting these two findings together, we conclude that A currency depreciation should raise net exports and therefore increase aggregate demand. Conversely, a currency appreciation should reduce net exports and therefore decrease aggregate demand.

The aggregate supply-and-demand diagram in Figure 2 illustrates this conclusion. If the currency depreciates, net exports rise and the aggregate demand curve shifts outward from D0D0 to D1D1. Both prices and output rise as the economy’s equilibrium moves from E0 to E1. If the currency appreciates instead, everything operates in reverse: net exports fall, the aggregate demand curve shifts inward to D2D2, and both prices and output decline.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

766

The United States in the World Economy

Part 8

F I GURE 2 The Effects of Exchange Rate Changes on Aggregate Demand D1 S D0 E1 D2 Price Level

(depreciation) E0 (appreciation)

D1

E2 D0 D2

This simple analysis helps us understand why the U.S. trade deficit grew so enormously in the late 1990s and early 2000s and has fallen a bit recently. We learned in the previous chapter that the international value of the dollar began to climb in 1995. According to the reasoning we have just completed, within a few years such an appreciation of the dollar should have boosted U.S. imports and damaged U.S. exports. That is precisely what happened. In constant dollars, American imports soared by over 40 percent between 1997 and 2002, whereas American exports rose by only 7 percent. The result was that a $105 billion real net export deficit in 1997 turned into a monumental $471 billion deficit by 2002. Then, the dollar’s decline helped push the trade deficit down from a record $625 billion in 2006 to “only” $556 billion in 2007.

S

Real GDP

AGGREGATE SUPPLY IN AN OPEN ECONOMY So far we have concluded that a currency depreciation increases aggregate demand and that a currency appreciation decreases it. To complete our model of macroeconomics in an open economy, we must turn to the implications of international trade for aggregate supply. Part of the story is already familiar. We know from previous chapters that the United States, like all economies, purchases some of its productive inputs from abroad. Oil is by far the most prominent example, but we also rely on foreign suppliers for metals such as titanium, raw agricultural products such as coffee beans, and thousands of other items used by American industry. When the dollar depreciates, all of these imported inputs cost more in U.S. dollars—just as if foreign prices had risen. The consequence is clear: With imported inputs more expensive, American firms will be forced to charge higher prices at any given level of output. Graphically, this means that the aggregate supply curve will shift upward (or inward to the left).

F I GURE 3

When the dollar depreciates, the prices of imported inputs rise. The U.S. aggregate supply curve therefore shifts inward, pushing up the prices of American-made goods and services. By exactly analogous reasoning, an appreciation of the dollar makes imported inputs cheaper and shifts the U.S. aggregate supply curve outward, thus pushing American prices down. S1 (depreciation) S0 (See Figure 3.)

The Effects of Exchange Rate Changes on Aggregate Supply

D

Price Level

S2 (appreciation) E1 E0 E2 S1 S0 S2 D Real GDP

Beyond this, a depreciating dollar has additional inflationary effects that do not even show up on an aggregate demand-and-supply diagram, because the price level depicted on the vertical axis is the price of gross domestic product. Most obviously, prices of imported goods are included in U.S. price indexes like the Consumer Price Index (CPI). So when the dollar prices of Japanese cars, French wine, and Swiss watches increase, the CPI goes up even if no American prices rise. For this and other reasons, the inflationary impact of a dollar depreciation on consumer prices is greater than that indicated by Figure 3.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 36

767

Exchange Rates and the Macroeconomy

THE MACROECONOMIC EFFECTS OF EXCHANGE RATES Let us now put aggregate demand and aggregate supply together and think through the macroeconomic effects of changes in exchange rates. First, suppose the international value of the dollar falls. Referring back to the blue lines in Figures 2 and 3, we see that this depreciation will shift the aggregate demand curve outward and the aggregate supply curve inward. The result, as Figure 4 shows, is that the U.S. price level certainly rises. But whether real GDP rises or falls depends on whether the supply or demand shift is the dominant influence. The evidence strongly suggests that aggregate demand shifts are usually larger, so we expect GDP to rise. Hence:

FI GURE 4 The Effects of a Currency Depreciation

S1 D1

S0

Price Level

D0

A currency depreciation is inflationary and probably also expansionary.

A E

A currency appreciation is disinflationary and probably also contractionary.

This analysis explains why many economists and financial experts cringed a bit when the yen and the euro appreciated relative to the dollar in 2002–2004 and then again in 2007. Japan, in particular, was just emerging from deflation, and growth there was mediocre. The last thing it needed, they argued, was a decrease in aggregate demand.

Price Level

The intuitive explanation for this result is clear. When the dolD1 S1 lar falls, foreign goods become more expensive to Americans; S0 D0 that effect is directly inflationary. At the same time, aggregate demand in the United States is stimulated by rising net exports. As long as the expansion of demand outweighs the adverse shift of Real GDP the aggregate supply curve brought on by currency depreciation, real GDP should rise. But wait. By this reasoning, the massive depreciations of several Southeast Asian currencies in 1997 and 1998 should have given these economies tremendous boosts. Instead, the socalled Asian Tigers suffered horrific slumps—as did Mexico when the peso tumbled in 1995. Why? The answer is that our simple analysis of aggregate supply and demand omits a detail that, although unimportant for the United States, is critical in many developing nations. Countries that borrow in foreign currency will see their debts increase whenever their currency values decline. For example, an Indonesian business that borrowed $1,000 in July 1997, when $1 was worth 2,500 rupiah, thought it owed 2.5 million rupiah. When the dollar suddenly became worth 10,000 rupiah, the company’s debt skyrocketed to 10 million rupiah. Many businesses found themselves unable to cope with their crushing debt burdens and simply went bankrupt. So although currency depreciation is expansionary in the FI GURE 5 United States, it was sharply contractionary in Indonesia. The Effects of a Returning to rich countries such as the United States, Currency Appreciation let’s now reverse direction and look at what happens when the currency appreciates. In this case, net exports fall, so the aggregate demand curve shifts inward. At the same time, imported inputs become cheaper, so the aggregate S0 supply curve shifts outward. Both of these shifts are shown D0 S2 in Figure 5. Once again, as the diagram shows, we can be D2 sure of the movement of the price level: it falls. Output also falls if the demand shift is larger than the supply E shift, as is likely. Thus:

B S0 D0

S2 D2 Real GDP

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

768

Part 8

The United States in the World Economy

Interest Rates and International Capital Flows One important piece of our international economic puzzle is still missing. We have analyzed international trade in goods and services in some detail, but we have ignored international movements of capital up to now. For some nations, this omission is inconsequential because they rarely receive or lend international capital. Things are quite different for the United States because the vast majority of international financial flows involve either buying or selling assets whose values are stated in U.S. dollars. In addition, we cannot hope to understand the origins of the various international financial crises of the 1990s and 2000s without incorporating capital flows into our analysis. Fortunately, given what we have just learned about the effects of exchange rates, this omission is easily rectified. Recall from the previous chapter that interest rate differentials and capital flows are typically the most important determinants of exchange rate movements. Specifically, suppose interest rates in the United States rise while foreign interest rates are unchanged. We learned in the previous chapter that this change in relative interest rates will attract capital to the United States and cause the dollar to appreciate. This chapter has just taught us that an appreciating dollar will, in turn, reduce net exports, prices, and output in the United States—as was indicated in Figure 5. Thus: A rise in interest rates tends to contract the economy by appreciating the currency and reducing net exports.

International capital flows are purchases and sales of financial assets across national borders.

Notice that this conclusion has a familiar ring. When we studied monetary policy in Chapter 30, we observed that higher interest rates deter investment spending and hence reduce the I component of C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM). Now, in studying an open economy with international capital flows, we see that higher interest rates also reduce the X 2 IM component. Thus, international capital flows strengthen the negative effects of interest rates on aggregate demand. If interest rates fall in the United States, or rise abroad, everything we have just said is turned in the opposite direction. The conclusion is A decline in interest rates tends to expand the economy by depreciating the currency and raising net exports.

EXERCISE Provide the reasoning behind this conclusion.

FISCAL AND MONETARY POLICIES IN AN OPEN ECONOMY We are now ready to use our model to analyze how fiscal and monetary policies work when capital is internationally mobile and the exchange rate floats. Doing so will teach us how international economic relations modify the effects of stabilization policies that we learned about in earlier chapters. Fortunately, no new theoretical apparatus is necessary; we need merely remember what we have learned in the chapter up to this point. Specifically: • A rise in the domestic interest rate leads to capital inflows, which make the exchange rate appreciate. A currency appreciation reduces aggregate demand and raises aggregate supply (see Figure 5). • A fall in the domestic interest rate leads to capital outflows, which make the exchange rate depreciate. A currency depreciation raises aggregate demand and reduces aggregate supply (see Figure 4).

Fiscal Policy Revisited With these points in mind, suppose the government cuts taxes or raises spending. Aggregate demand increases, which pushes up both real GDP and the price level in the usual manner. This effect is shown as the shift from D0D0 to the blue line D1D1 in Figure 6. In a Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 36

769

Exchange Rates and the Macroeconomy

closed economy, that is the end of the story. But in an open economy with international capital flows, we must add in the macroeconomic effects that work through the exchange rate. We do this by answering two questions. First, what will happen to the exchange rate? We know from earlier chapters that a fiscal expansion pushes up interest rates. At higher interest rates, American securities become more attractive to foreign investors, who go to the foreign-exchange markets to buy dollars with which to purchase them. This buying pressure drives up the value of the dollar. Thus, at least for a rich country that can easily sell its bonds on the world market,

A closed economy is one that does not trade with other nations in either goods or assets.

FI GURE 6 A Fiscal Expansion in an Open Economy

A fiscal expansion normally makes the exchange rate appreciate.

D1 D2 D0

S0

Price Level

Second, what are the effects of a higher dollar? We know that when the dollar rises in value, American goods become more expensive abroad and foreign goods become cheaper here. So exports fall and imports rise, driving down the X 2 IM component of aggregate demand. The fiscal expansion thus winds up increasing both America’s capital account surplus (by attracting foreign capital) and its current account deficit (by reducing net exports). In fact, the two must rise by equal amounts because, under floating exchange rates, it is always true that 2

S2 B

A

Current account surplus 1 Capital account surplus 5 0

C

D1

Because a fiscal expansion leads in this way to a trade S0 deficit, many economists believe that the large U.S. trade S2 D0 deficits of the 1980s were a side effect of the large tax cuts made early in the decade—and that the tax cuts of Real GDP 2001–2003 once again pushed the trade deficit up. We will return to that issue shortly. For now, note that the induced rise in the dollar will shift the aggregate supply curve outward and the aggregate demand curve inward, as we saw in Figure 5. Figure 6 adds these two shifts (in brick-colored lines) to the effect of the original fiscal expansion (in blue). The final equilibrium in an open economy is point C, whereas in a closed economy it would be point B. By comparing points B and C, we can see how international linkages change the picture of fiscal policy that we painted earlier in the book. Two main differences arise. First, a higher exchange rate makes imports cheaper and thereby offsets part of the inflationary effect of a fiscal expansion. Second, a higher exchange rate reduces the expansionary effect on real GDP by reducing X 2 IM. Here we have a new kind of “crowding out,” different from the one we studied in Chapter 32. There we learned that an increase in G will crowd out some private investment spending by raising interest rates. Here an increase in G, by raising both interest rates and the exchange rate, crowds out net exports. But the effect is the same: The fiscal multiplier is reduced. Thus, we conclude that

D2

International capital flows reduce the power of fiscal policy.

Table 2, which shows actual U.S. data, suggests that this new international variety of crowding out was much more important than the traditional type of crowding out during the huge fiscal expansion of the 1980s. Between 1981 and 1986, the share of investment in GDP barely changed despite the rise in the shares of both consumer spending and government purchases. Only the share of net exports, X 2 IM, fell—from 10.2 percent to 22.8 percent. American economists thus learned an important lesson. In 1981, many economists worried that large government budget deficits

2

TABLE 2 Percentage Shares of Real GDP in the United States, 1981 and 1986

Year

C

I

G

X 2 IM

1981 1986 Change

64.5% 67.3 12.8

14.3% 14.5 10.2

20.5% 21.2 10.7

0.2% 22.8 23.0

NOTE: Totals do not add up to 100 percent because of rounding and deflation.

If you need review, turn back to Chapter 35, page 754.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

770

Part 8

The United States in the World Economy

would crowd out private investment. By the end of the decade, most were more concerned that deficits were crowding out net exports and producing a massive trade deficit.

Monetary Policy Revisited F I GURE 7 A Monetary Contraction in an Open Economy

D0 D1

Price Level

D2

S0 S2

Now let us consider how monetary policy works in an open economy with floating exchange rates and international capital mobility. To remain consistent with the history of the 1980s, we consider a tightening, rather than a loosening, of monetary policy. As we know from earlier chapters, contractionary monetary policy reduces aggregate demand, which lowers both real GDP and prices. This situation is shown in Figure 7 by S0 the shift from D0D0 to the blue line D1D1, and it looks like the exact opposite of a fiscal expansion. Without internaS2 tional capital flows, that would be the end of the story. But in the presence of internationally mobile capital, we must also think through the consequences for interest A rates and exchange rates. As we know from previous B chapters, a monetary contraction raises interest rates—just like a fiscal expansion. Hence, tighter money attracts foreign capital into the United States in search of higher rates C of return. The exchange rate therefore rises. The appreciD0 ating dollar encourages imports and discourages exports; so X 2 IM falls. America therefore winds up with an D1 D2 inflow of capital and an increase in its trade deficit. In Figure 7, the two effects of the exchange rate appreciation Real GDP appear in the brick-colored lines S2S2 and D2D2: aggregate supply shifts outward and aggregate demand shifts inward. This time, as you can see in the figure, International capital flows increase the power of monetary policy.

In a closed economy, higher interest rates reduce investment spending, I. In an open economy, these same higher interest rates also appreciate the currency and reduce net exports, X 2 IM. Thus, the effect of monetary policy is enhanced. It may seem puzzling that capital flows strengthen monetary policy but weaken fiscal policy. The explanation of these contrasting results lies in their effects on interest rates. The main international repercussion of either a fiscal expansion or a monetary contraction is to raise interest rates and the exchange rate, thereby crowding out net exports. That means that the initial effects of a fiscal expansion on aggregate demand are weakened, whereas the initial effects of a monetary contraction are strengthened.

INTERNATIONAL ASPECTS OF DEFICIT REDUCTION We have now completed our theoretical analysis of the macroeconomics of open economies. Let us put the theory to work by applying it to the events of the 1990s, when fiscal policy was tightened and monetary policy was eased. Should reducing the budget deficit (or raising the surplus) strengthen or weaken the dollar? As discussed in Chapter 32, the U.S. government transformed its mammoth budget deficit into a notable surplus during the 1990s by raising taxes and cutting expenditures. Column (1) of Table 3 reviews the predicted effects of a fiscal contraction: It should lower real interest rates, make the dollar depreciate, reduce real GDP, and be less disinflationary than normal because of the falling dollar. This information is recorded by entering 1 signs for increases and 2 signs for decreases. Eliminating the budget deficit reduced aggregate demand. But the Federal Reserve restored the missing demand by lowering interest rates so that the economy would not

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 36

771

Exchange Rates and the Macroeconomy

suffer a slump. According to the analysis in this chapter, such TABLE 3 a monetary expansion should lower real interest rates, make Expected Effects of Policy the dollar depreciate, raise real GDP, and be a bit more infla(1) (2) (3) tionary than usual because of the falling dollar. These effects Fiscal Monetary Combination are recorded in column (2) of Table 3. Variable Contraction Expansion Column (3) puts the two pieces together. We conclude that Real interest rate 2 2 2 a policy mix of fiscal contraction and monetary expansion Exchange rate 2 2 2 should reduce interest rates strongly, push down the value of Net exports 1 1 1 the dollar, and strongly stimulate our foreign trade. The net Real GDP 2 1 ? effects on output and inflation are uncertain, however: The Inflation 2 1 ? balance depends on whether the fiscal contraction overwhelms the monetary expansion, or vice versa. What actually happened? First, interest rates did fall, just as predicted. The rate on 10-year U.S. government bonds dropped from almost 7 percent in late 1992 to just over 4.5 percent in December 1998, and by 1998 American households were enjoying the lowest home mortgage rates since the 1960s. Second, the U.S. economy expanded rapidly between 1992 and 1998; apparently, the monetary stimulus overwhelmed the fiscal contraction. Third, inflation fell despite such rapid growth. As we explained in Chapter 27, one major reason was a series of favorable supply shocks that pushed inflation down. What about the exchange rate and international trade? Here the theory did less well. The dollar generally declined from 1993 to 1995, just as the theory predicts. But then it turned around and rose sharply from 1995 to 1998, just when the budget deficit was turning into a surplus. America’s trade performance was even more puzzling. According to the theory, a lower budget deficit should have led to a lower exchange rate, and therefore to a smaller trade deficit. But, in fact, America’s real net exports sagged from just A country’s trade deficit is the excess of its imports 2$16 billion in 1992 to 2$204 billion in 1998. What went wrong?

The Loose Link between the Budget Deficit and the Trade Deficit To answer this question, let’s explore the connection between the budget deficit and the trade deficit in more detail. To do so, we need one simple piece of arithmetic. Begin with the familiar equilibrium condition for GDP in an open economy:

over its exports. If, instead, exports exceed imports, the country has a trade surplus.

Y 5 C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM) Because GDP can either be spent, saved, or taxed away,3

Y5C1S1T Equating these two expressions for Y gives

C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM) 5 C 1 S 1 T Finally, subtracting C from both sides and bringing the I and G terms over to the righthand side leads to an accounting relationship between the trade deficit and the budget deficit: X 2 IM 5 (S 2 I) 2 (G 2 T)

Notice that this equation is a matter of accounting, not economics. It must hold in all countries at all times, and it has nothing to do with any particular economic theory. In words, it says that a trade deficit—a negative value of X 2 IM—can arise from one of two sources: a government budget deficit (G larger than T) or an excess of investment over saving (I larger than S). Now let’s apply this accounting relationship to actual U.S. events in the 1990s. As we know, the government deficit, G 2 T, fell precipitously. Other things equal, that should

3 If you do not see why, recall that GDP equals disposable income (DI) plus taxes (T), Y 5 DI 1 T, and that disposable income can either be consumed or saved, DI 5 C 1 S. These two definitions together imply that Y 5 C 1 S 1 T.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

772

Part 8

The United States in the World Economy

have reduced the trade deficit. But other things were not equal. The equation reminds us that the balance between saving and investment matters, too. As shares of GDP, business investment boomed while household saving declined from 1992 to 1998. So (S 2 I) moved sharply in the negative direction. And that change, as our equation shows, should raise the trade deficit (reduce net exports). In brief, taken by itself, deficit reduction would have increased net exports. In reality, sharp changes in private economic behavior—specifically, less saving and more investment—overwhelmed the government’s actions and made net exports fall instead. The link from the budget deficit to the trade deficit can be a loose one.

SHOULD WE WORRY ABOUT THE TRADE DEFICIT? The preceding explanation suggests that the large U.S. trade deficits over the past decade are a symptom of a deeper trouble: The nation as a whole—including both the government and the private sector—has been consuming more than it has been producing for years. The United States has therefore been forced to borrow the difference from foreigners. The trade deficit is just the mirror image of the required capital inflows. Those who worry about trade deficits point out that these capital inflows create debts on which interest and principal payments must be made in the future. In this view, we Americans have been mortgaging our futures to finance higher consumer spending. But another, quite different, interpretation of the trade deficit is possible. Suppose foreign investors come to see the United States as an especially attractive place to invest their funds. Then capital will flow here, not because Americans need to borrow it, but because foreigners are eager to lend it. The desire of foreigners to acquire American assets should push the value of the dollar up, which should in turn push America’s net exports down. In that case, the trade deficit would still be the mirror image of the capital inflows, but it would signify America’s economic strength, not its weakness. Each view has elements of truth, but the second raises a critical question: How long can it go on? As long as the United States continues to run large trade deficits, foreigners will have to continue to accumulate large amounts of U.S. assets—one way or another. As we noted in the previous chapter, starting in 2002 private investors abroad began concluding that they had acquired about all the American assets they wanted. That would have marked the day of reckoning for the United States but for one important fact: The governments of Japan and China decided to buy hundreds of billions of dollars (selling equivalent amounts of their own currencies) rather than let the yen and the yuan appreciate. These large government capital inflows allowed the United States to continue to run mammoth trade deficits for a few more years. In 2007, with the U.S. economy looking weaker than in the past, foreigners decided to buy fewer U.S. assets, and the dollar declined again. But when the crisis worsened, foreigners reversed their attitudes and the dollar rose.

ON CURING THE TRADE DEFICIT How can we ameliorate our foreign trade problem and reduce our addiction to foreign borrowing? There are four basic ways.

Change the Mix of Fiscal and Monetary Policy The fundamental equation X 2 IM 5 (S 2 I) 2 (G 2 T)

suggests that a decrease in the budget deficit (that is, shrinking (G 2 T)) would be one good way to reduce the trade deficit. According to the analysis in this chapter, a reduction in G or an increase in T would lead to lower real interest rates in the United States, a depreciating dollar, and, eventually, a smaller trade deficit. Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 36

Exchange Rates and the Macroeconomy

When the government curtails its spending or raises taxes, aggregate demand falls. If we do not want the shrinking budget deficit to slow economic growth, we must therefore compensate for it by providing monetary stimulus. Like contractionary fiscal policy, expansionary monetary policy lowers interest rates, depreciates the dollar, and should therefore help reduce the trade deficit. So the policy recommendation actually amounts to tightening fiscal policy and loosening monetary policy. As we have just noted, the U.S. government—after years of vacillation—changed the policy mix decisively in this direction in the 1990s. Our trade deficit rose anyway because private investment spending soared while private saving stagnated. Then, starting in 2001, the federal budget turned rapidly from a substantial surplus to a record-high deficit, which pushed the trade deficit up further. And now, of course, the budget deficit is larger than ever. What else might work?

More Rapid Economic Growth Abroad One factor behind the growing U.S. trade deficit is that the economies of many foreign nations—the customers for our exports—grew more slowly than the U.S. economy for years. If foreign economies would grow faster, the U.S. government frequently argued, they would buy more American goods, thereby raising U.S. exports and reducing our trade deficit. So we have regularly urged our major trading partners to stimulate their economies and to open their markets more to American goods—but with only modest success. When the U.S. economy slowed down in 2000–2001, our trade deficit did recede a bit—albeit temporarily. And the same thing happened again in 2007–2008. But no one thought slower U.S. growth was a very good remedy.

Raise Domestic Saving or Reduce Domestic Investment Our fundamental equation calls attention to two other routes to a smaller trade deficit: more saving or less investment. The U.S. personal saving rate (saving as a share of disposable income) hit postwar lows a few years ago. The 1.8 percent average saving rate of the years 2005–2007 were the lowest since the Great Depression of the 1930s. If Americans would simply save more, we would need to borrow less from abroad. This solution, too, would lead to a cheaper dollar and a smaller trade deficit. The trouble is that no one has yet found a reliable way to induce Americans to save more except via extreme losses of wealth, as in 2008 and 2009. The government has implemented a variety of tax incentives for saving, and more are suggested every year, but little evidence suggests that any of them has worked. Instead, large increases in stock market wealth in the second half of the 1990s, and then in housing wealth in the early 2000s, convinced Americans that it was prudent to save even less than they used to. Only the massive wealth destruction brought on by the financial crisis persuaded Americans to save more. If the other cures for our trade deficit fail to work, the deficit may cure itself in a particularly unpleasant way: by reducing U.S. domestic investment. The 2007–2009 recession accomplished this in a very rude way, reducing the share of investment in real GDP from 17.2 percent in 2006 to 11.9 percent in 2009. (It also curbed our appetite for imports.) But these side effects of recession are only temporary, and the longer-run problem mentioned above remains: If our trade deficit persists, we will have to borrow more and more from foreigners who, at some point, will start demanding higher interest rates. At best, higher interest rates will lead to lower investment in the United States. At worst, interest rates will skyrocket, and we will experience a severe recession.

Protectionism We have saved the worst remedy for last. One seemingly obvious way to cure our trade deficit is to limit imports by imposing stiff tariffs, quotas, and other protectionist devices. We discussed protectionism, and the reasons why almost all economists oppose it, in Chapter 34. Despite the economic arguments against it, protectionism has an undeniable political allure. It seems, superficially, to “save American jobs,” and it conveniently shifts the blame for our trade problems onto foreigners. Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

773

774

Part 8

The United States in the World Economy

SOURCE: © The New Yorker Collection 1992, Mort Gerberg from Cartoonbank.com. All Rights Reserved.

In addition to depriving us and other countries of the benefits of comparative advantage, protectionism might not even succeed in reducing our trade deficit, however. One reason is that other nations may retaliate. If we erect trade barriers to reduce our imports, IM will fall, and if foreign countries erect corresponding barriers to our exports, X will fall, too. On balance, our net exports, X 2 IM, may or may not improve. But world trade will surely suffer. This game may have no winners, only losers. Even if other nations do not retaliate, tariffs and “But we’re not just talking about buying a car—we’re talking about quotas may not improve the U.S. trade deficit confronting this country’s trade deficit with Japan.” much. Why? If they succeed in reducing American spending on imports, tariffs and quotas will thereby reduce the supply of dollars on the world market—which will push the value of the dollar up. A rising dollar, of course, would hurt U.S. exports and encourage more imports. The fundamental equation X 2 IM 5 (S 2 I) 2 (G 2 T)

reminds us that protectionism can raise (X 2 IM) only if it raises the budget surplus, raises saving, or reduces investment.4

CONCLUSION: NO NATION IS AN ISLAND When the poet John Donne wrote that “no man is an island,” he was not referring to economic globalization. In the modern world, no nation is isolated from economic developments elsewhere on the globe. Instead, we live in a world economy in which the fates of nations are intertwined. The major trading countries are linked by exports and imports, by capital flows, and by exchange rates. What happens to national income, prices, and interest rates in one country affects other nations. No events make this point clearer than the international financial crises that erupt from time to time. As we noted in Chapter 35, one root cause of almost all of the crises of the 1990s was countries’ decisions to fix their exchange rates to the U.S. dollar. Unfortunately for nations such as Thailand, Indonesia, and South Korea, the dollar rose spectacularly from 1995 to 1997. With their exchange rates tied to the dollar, the Thai baht, the Indonesian rupiah, and the Korean won automatically appreciated relative to most other currencies—making their exports more costly. Soon these one-time export powerhouses found themselves in an unaccustomed position: running large trade deficits. Then the crisis hit, and all four of these countries watched their currencies tumble in value. The sharp depreciations restored their international competitiveness, but they also impoverished many of their citizens. Naturally, the shrinking Asian economies curbed their appetites for American goods, so our exports to the region fell—which contributed to further deterioration in the U.S. trade deficit. Thus, a primarily American development (the rise of the dollar) harmed the Asian economies, and then a primarily Asian development (deep recessions in the Asian Tigers) hurt the U.S. economy. Similarly, the financial crisis that started here in 2007, an American phenomenon, devastated economic growth around the world. The nations of the world are indeed linked economically.

4

Here tariffs, which raise revenue for the government, have a clear advantage over quotas, which do not.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 36

ISSUE REVISITED:

Exchange Rates and the Macroeconomy

775

SHOULD THE UNITED STATES LET THE DOLLAR FALL?

Recall the question with which we began this chapter: Should the United States let the dollar fall or try to stop it? Remember that a falling dollar boosts exports and growth in the United States but reduces exports and growth in, say, Europe and Japan. With economic growth in both Japan and Europe already slow, it was easy to understand why foreign leaders wanted the U.S. government to stop, or at least slow down, the dollar ’s rapid descent in 2007 and 2008. But it was also easy to understand why the United States was not eager to do so, especially because a falling dollar was boosting our exports and helping the United States grow—even if it meant that Europe and Japan would grow slower. Unfortunately, there is no way to avoid this conflict of interests. A cheaper dollar means a dearer euro and a dearer yen. For better or for worse, we all live in one world.

| SUMMARY | 1. The nations of the world are linked together economically because national income, prices, and interest rates in one country affect those in other countries. They are thus open economies.

interest rates and the stronger currency reduce aggregate demand. Hence, international capital flows make monetary policy more powerful than it would be in a closed economy.

2. Because one country’s imports are another country’s exports, rapid (or sluggish) economic growth in one country contributes to rapid (or sluggish) growth in other countries.

8. Expansionary fiscal policies also raise interest rates and make the currency appreciate. In this case, the international repercussions cancel out part of the demandexpanding effects of the policies. Hence, international capital flows make fiscal policy less powerful than it would be in a closed economy.

3. A country’s net exports depend on whether its prices are high or low relative to those of other countries. Because exchange rates translate one country’s prices into the currencies of other countries, the exchange rate is a key determinant of net exports. 4. If the currency depreciates, net exports rise and aggregate demand increases, thereby raising both real GDP and the price level. A depreciating currency also reduces aggregate supply by making imported inputs more costly. 5. If the currency appreciates, net exports fall and aggregate demand, real GDP, and the price level all decrease. An appreciating currency also increases aggregate supply by making imported inputs cheaper. 6. International capital flows respond strongly to rates of return on investments in different countries. For example, higher domestic interest rates lead to currency appreciations, and lower interest rates lead to depreciations.

9. Because eliminating the budget deficit in the 1990s combined tighter fiscal policy with looser monetary policy, it lowered interest rates. That should have pushed the dollar down and led to a smaller trade deficit in the United States. However, changes in private economic behavior— specifically, lower saving and higher investment—offset the presumed international effects of deficit reduction, and the trade deficit kept growing. 10. Budget deficits and trade deficits are linked by the fundamental equation (X 2 IM) 5 (S 2 I) 2 (G 2 T). 11. It follows from this equation that the U.S. trade deficit must be cured by some combination of lower budget deficits, higher savings, and lower investment. 12. Protectionist policies might not cure the U.S. trade deficit because (a) they will make the dollar appreciate and (b) they may provoke foreign retaliation.

7. Contractionary monetary policies raise interest rates and therefore make the currency appreciate. Both the higher

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

776

Part 8

The United States in the World Economy

| KEY TERMS | appreciation

765

closed economy depreciation

exchange rate

769

765

trade deficit or surplus 771

international capital flows

765

open economy

768

X 2 IM 5 (S 2 I) 2 (G 2 T ) 771

763

| TEST YOURSELF | 1. Use an aggregate supply-demand diagram to analyze the effects of a currency appreciation.

a 5 percent interest rate is r 5 5.) Exports and imports are as follows:

2. Explain why X 2 IM 5 (S 2 I) 2 (G 2 T). Now multiply both sides of this equation by –1 to get

IM 2 X 5 (I 2 S) 1 (G 2 T) and remember that the trade deficit, IM 2 X, is the amount we have to borrow from foreigners to get

Borrowing from foreigners 5 (I 2 S) 1 (G 2 T) Explain the common sense behind this version of the fundamental equation. 3. (More difficult) Suppose consumption and investment are described by the following:

C 5 150 1 0.75DI I 5 300 1 0.2Y 2 50r Here DI is disposable income, Y is GDP, and r, the interest rate, is measured in percentage points. (For example,

X 5 300 IM 5 250 1 0.2Y Government purchases are G 5 800, and taxes are 20 percent of income. The price level is fixed and the central bank uses its monetary policy to peg the interest rate at r 58. a. Find equilibrium GDP, the budget deficit or surplus, and the trade deficit or surplus. b. Suppose the currency appreciates and, as a result, exports and imports change to

X 5 250 IM 5 0.2Y Now find equilibrium GDP, the budget deficit or surplus, and the trade deficit or surplus.

| DISCUSSION QUESTIONS | 1. For years, the U.S. government has been trying to get Japan and the European Union to expand their economies faster. Explain how more rapid growth in Japan would affect the U.S. economy. 2. If inflation is lower in Germany than in Spain (as it is), and the exchange rate between the two countries is fixed (as it is, because of the monetary union), what is likely to happen to the balance of trade between the two countries?

indicated in the closed-economy model described earlier in this book. 5. Given what you now know, do you think it was a good idea for the United States to adopt a policy mix of tight money and large government budget deficits in the early 1980s? Why or why not? What were the benefits and costs of reversing that policy mix in the 1990s?

3. Explain why a currency depreciation leads to an improvement in a country’s trade balance.

6. In 2001, 2002, and 2003, Congress passed the series of tax cuts that President Bush had requested. What effect did this policy likely have on the U.S. trade deficit? Why?

4. Explain why American fiscal policy is less powerful and American monetary policy is more powerful than

7. In 2007 and 2008, the international value of the dollar fell. This development was viewed with alarm in Japan. Why?

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Part

Postscript: The Financial Crisis of 2007–2009

A

lthough its roots go back much further, one of the biggest economic upheavals in the history of the United States began in earnest in September 2008, just a few months after the eleventh edition was first published. Because so much has happened since then, it seems imperative that this mid-edition revision be far more than a routine update. The chapter that follows had no counterpart in the original eleventh edition; it is entirely new for this 2010 update. It tells—albeit in skeletal form—the story of the subprime crisis, the broader financial panic, the ensuing Great Recession, and some of the steps the U.S. government has taken to fight the crisis. But, more than that, it emphasizes where and how the principles and policy of macroeconomics that you have learned in this book help make sense of the stunning events of 2007–2009—and where they need to be supplemented. To be sure, this assessment comes far too soon. Scholars will be studying this episode for decades to come, and final verdicts are a long way off. But recent events are just too important, and too relevant to today’s economy, to wait for history’s judgment.

C H A P T E R 37 | The Financial Crisis and the Great Recession

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

The Financial Crisis and the Great Recession We came very, very close to a global financial meltdown. FEDER AL RE SERVE CHAI RM AN BEN BERNA N K E

I

f you have read this book, you have learned a great deal about the causes and consequences of recessions, especially in many of the chapters of Part 6. But the United States has not experienced a recession as severe as the most recent one since the 1930s. The recession of 2007–2009 clearly merits being called the “Great Recession.” You have also learned, especially in Part 7, how fiscal and monetary policies can be used to combat recessions by raising aggregate demand. But the nation has never witnessed a policy response as powerful or multifaceted as what the U.S. government has done to fight the Great Recession. And while this book has devoted some attention to banking and the financial markets, especially in Chapter 29, we have not provided nearly enough material on finance to understand the unprecedented series of events that shook the U.S. economy to its foundations in 2008 and 2009. This concluding chapter remedies at least some of these omissions. We review the history of the crisis, starting from its antecedents in the financial markets in 2003–2004 and finishing with a snapshot of where things stand at the start of 2010. Our focus is not so much on the chronology of events as on the “missing pieces” that are necessary to understand the crisis—items such as asset bubbles, subprime mortgages, mortgagebacked securities, and leverage—and on some of the lessons that have been learned. Indeed, the chapter closes with a list of such lessons.

C O N T E N T S ISSUE: DID THE FISCAL STIMULUS WORK?

ROOTS OF THE CRISIS LEVERAGE, PROFITS, AND RISK THE HOUSING PRICE BUBBLE AND THE SUBPRIME MORTGAGE CRISIS

FROM THE HOUSING BUBBLE TO THE FINANCIAL CRISIS FROM THE FINANCIAL CRISIS TO THE GREAT RECESSION

ISSUE: DID THE FISCAL STIMULUS WORK?

LESSONS FROM THE FINANCIAL CRISIS

HITTING BOTTOM AND RECOVERING

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

780

Part 9

Postscript: The Financial Crisis of 2007–2009

ISSUE:

DID THE FISCAL STIMULUS WORK?

The Federal Reserve, the administration, and Congress responded to the financial crisis and the Great Recession with massive doses of monetary and fiscal stimulus, some of them quite unconventional. Yet, despite this unprecedented effort, real GDP declined for four consecutive quarters (the last two quarters of 2008 and the first two of 2009), and employment dropped for 23 consecutive months. The unemployment rate reached a high of 10.1 percent in October 2009—a figure not seen since June 1983. Some critics interpret the severity of the recession as evidence that the Obama administration’s prodigious efforts to “save or create jobs” failed. How, they ask, can you claim to have saved jobs when more than 8 million jobs were lost? The $787 billion fiscal stimulus bill, enacted in February 2009, has been subjected to particularly vehement criticism on these grounds. To this day, a number of politicians still clamor for its repeal. But supporters of stimulus argue that the critics are ignoring something important: Without the stimulus, they insist, the economy would have performed even worse, and jobs would have been even scarcer. Which side of the argument comes closer to the truth? Read this chapter and then decide.

ROOTS OF THE CRISIS

A bubble is an increase in the price of an asset or assets that goes far beyond what can be justified by improving fundamentals, such as dividends and earnings for shares of stock or incomes and interest rates for houses.

An interest rate spread or risk premium is the difference between an interest rate on a risky asset and the corresponding interest rate on a risk-free Treasury security.

The rolling series of financial crises that began in the summer of 2007 traces its roots back further in the decade. Indeed, to understand the length and breadth of what followed, it is important to understand that the problems that beset the market for home mortgages were just one manifestation of a broader set of forces that swept through America’s credit markets during the years 2003–2006, leaving the financial system terribly vulnerable. When the U.S. economy failed to snap back from the mild recession of 2001 and employment kept falling, the Federal Reserve made borrowing cheaper by pushing the federal funds rate all the way down to 1 percent in June 2003, in an effort to stimulate the economy.1 It then held the rate there for an entire year. Although this super-low interest rate policy was promulgated for sound macroeconomic reasons, it produced several notable side effects that came back to haunt us later. Most obviously, it pushed up the demand for houses, and therefore house prices—after all, lower mortgage interest rates make it cheaper, and therefore more attractive, to own a home. This boost from monetary policy helped fuel the burgeoning house price bubble. Indeed, that very fact illustrates how hard it can be to distinguish between a bubble and improvements in one or more of the fundamental factors that determine an asset’s market value. Lower mortgage rates are certainly an important fundamental cause of higher house prices, but they also seem to have inflated the bubble. The paltry returns on safe assets such as Treasury bills also encouraged investors to “reach for yield” by purchasing riskier securities that paid correspondingly higher interest rates. This behavior increased the demands for assets such as “junk” bonds, emerging-market debt, mortgage-backed securities (which will be explained below), and others, thus pushing up their prices and reducing their yields.2 In other words, the gaps between interest rates on risky assets and the interest rates on safe Treasury securities—called interest rate spreads—were compressed as investors poured money into riskier securities. (See the accompanying boxed insert, “Risk and Reward in Interest Rates”.)

To review the federal funds rate, the Fed’s main policy instrument, see Chapter 30, page 650. Remember from Chapter 30 (page 652) that when the price of a bond goes up, the effective interest rate it pays goes down.

1 2

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 37

781

The Financial Crisis and the Great Recession

Risk and Reward in Interest Rates

Riskier borrowers pay higher interest rates than safer borrowers, in order to persuade lenders to accept the higher risk of default. For example, “junk” bonds—the debts of lesser corporations—carry higher interest rates than, say, the bonds of IBM or AT&T. And the bonds of emerging-market nations typically carry far higher interest rates than the bonds of the U.S. government. The gap between the interest rate on a risky bond and the corresponding risk-free interest rate on a Treasury bond is called the risk premium, or sometimes just the spread, on that bond. For example, if a 10-year Treasury bond pays 3.4 percent per annum, and the 10-year bond of a corporation pays 6 percent, we say that the spread on that particular bond is 2.6 percentage points over Treasuries—that is, 6 percent minus 3.4 percent. Notice that this spread, which is determined every day in the marketplace by supply and demand, compensates the investor for a 2.6 percent expected annual loss on the corporate bond. The implication is that:

In the years leading up to the financial crisis, many such risk spreads narrowed—perhaps by more than was justified by the apparently safer lending environment. Then, as the crisis exploded and deepened, risk spreads soared. Finally, as the financial system started to return to normal after March 2009, risk spreads narrowed again. (See the accompanying graph.) The graph shows one particular interest rate spread, that between Treasury bills and bank-to-bank lending. Normally, this spread is very small because interbank lending is considered nearly riskless. But, during the heat of the crisis, banks became wary of lending even to other banks—so the spread depicted in the graph soared to unprecedented heights. Then, as the worst of the crisis passed, the spread returned to normal. While this is just one example, virtually every interest rate spread displayed a pattern like this over 2007–2009. Because this pattern was so typical, remembering that there are many different interest rates is essential to understanding how the crisis unfolded. In normal times, the various interest rates rise and fall together; so the convenient fiction that there is only one interest rate does not lead us astray. But during the crisis, there were several periods in which the risk-free Treasury bill rate actually went down while other, riskier rates went up.

SOURCE: 2010 Bloomberg L.P. All rights reserved. Used with Permission.

Up until now, this book has proceeded mainly as if there was only one interest rate in the economy—“the” interest rate. In fact, there are many, and differences among the various rates played a major role in the boom and subsequent bust. One key respect in which interest-bearing securities differ is in their risk of default, that is, the risk that the borrower will not repay the loan. There is no such risk in U.S. government securities. Dating back to fundamental decisions made by the nation’s first Secretary of the Treasury Alexander Hamilton, the U.S. government has always paid its debts in full and on time. Investors assume it always will. So Treasury securities are considered risk-free. Moving up the risk spectrum, the debts of the nation’s leading corporations carry some small risk of default. Thus, in order to induce investors to buy their securities, corporations must pay higher interest rates than Treasuries. In general:

When the perceived risk of default increases, risk spreads widen. When the perceived risk of default decreases, risk spreads narrow.

This investment trend was compounded by the fact that the frequencies of delinquency (late payment) and default (nonpayment) on virtually all sorts of lending, including home mortgages, were extraordinarily low during the years 2004–2006. Low defaults, in turn, deluded bankers and other lenders into believing that these riskier assets were not so risky after all. And that cavalier attitude, coupled with lax regulation, encouraged and permitted careless lending standards across the board. So, for example, we witnessed an explosion of so-called subprime mortgages and even the notorious NINJA loans (made to people with “no income, no job or assets”). Many of these subprime mortgages were granted with low or negligible down payments to borrowers of questionable credit standing who could make their payments only if the values of their homes increased enough to bail them out of excessive debt burdens. (More on this below.) The narrowing of interest rate spreads meant, as a matter of arithmetic, that the financial rewards for bearing risk had shrunk. The same amount of risk that used to earn an investor, say, a 3 percent spread over Treasuries might now earn her only a 1 percent

A home mortgage is a particular type of loan used to buy a house. The house normally serves as the collateral for the mortgage. Collateral is the asset or assets that a borrower pledges in order to guarantee repayment of a loan. If the borrower fails to pay, the collateral becomes the property of the lender. A mortgage is classified as subprime if the borrower fails to meet the traditional credit standards of “prime” borrowers.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

782

Part 9

Postscript: The Financial Crisis of 2007–2009

spread. That compression, in turn, led yield-hungry investors to make heavy use of leverage as a way to boost returns. And all that leverage created tremendous vulnerabilities in our financial system, which made the subsequent crisis far worse than it otherwise would have been. Since leverage played such a major role in the financial crisis, we must understand how it works.

LEVERAGE, PROFITS, AND RISK When an asset is bought with leverage, the buyer uses borrowed money to supplement his own funds. Leverage is typically measured by the ratio of assets to equity. For example, if the buyer commits $100,000 of his or her own funds and borrows $900,000 to purchase a $1 million asset, we say that leverage is 10-to-1 ($1 million divided by $100,000).

Leverage refers to the use of borrowed funds to purchase assets. The word itself derives from Archimedes, who famously declared that, if given a large enough lever, he could move the earth. (One wonders where he imagined he would place the fulcrum!) There is nothing wrong with leverage per se. However, just as with consumption of alcoholic beverages, excesses can lead to disaster, as we shall see presently. We have encountered financial leverage before. Back in Chapter 29 (page 636), we studied the balance sheet of the hypothetical Bank-a-Mythica, which is repeated below in Table 1. Notice that this tiny bank owns $5.5 million worth of assets on an equity base (the stockholders’ investment) of only one-half million. Since the degree of leverage is conventionally measured by the ratio of assets to net worth, we say that this bank is leveraged 11-to-1, which is pretty typical for U.S. commercial banks. TABLE 1 Balance Sheet of Bank-a-Mythica, December 31, 2007

Assets Assets Reserves Loans outstanding Total Addendum: Bank Reserves Actual reserves Required reserves Excess reserves

Liabilities and Net Worth $1,000,000 $4,500,000 $5,500,000 $1,000,000 21,000,000 0

Liabilities Checking deposits Net Worth Stockholders’ equity Total

$5,000,000

$500,000 $5,500,000

Leverage is a major source of Bank-a-Mythica’s, or any bank’s, profitability. To see why, suppose the bank’s deposits carry an average annual interest cost of 2 percent, or $100,000 per year in total, whereas its loans return, on average, 4 percent a year, or $180,000.3 The bank is nicely profitable because of the wide spread between its lending and deposit rates. It returns $80,000 per year in profit to its investors, which is a 16 percent rate of return on their invested capital of $500,000. Now suppose the bank was forced to operate without borrowed funds, which, in this case, means without deposits.4 In that case, the bank’s far-smaller balance sheet would look like Table 2. A 4 percent return on its $500,000 loan portfolio would now net the bank just $20,000 per year, which is, of course, also a 4 percent rate of return on its $500,000 equity. With such low prospective returns, investors would probably find better uses for their money. So this bank would never exist. Thus: Leverage is essential to a bank’s profitability, but leverage also exacerbates risk.

3 For example, the average loan rate might be 7 percent with an average 3 percent loss rate. Alas, not all loans get paid back! 4 Remember from Chapter 29 that bank deposits are liabilities to banks because, when they are cashed in, the bank must pay out the cash. Thus, you lend money to your bank, and the bank borrows money from you, when you make a deposit.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

783

The Financial Crisis and the Great Recession

Chapter 37

TABLE 2 Unleveraged Balance Sheet

Assets Loans outstanding

Liabilities and Net Worth $500,000

Stockholders’ equity

$500,000

Using the unleveraged balance sheet of Table 2, now suppose that loans decline in value by 10 percent, creating the new balance sheet shown in Table 3. The stockholders have lost 10 percent of their investment, which is bad but not devastating. Now consider the same 10 percent loan losses (which now amount to $450,000) in the highly levered balance sheet we started with (Table 1). We would get the result shown in Table 4. Notice that the bank’s shareholders have now lost 90 percent of their $500,000 investment. They are almost wiped out. TABLE 3 Unleveraged Balance Sheet after 10 Percent Loan Losses

Assets Loans outstanding

Liabilities and Net Worth $450,000

Stockholders’ equity

$450,000

TABLE 4 Leveraged Balance Sheet after 10 Percent Loan Losses

Assets Assets Reserves Loans outstanding Total

Liabilities and Net Worth $1,000,000 $4,050,000 $5,050,000

Liabilities Deposits Net Worth Stockholders’ equity Total

$5,000,000 $ 50,000 $5,050,000

Thus leverage is the proverbial double-edged sword. It magnifies returns on the upside, which is what investors want, but it also magnifies losses on the downside, which can be fatal. The moral of this story is not that leverage must be shunned. Leverage is, for example, inherent in the very idea of banking, where an “unlevered bank” is an oxymoron because every dollar of deposits is “borrowed” from customers. Rather, the true moral of the story is that a company operating with high leverage should be labeled “Fragile: Handle with Care.” Its shock absorbers are not very resilient. Unfortunately, too many banks and other financial institutions forgot this elementary lesson during the heady days of the real estate boom. Commercial banks employed legal and accounting gimmicks to push their leverage above the traditional 10-to-1 or 12-to-1 level. Some investment banks operated with 30-to-1 or even 40-to-1 leverage. With 40-to-1 leverage, for example, a mere 2.5 percent decline in the value of your assets is enough to destroy all shareholder value.5 That’s a risky way to run a business. And when asset values dropped after the housing bubble burst, many of these firms were ill prepared to absorb losses and became insolvent. So those were the four main ingredients in the dangerous witches’ brew that existed before the housing bubble burst: the bubble itself, lenient lending standards, compressed risk spreads, and high leverage.

But none of this mattered much as long as house prices continued to inflate.

5

A company is insolvent when the value of its liabilities exceeds the value of its assets, that is, when its net worth is negative.

EXERCISE: Demonstrate this conclusion with a hypothetical balance sheet both before and after a 2.5 percent loss.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

784

Part 9

Postscript: The Financial Crisis of 2007–2009

Leverage and Returns: An Example

To illustrate this general principle, consider the contrasting investment behaviors of Jane Doe and John Dough. Jane invests $1,000,000 in one-year corporate bonds paying 6 percent interest. At the end of the year, she gets back her $1,000,000 in principal plus $60,000 in interest. Since what she receives is 6 percent more than what she originally paid, her rate of return is, naturally, 6 percent. Now consider John Dough, who also commits $1,000,000 of his own money to these same bonds. However, John leverages his investment by borrowing another $9,000,000 from a bank, at 3 percent interest, and investing the entire $10,000,000 in the bonds. At year’s end, John gets back his $10,000,000 in principal plus $600,000 in interest, or $10,600,000 in total. He repays the bank $9,000,000 in principal plus $270,000 in interest, or $9,270,000 in total. Hence his net earnings are $10,600,0002$9,270,000 = $1,330,000 on a $1,000,000 investment. Thus, John’s rate of return is 33 percent—more than five times higher than Jane’s. So is John, who uses high leverage, a smarter investor than Jane, who does not? Well, maybe not. Let’s now suppose that the bond falls 5 percent in value during the year. Jane will now receive $950,000 in principal plus $60,000 in interest, or $1,010,000 in

total. Her rate of return is thus a paltry 1 percent. John, on the other hand, will get back $9,500,000 in principal plus $600,000 in interest, or $10,100,000 in total. But he will still have to pay the bank $9,270,000, leaving him with only $830,000 of his original $1,000,000 investment. John’s rate of return is therefore minus 17 percent. (He has lost 17 percent of his money.) Maybe John wasn’t so smart after all.

THE HOUSING PRICE BUBBLE AND THE SUBPRIME MORTGAGE CRISIS Let us now see what all this tells us about how the end of the housing bubble led to the financial crisis. Cracks in the system began to emerge when house prices stopped rising in either 2006 or 2007, depending on what measure you use. Over the period from 2000 until 2006 or 2007, house prices in the United States soared by 60 to 90 percent, which constituted a faster rate of increase than we had ever seen before on a nationwide basis. Many observers believed that such sharp price increases far outstripped what could be justified by the fundamentals, such as rising incomes and falling mortgage interest rates; hence the term bubble. Their warnings were not heeded, however. Once the bubble burst, house prices began to fall, especially severely in previous boom markets in states like California, Florida, Arizona, and Nevada. Again, depending on how you measure it, the price of an average American home fell about 12 to 25 percent over the next two to three years; in some areas, price declines of 50 percent and more were common. These sharp declines had a number of obvious effects on the economy, plus a few that were not so obvious. First, plunging prices made both buying and building new homes far less attractive than when prices were soaring. For-sale signs sprouted up everywhere, and inventories of unsold houses piled up, driving prices down further. Think about the profitability of a builder whose construction costs for a certain type of home is $250,000. At a selling price of $300,000, the business is quite profitable, inducing a great deal of new construction. But if the market price drops to $200,000, that’s a signal to stop building, which is precisely what many construction companies did. Residential construction tumbled by a remarkable 56 percent between the winter of 2005–2006 and the spring of 2009, when it hit rock bottom. Remember, spending on newly constructed homes is part of investment, I, and this sharp decline starting dragging down GDP growth in late 2005.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

SOURCE: HIP/Art Resource, NY

Leverage magnifies gains on the way up but also magnifies losses on the way down.

Chapter 37

785

The Financial Crisis and the Great Recession

Second, a great deal of consumer wealth was destroyed in the process. After all, a house is far and away the most valuable asset for most American families. If the value of the family house falls from, say, $300,000 to $200,000, which happened in many markets, the family is substantially poorer. As we learned in Chapter 25, reduced wealth normally leads to lower consumer spending, C. It did so in 2008. The roots of recession were sown. But there was much more. Most houses are purchased mainly with borrowed funds— mortgages. A typical mortgage obligates the homeowner to make monthly payments of a fixed number of dollars over a certain number of years (often 30). Obviously, the more a household borrows, the larger its monthly mortgage payment will be. If the homeowner fails to make the monthly payments, the bank can take back the house—which is the collateral on the loan—through a legal process called foreclosure. Notice that as falling home values reduce the value of the collateral, the bank finds itself in a more precarious position. If it forecloses on a homeowner who fails to make the required payments, the bank might not get all of its money back because the house might be worth less than the mortgage. Let’s think about some numbers that typified “the good old days” before the housing bubble. Down payments of about 20 percent were typical. So a $200,000 house was normally bought with about $40,000 in cash and a mortgage of $160,000. The down payment served as a cushion. Since the original mortgage debt amounted to only 80 percent of the value of the house, even a 10 to 15 percent drop in price, which was a very rare event, would leave the property worth more than the mortgage. If the mortgage interest rate was, say, 7.5 percent per annum, the monthly payment would be about $1,120. By traditional banking rules of thumb, a household should have income of three to four times that amount to qualify for such a mortgage—say, $40,000 to $55,000 a year. But mortgage lending standards dropped like a stone during the housing boom, in three main ways. The reason in each case was the same: As the bubble inflated, both borrowers and lenders came to believe that house prices would continue to rise indefinitely. First, the rule of thumb just mentioned came to be viewed as hopelessly out of date. Housing was now such a fine investment, it was thought, that families could safely afford to devote more than 25 or 33 percent of their incomes to mortgage payments. Second, banks and other lenders started to grant loans with small or even zero down payments. Both of these changes enabled households to purchase even more expensive homes— homes that ultimately proved to be beyond their means. Third, banks and other lenders started offering more and more mortgages to families with less-than-stellar credit ratings—the notorious subprime mortgages—often in amounts that borrowers could not afford. Under normal market conditions, such loans would have been considered too risky by borrowers and lenders alike. As the bubble continued to grow, though, lenders reasoned (incorrectly, as it turned out) that ever-rising house prices would make their loans secure even if borrowers defaulted because the value of the collateral (the house) would keep rising. The corresponding delusion for households went something like this: “I know I shouldn’t borrow $200,000 to buy a $200,000 house that I can’t afford on my $25,000 annual income. But if I can muddle through for just two or three years, the house will be worth $300,000. Then I can pay off my old $200,000 loan, replacing it with a much safer $240,000 mortgage with $60,000 down (20 percent of $300,000)—leaving $40,000 in cash in my pocket.”6 That all sounded good—until it didn’t. When house prices stopped rising, subprime mortgages began to default in large numbers. The house of cards was beginning to crumble.

Foreclosure is the legal process through which a mortgage lender obtains control of the property after the mortgage goes into default.

Here is the arithmetic: If Bank Two will lend $240,000 against the $300,000 house—a safe loan with a 20 percent down payment, the homeowner can take $200,000 of the newly-borrowed $240,000 and pay off his original loan from Bank One, keeping $40,000 for himself.

6

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

786

Part 9

Postscript: The Financial Crisis of 2007–2009

FROM THE HOUSING BUBBLE TO THE FINANCIAL CRISIS

Loans are securitized— that is, transformed into marketable securities— when they are packaged together into a bondlike instrument that can be sold to investors, potentially all over the world.

A mortgage-backed security is a bondlike security whose interest payments and principal repayments derive from the monthly mortgage payments of many households.

At first, most observers thought the damage from the impending subprime mortgage debacle would be too small to cause a recession. There were two main errors in this reasoning. The first mistake was simple: Most people underestimated the scale of the subprime mortgage market, which had soared in volume during the late stages of the bubble. The second mistake is harder to explain. Doing so requires a detour through a once-arcane aspect of finance called securitization. A simple example will illustrate how securitization works. Consider Risky Bank Corporation (RBC), which has made 1,000 subprime mortgage loans averaging $200,000—all, let us say, in the Las Vegas area. RBC’s highly concentrated loan portfolio of $200 million is, well, risky. Should an economic downturn or natural disaster hit its local market, many of these loans would likely default, potentially driving RBC into bankruptcy. Enter Friendly Investment Bank (FIB), a securitizer. FIB offers the bank an attractive deal. “Sell us your $200 million in subprime mortgages. We will pay you cash immediately, which you can use to make loans to other borrowers. We’ll then take your mortgages, combine them with others from banks around the country, and package them all into more diversified mortgage-backed securities (MBS). These securities will be less risky than the underlying mortgages because they will be backed by payments emanating from several different geographical areas. Then we will spread the risk further by selling pieces of the MBS to investors all over the world.” FIB, of course, would earn fees for all of its services. On the surface, this little bit of “financial engineering,” as it is called, seems to make good sense. RBC is relieved of a substantial risk that could threaten its very existence. FIB’s securitization of all those mortgages reduces risk in the two ways claimed. The first is geographical diversification. Even though Las Vegas real estate prices might fall, it is unlikely that real estate prices would drop simultaneously in Los Angeles, Chicago, Orlando, etc. Second, the risks that remain in the (diversified) MBS are then parceled out to hundreds or even thousands of investors all over the world, rather than being held in just a few banks. Thus no one bank is left “holding the bag” if mortgage defaults rise unexpectedly. That was the theory, but it didn’t always work smoothly in practice. Why not? The preceding paragraph contains the first two clues. First, when the national housing bubble burst, home prices did indeed fall almost everywhere—an “impossible” event that had not occurred since the Great Depression of the 1930s. For decades, Americans had witnessed periodic house-price bubbles in particular areas of the country. But when prices fell in, say, Boston they kept rising in, say, Los Angeles—and vice versa. The period after 2006–2007 was different, however. With house prices falling all over the map, the expected gains from geographical diversification disappeared just when they were most needed. For this reason alone, the values of the MBS declined—it turned out they were riskier than investors thought. Remember, more perceived risk induces lenders to demand higher interest rates to compensate them for the higher risk. And higher interest rates mean lower bond prices. Second, we learned that the securities were not as widely distributed as had been thought. On the contrary, many of the world’s leading financial institutions apparently found MBS and other mortgage-related assets so attractive during the boom that they were left holding very large concentrations of such assets when the markets collapsed. The failures and near failures of such venerable firms as Bear Stearns, Lehman Brothers, Merrill Lynch, Wachovia, Citigroup, Bank of America, and others were all traceable, directly or indirectly, to excessive concentrations of mortgage-related risks. As one institution after another tried to unload their now-unwanted securities in a market with many sellers and few buyers, prices plummeted further.7

EXERCISE: Draw a supply-and-demand diagram for mortgage-backed securities. Show what happens when the demand curve shifts in and the supply curve shifts out.

7

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 37

The Financial Crisis and the Great Recession

There is more to the story. We have already mentioned that excessive leverage is dangerous, and that mortgages with less collateral (less valuable houses) behind them command lower prices in the marketplace because they are riskier. But there was another, very important, factor: Many of the MBS and related assets were far more complex than our simple example suggests. Let us explain. During the boom, Wall Street created and sold a dizzying array of financial securities that, in effect, offered investors complex combinations of shares of mortgage loans— securities so complex that few investors understood what they really owned. As more and more of the underlying mortgages started to look like they might default, the values of all mortgage-backed securities naturally plummeted. In the cases of the most complex and opaque securities, this fear was exacerbated by the fact that nobody knew what they were really worth, which is a surefire cause for panic once the seeds of doubt are sown. This panic simmered for a while and then burst into the open in the summer of 2007. The financial crisis had begun in earnest. The creaky system began to crack in July 2007, when Bear Stearns—a large investment bank that would become infamous later—told investors that there was “effectively no value left” in one of its mortgage funds. Not exactly encouraging. Soon a variety of financial markets were acting extremely nervous. The big bang came on August 9, 2007, when BNP Paribas, a huge French bank, halted withdrawals on three of its subprime mortgage funds—citing as its reason the inability to put values on the securities the funds owned. Those acquainted with American history were reminded of the periodic banking panics of the 19th century, which often were set off when some bank “suspended specie payments”—that is, refused to exchange its bank notes for gold or silver. Whether French or American, the signal to panic was clear, which is precisely what markets did, all over the world. At first, the Federal Reserve and the European Central Bank (ECB) tried to hold the system together by acting as “lenders of last resort”, as described in Chapter 30 (pages 653–654), which is what central banks have done since the 17th century. They lent astonishing sums of money to commercial banks within a matter of days. Although that improved markets, the “cure” didn’t last long. By March 2008, Bear Stearns was suffering from the modern-day equivalent of a run on the bank. When it became clear that Bear had only days to live, the Federal Reserve stepped in to help J.P. Morgan Chase, a giant commercial bank, purchase Bear Stearns at a bargain-basement price. Most surprisingly, the Federal Reserve put some of its own money at risk when, in order to seal the deal, it agreed to buy some of the Bear Stearns assets that J.P. Morgan Chase did not want. These actions, which remain controversial to this day, were unprecedented. As the Federal Reserve vice chairman, Donald Kohn, put it at the time, alluding to Julius Caesar’s risky approach to Rome, the Federal Reserve “crossed the Rubicon” with the Bear Stearns deal. Even as of this writing in March 2010, the Federal Reserve has been unable to recross the Rubicon and head back in the other direction. Not all of the anti-recessionary policies were financial. Conventional fiscal policy, as described in Chapter 28, was also employed to fight the recession. This process started in early 2008, when Congress enacted a one-time “tax rebate” to put more disposable income into the hands of consumers, just as it had done in 1975 and 2001.8 As the economy worsened, it became clear that the modestly sized fiscal stimulus (roughly 1 percent of GDP) was far too small, given the deteriorating economy.9 In addition, many economists argued (as in the text on pages 547–548) that temporary tax cuts have smaller effects on consumer spending than permanent cuts. So the first major action of the new Obama administration in 2009 was to recommend far more fiscal stimulus (more on this follows).

These two episodes were analyzed in Chapter 25, pages 538 and 547–548. The calculations behind such conclusions are more elaborate versions of the multiplier analysis presented in Chapters 26 and 28.

8 9

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

787

788

Part 9

Postscript: The Financial Crisis of 2007–2009

FROM THE FINANCIAL CRISIS TO THE GREAT RECESSION A financial crisis does remain purely financial for long. Soon, the real economy gets dragged down. As we have learned in this book, all economies depend on credit. Borrowed funds are used to finance not only home purchases but also several types of consumer expenditures, C, such as automobile purchases, and virtually all forms of business investment, I. Credit is also vital to exporting and importing, X 2 IM, and to financing substantial chunks of government spending, G. That list takes in every component of C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM). So when credit contracts, so does aggregate demand. And as we have learned, declining aggregate demand is the most common cause of recessions. Furthermore, banks are central to the credit system. If banks feel imperiled and become cautious about lending, businesses may find themselves starved for credit to finance inventories, households may be unable to obtain mortgages or auto loans, and even local governments may find it hard to float their bonds. In worst-case scenarios—which briefly became a reality in the fall of 2008—firms may not even be able to obtain the short-term credit they need to make payrolls. Such a situation is what Federal Reserve Chairman Ben Bernanke feared when he spoke of a “global financial meltdown.” The Fed’s job was not just to stop the financial bleeding, which was hard enough. It also had to find ways to repair the broken financial system and to get credit flowing again. In addition, it had to offset the drag on aggregate demand caused by the creditmarket disruptions. The first two tasks were virtually unprecedented and required the Fed to improvise; the last one was familiar. Central banks know how to stimulate (or contract) aggregate demand. We learned in Chapter 30 that monetary policymakers normally boost demand by cutting interest rates. In the case of the Federal Reserve, that meant lowering the federal funds rate (see Chapter 30, pages 649–651), which stood at 5.25 percent when the crisis began. The Fed began cutting the funds rate in September 2007, cautiously at first. However, it soon realized that timidity would not do, and accelerated its rate cutting enormously during the first quarter of 2008—including a dramatic cut of 0.75 percent right after the Bear Stearns deal. By the end of April 2008, the federal funds rate stood at just 2 percent, where the Fed decided to leave it. Or so it thought. Then the demise of Lehman Brothers happened in September 2008. The Lehman bankruptcy changed everything by triggering the biggest financial panic yet. Within days, other large financial firms were collapsing or teetering on the brink. Investors seemed unwilling to bear any risk at all; everyone, it seemed, wanted to stash their funds either in safe Treasury securities or FDIC-insured bank deposits. So, as we mentioned earlier, the interest rates on Treasury securities fell even though most other rates were rising. Banks, in turn, started hoarding excess reserves rather than lending them out. It is no exaggeration to say that most of the economy’s credit-granting mechanisms froze. It seemed that no one wanted to lend money to anyone. Within weeks, the real economy, starved of credit, looked like it was falling off a cliff. (See the box, “The Collapse of Lehman Brothers.”) These developments posed a huge new problem for the Fed. We learned in Chapters 29 and 30 that an injection of new bank reserves normally sets in motion a multiple expansion of the money supply and bank lending, which is how the Fed pushes the economy forward. In late 2008, the need for expansionary monetary policy was clear. But, as you will recall, the main reason why the multiple expansion process works is that banks do not want to hold excess reserves, which earn them nothing. Instead, they lend the funds out. Or at least that is what they do in normal times. However, when banks fear a “run” by their depositors and/or worry that loans will not be repaid, it becomes rational for them to hang onto excess reserves.10 Idle balances at the Federal Reserve may pay

10

We discussed this possibility in Chapter 29, page 643.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

789

The Financial Crisis and the Great Recession

Chapter 37

SOURCE: REUTERS/Yuriko Nakao /Landov

The Collapse of Lehman Brothers: The Turning Point

The collapse of Lehman Brothers, a venerable Wall Street “brand name” that had survived the Great Depression, marked a turning point in the crisis—and not just financially. The real economy also

took a sharp turn for the worse immediately after Lehman filed for bankruptcy on September 15, 2008. Virtually all indicators of the health of the macroeconomy plunged downwards. Two of them are depicted here. The right-hand panel shows the growth rate of real GDP, quarterly, from the fourth quarter of 2007 (the official start of the recession) through the first quarter of 2009, when the nosedive ended. Notice that GDP actually grew slightly over the first three quarters shown in the graph, but then began plummeting just when Lehman fell. The left-hand panel depicts, in this case month by month, the rate of job loss over approximately the same time period. Once again, we see only modest monthly job losses through August, and then stunningly large ones in the months after Lehman’s collapse. It’s no wonder that the fall of Lehman Brothers is considered a milestone—and not a happy one—in the history of the financial and economic crisis of 2007–2009.

3

Monthly Job Loss

1

–100

0

–200

–1

–7

nothing, but at least they are safe from loss. However, idle cash balances at the Fed do not increase aggregate demand. Thus, conventional monetary policy becomes, in a sense, powerless. The Fed, the Treasury, the FDIC, and others reacted to this frightening state of affairs in multiple ways. First, the Fed resumed cutting interest rates, bringing the federal funds rate down to virtually zero by December 2008. But, for the reasons just mentioned, it is not clear that this additional dose of expansionary monetary policy did much good. Second, the Fed and the Treasury together mounted a rapid-fire series of dramatic rescue operations to prevent what was threatening to become “a global financial meltdown.” They encouraged several gigantic mergers via which “strong” companies acquired “weak” ones. The Fed threw a big lifeline to AIG, a giant insurance company (not a bank) that was closely linked to Wall Street firms and banks, by lending it an enormous amount of money. In the process, the Fed effectively “nationalized” AIG without ever using the word—and without

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

2009-1

–6 2008-4

Mar-09

Feb-09

Jan-09

Dec-08

Nov-08

Oct-08

Sep-08

Aug-08

Jul-08

Jun-08

May-08

Apr-08

Mar-08

Feb-08

Jan-08

–700

–5

2008-3

–600

–4

2008-2

–500

–3

2008-1

–400

–2

2007-4

–300

SOURCE: U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics, http://www.bls.gov.

0

–800

GDP Growth

2

SOURCE: U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics, http://www.bls.gov.

Thousands of Jobs

100

790

Part 9

Postscript: The Financial Crisis of 2007–2009

TARP enabled the US Treasury to purchase assets and equity from banks and other financial institutions as a means of strengthening the financial sector.

A bank is said to be recapitalized when some investor, private or government, provides new equity capital in return for partial ownership.

a vote in Congress. This operation eventually proved to be the most controversial of them all. As this is written, the Fed is still being accused of making serious errors in the AIG case. The Fed also declared the two surviving Wall Street giants, Goldman Sachs and Morgan Stanley, to be “banks” so that it could lend them money as necessary. The Treasury, which had previously said it had no funds to commit to rescue operations (and hence left that to the Fed), suddenly discovered a large pot of money that it used to stop runs on money market mutual funds.11 The FDIC, which had long guaranteed bank deposits, extended its guarantee and also invented a new program to guarantee some of the bonds that banks wanted to issue. These examples are only a few of the attempted rescue operations. No living person had ever seen anything like it. Despite all these prodigious and unprecedented efforts, the financial markets remained in a state of panic and the economy teetered on the brink of disaster. Against that background, Federal Reserve Chairman Bernanke and then-Secretary of the Treasury Henry Paulson locked arms (pretty much literally) and persuaded Congress to pass the Trouble Assets Relief Program (TARP) on October 3, 2008 (on the second try)—just four weeks before the 2008 election. The central idea behind TARP, for which Congress appropriated the astonishing sum of $700 billion,12 was that MBS and other, more complicated, securities based on mortgages were clogging up the financial system. Without buyers, the markets for these assets had pretty much shut down; there were hardly any transactions. Although most financial institutions owned mortgage-related securities, and some owned huge amounts, no one knew what they were worth. In a nervous environment, investors tended to assume the worse, which led to fears that most of the large financial institutions were concealing large losses; not many lenders want to extend credit to potentially insolvent institutions. The original idea was that the Treasury Department would use TARP money to buy up some of the unwanted securities, hold them until the storm passed, and then sell them back into the market, hopefully at a profit. But that did not happen. Instead, Secretary Paulson utilized a catchall provision in the bill to divert TARP money to an entirely different purpose: to recapitalize the banks.13 What does that mean? Look back at the simplified balance sheet of the nearly-insolvent bank we considered in Table 4. This bank is barely alive; the slightest further loss on its holdings of loans and securities will render it insolvent. But now suppose the bank receives $1 million in cash from the government, which purchases $1 million worth of bank stock. The bank’s new balance sheet is shown in Table 5. The bank now has plenty of capital and plenty of capacity to lend. It’s just that most of the new capital is owned by the government. Part of the idea, of course, is that the government will sell its shares later. TABLE 5 Balance Sheet after Recapitalization

Assets Assets Reserves Loans and securities Total

Liabilities and Net Worth $2,000,000 $4,050,000 $6,050,000

Liabilities Deposits Stockholders’ equity Total

$5,000,000 $1,050,000 $6,050,000

11 Money market mutual fund deposits are very much like bank accounts; depositors can even write checks on them. Although not insured by the FDIC, millions of Americans considered the money in these funds to be totally safe—until one large money fund, which had invested in Lehman’s debt instruments, suffered losses. That stunning event precipitated a run on money market funds in general. 12 To put that number into perspective, the entire federal budget deficit for fiscal year 2008, which ended three days before the TARP legislation passed, was $469 billion. 13 This catchall provision authorizes the secretary of the Treasury to purchase any asset he decides “is necessary to promote financial market stability.”

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Chapter 37

The Financial Crisis and the Great Recession

What Secretary Paulson actually did was a good deal more complicated than this simple example. But the balance sheets in Tables 4 and 5 give you the basic idea: The recapitalizations saved the banks by making the government a part owner. Many financial experts applauded the secretary’s actions; others did not. However, the public at large felt it was fundamentally unfair to funnel all that money to the very banks that had caused the problems, while so many families and other businesses were struggling. The recapitalization of the banks, and the TARP itself, became wildly unpopular—hated by Republicans and Democrats alike. That attitude prevails to this day, even though the banks have repaid the TARP funds with a profit to the government. Indeed, saying that some idea is “like the TARP” is a good way to kill it politically. Politics aside, the recapitalizations did save the banks. It proved to be the first step on the long, bumpy road to recovery. Unfortunately, as we traveled along this road, the economy was tanking. Look back at the boxed insert, “The Collapse of Lehman Brothers: The Turning Point.” The right-hand diagram shows that real GDP declined at an annualized rate of about 6 percent during the last quarter of 2008 and the first quarter of 2009, which were two of the worst quarters in the history of the U.S. economy since the 1930s. Commensurately, the unemployment rate rose from 4.8 percent in February 2008 to 6.1 percent at the time Lehman failed to 8.5 percent by March 2009—and rose further as 2009 progressed.14 As we know, governments normally fight rising unemployment with expansionary monetary and fiscal policies. But the Fed was more or less “out of ammunition” after December 2008, when it had lowered the federal funds rate to virtually zero. Policymakers worried: What if all that expansionary monetary policy was not enough? When President Barack Obama took office in January 2009, his first major policy initiative was a massive fiscal stimulus bill, including both tax cuts and increases in government spending. The overall magnitude of the February 2009 fiscal package was announced as $787 billion, or about 5.5 percent of GDP, although it was spread out over several years. The idea, of course, was to close the sizable recessionary gap between potential and actual GDP—precisely as explained in Chapter 28.

HITTING BOTTOM AND RECOVERING Most financial markets appear to have hit bottom around March 2009. The low point of the stock market came in March, and the subsequent recovery was spectacular: Stock prices rose more than 60 percent from March to November. The interest rate spreads we discussed earlier also seem to have peaked in March, and they narrowed sharply thereafter. Perhaps not coincidentally, real GDP began to grow again in the third quarter of 2009—only modestly at first, but then rapidly in the fourth quarter. However, job growth did not resume until 2010. As 2010 started, the economy appeared to be on the mend, the recession behind us. But many economists wondered how lasting and strong the recovery would be, and jobs were still disappearing, albeit at a much slower pace. The Obama administration was looking for further ways to jump-start hiring and to get credit flowing again to small businesses. The Fed, for its part, was beginning to think about its “exit strategy” from the many emergency policies it had put into place. Normalcy seemed to be returning—though not quite there yet.

14

As mentioned at the start of this chapter, the unemployment rate finally peaked at 10.1 percent in October 2009.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

791

792

Part 9

Postscript: The Financial Crisis of 2007–2009

ISSUE:

DID THE FISCAL STIMULUS WORK?

Did the monetary and fiscal policy stimulus work, especially President Obama’s controversial $787 billion fiscal stimulus package? Controversy still swirls around that question, but here are a few facts. First, real GDP growth moved from the minus 6 percent range to the plus 4 percent range within a few quarters. Not all of this sharp improvement can be traced directly to fiscal stimulus, of course, but quantitative models of the U.S. economy say that a sizable chunk can be attributed to these measures. Second, job losses, which were running over 700,000 a month during January-February 2009, started to improve immediately, and positive job growth resumed in March 2010. Third, some of the sectors specifically targeted by the stimulus and related policies—such as state and local government spending, automobiles, and housing—showed noticeable improvements. These developments seem to provide at least circumstantial evidence that the fiscal policy worked. Skeptics point out that employment continued to fall into early 2010, even though the stimulus bill passed in February 2009. That’s a long lag, they argue. They also point out that the economy has a natural self-correcting mechanism that we discussed in Chapters 27, 30, and elsewhere. Even without fiscal and monetary stimulus, recessions and depressions eventually come to an end. Finally, some people credit monetary policy, rather than fiscal policy, with stimulating the economy. The debate rages on. What do you think?

LESSONS FROM THE FINANCIAL CRISIS It is far too early to have the proper historical perspective on the incredible events of 2007–2009, but we know a few things already. First, most observers think financial regulation was too “light” prior to the crisis; that is, that regulators did not properly perform the functions discussed in Chapter 29. Second, these regulatory failures extended well beyond poor job performance by regulatory personnel; myriad weaknesses in the regulatory structure became painfully clear during the crisis. Consequently, Congress is now working on rewriting many of the laws that govern financial regulation in the United States, as are the governments of other countries. Third, virtually everyone agrees that we allowed the financial system to operate with far too much leverage, a point we have discussed extensively in this chapter. In part, excessive leverage can be traced to lax regulation. But a great deal of it reflects poor business (and household) judgments. Alas, we humans—even when armed with powerful computers—are a highly fallible lot, prone to wishful thinking. Fourth, and closely related, we learned that excessive complexity and opacity can make a financial system fragile, and therefore dangerous. When investors don’t quite understand what they are buying, they are prone to panic at bad news. Fifth, we were rudely reminded that the business cycle is by no means dead. Each time our economy enjoys a lengthy period without serious recessions—such as during the long booms of the 1960s, the 1980s, and the 1990s—some analysts start waxing poetic about the death of the business cycle. But to paraphrase Mark Twain, the reports of its death have been greatly exaggerated. That means, among other things, that the lessons you learned about macroeconomics in Parts 6 and 7 are not historical relics. They are still tremendously useful in understanding the world in which you live. Sixth, what had become almost a consensus view—that the job of stabilizing aggregate demand should be assigned to monetary policy, not to fiscal policy—is no longer the consensus. With its weapons for reviving the moribund economy badly depleted in 2008

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

793

The Financial Crisis and the Great Recession

Chapter 37

and 2009, the Fed found that it needed help from the president and Congress. And the fiscal authorities delivered on a timely basis. Although still controversial (as noted in this chapter), it looks as if expansionary fiscal policy really worked in 2008 and 2009, thereby shortening and moderating the Great Recession. Seventh, we learned that expansionary monetary policy is not necessarily finished once the Fed reduces the federal funds rate to zero. The central bank under Chairman Ben Bernanke invented a number of unorthodox ways to lend to banks and nonbanks, to guarantee lending by others and, when necessary, to buy unwanted assets itself. That’s a long list of lessons, but a few years from now, the list will probably be longer still.

| SUMMARY | 7. The crisis entered a whole new stage in March 2008, when the Federal Reserve arranged, and helped finance, an emergency merger so that Bear Stearns, a large investment bank, would not fail. Six months later, Lehman Brothers, a much larger investment bank, did fail; and for the next several weeks there was utter panic in financial markets around the world.

1. An asset-price bubble occurs when the prices of some assets rise far above their fundamental values. Most observers believe that a large house-price bubble ended in the United States in 2006–2007, helping to bring on both the financial crisis and the worst recession since the 1930s. 2. A second major cause of the financial crisis was that interest rate spreads, which had narrowed to unsustainably low levels in the years 2004–2006, widened dramatically in 2007–2008, driving down the corresponding bond prices. One prominent example was mortgagebacked securities, which tumbled in value.

8. The collapse of the housing bubble and the severe damage to the financial system brought on a serious recession for three main reasons: a great deal of wealth was destroyed, spending on new houses collapsed, and businesses and households found it difficult to borrow.

3. As house prices fell, the collateral behind many mortgages automatically declined in value, making these mortgages (and hence the securities based on them) riskier and therefore less valuable in the market.

9. The U.S. government fought the recession with a tax rebate in 2008 and a vastly larger fiscal stimulus in 2009. Congress also appropriated $700 billion for the controversial Troubled Assets Relief Program (TARP) in October 2008. Much of the TARP money was used to recapitalize banks.

4. A third major cause of the crisis was the large volume of subprime mortgages that were granted during the housing boom, often to borrowers who were not creditworthy. The explosion of subprime mortgages was enabled by both poor banking practices and lax regulation.

10. At first, the Federal Reserve fought the recession in the usual way: by cutting interest rates. Eventually, the federal funds rate was reduced to nearly zero. After that, the Fed had to resort to a variety of unconventional rescue policies.

5. Perhaps the biggest and broadest cause of the financial crisis was the excessive amounts of leverage that developed all over the financial system. Since leverage magnifies both gains and losses, it boosted profits during the boom but inflicted tremendous damage when asset prices started falling.

11. The U.S. economy hit bottom in the second quarter of 2009; after that, real GDP growth resumed. But jobs did not start growing again until months later. Many, but not all, observers credit the wide-ranging fiscal and monetary policy actions with bringing the recession to a more rapid conclusion.

6. The financial crisis began in earnest in the summer of 2007 when several funds based on complex mortgage-related securities lost most of their value. That development, in turn, led investors to question the values of similar securities.

| KEY TERMS | bubble

780

leverage

782

subprime mortgage

collateral 781

mortgage

foreclosure

mortgage-backed securities (MBS) 786

785

insolvent 783 interest rate spread (risk premium) 780

781

recapitalization securitization

781

Troubled Assets Relief Program (TARP) 790

790 786

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

794

Part 9

Postscript: The Financial Crisis of 2007–2009

| TEST YOURSELF | 1. If the expected default rate on a particular mortgagebacked security is 4 percent per year, and the corresponding Treasury security carries a 3 percent annual interest rate, what should be the interest rate on the mortgage-backed security? What happens if the expected default rate rises to 8 percent?

3. Why do we say that deposits are “liabilities” of banks? 4. During the financial crisis and recovery, stock market prices first fell by about 55 percent and then rose by about 65 percent. Did investors therefore come out ahead? Explain why not.

2. Create your own numerical example to illustrate how leverage magnifies returns both on the upside and on the downside.

| DISCUSSION QUESTIONS | 1. If you were watching house prices rise during the years 2000–2006, how might you have decided whether or not you were witnessing a “bubble”? 2. What factors do you think bankers normally use to distinguish “prime” borrowers from “subprime” borrowers? 3. Explain why a mortgage-backed security becomes riskier when the values of the underlying houses decline. What, as a result, happens to the price of the mortgage-backed security? 4. Explain how a collapse in house prices might lead to a recession.

5. Explain how a collapse of the economy’s credit-granting mechanisms might lead to a recession. 6. Explain the basic idea behind the TARP legislation. Was that idea carried out in practice? 7. (More difficult) In March 2008, the Fed helped prevent the bankruptcy of Bear Stearns. However, in September 2008, the Fed and the Treasury let Lehman Brothers go bankrupt. What accounts for the different decisions? (Note: You may want to discuss this question with your instructor and/or do some Internet or library research. The answer is not straightforward.)

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Appendix: Answers to Odd-Numbered Test Yourself Questions Answers to odd-numbered Discussion Questions are available on the text support site at academic.cengage.com/economics/baumol.

CHAPTER 1: What Is Economics? Answers to Appendix Questions

3.

7

1. 6 Slope is 1 3,500 # of Job Offers

5

Total Enrollment

3,400 3,300 3,200

4 3 2

3,100

Slope is 3 1

3,000 2,900

0

1

2

3

4

# of Grades B+ or better 2,800 2000– 2001

2001– 2002

2002– 2003 Year

2003– 2004

2004– 2005

A marginal increase in the number of job offers is relatively larger with the first good grade compared to additional good grades.

Slope is 100 interpreted as 100 new students each academic year.

5. A 5 30 hr labor and 40 yd cloth 5 20 units of output. B 5 40 hr labor and 28 yd cloth 5 20 units of output. Common: 20 units of output; Difference: Amount of labor and cloth charge—more labor, less cloth.

450

CHAPTER 3: The Fundamental Economic Problem: Scarcity and Choice

Economics Enrollment

400 350 300 250 200 150 100 50 0 2000– 2001

2001– 2002

2002– 2003 Year

2003– 2004

2004– 2005

Slope is 25 interpreted as 25 new economics students each academic year.

1. This question asks the students to apply opportunity cost to a straightforward decision: to rent or buy. After buying the house, the person would no longer have to pay $24,000 annual rent. On the other hand, she would lose the $8,000 she currently earns in interest from her bank account. She would be ahead by $16,000, and the purchase is therefore a good deal. In order to get a service (housing) for which she had been willing to pay $24,000, she only has to give up (that is, the opportunity cost is) goods and services worth $8,000. It is worth pointing out to students that if she did continue to rent the house, it must be because the services she receives from the landlord are worth more than $16,000. Also, it is important to realize that this question is very simplified—it ignores home equity, property taxes, etc. 795

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

796

Appendix

equilibrium quantity is 27 million bicycles, as shown by the intersection of D1 and S1.

FIGUR E 1

15

D0

$360

S1

S0

D1 320 10 300 Price

Pizza Ovens (thousands)

FIGURE 2 20

5

250 210

0

15

30 45 60 Pizzas (millions)

75 S1

160

S0 D1

3. In case (b), the production possibilities frontier will be further from the origin in 2009, since Stromboli will have more pizza ovens with which it can produce more pizzas.

1. (a) The demand curve for a medicine that means life or death for a patient will be vertical, provided the patient has access to any money at all. One would not expect a decline in quantity demanded as the price rises, if that decline meant that the patient would die. (b) The demand curve for french fries in a food court with many other stands will be fairly flat, perhaps even horizontal. If the firm raises its price at all, many if not most of its customers will just move to a different stand. Thus a small change in price results in a large change in the amount of fries bought. 3. The answers to all three parts are shown in Figure 2. (a) Initially, the equilibrium price is $250, and the equilibrium quantity is 35 million bicycles, as shown by the intersection of D0 and S0. (b) If demand falls by 8 million bikes per year, the new demand curve is D1. The price falls to $210, and the quantity falls to 31 million, as shown by the intersection of D1 and S0. Although demand falls by 8 million at each price, the quantity exchanged falls by only 4 million because the price fall has induced a movement out along the new demand curve, as well as a movement back along the old supply curve. (c) If supply falls by 8 million bikes per year, the new supply curve is S1. The price rises to $300, and the quantity falls to 31 million, as shown by the intersection of D0 and S1. Although supply falls by 8 million at each price, the quantity exchanged falls by only 4 million because the price increase has induced a movement out along the new supply curve, as well as a movement back along the old demand curve. (d) If demand and supply each fall by 8 million bikes per year, the equilibrium price is $250, and the

27

31

35

36

40

44

Quantity (millions)

5. The same diagram, Figure 4, can be used for all three cases, because they all entail a decline in demand, from D0 to D1. Price falls from P0 to P1, and quantity falls from Q0 to Q1. (a) In a drought, people have less need for umbrellas, so demand falls. (b) Popcorn is a complement for movie tickets, so when popcorn prices rise, the demand for tickets falls. (c) Coca-Cola is a substitute for coffee, so when the price of the soda falls, the demand for coffee falls. 7. (a) Each price in Table 2 is raised by 50 cents. (b) No answer needed. (c) Yes, consumption is reduced. (d) The price rise is less than the 50 cent tax. (e) There is no answer for this question—this may be a good question to discuss in class.

FIGURE 4

D0 D1

Price

CHAPTER 4: Supply and Demand: An Initial Look

20

D0

S

P0 P1

S

D1 Q1

D0

Q0 Quantity

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

797

Appendix

of the good on the X-axis (say, compact discs). An indifference curve that is U-shaped with respect to the origin has a relatively large slope towards the upper left side and a relatively small slope towards the lower right. This indicates that a consumer who has many cookies but few compact discs is willing to give up a lot of cookies in order to get one more compact disc—but when the tables are turned, the consumer who has many compact discs and only a few cookies is willing to give up only a small number of cookies to get an additional compact disc. This is consistent with the idea of diminishing marginal utility in the case of one good considered alone.

CHAPTER 5: Consumer Choice: Individual and Market Demand 1. The total utility from 22 gallons is greater, since it is equal to the total utility (or usefulness) of the first 14 gallons, plus the total utility of the next 8.* 3. Normal: (a) and (d). Inferior: (b) and (c). 5.

Baskets

Marginal Utility ($)

Total Utility ($)

0 1 2 3 4

— 6 4 3 1

— 6 10 13 14

CHAPTER 6: Demand and Elasticity

At a price of $3 per basket Jim will buy 3 baskets. 7.

1. The answer depends upon the product, but general variables include tastes, prestige value of the product, income levels, population, prices of substitutes and complements, and new uses to which the product can be put. 3. (a) Goods with low price elasticity of demand (inelastic demand).

FIGU RE 2

(b) Goods with low price elasticity of demand (inelastic demand).

5 P

5 P

4

(c) Goods with high price elasticity of demand (elastic demand).

5 P

4

4

3

3

3

2

2

2

1

1

1

1 2 3 4 Q Jasmine (a)

1 2 3 4 Q Jim (b)

(d) Goods with high price elasticity of demand (elastic demand).

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 Q Market (c)

5. Using the formula in the text, (change in quantity/change in price) times (price/quantity), where price and quantity are the average of the beginning and ending values, the elasticity is (15,000/5) 3 (22.5/17,500) 5 3.86. 7. Complements: (b) and (c) Substitutes: (a) and (d)

Answers to Appendix Questions

CHAPTER 7: Production, Inputs, and Cost: Building Blocks for Supply Analysis

1.

1. 75

75

50

50

50 40 25

25 25 50 75 Hot Dogs

Gas

75 Gas

Gas

FIGU RE 3

25 25 50 75 Hot Dogs

25 50 75 Hot Dogs

3. The slope of an indifference curve is the maximum number of units of the good on the Y-axis (say, cookies) the consumer is willing to give up to get one more unit

Output

TFC (thousands of dollars)

AFC (thousands of dollars)

0 1 2 3 4 5 6

360 360 360 360 360 360 360

— 360 180 120 90 72 60

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

798

Appendix

7.

Cost (thousands of dollars)

F IGUR E 1

$400 360 320 280 240 200 160 120 80 40

150,000 Bushels

325,000 Bushels

$40,000 45,000 85,000 0.57

$ 80,000 90,000 170,000 0.52

TFC

Wages Rent Total Cost Average Cost

When returns to scale diminish, average costs fall. AFC

1

2

3

4

5

9. For labor, the MPP is 16, the price is $12, and the ratio of the two is a bit more than 1.3; for land, the MPP is 1,400, the price is $1,200, and the ratio of the two is less than 1.2. Since the two ratios are not equal, the farmer is not minimizing costs. She should increase labor and reduce land, thereby reducing the MPP of the former and increasing the MPP of the latter.

6

Output

3.

Answers to Appendix Questions Output

TC (thousands of dollars)

AC (thousands of dollars)

0 1 2 3 4 5 6

360 400 440 480 536 600 720

— 400 220 160 134 120 120

1.

FIGURE 4

10,000

Labor Hours

7,500

F IGURE 3

5,000 1,000 Containers 2,500

$800

600 Containers TC

Cost (thousands of dollars)

720

5,000 10,000 15,000 20,000 Glue (gallons)

640 560 480 400 320 240 160

AC

80 0

1

2

3

4

5

6

Output

5. It can raise its profits by increasing its use of oil. Adding 1 gallon of oil will raise its revenues by $2.20, and its cost by only $2.07, leaving it with an increase in profits of $0.l3.

3. When the price ratio of glue to labor falls, the ratio of glue to labor used rises. Therefore, the expansion path, which shows the amounts of glue and labor used as output rises, given unchanging factor prices, becomes flatter, or closer to the glue axis.

CHAPTER 8: Output, Price, and Profit: The Importance of Marginal Analysis 1. Unfortunately for the firm, exchange is voluntary. Assuming that the demand curve is negatively sloped, when the firm prices its product at $18, it will find buyers for less than 2 million units, and it will discover its inventory rising by more than 1 million units.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Appendix

3. One presumes that the owners of the firm would like to get as rich as possible. If they were to maximize their marginal profit, they would be forgoing wealth. A marginal profit greater than zero implies that the owners can make more money by increasing output. 5.

Garages

TR

AR

TC

AC

TP

0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

$ 0 30 56 78 96 110 120 126 128 126 120

$ 0 30 28 26 24 22 20 18 16 14 12

$ 12 40 56 66 74 80 87 96 112 144 190

$— 40 28 22 18.5 16 14.5 13.7 14 16 19

2$12 210 0 12 22 30 33 30 16 218 270

When average cost is equal to average revenue (at two garages in this example), the firm makes no profit. This is because for average revenue to equal average cost, total revenue must equal total cost. 7. At one unit, average and marginal cost are identical. Beyond one unit, since average cost is falling, marginal cost lies below average cost, as shown in Figure 1.

FIGU RE 1

Average and Marginal Costs

$800 AC 600 400

MC

200 1

2

3

Output

Answers to Appendix Questions 1.

Date

Total Grade

Average Grade

Marginal Grade

9/30 10/28 11/26 12/13 1/24

65 140 230 315 410

65 70 77 79 82

65 75 90 85 95

Note: numbers are rounded for simplicity.

799

CHAPTER 9: Investing in Business: Stocks and Bonds 1. The value of the bond times the interest rate (0.06) equals the annual payment ($3.00). So the price of the bond is the annual payment divided by the interest rate: $3.00/0.06 5 $50.00. 3. For corporations, bonds are riskier than stocks. For individual investors, stocks are riskier than bonds. 5. Ultimately, the answer to this question depends on whether or not either of these two company stocks have no risk or infinite risk. Barring those possibilities, a portfolio will lower the risk.

CHAPTER 10: The Firm and the Industry Under Perfect Competition 1. (a) A demand curve might be vertical for a good that is absolutely necessary to the continuance of life, or for a good which is so cheap, and which has so few close substitutes, that a rise in price would barely be noticed by the consumer. (b) A demand curve facing a firm in a perfectly competitive industry is horizontal. Because the products of the different firms are identical, and because there are so many firms, no single firm can take a production decision that is large enough to affect industry supply enough to alter the price. (c) A firm’s demand curve will be negatively sloping if the firm’s output is a relatively large portion of the industry’s output, or if the firm’s output is differentiated from the output of the other firms and is identifiable. Under such circumstances, if the firm seeks to sell a significantly higher output, it will have to lower its selling price in order to attract new business. (d) A firm’s demand curve might be positively sloping if it could somehow persuade the public that the quality of the good it was selling was signaled by its price. 3. If a firm is earning zero economic profit, the owner’s invested capital is earning the same return it could earn in another use, while the owner’s labor (if she is working in the firm) is earning the same income it could earn elsewhere, so the owner has no incentive to close the firm. 5. If the market price is above equilibrium, profits will attract new firms into the industry. The increase in supply will reduce the price to its equilibrium, zero-profit level.

CHAPTER 11: Monopoly 1. (a) Pure monopolist. There is no good substitute for heat (bulky sweaters don’t help a great deal), and one firm controls the source. (b) Not a pure monopolist. Consumers can buy close substitutes—that is to say, other types of personal computers—from other firms.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

800

Appendix

reduce the power-generating capacity that must be built. The resources saved can be used for something else.

(c) Not a pure monopolist. The one supplier of instant cameras is likely to have more market power than the one supplier of Getty gasoline, but still many other types of cameras are substitutes for instant cameras.

(b) In a drought-stricken area, there has to be a way to reduce water usage; otherwise, the society will simply run out and not have water for its most critical, life-saving uses. Raising the price of water can accomplish this, by inducing people to use water only for high-priority purposes.

3. The price per 50,000-gallon unit is found by multiplying by 50,000. As the following table shows, for each level of output, marginal revenue is less than price.

Output 50,000 100,000 150,000 200,000 250,000 300,000

Price

2. and 3.

MR

$14,000 13,000 11,000 10,000 8,000 6,000

$14,000 12,000 7,000 7,000 0 24,000

Buyers’ Individual Individual Firms’ Acceptable Buyer’s Marginal Actual Cumulative Total Firm’s Marginal Acceptable Buyers Price Surplus Price Surplus Surplus Price Firms

CHAPTER 12: Between Competition and Monopoly

A B C E F G

$70 60 50 40 30 20

$30 20 10 0 210 220

$40 40 40 40 40 40

$30 50530120 60550110 6056010 50560210 30550220

$30 20 10 0 210 220 230

$10 20 30 40 50 60 70

h g f e c b a

1. The payoff matrix for GM might be Table 1:

CHAPTER 15: The Shortcomings of Free Markets

TABLE 1 Hire a Movie Star

Cut Price

New Product

Hire a new star Hire a new ad agency Cut price New product

It is, of course, hard to tell what the entries in the payoff matrix will be. 3. In Table 2, we can see that if Firm A chooses the LowTech option, Firm B would be better off choosing the High-Tech option since it would get a payoff of $12 million (vs. $10 million if it chooses Low-Tech). If Firm A chooses the High-Tech option, Firm B would be better off choosing the High-Tech option once again because it would get a payoff of $3 million (vs. 2$2 million for the Low-Tech option). Therefore, High-Tech is Firm B’s dominant strategy since it is the best strategy regardless of Firm A’s strategy.

CHAPTER 14: The Case for Free Markets I: The Price System 1. (a) If there is enough electrical generating capacity to run all the air conditioners on very hot days, much of that capacity will be idle, and therefore wasted, on most days. Charging higher prices on the hot days will restrict usage at those times and therefore

1. The opportunity cost to society of a trip by a truck is the goods and services that would have been available had the trip not been made. Some of these are forgone because the gasoline used to fuel the truck is not available for other uses. The price paid for the gasoline likely represents this part of the opportunity cost quite well. But some part of the opportunity cost consists of the clean environment forgone because of the truck’s pollutants. This is not included in the price of the gas. 3. Examples of goods causing detrimental externalities: the use of substances in spray cans, which depletes the atmosphere’s ozone layer, minerals that are stripmined, forest products that destroy natural habitats when the trees are cut. Examples of goods creating beneficial externalities: freshly painted houses, workers who are trained in one firm and then work for another. 5. About $20 million will be spent in the legal battles. If any less were spent, it would be advantageous for another litigant to spend more, since the prize is worth $20 million. Perfect competition eliminates economic profits.

CHAPTER 17: Externalities, the Environment, and Natural Resources 1. At equilibrium, the price is $8, and 90 units of X are sold. Consequently, 900 pounds of pollution are emitted. 3. There are now 850 pounds of emissions.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Appendix

CHAPTER 18: Taxation and Resource Allocation 1. The tax is regressive, since the average tax rate falls as income rises:

Tax Rate Income

Tax

Marginal

Average

$20,000 30,000 40,000 50,000

$2,000 2,700 3,200 3,500

0.10 0.07 0.05 0.03

0.10 0.09 0.08 0.07

3. (a) Before the tax is imposed, the equilibrium price is $4.00 and the equilibrium quantity is 240 million cartons. (b) After the tax is imposed, the supply curve shifts up by the amount of the tax to:

Price (including tax)

Price (excluding tax)

Quantity Demanded

Quantity Supplied

$4.25 4.50 4.75 5.00

$3.00 3.25 3.50 3.75

210 180 150 120

160 180 200 240

So the new equilibrium quantity will be 180 million cartons. The new equilibrium price paid by the consumers (including the tax) will be $4.50, whereas the price received by the producers (excluding the tax) will be $3.25.

801

(f) Cigarette consumption has fallen from 240 million cartons to 180 million cartons. This may actually be the goal that the government sought, in its attempt to improve health. 5. If Taxmanians care mostly about efficiency, they will tax rice most heavily. Since the elasticities of supply and demand are both low, there will be little reduction in the quantity of rice traded as a consequence of the tax, and therefore little excess burden. If they care mostly about vertical equity, they will tax caviar most heavily, since this tax will fall only on the rich, not the poor. A tax on rice would be vertically inequitable, since the poor spend all of their income on rice while the rich spend only part of their income on rice.

CHAPTER 19: Pricing the Factors of Production 1. (a) Nuts and bolts: no economic rent. Many manufacturers easily produce nuts and bolts, and in the long run their costs are constant, that is to say, the supply curve is close to horizontal. If the price were lower, they would not be produced. (b) Petroleum: some economic rent. Petroleum has a positively sloped supply curve; some would be produced at a low price and as the price increases, more is produced (from wells that are more expensive to drill and maintain). When demand conditions are such that the price is above the minimum price, therefore, some of the oil is earning economic rent; that is, income greater than would be needed to have it produced. (c) A champion racehorse: almost all economic rent. The supply curve is vertical at a quantity of one; no matter what the price, the racehorse will still exist. Possibly at very low prices it might not be worth it to the owner and trainer to bring the horse to its full racing potential, but with that exception, all the rest of the horse’s earnings are economic rent. 3. Firms can shift part of a tax on their revenue by reducing their output and raising the price to the consumers. But owners of land cannot reduce the amount of land when a land tax is imposed, and therefore they cannot raise the price and shift the tax.

(c) Regardless of who pay it, the tax is a wedge of $1.25 between the price paid by the consumer and the price received by the seller. In the situation described in part (b), the seller may list the price at $3.25, and then require the buyer to pay a tax of $1.25 above this. Or the seller may list the price at $4.50, including tax, and give $1.25 of this to the government. In either case, the net price paid by the consumer is $4.50, the net price received by the seller is $3.25, and the equilibrium quantity is 180.

5. Capital includes various means of production that have themselves previously been produced, such as the goods produced by a factory, the equipment in that factory, and any other resources the factory uses to make its final products. Investment is an addition to capital.

(d) The sellers shift $0.50 of the tax to the buyers, since the market price rises from $4.00 to $4.50. They do this by reducing output, which raises the market price.

7. Interest is the return to the suppliers of capital or the lenders of funds. Profit is the return to entrepreneurship, and it accrues to people who take risks, who innovate, and/or who secure a monopoly position.

(e) There is excess burden borne by both buyers and sellers. The buyers’ excess burden arises from the fact that they are purchasing fewer cigarettes than before the tax. The sellers’ excess burden arises from the fact that they are producing fewer cigarettes than before.

Answers to Appendix Questions 1. The present value of $1,000 to be received in 3 years, when the rate of interest is 11 percent, is $1,000 divided by (1.11)3, or $1,000/1.368 5 $730.99.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

802

Appendix

(f) Raises GDP by $25,000.

CHAPTER 20: Labor: The Human Inputs

(g) GDP actually falls by $100. The casino is selling “gambling services” to you, which are measured by how much you lose. Winning $100 therefore reduces sales of gambling services.

1.

Number of Chefs

Number of Pizzas per Day

Marginal Physical Product

Marginal Revenue Product when P = $9

Marginal Revenue Product when P = $12

1 2 3 4 5 6

40 64 82 92 100 92

40 24 18 10 8 28

$360 216 162 90 72 272

$480 288 216 120 96 296

(a) The MPP schedule is in the third column. (b) The fourth column contains the MRP schedule, when pizzas sell for $9. (c) If the wage rate is $100, the pizza parlor hires three chefs. It would not pay to hire the fourth, because the wage would exceed the MRP. If the wage rose to $125, employment would still be three chefs. (d) The MRP schedule for pizzas priced at $12 is shown in the fifth column. At a wage of $100, the firm hires four chefs, and at a wage of $125, employment would be cut to three chefs. 3. (a) Odd-job repairs in private homes: perfect competition. (b) Low-priced clothing for women: pure monopoly. (c) Auto manufacturing: bilateral monopoly. 5. You can reduce the price in year 2010 and raise the price in 2011, thereby selling more in 2010, with its higher MR, and leaving less to sell in 2011, with its lower MR. 7. One would expect the wage of the unpleasant, dangerous job to be higher to induce individuals to take that job, but it doesn’t always work out that way in reality.

(h) GDP does not rise. Because nothing new is produced, capital gains and losses do not count in GDP. (i) GDP does not change because you did not produce a good or service. ( j) Raises GDP by $100.

CHAPTER 23: The Goals of Macroeconomic Policy 1. After 25 years Country A‘s economy has grown by 109 percent because (1.03)25 5 2.09. After 25 years Country B’s economy has grown by 167 percent because (1.04)25 5 2.67. If we index both countries’ GDP to be 100 at the start of the 25-year period, by the end of the period, Country A’s GDP would be 209 and Country B’s would be 267. Therefore, Country B’s economy would be roughly 28 percent larger than that of Country A because (267 2 209)/(209) 5 0.28. The gap between the GDPs of the two countries is larger than 25 percent due to the compounding of a 1 percent higher growth rate for 25 years. 3. If actual GDP grew slower than potential GDP from 2003 to 2006, unemployment should have increased, which it did. Similarly, from 2006 to 2009, unemployment should have decreased because actual GDP was growing faster than potential. Unemployment did, in fact, fall between 2006 and 2009. 5. (a) 18 percent (b) 14 percent (c) 10 percent (d) 3 percent (e) 22 percent

Answers to Appendix Questions 1.

CHAPTER 21: Poverty, Inequality, and Discrimination 1. The poverty rate is the percentage of families whose annual income falls below the poverty line. The rate increases during recessions.

Dow Jones Industrial Average (DJIA) CPI Deflated DJIA

1. Microeconomist: (a) and (d); macroeconomist: (b) and (c) 3. (a) Raises GDP by $50,000.

1990

2000

753 38.8 1,941

891 82.4 1,081

2,679 130.7 2,050

10,735 172.2 6,234

3.

(c) GDP does not rise, because there is no market transaction. (d) GDP rises by $500,000, the value of the newly constructed house.

1980

The deflated DJIA is found by dividing the DJIA by the CPI of the same year, then multiplying by the base year CPI, which is 100. Stock prices do not rise every decade. They declined notably during the decade between 1970 and 1980 but then rose between 1980 and 2000. Stocks were most valuable in 2000.

CHAPTER 22: An Introduction to Macroeconomics

(b) Raises GDP by $10,000.

1970

Nominal GDP Real GDP GDP deflator

2006 13,399 12,976 103.3

2007 14,078 13,254 106.2

2008 14,441 13,312 108.5

(e) GDP does not rise, because nothing new was produced.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

803

Appendix

truck by hand versus using a forklift. One forklift operator can load and unload the truck in far less time than can be done by hand.

5.

Money wages CPI Real wages

1970

1980

1990

2000

$3.23 38.8 $8.32

$6.66 82.4 $8.08

$10.01 130.7 $7.66

$13.75 172.2 $7.98

FIGURE 1

K3

1980290

1990200

106.2% 22.9%

50.3% 25.2%

37.4% 4.2%

Yc Output

Growth, money wages Growth, real wages

1970280

c K2 b

Yb

K1

a

5 240/300 5 0.8

C

$ 2,160

$ 1,920

$ 1,680

$ 1,440

2, 7

0

00

$ 1,200

$

5. Draw a graph similar to Figure 1 in the text. Higher levels of capital increase labor productivity, resulting in higher levels of output produced with the same quantity of labor. For example, in Figure 1 increasing the amount of capital from K1 to K2 increases the output from Ya to Yb. Labor productivity increases when the capital stock is larger because workers can use the additional capital to produce more goods and services. For example, imagine loading and unloading a semitrailer

5 (2,160 2 1,920)/(2,700 2 2,400)

00

3. The prices of items (b), (d), and (e) would be expected to rise rapidly over time, as each of these are personally provided services for which productivity improvements are difficult or impossible. By contrast, items (a) and (c) are not personally provided. In fact, productivity in these two electronically delivered services has increased dramatically over time, pushing down their prices.

MPC 5 [C(2007) 2 C(2006)]/[Y(2007) 2 Y(2006)]

2, 4

Productivity growth was highest for Country C, which had a very low initial level of productivity. Note that the productivity growth for Country D lagged far behind Countries B and C despite Country D’s lower starting point. As mentioned in the text, not all countries (such as Country D here) are able to participate in the convergence process. However, Countries B and C did close some of the gap on Country A.

3. Line C0 is the consumption function for Simpleland. The marginal propensity to consume can be calculated from the data for any pair of years. For example, for the period 200622007:

00

20% 40% 50% 20%

$

$48 35 3 0.60

2, 1

$40 25 2 0.50

1. Consumption (largest), government spending, investment, net exports (smallest—actually negative in the United States)

$

Productivity Growth 200022010

1, 80 0

A B C D

2010 Output per Hour

CHAPTER 25: Aggregate Demand and the Powerful Consumer

$

Country Country Country Country

2000 Output per Hour

Hours of Labor Input

1, 50 0

1. The productivity growth for each country is shown in the fourth column below.

L1

0

$

CHAPTER 24: Economic Growth: Theory and Policy

Consumer Spending

Money wages grew fastest in the decade 197021980, but real wages grew fastest in 199022000. In fact, real wages declined in the preceding two decades.

Ya

Disposable Income

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

804

Appendix

Answers to Appendix Questions

(since taxes are 10% of wages 1 interest 1 rent, which total 13.3)

1. (a) Included: GDP rises by $25,000. (b) Not included, because it was produced in another country. Actually, it is included as part of C, but then deducted as part of IM, which enters negatively in C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM ).

Note: Profits were computed as follows:

(c) Not included, since it was not produced this year. (d) Included: GDP rises by $500 million (in investment, I ).

Revenues 2 Wages 2 Interest 2 Rent 2 Intermediate goods 2 Depreciation 2 Ind. taxes 5 Profits

(e) Not included; it’s a government transfer payment. (f) Included, as investment in inventory: GDP rises by $15 million. (g) Included, as consumption (legal services): GDP rises by $10,000. (h) Not included: previously produced. 3.

Specific Motors

Super Duper

6.8 23.8 20.1 20.2

14.0 24.5 20.2 21.0 27.0 20.6 20.2 0.9

20.5 21.6

Farmers 7.0 20.7 22.0 20.2 4.3

GDP as the Sum of Final Demands (all figures in millions)

Source

C I G 3 2IM Y

Specific Motors

Super Duper

4.8 0.8 0.3 0.9

14.0

Government

Rest of World 1.0

0.8 21.0

Total 19.8 0.8 1.1 0.9 21.0 21.6

CHAPTER 26: Demand-Side Equilibrium: Unemployment or Inflation? 1.

FIGURE 1 45°

4,000 GDP as the Sum of Incomes (all figures in millions)

3,900

Specific Super Motors Duper Farmers Wages 1 Interest 1 Rent 1 Profits 5 Nat. Income 1 Ind. Bus.Tax 5 NNP 1 Depreciation 5 GDP

3.8 0.1 0.2 1.6

4.5 0.2 1.0 0.9

0.5

0.2

0.6

0.2

Government

Total

0.8

9.1 1.0 3.2 6.8 20.1 0.7 20.8 0.8 21.6

0.7 2.0 4.3

Personal income 5 National income 1 Transfer payments 5 20.1 1 1.2 5 21.3 Disposable income 5 Personal income 2 Taxes 5 21.3 2 1.33 5 19.97

Expenditure

Source 3,800

3,700 3,600

0

3,600 3,700 3,800 3,900 4,000 GDP

The original equilibrium GDP is at Y 5 3,800, where spending equals output. This is shown by the intersection of the lower of the two expenditure lines in the graph above with the 45° line. The MPC calculated from the data is 0.90, so the multiplier is 10. If investment spending rises by $20 (to $260) the equilibrium GDP will increase by $20 3 10 5 $200, which is represented by a vertical shift (by $20) to the upper expenditure function in the diagram.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

805

Appendix

3.

Income

FIGU RE 2

Price Level

$1,080 $ 880 1,140 920 1,200 960 1,260 1,000 1,320 1,040 1,380 1,080 1,440 1,120 1,500 1,160 1,560 1,200

D

110

Before Shift Consumption Expenditure

105 100 95

$1,160 1,200 1,240 1,280 1,320 1,360 1,400 1,440 1,480

After Shift Consumption Expenditure $ 920 960 1,000 1,040 1,080 1,120 1,160 1,200 1,240

$1,200 1,240 1,280 1,320 1,360 1,400 1,440 1,480 1,520

D

1, 14 0

0 12 1,

1, 10 0

0 08 1,

1, 06 0

90

GDP

At lower prices, the real value of money and other assets that are denominated in money terms is higher. Since wealth influences consumption, at lower prices consumption is higher. 5. Y 5 C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM)

The graph in Figure 3 indicates that equilibrium GDP rises from 1,320 to 1,440, or by 120. The oversimplified multiplier formula can be used in this case. The marginal propensity to consume can be calculated between any two income levels. The numbers in the table above show that each $60 of additional income leads to $40 more in consumer spending, so the MPC is 40/60 5 2/3, and the multiplier is 1/[1 2 (2/3)] 5 3. So a shift in consumption of 40 should raise equilibrium GDP by 120, which it does.

C 5 300 1 0.75DI

Answers to Appendix A Questions

C 5 300 1 0.75(Y 2 1,200) C 5 300 1 0.75Y 2 900

1. Y 5 C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM)

C 5 2600 1 0.75Y Y 5 2600 1 0.75Y 1 1,100 1 1,300 2 100 Y 5 0.75Y 1 1,700

C 5 150 1 0.75(Y 2 400) C 5 150 1 0.75Y 2 300 C 5 2150 1 0.75Y

0.25Y 5 1,700

Y 5 2150 1 0.75Y 1 300 1 400 2 50

Y 5 4 3 1,700 5 6,800 This algebraic model yields the same equilibrium GDP as Table 3 and Figure 10 in the chapter. Compared to the answer to Test Yourself Question 4, we find $800 more in GDP from a $200 increase in I. Thus this question demonstrates that the multiplier of four applies to changes in I as well as to changes in C.

Y 5 0.75Y 1 500 0.25Y 5 500 Y 5 4 3 500 5 2,000 3. Saving is equal to disposable income minus consumption. In Question 1: S 5 (Y 2 T) 2 C S 5 (2,000 2 400) 2 [2150 1 0.75(2,000)]

7.

S 5 1,600 2 (2150 1 1,500)

FIGU RE 3

S 5 1,600 2 1,350 S 5 250 45°

C1 + I + G + (X – IM)

S is not equal to I. (In Question 2, S is equal to I. The difference is that X and IM are equal in Question 2 but unequal in Question 1. 5. (a) Y 5 C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM)

Spending

C0 + I + G + (X – IM)

C 5 100 1 0.8(Y 2 500) C 5 100 1 0.8Y 2 400 C 5 2300 1 0.8Y Y 5 2300 1 0.8Y 1 700 1 500 1 0 Y 5 0.8Y 1 900 0.2Y 5 900

$1,320

$1,440

Y 5 5 3 900 5 4,500

Income

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

806

Appendix

(b) S 5 (Y 2 T) 2 C S 5 (4,500 2 500) 2 [2300 1 0.8(4,500)] S 5 4,300 2 3,600 5 700, which is equal to investment, so S 5 I. (c) Now X 2 IM 5 100, so the last four lines of 5(a) above are replaced by

CHAPTER 27: Supply-Side Equilibrium: Unemployment and Inflation? 1.

FIGURE 1

Y 5 2300 1 0.8Y 1 700 1 500 1 100 Y 5 0.8Y 1 1,000

Full employment

0.2Y 5 1,000

Aggregate supply $110

S 5 (Y 2 T) 2 C

$105

Price Level

Y 5 5 3 1,000 5 5,000

S 5 (5,000 2 500) 2 [2300 1 0.8(5,000)] S 5 4,800 2 4,000 5 800 Now, S is not equal to I.

$100 $95 Aggregate demand

$90

Answers to Appendix B Questions 1.

00

00

,8

$2

,9

$2

00 100 200 , , ,0 $3 $3 $3

GDP

Exports

Imports

Net Exports

GDP

$2,500 3,000 3,500 4,000 4,500 5,000

$400 400 400 400 400 400

$250 300 350 400 450 500

$150 100 50 0 250 2100

Equilibrium real output is $3,000, whereas the price level is 100. Full employment is at $2,800 billion, so there is an inflationary gap of 200. 3.

FIGURE 2

F IGUR E 4

$115 45°

$110

Spending

$4,500

C + I + G1 + (X1 – IM)

$4,000 C + I + G + (X0 – IM )

Price Level

$5,000 $105 $100 $95

$3,500 $90

$3,000

$3,600 $3,700 $3,800 $3,900 $4,000 $4,100

$2,500

$2 ,5 00 $3 ,0 00 $3 ,5 00 $4 ,0 00 $4 ,5 00 $5 ,0 00

GDP

Income

3. In Figure 4, the intersection of the upper expenditure line with the 45° line shows an equilibrium GDP of 4,500. (The lower expenditure line shows the solution to Test Yourself Question 2, with a GDP of 4,000.) Exports have risen by 250, and GDP has risen by 500, so the multiplier is two.

(a) In Chapter 26, Test Yourself Question 2, the marginal propensity to consume was 0.9, and the (oversimplified) multiplier was therefore 10. The table in this question confirms that when investment rises by 20, from 240 to 260, aggregate demand rises by 200 at any given price level. For example, at a price level of 105, aggregate demand rises from 3,770 to 3,970. (b) Initial equilibrium: P 5 100, Y 5 3,800. Eventual equilibrium: P 5 110, Y 5 3,940. The multiplier, taking account of price increases, is 140/20 5 7, which is less than 10.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Appendix

807

expenditure by 60. You may raise government spending on GDP by 60, or you may lower taxes or raise transfer payments by 80 (since 3/4 of 80 is 60).

CHAPTER 28: Managing Aggregate Demand: Fiscal Policy

Answers to Appendix A Questions

1.

GDP

Taxes

Disposable Income Consumption Total Expenditure

$1,360 $400 1,480 400 1,600 400 1,720 400 1,840 400

$ 960 1,080 1,200 1,320 1,440

$ 720 810 900 990 1,080

$1,450 1,540 1,630 1,720 1,810

FIGU RE 1

1. (a) Variable tax (as GDP rises, people drive more); (b) variable tax; (c) fixed tax; (d) variable tax 3. The higher fixed tax reduces consumer spending, but the lower income-tax rate increases consumer spending. The question is: Which effect is larger? The answer is found by seeing which tax change is larger, since C depends on DI 5 Y 2 T. At a GDP of Y 5 10,000 billion, a two percentage point cut in the income-tax rate reduces tax receipts by $200 billion, which is larger than the $100 billion fixed-tax increase. So C, and hence equilibrium GDP on the demand side, rises.

Answers to Appendix B Questions

45° C + I + G0 + (X – IM)

1. Y 5 C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM) Spending

C + I + G1 + (X – IM )

C 5 120 1 0.8DI DI 5 Y 2 T DI 5 Y 2 (200 1 0.25Y) DI 5 0.75Y 2 200 C 5 120 1 0.8(0.75Y 2 200) C 5 0.6Y 2 40

$1 ,8 40

$1 ,7 20

$1 ,6 00

$1 ,4 80

$1 ,3 60

C 5 120 1 0.6Y 2 160 Y 5 0.6Y 2 40 1 320 1 480 2 80 Y 5 0.6Y 1 680

Income

0.4Y 5 680 Equilibrium GDP is 1,720 (see diagram). The marginal propensity to consume is 0.75 and the multiplier is four. If government purchases fall by 60, and the price level is unchanged, GDP would fall by 4 3 60 5 240, that is, to 1,480. 3. At each level of GDP, G is now higher by 120, whereas C is lower by 3/4 of 120, or 90. Therefore, there is a net increase in total expenditure of 30 at each level of GDP, as shown in the following table:

GDP

Taxes

$1,360 $520 1,480 520 1,600 520 1,720 520 1,840 520

Disposable Income Consumption Total Expenditure $ 840 960 1,080 1,200 1,320

$630 720 810 900 990

$1,480 1,570 1,660 1,750 1,840

Y 5 (1/0.4) 3 680 Y 5 2.5 3 680 5 1,700 Equilibrium GDP is 1,700. There are three different ways to find the multipliers, any one of which is correct. For government purchases: 1. Note from the preceding equations that equilibrium GDP is 2.5 times all autonomous spending. Since G is autonomous spending, the multiplier for G is 2.5. 2. Raise G from 480 to 481. Working through the algebra above, this comes to 0.4Y 5 681, which implies that Y 5 1,702.5. So the increase in G of 1 has raised Y by 2.5, and the multiplier is 2.5. 3. From the formula in the appendix, the multiplier is 1/1 2 b(1 2 t) 5 1/[1 2 0.8(1 2 0.25)] 5 1/[1 2 0.8(0.75)] 5 1/(1 2 0.6) 5 1/0.4 5 2.5

Equilibrium GDP is now 1,840, which is 120 more than in Test Yourself Question 1. 5. The answer to Test Yourself Question 2 is 1,720. So you want to increase GDP by 120 (raising it to 1,840). Because the marginal propensity to consume is 0.75, and the marginal tax rate is 1/3, the multiplier is 2. Therefore, you must take some action that will have the initial effect of raising

for fixed taxes. 1. Note that a rise in fixed taxes decreases GDP (so the sign of the multiplier is negative) and that it increases spending in the first round by the marginal propensity to consume times the tax reduction. So the tax multiplier is the multiplier found above, multiplied by (minus) the MPC, or 2.5 3 (20.8) 5 22.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

808

Appendix

5 540 2 [(1/3) 3 1500]

2. Raise fixed taxes in the model from 200 to 201. Working through the algebra, this comes to 0.4Y 5 679.2, or Y 5 1,698. So an increase in taxes of 1 has reduced GDP by 2, and the multiplier is 22.

5 540 2 500 5 40 (b) Since the budget deficit in part (a) is 40, the government would reduce its purchases by 40, to 500. Repeating the steps above, but now with G 5 500:

3. From the formula in the appendix, the tax multiplier is 2b/1 2 b(1 2 t) 5 20.8/[1 2 0.8(1 2 0.25)] 5 20.8/[1 2 0.8(0.75)] 5 20.8/(1 2 0.6) 5 20.8/0.4 5 22

Y 5 0.6Y 1 100 1 500 2 40 Y 5 0.6Y 1 560

To raise GDP by 100, the government can (a) raise G by 40, and the multiplier of 2.5 will do the rest, or (b) lower taxes or raise transfer payments by 50, and the multiplier of 22 will do the rest.

0.4Y 5 560 Y 5 (1/0.4) 3 560 Y 5 2.5 3 560 5 1,400

3. (a) Y 5 C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM)

Budget deficit 5 G 2 T

C 5 0.9(Y 2 T)

5 500 2 [(1/3) 3 1,400]

C 5 0.9[Y 2 (1/3) Y]

5 500 2 4662/3

C5 0.9[(2/3)Y]

5 331⁄3

C5 0.6Y

GDP falls by 100, to 1,400. That drop reduces tax receipts, which are one-third of GDP, by 331⁄3 (to 4662/3). So in the new equilibrium, the deficit has fallen by only 62/3 (to 331⁄3), not by the full 40 in lower spending. Although G fell by the amount of the deficit, this in turn caused Y to fall, which in turn lowered taxes, and the deficit persisted.

Y 5 0.6Y 1 100 1 540 2 40 Y 5 0.6Y 1 600 0.4Y 5 600 Y 5 (1/0.4) 3 600 Y 5 2.5 3 600 5 1,500 Budget deficit 5 G 2 T

CHAPTER 29: Money and the Banking System 1. Under those conditions, the money multiplier is 1/.10, or 10, so an infusion of $12 million into reserves will support an increase in money of $120 million. 3.

(a) Assets Reserves 2100

(c)

(b) Liabilities Deposits 2100

Assets Reserves

1100

CHAPTER 30: Managing Aggregate Demand: Monetary Policy 1. In each case, there is $60 billion in the form of cash in circulation, and the rest of the money supply is held in bank deposits, backed by $60 billion in reserves. The total money supply is calculated as follows:

Assets

Liabilities Deposits

1100

Reserve Ratio 10% 12.5% 16 2/3%

Liabilities

Hometown Bank Reserves 2500 Big City Bank

Deposits

2500

Reserves 1500 All Banks Reserves no change

Deposits

1500

Deposits no change

Money Multiplier

Total Deposits

Money Supply

10 8 6

$600 480 360

$660 540 420

The M1 money supply always exceeds total deposits by the $60 billion in cash outside banks.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

809

Appendix

3. Note: all figures are in billions of dollars.

Bill Gates Assets

Liabilities

Deposit at B of A 15 no change

The Fed simply creates the $5 billion (in the form of bank reserves) to buy the bonds. In the long run, it makes no difference whether the Fed buys the bonds from a bank or from an individual. In this case, Bank of America’s $5 billion in new reserves are offset by $5 billion in new deposits, so that not all of the new reserves are excess reserves, whereas if the Fed had bought the bonds from Bank of America directly there would have been no change in deposits, and all the new reserves would have been excess. In the long run, however, the new reserves of $5 billion will support the same increase in deposits. Why? Because in this case, the original transaction between the Fed and Bill Gates already creates $5 billion in new deposits.

Bank of America Assets Liabilities Reserves 15

Y5C1I C 5 300 1 0.75Y

Bank reserves 15

(c) If it follows a monetarist policy, it can restore the original quantity of money, M0, by increasing the supply curve to M2S2. This will have the effect of reducing the interest rate still further, to r2.

FIGURE 1 M0

S1

S0 S2

M1 r0 Interest Rate

7. There are several ways to solve this problem. Investment (I) can be found at the three different interest rates, and then equilibrium GDP can be calculated three times using the three different values for I. Alternatively, a more general solution just works with the symbol r for the interest rate:

Bonds 15

(b) It can restore the previous interest rate, r0, by lowering the money supply curve to M1S1. This will further reduce the quantity of moneyto M2.

(b) A reduction in interest rates of 2.5 percentage points stimulates $75 billion of new investment spending. (d) The aggregate supply curve is horizontal, and GDP rises by $150 billion.

Deposits 15 Bonds 25

Federal Reserve Liabilities

(a) It can accept the new money supply and interest rate.

5. (a) A $5 billion increase in the bank reserves lowers interest rates by 2.5 percentage points.

(c) Aggregate demand rises by $150 billion.

Assets

r1 r2 D0 M1

M0 M2

M2

D1

M1 M0 Money

I 5 1,000 2 100r Y 5 300 1 0.75Y 1 1,000 2 100r Y 5 1,300 1 0.75Y 2 100r 0.25Y 5 1,300 2 100r Y 5 4(1,300 2 100r) Y 5 5,200 2 400r Therefore: (a) If r 5 0.02, Y 5 5,192. (b) If r 5 0.05, Y 5 5,180. (c) If r 5 0.1, Y 5 5,160.

CHAPTER 31: The Debate over Monetary and Fiscal Policy 1. Based on recent data, the velocity of money in the United States, for M1, is about 9.5210. Students will probably calculate a much higher velocity for themselves. 3. In Figure 1, M0S0 is the initial money supply. The demand for money falls from M0D0 to M1D1; as a consequence, the quantity of money in the economy falls from M0 to M1, and the interest rate falls from r0 to r1. The Fed has three choices.

5. (a) Since people hold no currency, M 5 D. Both M and D will therefore be (1/0.2) 3 $50 billion 5 5 3 $50 billion5 $250 billion. If the Fed increases reserves to $60 billion, M and D will rise to $300 billion instead. The money multiplier is therefore $50/$10 5 5. (b) Now, since people hold currency, M 5 C 1 D 5 1.2D, because C 5 0.2D. The $50 billion monetary base (B 5 50) must now serve two purposes: bank reserves plus currency, B 5 R 1 C. Since R 5 0.2D (reserve requirements) and C 5 0.2D (currency holdings), this means B 5 0.4D. With B 5 50, D 5 125 now. But now people also hold 0.2 3 $125 5 $25 billion in currency, so the money supply is M 5 D 1 C 5 $150. Notice that the money supply is much less than in part (a). The reason is that half of the monetary base is now used as currency rather than as bank reserves. (Notice that required reserves are 0.2 3 $125 5 $25 billion and cash holdings are also $25 billion.) When the Fed increases the monetary base to $60 billion, the equation B 5 R 1 C now becomes 60 5 0.4D, so deposits rise to D 5 $150 billion ($60/0.4). With an additional C 5 $30 billion in cash in circulation (0.2 3 $150), the money supply will rise

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

810

Appendix

CHAPTER 32: Budget Deficits in the Short and Long Run 1. The budget deficit is an annual-flow concept. It is the excess of government expenditures over government revenues in a given year. The national debt is an accumulated stock of debt. It is increased each year by the deficit or reduced by the surplus. If the deficit becomes a surplus, the debt will fall (although the accumulated debt may still be very large). 3. Expansionary monetary policy will raise GDP, and this will raise tax receipts. The lower interest rates will also decrease the government’s interest payments. Both changes will reduce the government’s budget deficit. If the government tries to counteract the Fed’s positive effect on aggregate demand, it will institute a more contractionary fiscal policy by decreasing government spending or raising taxes, or both. The deficit will shrink still more.

CHAPTER 33: The Trade-Off between Inflation and Unemployment 1. Figure 1 shows that when the aggregate supply curve is vertical, shifting aggregate demand curves change only the price level, not output.

1. (a) In the absence of trade, 1 barrel of wine costs 4 yards of cloth in England. (b) In the absence of trade, 1 barrel of wine costs 2 yards of cloth in Portugal. (c)

FIGURE 1 12 10 8 6 4 2 2 4 6 Wine (millions of barrels) (a) England

Cloth (millions of yards)

(c) As the monetary base increases, the money supply M increases as well. However, the size of the increase in the money supply depends both on the required reserve ratio (0.2) in the example and how much the public holds in currency (zero in part (a), 0.2D in part (b)). In part (a), the monetary base (B 5 R 1 C) and bank reserves are identical because C 5 0. So all $10 billion in new monetary base goes into bank reserves, where it supports $50 billion in new deposits. But in part (b), half of the new $10 billion in monetary base gets absorbed by currency holdings, leaving an increase of only $5 billion in bank reserves—which supports only $25 billion in new deposits.

CHAPTER 34: International Trade and Comparative Advantage

Cloth (millions of yards)

to M 5 D 1 C 5 $150 1 $30 5 $180. So the money multiplier is just $30/$10 5 3 now.

12 10 8 6 4 2 2 4 6 Wine (millions of barrels) (b) Portugal

(d) Portugal has the absolute advantage in the production of both goods, and the comparative advantage in wine. England has the comparative advantage in cloth. (e) When trade opens, England will specialize in cloth and export it to Portugal, which in turn will specialize in wine and export it to England. (f) In the international market, the price of a barrel of wine will wind up somewhere between 4 yards and 2 yards of cloth, perhaps 3. Stated another way, the price of 1 yard of cloth will be between 1/2 gallon of wine and 1/4 gallon of wine.

Answers to Appendix Questions 1. (a)

FIGURE 3

F IGUR E 1 D1 S

Price Level

D0 P1

6 Price (thousands)

Price (thousands)

6 5 4 3 2 1 0

P0 D1

5 4 3 2 1

20 40 60 80 100 Quantity (thousands)

0

20 40 60 80 100 Quantity (thousands)

United States

Japan Microcomputers

S

D0

Y0 GDP

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

811

Appendix

(b) If there is no trade, in the United States the equilibrium price is $5,000 and the equilibrium quantity is 50,000 units. In Japan, the price is $1,000 and the quantity is 50,000. (c) The new world price will be $3,000 because, at that price, world quantity demanded is 100,000 units (70,000 plus 30,000) and world quantity supplied is also 100,000 units (40,000 plus 60,000). The price of computers has fallen in the United States and risen in Japan. (Note: To arrive at the answer graphically, construct world demand and supply curves. The equilibrium will be found at a world price of $3,000.) (d) Japan will export 30,000 computers. (e) In the United States, computer production falls from 50,000 to 40,000, and therefore employment in the computer industry falls. In Japan, computer production rises from 50,000 to 60,000, with a consequent increase in employment. Initially, American consumers and Japanese computer producers (both employers and employees) are helped by free trade, whereas American computer producers and Japanese consumers are hurt.

CHAPTER 36: Exchange Rates and the Macroeconomy 1. In Figure 1, the economy begins at A, with price P0 and output Y0, resulting from aggregate demand D0 and aggregate supply S0. The currency appreciation leads to a decrease in exports and therefore a decrease in aggregate demand to D1. Because imported inputs become less expensive, it also leads to an increase in aggregate supply to S1. The price level will definitely fall to P1 in the diagram. Whether output falls or rises depends on the relative strength of the aggregate demand and aggregate supply effects, but since the aggregate demand shift is probably greater, output is likely to decrease, as shown in the diagram, to Y1.

FIGURE 1 D0 S0 S1

1. One can use supply and demand curves for either the yen or the dollar. If one chooses the market for dollars, then the exchange rate measured on the vertical axis is the price of a dollar in yen:

Price Level

CHAPTER 35: The International Monetary System: Order or Disorder?

D1 P0

P1 D0 S0 S1

(a) Japanese imports increase and U.S. exports increase. So the demand for dollars rises, and the dollar therefore appreciates. (b) Because Japanese stocks are less attractive, there is less capital outflow from the United States to Japan to buy stocks. The supply of dollars decreases, and the dollar therefore appreciates. (c) With lower interest rates, American financial assets become less attractive. So capital flows out of the United States (or less flows in). This increases the supply of dollars, leading to a depreciation of the dollar. (d) The increase in foreign aid increases the supply of dollars and leads to a depreciation of the dollar. (e) Because the Japanese economy booms and the U.S. economy is in a recession, Japanese imports increase while U.S. imports fall. Japanese demand for dollars therefore increases, whereas U.S. supply of dollars decreases. So the dollar appreciates. (f) At any given exchange rate, higher U.S. inflation causes an increase in imports and a decrease in exports. This leads to consequent increases in the supply of dollars and decreases in the demand for dollars. Therefore, the dollar depreciates. 3. Items (a) and (c) would lead to a depreciation of the dollar. Items (b) and (e) would lead to an appreciation. Item (d) would have no effect on the value of the dollar because it is purely a domestic transaction.

A

D1 Y1

Y0 GDP

3. (a) Y 5 C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM) C 5 150 1 0.75DI C 5 150 1 0.75(0.8)Y C 5 150 1 0.6Y I 5 300 1 0.2Y 2 50(r) I 5 300 1 0.2Y 2 50(8) I 5 0.2Y 2 100 (X 2 IM) 5 300 2 (250 1 0.2Y) (X 2 IM) 5 50 2 0.2Y Y 5 150 1 0.6Y 1 0.2Y 2 100 1 800 1 50 2 0.2Y Y 5 900 1 0.6Y 0.4Y 5 900 Y 5 2.5(900) Y 5 2,250 G 2 T 5 800 2 0.2(2,250) G 2 T 5 800 2 450 G 2 T 5 350

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

812

Appendix

X 2 IM 5 50 2 0.2(2,250) X 2 IM 5 50 2 450 X 2 IM 5 2400

CHAPTER 37: The Financial Crisis and the Great Recession

(b) Y 5 C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 IM) C 5 150 1 0.75DI C 5 150 1 0.75(0.8)Y C 5 150 1 0.6Y I 5 300 1 0.2Y 2 50(r) I 5 300 1 0.2Y 2 50(8) I 5 0.2Y 2 100

1. With a 4% expected default rate, the interest rate should be 7% (4% 1 3%). If the expected default rate rises to 8%, the interest rate should rise to 11% (8% 1 3%). (NOTE TO INSTRUCTORS: These suggested answers assume, e.g., 4% and 8% default probabilities with 100% loss, or 8% and 16% default probabilities with 50% loss, and so on. Thus other correct answers are possible.) 3. Deposits are liabilities because, if converted into cash, the bank will have to pay out the cash.

(X 2 IM) 5 250 2 (0.2Y) (X 2 IM) 5 250 2 0.2Y Y 5 150 1 0.6Y 1 0.2Y 2 100 1 800 1 250 2 0.2Y Y 5 1,100 1 0.6Y 0.4Y 5 1,100 Y 5 2.5(1,100) Y 5 2,750 G 2 T 5 800 2 0.2(2,750) G 2 T 5 800 2 55 G 2 T 5 250 X 2 IM 5 250 2 0.2(2,750) X 2 IM 5 250 2 550 X 2 IM 5 2300

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Glossary 45° line Rays through the origin with a slope of 1 are called 45° lines because they form an angle of 45° with the horizontal axis. A 45° line marks off points where the variables measured on each axis have equal values. (p. 18) 45° line diagram An income-expenditure diagram, or 45° line diagram, plots total real expenditure (on the vertical axis) against real income (on the horizontal axis). The 45° line marks off points where income and expenditure are equal. (p. 564) Ability-to-pay principle The ability-topay principle of taxation refers to the idea that people with greater ability to pay taxes should pay higher taxes. (p. 384) Absolute advantage One country is said to have an absolute advantage over another in the production of a particular good if it can produce that good using smaller quantities of resources than can the other country. (p. 727) Abstraction Abstraction means ignoring many details so as to focus on the most important elements of a problem. (p. 9) Affirmative action Affirmative action refers to active efforts to locate and hire members of underrepresented groups. (p. 458) Agents Agents are people hired to run a complex enterprise on behalf of the principals, those whose benefit the enterprise is supposed to serve. (p. 321) Aggregate demand Aggregate demand is the total amount that all consumers, business firms, government agencies, and foreigners spend on final goods and services. (p. 538) Aggregate demand curve The aggregate demand curve shows the quantity of domestic product that is demanded at each possible value of the price level. (pp. 470, 564) Aggregate supply curve The aggregate supply curve shows, for each possible price level, the quantity of goods and services that all the nation’s businesses are willing to produce during a specified period of time, holding all other determinants of aggregate quantity supplied constant. (pp. 470, 584)

Aggregation Aggregation means combining many individual markets into one overall market. (p. 468) Allocation of resources Allocation of resources refers to the society’s decisions on how to divide up its scarce input resources among the different outputs produced in the economy and among the different firms or other organizations that produce those outputs. (p. 47) Antitrust policy Antitrust policy refers to programs and laws that preclude the deliberate creation of monopoly and prevent powerful firms from engaging in related “anticompetitive practices.” (p. 265) Applied research Applied research is research whose goal is to invent or improve particular products or processes, often for profit. Note, however, that the military and government health-related agencies provide examples of not-for-profit applied research. (p. 351) Appreciate A nation’s currency is said to appreciate when exchange rates change so that a unit of its currency can buy more units of foreign currency. (pp. 746, 765) Asset An asset of an individual or business firm is an item of value that the individual or firm owns. (p. 635) Automatic stabilizer An automatic stabilizer is a feature of the economy that reduces its sensitivity to shocks, such as sharp increases or decreases in spending. (p. 609) Autonomous increase in consumption An autonomous increase in consumption is an increase in consumer spending without any increase in consumer incomes. It is represented on a graph as a shift of the entire consumption function. (p. 573) Average physical product (APP) The average physical product (APP) is the total physical product (TPP) divided by the quantity of input. Thus, APP 5 TPP/X where X 5 the quantity of input. (p. 130) Average revenue (AR) The average revenue (AR) is total revenue (TR) divided by quantity. (p. 160) Average tax rate The average tax rate is the ratio of taxes to income. (p. 379)

Backward-bending A supply curve of labor is backward-bending when a rise in an initially low wage leads to a rise in quantity of labor supplied, but a rise in a wage that was already high reduces the amount supplied. (p. 427) Balance of payments deficit The balance of payments deficit is the amount by which the quantity supplied of a country’s currency (per year) exceeds the quantity demanded. Balance of payments deficits arise whenever the exchange rate is pegged at an artificially high level. (p. 753) Balance of payments surplus The balance of payments surplus is the amount by which the quantity demanded of a country’s currency (per year) exceeds the quantity supplied. Balance of payments surpluses arise whenever the exchange rate is pegged at an artificially low level. (p. 753) Balance sheet A balance sheet is an accounting statement listing the values of all assets on the left side and the values of all liabilities and net worth on the right side. (p. 636) Barriers to entry Barriers to entry are attributes of a market that make it more difficult or expensive for a new firm to open for business than it was for the firms already present in that market. (p. 219) Barter Barter is a system of exchange in which people directly trade one good for another, without using money as an intermediate step. (p. 627) Basic research Basic research refers to research that seeks to provide scientific knowledge and general principles rather than coming up with any specific marketable inventions. (p. 350) Beneficial or detrimental externality An activity is said to generate a beneficial or detrimental externality if that activity causes incidental benefits or damages to others not directly involved in the activity and no corresponding compensation is provided to or paid by those who generate the externality. (p. 312) Benefits principle The benefits principle of taxation holds that people who derive benefits from a service should pay the taxes that finance it. (p. 385) 813

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

814

Glossary

Bilateral monopoly A bilateral monopoly is a market situation in which there is both a monopoly on the selling side and a monopsony on the buying side. (p. 433) Bond A bond is simply an IOU sold by a corporation that promises to pay the holder of the bond a fixed sum of money at the specified maturity date and some other fixed amount of money (the coupon or interest payment) every year up to the date of maturity. (p. 180)

financial assets to and from citizens and companies of other countries. (p. 754) Capital formation Capital formation is synonymous with investment. It refers to the process of building up the capital stock. (p. 522) Capital gain A capital gain is the difference between the price at which an asset is sold and the price at which it was bought. (p. 506)

Bubble A bubble is an increase in the price of an asset or assets that goes far beyond what can be justified by improving fundamentals, such as dividends and earnings for shares of stock or incomes and interest rates for houses. (p.780)

Capitalism Capitalism is an economic system in which most of the production process is controlled by private firms operating in markets with minimal government control. The investors in these firms (called “capitalists”) own the firms. (p. 335)

Budget deficit The budget deficit is the amount by which the government’s expenditures exceed its receipts during a specified period of time, usually a year. If receipts exceed expenditures, it is called a budget surplus instead. (pp. 687, 771)

Cartel A cartel is a group of sellers of a product who have joined together to control its production, sale, and price in the hope of obtaining the advantages of monopoly. (p. 243)

Budget line, household The budget line for a household graphically represents all possible combinations of two commodities that it can purchase, given the prices of the commodities and some fixed amount of money at its disposal. (p. 100) Budget line, firm A firm’s budget line is the locus of all points representing every input combination of inputs that the producer can afford to buy with a given amount of money and given input prices. (p. 150) Budget surplus The budget surplus is the amount by which the government’s receipts exceed its expenditures during a specified period of time, usually a year. If expenditures exceed receipts, it is called a budget deficit instead. (p. 687) Bundling Bundling refers to a pricing arrangement under which the supplier offers substantial discounts to customers if they buy several of the firm’s products, so that the price of the bundle of products is less than the sum of the prices of the products if they were bought separately. (p. 271) Burden of a tax The burden of a tax to an individual is the amount one would have to be given to be just as well off with the tax as without it. (p. 386) Capital A nation’s capital is its available supply of plant, equipment, and software. It is the result of past decisions to make investments in these items. (pp. 401, 522) Capital account The capital account balance includes purchases and sales of

Central bank A central bank is a bank for banks. The United States’ central bank is the Federal Reserve System. (p. 647) Central bank independence Central bank independence refers to the central bank’s ability to make decisions without political interference. (p. 648) Closed economy A closed economy is one that does not trade with other nations in either goods or assets. (pp. 24, 769) Collateral Collateral is the asset or assets that a borrower pledges in order to guarantee repayment of a loan. If the borrower fails to pay, the collateral becomes the property of the lender. (p. 781) Collective bargaining Collective bargaining is the process of negotiation of wages and working conditions between a union and the firms in the industry. (p. 433) Commodity money Commodity money is an object in use as a medium of exchange, but that also has a substantial value in alternative (nonmonetary) uses. (p. 629) Common stock A common stock (also called a share) of a corporation is a piece of paper that gives the holder of the stock a share of the ownership of the company. (p. 180) Comparative advantage One country is said to have a comparative advantage over another in the production of a particular good relative to other goods if it produces that good less inefficiently as compared with the other country. (pp. 49, 727)

Complements Two goods are called complements if an increase in the quantity consumed of one increases the quantity demanded of the other, all other things remaining constant. (p. 117) Concentration of an industry Concentration of an industry measures the share of the total sales or assets of the industry in the hands of its largest firms. (p. 267) Concentration ratio A concentration ratio is the percentage of an industry’s output produced by its four largest firms. It is intended to measure the degree to which the industry is dominated by large firms. (p. 267) Consumer expenditure Consumer expenditure (C) is the total amount spent by consumers on newly produced goods and services (excluding purchases of new homes, which are considered investment goods). (p. 538) Consumer Price Index (CPI) The Consumer Price Index (CPI) is measured by pricing the items on a list representative of a typical urban household budget. (p. 512) Consumer’s surplus Consumer’s surplus is the difference between the value to the consumer of the quantity of Commodity X purchased and the amount that the market requires the consumer to pay for that quantity of X. (pp. 93, 299) Consumption function The consumption function shows the relationship between total consumer expenditures and total disposable income in the economy, holding all other determinants of consumer spending constant. (p. 544) Convergence hypothesis The convergence hypothesis holds that nations with low levels of productivity tend to have high productivity growth rates, so that international productivity differences shrink over time. (p. 521) Coordination failure A coordination failure occurs when party A would like to change his behavior if party B would change hers, and vice versa, and yet the two changes do not take place because the decisions of A and B are not coordinated. (p. 568) Corporate income tax The corporate income tax is a tax levied on the profits of corporations, after all expenditures on wages, interest, rent, and purchases of other inputs are deducted. (p. 381) Corporation A corporation is a firm that has the legal status of a fictional individual.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Glossary

815

This fictional individual is owned by a number of persons, called its stockholders, and is run by a set of elected officers and a board of directors, whose chairperson is often also in a powerful position. (p. 179)

and sales of goods and services, crossborder interest and dividend payments, and cross-border gifts to and from both private individuals and governments. It is approximately the same as net exports. (p. 754)

Depreciation Depreciation is the value of the portion of the nation’s capital equipment that is used up within the year. It tells us how much output is needed just to maintain the economy’s capital stock. (pp. 555, 765)

Correlated Two variables are said to be correlated if they tend to go up or down together. Correlation need not imply causation. (p. 11)

Cyclical unemployment Cyclical unemployment is the portion of unemployment that is attributable to a decline in the economy’s total production. Cyclical unemployment rises during recessions and falls as prosperity is restored. (p. 498)

Derivative A derivative is a financial instrument whose value depends on the prices of some other assets. For example, a derivative contract may entitle its owner to buy 100 shares of Company X's stock at a price of $30 in four months, where $30 may be higher or lower than the market price of that stock at the specified date. (p. 188)

Cost disease of the personal services The cost disease of the personal services is the tendency of the costs and prices of these services to rise persistently faster than those of the average output in the economy. (pp. 327, 530) Credible threat A credible threat is a threat that does not harm the threatener if it is carried out. (p. 255) Credit default swap A credit default swap (CDS) is a financial instrument that functions like an insurance policy that protects a lender. The buyer of a CDS pays the seller for insuring against a third-party's default on a debt that is owed to the former. If the third party defaults on the debt, failing to make the required repayment, the seller of the CDS must pay a lump sum to the buyer of the CDS. (p. 188) Cross elasticity of demand The cross elasticity of demand for product X to a change in the price of another product, Y, is the ratio of the percentage change in quantity demanded of X to the percentage change in the price of Y that brings about the change in quantity demanded. (p. 117) Cross licensing Cross licensing of patents occurs when each of two firms agrees to let the other use some specified set of its patents, either at a price specified in their agreement or in return for access to the other firm’s patents. (p. 352) Cross-subsidization Cross-subsidization means selling one product of the firm at a loss, which is balanced by higher profits on another of the firm’s products. (p. 275) Crowding in Crowding in occurs when government spending, by raising real GDP, induces increases in private investment spending. (p. 695) Crowding out Crowding out occurs when deficit spending by the government forces private investment spending to contract. (p. 694) Current account The current account balance includes international purchases

Deflating Deflating is the process of finding the real value of some monetary magnitude by dividing by some appropriate price index. (p. 513) Deflation Deflation refers to a sustained decrease in the general price level. (p. 477) Demand curve A demand curve is a graphical depiction of a demand schedule. It shows how the quantity demanded of some product will change as the price of that product changes during a specified period of time, holding all other determinants of quantity demanded constant. (p. 58) Demand schedule A demand schedule is a table showing how the quantity demanded of some product during a specified period of time changes as the price of that product changes, holding all other determinants of quantity demanded constant. (p. 58) Demand-side inflation Demand-side inflation is a rise in the price level caused by rapid growth of aggregate demand. (p. 702) Depletable A commodity is depletable if it is used up when someone consumes it. (p. 317) Deposit creation Deposit creation refers to the process by which a fractional reserve banking system turns $1 of bank reserves into several dollars of bank deposits. (p. 636) Deposit insurance Deposit insurance is a system that guarantees that depositors will not lose money even if their bank goes bankrupt. (p. 634) Depreciate A nation’s currency is said to depreciate when exchange rates change so that a unit of its currency can buy fewer units of foreign currency. (p. 746)

Derived demand The derived demand for an input is the demand for the input by producers as determined by the demand for the final product that the input is used to produce. (p. 400) Devaluation A devaluation is a reduction in the official value of a currency. (p. 747) Development assistance Development assistance (“foreign aid”) refers to outright grants and low-interest loans to poor countries from both rich countries and multinational institutions like the World Bank. The purpose is to spur economic development. (p. 531) Direct controls Direct controls are government rules that tell organizations or individuals what processes or raw materials they may use or what products they are permitted to supply or purchase. (p. 364) Direct taxes Direct taxes are taxes levied directly on people. (p. 379) Discounting, or computing the present value The process that has been invented for making the magnitudes of payments at different dates comparable to one another is called discounting, or computing the present value. (p. 417) Discount rate The discount rate is the interest rate the Fed charges on loans that it makes to banks. (p. 654) Discouraged worker A discouraged worker is an unemployed person who gives up looking for work and is therefore no longer counted as part of the labor force. (p. 498) Disposable income Disposable income (DI) is the sum of the incomes of all individuals in the economy after all taxes have been deducted and all transfer payments have been added. (p. 539)

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

816

Glossary

Division of labor Division of labor means breaking up a task into a number of smaller, more specialized tasks so that each worker can become more adept at a particular job. (p. 48) Dominant strategy A dominant strategy for one of the competitors in a game is a strategy that will yield a higher payoff than any of the other strategies that are possible, no matter what choice of strategy is made by competitors. (p. 250) Dumping Dumping means selling goods in a foreign market at lower prices than those charged in the home market. (p. 737) Earned Income Tax Credit (EITC) The Earned Income Tax Credit (EITC) is a federal program like a negative income tax. It supplements earnings up to a point via an income tax credit and, beyond that point, taxes those benefits away. (p. 457) Economic discrimination Economic discrimination occurs when equivalent factors of production receive different payments for equal contributions to output. (p. 452) Economic model An economic model is a simplified, small-scale version of some aspect of the economy. Economic models are often expressed in equations, by graphs, or in words. (p. 12) Economic profit Economic profit equals net earnings, in the accountant’s sense, minus the opportunity costs of capital and of any other inputs supplied by the firm’s owners. (pp. 159, 209, 412) Economic rent Economic rent is any portion of the payment to labor or any other input that does not lead to an increase in the amount of labor supplied. (p. 406) Economies of scale Economies of scale are savings that are obtained through increases in quantities produced. Scale economies occur when an X percent increase in input use raises output by more than X percent, so that the more the firm produces, the lower its per unit costs become. (pp. 142, 264) Economies of scope Economies of scope are savings that are obtained through simultaneous production of many different products. They occur if a firm that produces many commodities can supply each good more cheaply than a firm that produces fewer commodities. (p. 274) Efficiency A set of outputs is said to be produced efficiently if, given current technological knowledge, there is no way one can produce larger amounts of

any output without using larger input amounts or giving up some quantity of another output. (p. 47) Efficient allocation of resources An efficient allocation of resources is one that takes advantage of every opportunity to make some individuals better off in their own estimation while not worsening the lot of anyone else. (p. 288) Elastic demand curve A demand curve is elastic when a given percentage price change leads to a larger percentage change in quantity demanded. (p. 112) Emissions permits Emissions permits are licenses issued by government specifying the maximum amount the license holder is allowed to emit. The licenses are restricted to permit a limited amount of emissions in total. Often, they must be purchased from the government or on a special market. (p. 366) Entrepreneurship Entrepreneurship is the act of starting new firms, introducing new products and technological innovations, and, in general, taking the risks that are necessary to seek out business opportunities. (p. 398) Equation of exchange The equation of exchange states that the money value of GDP transactions must be equal to the product of the average stock of money times velocity. That is: M 3 V 5 P 3 Y. (p. 662) Equilibrium An equilibrium is a situation in which there are no inherent forces that produce change. Changes away from an equilibrium position will occur only as a result of “outside events” that disturb the status quo. (pp. 65, 560) Equities Equities and common stocks are essentially the same thing—pieces of paper issued by a company that give the holder a share of the ownership of that company and offers payments to the holder that are called dividends. The amount of these payments may be high, low, and sometimes even zero, depending on the company's profit earnings (or losses) during the time period for which the dividends are paid. (p. 184) Excess burden The excess burden of a tax to an individual is the amount by which the burden of the tax exceeds the tax that is paid. (p. 386)

which another currency can be bought. (pp. 746, 765) Excise tax An excise tax is a tax levied on the purchase of some specific good or service. (p. 381) Excludable A commodity is excludable if someone who does not pay for it can be kept from enjoying it. (p. 317) Expansion path The expansion path is the locus of the firm’s cost-minimizing input combinations for all relevant output levels. (p. 151) Expenditure schedule An expenditure schedule shows the relationship between national income (GDP) and total spending. (p. 563) Export subsidy An export subsidy is a payment by the government to exporters to permit them to reduce the selling prices of their goods so they can compete more effectively in foreign markets. (p. 733) Externality An activity is said to generate a beneficial or detrimental externality if that activity causes incidental benefits or damages to others not directly involved in the activity, and no corresponding compensation is provided to or paid by those who generate the externality. (pp. 312, 334, 356) Factors of production Inputs or factors of production are the labor, machinery, buildings, and natural resources used to make outputs. (pp. 22, 397) Federal funds rate The federal funds rate is the interest rates that banks pay and receive when they borrow reserves from one another. (p. 650) Fiat money Fiat money is money that is decreed as such by the government. It is of little value as a commodity, but it maintains its value as a medium of exchange because people have faith that the issuer will stand behind the pieces of printed paper and limit their production. (p. 630) Final goods and services Final goods and services are those that are purchased by their ultimate users. (p. 473) Fiscal federalism Fiscal federalism refers to the system of grants from one level of government to the next. (p. 384)

Excess reserves Excess reserves are any reserves held in excess of the legal minimum. (p. 636)

Fiscal policy The government’s fiscal policy is its plan for spending and taxation. It can be used to steer aggregate demand in the desired direction. (pp. 479, 605, 685)

Exchange rate The exchange rate states the price, in terms of one currency, at

Fixed cost A fixed cost is the cost of an input whose quantity does not rise when

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Glossary

output goes up, one that the firm requires to produce any output at all. The total cost of such indivisible inputs does not change when the output changes. Any other cost of the firm’s operation is called a variable cost. (p. 129) Fixed exchange rates Fixed exchange rates are rates set by government decisions and maintained by government actions. (p. 753) Fixed taxes Fixed taxes are taxes that do not vary with the level of GDP. (p. 619) Floating exchange rates Floating exchange rates are rates determined in free markets by the law of supply and demand. (p. 747) Foreclosure Foreclosure is the legal process through which a mortgage lender obtains control of the property after the mortgage goes into default. (p. 785) Foreign direct investment Foreign direct investment is the purchase or construction of real business assets—such as factories, offices, and machinery—in a foreign country. (p. 531) Fractional reserve banking Fractional reserve banking is a system under which bankers keep as reserves only a fraction of the funds they hold on deposit. (p. 632) Frictional unemployment Frictional unemployment is unemployment that is due to normal turnover in the labor market. It includes people who are temporarily between jobs because they are moving or changing occupations, or are unemployed for similar reasons. (p. 498) Full employment Full employment is a situation in which everyone who is willing and able to work can find a job. At full employment, the measured unemployment rate is still positive. (p. 499) GDP deflator The price index used to deflate nominal GDP is called the GDP deflator. It is a broad measure of economy-wide inflation; it includes the prices of all goods and services in the economy. (p. 513) Gold standard The gold standard is a way to fix exchange rates by defining each participating currency in terms of gold and allowing holders of each participating currency to convert that currency into gold. (p. 755) Government purchases Government purchases (G) refer to the goods (such as airplanes and paper clips) and services (such as school teaching and police protection)

817

purchased by all levels of government. (p. 539)

in better machines as a way to increase their productivity. (p. 429)

Gross domestic product (GDP) Gross domestic product (GDP) is the sum of the money values of all final goods and services produced in the domestic economy and sold on organized markets during a specified period of time, usually a year. (pp. 23, 337, 472, 552)

Incidence of a tax The incidence of a tax is an allocation of the burden of the tax to specific individuals or groups. (p. 387)

Gross national product (GNP) Gross national product (GNP) is a measure of all final production, making no adjustment for the fact that some capital is used up each year and thus needs to be replaced. (p. 555) Gross private domestic investment (I) Gross private domestic investment includes business investment in plant, equipment, and software; residential construction; and inventory investment. (p. 553) Growth policy Growth policy refers to government policies intended to make the economy grow faster in the long run. (p. 490) Herfindahl-Hirschman Index (HHI) The Herfindahl-Hirschman Index (HHI) is an alternative and widely used measure of the degree of concentration of an industry. It is calculated, in essence, by adding together the squares of the market shares of the firms in the industry, although the smallest firms may be left out of the calculation because their small market share numbers have a negligible effect on the result. (p. 267) High-tech (high-technology) A high-tech (high-technology) firm or industry is one whose products, equipment and production methods utilize highly advanced technology that is constantly modified and improved. Examples are the aerospace, scientific instruments, computer, communications, and pharmaceutical industries. (p. 341) Horizontal equity Horizontal equity is the notion that equally situated individuals should be taxed equally. (p. 384) Human capital Human capital is the amount of skill embodied in the workforce. It is most commonly measured by the amount of education and training. (p. 520) Human capital theory Human capital theory focuses on the expenditures that have been made to increase the productive capacity of workers via education or other means. It is analogous to investment

Income effect The income effect of a rise in wages is the resulting rise of workers’ purchasing power that enables them to afford more leisure. (p. 426) Income elasticity of demand Income elasticity of demand is the ratio of the percentage change in quantity demanded to the percentage change in income. (p. 116) Income-expenditure diagram An incomeexpenditure diagram, or 45° line diagram, plots total real expenditure (on the vertical axis) against real income (on the horizontal axis). The 45° line marks off points where income and expenditure are equal. (p. 564) Increasing returns to scale Production is said to involve economies of scale, also referred to as increasing returns to scale, if, when all input quantities are increased by X percent, the quantity of output rises by more than X percent. (p. 142) Index fund An index fund is a mutual fund that chooses a particular stock price index and then buys the stocks (or most of the stocks) that are included in the index. The value of an investment in an index fund depends on what happens to the prices of all stocks in that index. (p. 184) Indexing Indexing refers to provisions in a law or a contract whereby monetary payments are automatically adjusted whenever a specified price index changes. Wage rates, pensions, interest payments on bonds, income taxes, and many other things can be indexed in this way, and have been. Sometimes such contractual provisions are called escalator clauses. (p. 716) Index number An index number expresses the cost of a market basket of goods relative to its cost in some “base” period, which is simply the year used as a basis of comparison. (p. 511) Index number problem When relative prices are changing, there is no such thing as a “perfect price index” that is correct for every consumer. Any statistical index will understate the increase in the cost of living for some families and overstate it for others. At best, the index can represent the situation of an “average” family. (p. 511) Indifference curve An indifference curve is a line connecting all combinations of

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

818

Glossary

the commodities that are equally desirable to the consumer. (p. 102) Indirect taxes Indirect taxes are taxes levied on specific economic activities. (p. 379) Induced increase in consumption An induced increase in consumption is an increase in consumer spending that stems from an increase in consumer incomes.It is represented on a graph as a movement along a fixed consumption function. (p. 573) Induced investment Induced investment is the part of investment spending that rises when GDP rises and falls when GDP falls. (p. 563) Industrial Revolution The Industrial Revolution is the stream of new technology and the resulting growth of output that began in England toward the end of the eighteenth century. (p. 335) Inelastic demand curve A demand curve is inelastic when a given percentage price change leads to a smaller percentage change in quantity demanded. (p. 112) Infant-industry argument The infantindustry argument for trade protection holds that new industries need to be protected from foreign competition until they develop and flourish. (p. 736) Inferior good An inferior good is a commodity whose quantity demanded falls when the purchaser’s real income rises, all other things remaining equal. (p. 96) Inflation Inflation refers to a sustained increase in the general price level. Inflation occurs when prices in an economy rise rapidly. The rate of inflation is calculated by averaging the percentage growth rate of the prices of a selected sample of commodities. (pp. 181, 471) Inflationary gap The inflationary gap is the amount by which equilibrium real GDP exceeds the full-employment level of GDP. (pp. 567, 589) Innovation Innovation is the process that begins with invention and includes improvement to prepare the invention for practical use and marketing of the invention or its products. (pp. 338, 413, 526) Innovative entrepreneur An innovative entrepreneur is someone who introduces into the economy a new product or a new process for producing goods, or finds a new market for the sale of commodities or a new way of conducting business. (p. 436)

Input-output analysis Input-output analysis is a mathematical procedure that takes account of the interdependence among the economy’s industries and determines the amount of output each industry must provide as inputs to the other industries in the economy. (p. 296) Inputs Inputs or factors of production are the labor, machinery, buildings, and natural resources used to make outputs. (pp. 22, 42, 489) Insolvent A company is insolvent when the value of its liabilities exceeds the value of its assets, that is, when its net worth is negative. (p. 783) Interest Interest is the payment for the use of funds employed in the production of capital; it is measured as the percent per year of the value of the funds tied up in the capital. (p. 402) Interest rate The interest rate is the amount that borrowers currently pay to lenders per dollar of the money borrowed—it is the current market price of a loan. (p. 181) Interest rate spread (risk premium) An interest rate spread or risk premium is the difference between an interest rate on a risky asset and the corresponding interest rate on a risk-free Treasury security. (p. 780) Intermediate good An intermediate good is a good purchased for resale or for use in producing another good. (p. 473) International capital flows International capital flows are purchases and sales of financial assets across national borders. (p. 768) Invention Invention is the act of discovering new products or new ways of making products. (pp. 338, 413, 526) Investment Investment is the flow of resources into the production of new capital. It is the labor, steel, and other inputs devoted to the construction of factories, warehouses, railroads, and other pieces of capital during some period of time. (pp. 401, 522) Investment in human capital Investment in human capital is any expenditure on an individual that increases that person’s future earning power or productivity. (p. 422) Investment spending Investment spending (I) is the sum of the expenditures of business firms on new plant and equipment and households on new homes.

Financial “investments” are not included, nor are resales of existing physical assets. (p. 539) Invisible hand The invisible hand is a phrase used by Adam Smith to describe how, by pursuing their own self-interests, people in a market system are “led by an invisible hand” to promote the well-being of the community. (p. 56) Kinked demand curve A kinked demand curve is a demand curve that changes its slope abruptly at some level of output. (p. 249) Labor force The labor force is the number of people holding or seeking jobs. (p. 492) Labor productivity Labor productivity is the amount of output a worker turns out in an hour (or a week, or a year) of labor. If output is measured by GDP, it is GDP per hour of work. (p. 491) Labor union A labor union is an organization made up of a group of workers (usually with the same specialization, such as plumbing or costume design, or in the same industry). The unions represent the workers in negotiations with employers over issues such as wages, vacations, and sick leave. (p. 431) Laissez-faire Laissez-faire refers to a situation in which there is minimal government interference with the workings of the market system. The term implies that people should be left alone in carrying out their economic affairs. (p. 293) “Law” of demand The “law” of demand states that a lower price generally increases the amount of a commodity that people in a market are willing to buy. Therefore, for most goods, market demand curves have negative slopes. (p. 97) “Law” of diminishing marginal utility The “law” of diminishing marginal utility asserts that additional units of a commodity are worth less and less to a consumer in money terms. As the individual’s consumption increases, the marginal utility of each additional unit declines. (p. 87) Law of supply and demand The law of supply and demand states that in a free market the forces of supply and demand generally push the price toward the level at which quantity supplied and quantity demanded are equal. (p. 66) Leverage When an asset is bought with leverage, the buyer uses borrowed money to supplement his own funds.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Glossary

Leverage is typically measured by the ratio of assets to equity. For example, if the buyer commits $100,000 of his or her own funds and borrows $900,000 to purchase a $1 million asset, we say that leverage is 10-to-1 ($1 million divided by $100,000). (p. 782) Liability A liability of an individual or business firm is an item of value that the individual or firm owes. Many liabilities are known as debts. (p. 635) Limited liability Limited liability is a legal obligation of a firm’s owners to pay back company debts only with the money they have already invested in the firm. (p. 180) Liquidity An asset’s liquidity refers to the ease with which it can be converted into cash. (p. 631) Long run The long run is a period of time long enough for all of the firm’s current commitments to come to an end. (p. 129) M1 The narrowly defined money supply, usually abbreviated M1, is the sum of all coins and paper money in circulation, plus certain checkable deposit balances at banks and savings institutions. (p. 631) M2 The broadly defined money supply, usually abbreviated M2, is the sum of all coins and paper money in circulation, plus all types of checking account balances, plus most forms of savings account balances, plus shares in money market mutual funds. (p. 631) Marginal analysis Marginal analysis is a method for calculating optimal choices— the choices that best promote the decision maker’s objective. It works by testing whether, and by how much, a small change in a decision will move things toward or away from the goal. (p. 88) Marginal land Marginal land is land that is just on the borderline of being used—that is, any land the use of which would be unprofitable if the farmer had to pay even a penny of rent. (p. 407)

Marginal private cost (MPC) The marginal private cost (MPC) is the share of an activity’s marginal cost that is paid for by the persons who carry out the activity. (p. 313) Marginal profit Marginal profit is the addition to total profit resulting from one more unit of output. (p. 163) Marginal propensity to consume (MPC) The marginal propensity to consume (MPC) is the ratio of changes in consumption relative to changes in disposable income that produce the change in consumption. On a graph, it appears as the slope of the consumption function. (p. 544) Marginal revenue (MR) Marginal revenue (MR) is the addition to total revenue resulting from the addition of one unit to total output. Geometrically, marginal revenue is the slope of the total revenue curve at the pertinent output quantity. Its formula is MR 1 5 TR 1 2 TR 0 , and so on. (p. 160) Marginal revenue product (MRP) The marginal revenue product (MRP) of an input is the money value of the additional sales that a firm obtains by selling the marginal physical product of that input. (pp. 133, 398) Marginal revenue product of labor (MRPL) The marginal revenue product of labor (MRPL) is the increase in the employer’s total revenue that results when it hires an additional unit of labor. (p. 422) Marginal social benefit (MSB) The marginal social benefit (MSB) of an activity is the sum of its marginal private benefit (MPB) plus its incidental benefits (positive or negative) that are received by others, and for which those others do not pay. (p. 313) Marginal social cost (MSC) The marginal social cost (MSC) of an activity is the sum of its marginal private cost (MPC) plus its incidental costs (positive or negative) that are borne by others who receive no compensation for the resulting damage to their well-being. (p. 313)

Marginal physical product (MPP) The marginal physical product (MPP) of an input is the increase in total output that results from a one-unit increase in the input quantity, holding the amounts of all other inputs constant. (pp. 131, 398)

Marginal tax rate The marginal tax rate is the fraction of each additional dollar of income that is paid in taxes. (p. 379)

Marginal private benefit (MPB) The marginal private benefit (MPB) is the share of an activity’s marginal benefit that is received by the persons who carry out the activity. (p. 313)

Marginal utility The marginal utility of a commodity to a consumer (measured in money terms) is the maximum amount of money that she or he is willing to pay for one more unit of that commodity. (p. 86)

819

Market demand curve A market demand curve shows how the total quantity of some product demanded by all consumers in the market during a specified period of time changes as the price of that product changes, holding all other things constant. (p. 96) Market system A market system is a form of economic organization in which resource allocation decisions are left to individual producers and consumers acting in their own best interests without central direction. (p. 50) Maximin criterion The maximin criterion requires a player to select the strategy that yields the maximum payoff on the assumption that the opponent will do as much damage as it can. (p. 252) Mediation Mediation takes place during collective bargaining when a neutral individualis assigned the job of persuading the two parties to reach an agreement. (p. 441) Medium of exchange The medium of exchange is the object or objects used to buy and sell other items such as goods and services. (p. 628) Mercantilism Mercantilism is a doctrine that holds that exports are good for a country, whereas imports are harmful. (p. 732) Misallocated resources Resources are misallocated if it is possible to change the way they are used or the combination of goods and services they produce and thereby make consumers and producers better off. (p. 311) Mixed economy A mixed economy is one with some public influence over the workings of free markets. There may also be some public ownership mixed in with private property. (p. 36) Monetarism Monetarism is a mode of analysis that uses the equation of exchange to organize and analyze macroeconomic data. (p. 665) Monetary policy Monetary policy refers to actions taken by the Federal Reserve to influence aggregate demand by changing interest rates. (pp. 481, 645, 685) Monetize the deficit The central bank is said to monetize the deficit when it purchases bonds issued by the government. (p. 693) Money Money is the standard object used in exchanging goods and services. In

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

820

Glossary

short, money is the medium of exchange. (p. 628)

large variety of mutual funds, such as stock funds, bond funds, and so forth. (p. 184)

Money-fixed asset A money-fixed asset is an asset whose value is a fixed number of dollars. (p. 546)

Nash equilibrium A Nash equilibrium results when each player adopts the strategy that gives the highest possible payoff if the rival sticks to the strategy it has chosen. (p. 253)

Money multiplier The money multiplier is the ratio of newly created bank deposits to new reserves. (p. 640) Monopolistic competition Monopolistic competition refers to a market in which products are heterogeneous but which is otherwise the same as a market that is perfectly competitive. (p. 237) Monopoly power Monopoly power (or market power) is the ability of a business firm to earn high profits by raising the prices of its products above competitive levels and to keep those prices high for a substantial amount of time. (p. 264) Monopoly profits Monopoly profits are any excess of the profits earned persistently by a monopoly firm over and above those that would be earned if the industry were perfectly competitive. (p. 224) Monopsony A monopsony is a market situation in which there is only one buyer. (p. 433) Moral hazard Moral hazard refers to the tendency of insurance to discourage policyholders from protecting themselves from risk. (pp. 320, 634) Mortgage A home mortgage is a particular type of loan used to buy a house. The house normally serves as the collateral for the mortgage. (p. 781) Mortgage-backed security A mortgagebacked security is a type of security whose returns to investors come from a large pool of mortgages and home-equity loans. Investors who hold these securities receive a portion of the interest and principal payments made by property owners on their mortgages and home-equity loans. (p. 786) Multinational corporations Multinational corporations are corporations, generally large ones, which do business in many countries. Most, but not all, of these corporations have their headquarters in developed countries. (p. 531) Multiplier The multiplier is the ratio of the change in equilibrium GDP (Y) divided by the original change in spending that causes the change in GDP. (p. 569) Mutual fund A mutual fund, in which individual investors can buy shares, is a private investment firm that holds a portfolio of securities. Investors can choose among a

National debt The national debt is the federal government’s total indebtedness at a moment in time. It is the result of previous budget deficits. (p. 687) National income National income is the sum of the incomes that all individuals in the country earn in the forms of wages, interest, rents, and profits. It includes indirect business taxes, but excludes transfer payments and makes no deduction for income taxes. (p. 539, 554) National income accounting The system of measurement devised for collecting and expressing macroeconomic data is called national income accounting. (p. 552) Natural monopoly A natural monopoly is an industry in which advantages of largescale production make it possible for a single firm to produce the entire output of the market at lower average cost than a number of firms, each producing a smaller quantity. (p. 220) Natural rate of unemployment The economy’s self-correcting mechanism always tends to push the unemployment rate back toward a specific rate of unemployment that we call the natural rate of unemployment. (p. 707) Near moneys Near moneys are liquid assets that are close substitutes for money. (p. 631) Negative income tax (NIT) The negative income tax (NIT) is a program where people below a certain income range would receive a payment from the government. (p. 456) Net exports Net exports, or X 2 IM, is the difference between exports (X) and imports (IM). It indicates the difference between what we sell to foreigners and what we buy from them. (pp. 539, 764) Net national product (NNP) Net national product (NNP) is a measure of production. NNP is conceptually identical to national income. However, in practice, national income accountants estimate income and production independently; and so the two measures are never precisely equal. (p. 554) Net worth Net worth is the value of all assets minus the value of all liabilities. (p. 636)

Nominal GDP Nominal GDP is calculated by valuing all outputs at current prices. (p. 472) Nominal rate of interest The nominal rate of interest is the percentage by which the money the borrower pays back exceeds the money that was borrowed, making no adjustment for any decline in the purchasing power of this money that results from inflation. (p. 505) Oligopoly An oligopoly is a market dominated by a few sellers, at least several of which are large enough relative to the total market to be able to influence the market price. (p. 241) On-the-job training On-the-job training refers to skills that workers acquire while at work, rather than in school or in formal vocational training programs. (p. 525) Open economy An open economy is one that trades with other nations in goods and services, and perhaps also trades in financial assets. (pp. 24, 763) Open-market operations Open-market operations refer to the Fed’s purchase or sale of government securities through transactions in the open market. (p. 649) Opportunity cost The opportunity cost of some decision is the value of the next best alternative that must be given up because of that decision (for example, working instead of going to school). (pp. 4, 41) Optimal decision An optimal decision is one that best serves the objectives of the decision maker, whatever those objectives may be. It is selected by explicit or implicit comparison with the possible alternative choices. The term optimal connotes neither approval nor disapproval of the objective itself. (pp. 42, 119, 156) Origin (of a graph) The “0” point in the lower-left corner of a graph where the axes meet is called the origin. Both variables are equal to zero at the origin. (p. 14) Outputs The outputs of a firm or an economy are the goods and services it produces. (pp. 22, 42, 489) Patent A patent is a privilege granted to an inventor, whether an individual or a firm, that for a specified period of time prohibits anyone else from producing or using that invention without the permission of the holder of the patent. (p. 219) Payoff matrix A payoff matrix shows how much each of two competitors (players) can expect to earn, depending on the strategic choices each of them makes. (p. 250)

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Glossary

Payroll tax The payroll tax is a tax levied on the earnings from work. In the United States, the tax starts at the first dollar earned and ends at an upper limit that increases each year. (p. 381) Per capita income Per capita income in an economy is the average income of all people in that economy. (p. 334) Perfect competition Perfect competition occurs in an industry when that industry is made up of many small firms producing homogeneous products, when there is no impediment to the entry or exit of firms, and when full information is available. (p. 198) Perfectly contestable A market is perfectly contestable if entry and exit are costless and unimpeded. (p. 257) Personal income tax The personal income tax is a tax levied on the income of an individual or a family, typically with a progressive rate structure. (p. 379) Phillips curve A Phillips curve is a graph depicting the rate of unemployment on the horizontal axis and either the rate of inflation or the rate of change of money wages on the vertical axis. Phillips curves are normally downward sloping, indicating that higher inflation rates are associated with lower unemployment rates. (p. 703) Plowback Plowback (or retained earnings) is the portion of a corporation’s profits that management decides to keep and reinvest in the firm’s operations rather than paying out as dividends to stockholders. (p. 182) Pollution charges Pollution charges (taxes on emissions) are taxes that polluters are required to pay. The amount they pay depends on what they emit and in what quantities. (p. 364) Portfolio diversification Portfolio diversification means inclusion of a number and variety of stocks, bonds, and other such items in an individual’s portfolio. If the individual owns airline stocks, for example, diversification requires the purchase of a stock or bond in a very different industry, such as breakfast cereal production. (p. 184) Potential GDP Potential GDP is the real GDP that the economy would produce if its labor and other resources were fully employed. (p. 492) Poverty line The poverty line is an amount of income below which a family is considered “poor.” (p. 447)

Predatory pricing Predatory pricing is pricing that threatens to keep a competitor out of the market. It is a price that is so low that it will be profitable for the firm that adopts it only if a rival is driven from the market. (p. 270) Price cap A price cap is a ceiling above which regulators do not permit prices to rise. The cap is designed to provide an efficiency incentive to the firm by allowing it to keep part of any savings in costs it can achieve. (p. 278) Price ceiling A price ceiling is a maximum that the price charged for a commodity cannot legally exceed. (p. 70) Price discrimination Price discrimination is the sale of a given product at different prices to different customers of the firm, when there are no differences in the costs of supplying these customers. Prices are also discriminatory if it costs more to supply one customer than another, but they are charged the same price. (p. 227) (Price) elasticity of demand The (price) elasticity of demand is the ratio of the percentage change in quantity demanded to the percentage change in price that brings about the change in quantity demanded. (p. 109) Price floor A price floor is a legal minimum below which the price charged for a commodity is not permitted to fall. (p. 73) Price index A price index expresses the cost of a market basket of goods relative to its cost in some “base” period, which is simply the year used as a basis of comparison. (p. 511) Price leadership Under price leadership, one firm sets the price for the industry and the others follow. (p. 245) Price taker Under perfect competition, the firm is a price taker. It has no choice but to accept the price that has been determined in the market. (p. 199) Price war In a price war, each competing firm is determined to sell at a price that is lower than the prices of its rivals, often regardless of whether that price covers the pertinent cost. Typically, in such a price war, Firm A cuts its price below Firm B’s price; B retaliates by undercutting A; and so on and on until some of the competitor firms surrender and let themselves be undersold. (p. 245) Principals Agents are people hired to run a complex enterprise on behalf of the

821

principals, those whose benefit the enterprise is supposed to serve. (p. 321) Principle of increasing costs The principle of increasing costs states that as the production of a good expands, the opportunity cost of producing another unit generally increases. (p. 44) Private good A private good is a commodity characterized by both depletability and excludability. (p. 317) Process innovation A process innovation is an innovation that changes the way in which a commodity is produced. (p. 349) Producer’s surplus The producer’s surplus from a sale is the difference between the market price of the item sold and the lowest price at which the supplier would be willing to provide the item. (p. 299) Product innovation A product innovation is the introduction of a good or service that is entirely new or involves major modifications of earlier products. (p. 348) Production function The economy’s production function shows the volume of output that can be produced from given inputs (such as labor and capital), given the available technology. (p. 492) Production indifference curve A production indifference curve (sometimes called an isoquant) is a curve showing all the different quantities of two inputs that are just sufficient to produce a given quantity of output. (p. 149) Production indifference map A production indifference map is a graph whose axes show the quantities of two inputs that are used to produce some output. A curve in the graph corresponds to some given quantity of that output, and the different points on that curve show the different quantities of the two inputs that are just enough to produce the given output. (p. 19) Production possibilities frontier The production possibilities frontier is a curve that shows the maximum quantities of outputs it is possible to produce with the available resource quantities and the current state of technological knowledge. (pp. 43, 311) Productivity Productivity is the amount of output produced by a unit of input. (pp. 334, 586) Progressive tax A progressive tax is one in which the average tax rate paid by an individual rises as income rises. (pp. 35, 379)

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

822

Glossary

Property rights Property rights are laws and/or conventions that assign owners the rights to use their property as they see fit (within the law)—for example, to sell the property and to reap the benefits (such as rents or dividends) while they own it. (p. 524) Property tax The property tax is levied on the assessed values of taxable properties, such as houses and office buildings. (p. 383) Proportional tax A proportional tax is one in which the average tax rate is the same at all income levels. (p. 379) Public good A public good is a commodity or service whose benefits are not depleted by an additional user and from which it is generally difficult or impossible to exclude people, even if the people are unwilling to pay for the benefits. (p. 317) Purchasing power The purchasing power of a given sum of money is the volume of goods and services that it will buy. (p. 501) Pure monopoly A pure monopoly is an industry in which there is only one supplier of a product for which there are no close substitutes and in which it is very difficult or impossible for another firm to coexist. (p. 218) Quantity demanded The quantity demanded is the number of units of a good that consumers are willing and can afford to buy over a specified period of time. (p. 57) Quantity supplied The quantity supplied is the number of units that sellers want to sell over a specified period of time. (p. 61) Quantity theory of money The quantity theory of money assumes that velocity is (approximately) constant. In that case, nominal GDP is proportional to the money stock. (p. 663) Quota A quota specifies the maximum amount of a good that is permitted into the country from abroad per unit of time. (p. 732) Random walk The time path of a variable such as the price of a stock is said to constitute a random walk if its magnitude in one period (say, May 2, 2005) is equal to its value in the preceding period (May 1, 2005) plus a completely random number. That is: Price on May 2, 2005 5 Price on May 1, 2005 1 Random number, where the random number (positive or

negative) can be obtained by a roll of dice or some such procedure. (p. 190) Ratchet A ratchet is an arrangement that permits some economic variable, such as investment or advertising, to increase, but prevents that variable from subsequently decreasing. (p. 348) Rational expectations Rational expectations are forecasts that, although not necessarily correct, are the best that can be made given the available data. Rational expectations, therefore, cannot err systematically. If expectations are rational, forecasting errors are pure random numbers. (p. 712) Ray through the origin (or Ray) Lines whose Y-intercept is zero have so many special uses in economics and other disciplines that they have been given a special name: a ray through the origin, or a ray. (p. 17)

Regulation Regulation of industry is a process established by law that restricts or controls some specified decisions made by the affected firms; it is designed to protect the public from exploitation by firms with monopoly power. Regulation is usually carried out by a special government agency assigned the task of administering and interpreting the law. That agency also acts as a court in enforcing the regulatory laws. (p. 273) Relative price An item’s relative price is its price in terms of some other item rather than in terms of dollars. (p. 503) Rent seeking Rent seeking refers to unproductive activity in the pursuit of economic profit—in other words, profit in excess of competitive earnings. (p. 320) Repeated game A repeated game is one that is played over again a number of times. (p. 254)

Real GDP Real GDP is calculated by valuing outputs of different years at common prices. Therefore, real GDP is a far better measure than nominal GDP of changes in total production. (p. 472)

Required reserves Required reserves are the minimum amount of reserves (in cash or the equivalent) required by law. Normally, required reserves are proportional to the volume of deposits. (p. 635)

Real GDP per capita Real GDP per capita is the ratio of real GDP divided by population. (p. 476)

Research and development (R&D) Research and development (R&D) is the activity of firms, universities, and government agencies that seeks to invent new products and processes and to improve those inventions so that they are ready for the market or other users. (pp. 340, 526)

Real rate of interest The real rate of interest is the percentage increase in purchasing power that the borrower pays to the lender for the privilege of borrowing. It indicates the increased ability to purchase goods and services that the lender earns. (p. 505) Real wage rate The real wage rate is the wage rate adjusted for inflation. Specifically, it is the nominal wage divided by the price index. The real wage thus indicates the volume of goods and services that the nominal wages will buy. (p. 501) Recapitalization A bank is said to be recapitalized when some investor, private or government, provides new equity capital in return for partial ownership. (p. 790) Recession A recession is a period of time during which the total output of the economy declines. (pp. 24, 471) Recessionary gap The recessionary gap is the amount by which the equilibrium level of real GDP falls short of potential GDP. (pp. 567, 589) Regressive tax A regressive tax is one in which the average tax rate falls as income rises. (p. 379)

Resources Resources are the instruments provided by nature or by people that are used to create goods and services. Natural resources include minerals, soil, water, and air. Labor is a scarce resource, partly because of time limitations (the day has only 24 hours) and partly because the number of skilled workers is limited. Factories and machines are resources made by people. These three types of resources are often referred to as land, labor, and capital. They are also called inputs or factors of production. (p. 40) Retained earnings Plowback (or retained earnings) is the portion of a corporation’s profits that management decides to keep and reinvest in the firm’s operations rather than paying out as dividends to stockholders. (p. 182) Revaluation A revaluation is an increase in the official value of a currency. (p. 747) Risk premium An interest rate spread or risk premium is the difference between an interest rate on a risky asset and the

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Glossary

corresponding interest rate on a risk-free Treasury security. (p. 780) Run on a bank A run on a bank occurs when many depositors withdraw cash from their accounts all at once. (p. 626) Sales maximization A firm’s objective is said to be sales maximization if it seeks to adopt prices and output quantities that make its total revenue (its “sales”), rather than its profits, as large as possible. (p. 246) Scatter diagram A scatter diagram is a graph showing the relationship between two variables (such as consumer spending and disposable income). Each year is represented by a point in the diagram, and the coordinates of each year’s point show the values of the two variables in that year. (p. 542) Securities Securities are financial instruments other than insurance policies and fixed annuities that are offered for sale to investors and which guarantee a set payment each year. Securities can be divided into three main categories: debt securities (e.g., bonds that are loans from the investor to the company), equity securities (e.g., common stocks, whose purchaser obtains a share of the company that creates those stocks), and derivative contracts that are essentially a bundle of other investments. (p. 181) Securitization Loans are securitized— that is, transformed into marketable securities— when they are packaged together into a bondlike instrument that can be sold to investors, potentially all over the world. (p. 786) Self-correcting mechanism The economy’s self-correcting mechanism refers to the way money wages react to either a recessionary gap or an inflationary gap. Wage changes shift the aggregate supply curve and therefore change equilibrium GDP and the equilibrium price level. (pp. 593, 706) Shift in a demand curve A shift in a demand curve occurs when any relevant variable other than price changes. If consumers want to buy more at any and all given prices than they wanted previously, the demand curve shifts to the right (or outward). If they desire less at any given price, the demand curve shifts to the left (or inward). (p. 59) Short run The short run is a period of time during which some of the firm’s cost commitments will not have ended. (p. 129)

Shortage A shortage is an excess of quantity demanded over quantity supplied. When there is a shortage, buyers cannot purchase the quantities they desire at the current price. (p. 65) Slope of a budget line The slope of a budget line is the amount of one commodity that the market requires an individual to give up to obtain one additional unit of another commodity without any change in the amount of money spent. (p. 103) Slope of a curved line The slope of a curved line at a particular point is defined as the slope of the straight line that is tangent to the curve at that point. (p. 16) Slope of an indifference curve The slope of an indifference curve, referred to as the marginal rate of substitution (MRS) between the commodities, represents the maximum amount of one commodity that the consumer is willing to give up in exchange for one more unit of another commodity. (p. 103) Slope of a straight line The slope of a straight line is the ratio of the vertical change to the corresponding horizontal change as we move to the right along the line between two points on that line, or, as it is often said, the ratio of the “rise” over the “run.” (p. 15) Social Security System The Social Security System raises funds from the payroll tax and pays Social Security benefits to retirees. (p. 381) Specialization Specialization means that a country devotes its energies and resources to only a small proportion of the world’s productive activities. (p. 725) Speculation Individuals who engage in speculation deliberately invest in risky assets, hoping to obtain profits from future changes in the prices of these assets. (p. 189) Stabilization policy Stabilization policy is the name given to government programs designed to prevent or shorten recessions and to counteract inflation (that is, to stabilize prices). (p. 483) Stagflation Stagflation is inflation that occurs while the economy is growing slowly (“stagnating”) or in a recession. (pp. 480, 594, 702) Statistical discrimination Statistical discrimination is said to occur when the productivity of a particular worker is estimated to be low just because that worker belongs to a particular group (such as women). (p. 462)

823

Sticky price A price is called sticky if it does not change often even when there is a moderate change in cost. (p. 249) Stock option A stock option is a contract that permits its owner to buy a specified quantity of stocks of a corporation at a future date, but at the price specified in the contract rather than the stock’s market price at the date of purchase. (p. 322) Stock price index A stock price index, such as the S&P 500, is an average of the prices of a large set of stocks. These stocks are selected to represent the price movements of the entire stock market, or some specified segment of the market, and the chosen set is rarely changed. (p. 184) Store of value A store of value is an item used to store wealth from one point in time to another. (p. 628) Strategic argument for protection The strategic argument for protection holds that a nation may sometimes have to threaten protectionism to induce other countries to drop their own protectionist measures. (p. 737) Structural budget deficit or surplus The structural budget deficit or surplus is the hypothetical deficit or surplus we would have under current fiscal policies if the economy were operating near full employment. (p. 690) Structural unemployment Structural unemployment refers to workers who have lost their jobs because they have been displaced by automation, because their skills are no longer in demand, or because of similar reasons. (p. 498) Subprime mortgage A mortgage is classified as subprime if the borrower fails to meet the traditional credit standards of “prime” borrowers. (p. 781) Substitutes Two goods are called substitutes if an increase in the quantity consumed of one cuts the quantity demanded of the other, all other things remaining constant. (p. 117) Substitution effect The substitution effect of a wage increase is the resulting incentive to work more because of the higher relative reward to labor. (p. 426) Supply curve A supply curve is a graphical depiction of a supply schedule. It shows how the quantity supplied of some product will change as the price of that product changes during a specified period of time, holding all other determinants of quantity supplied constant. (p. 62)

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

824

Glossary

Supply curve of a firm The supply curve of a firm shows the different quantities of output that the firm would be willing to supply at different possible prices during some given period of time. (p. 204) Supply curve of an industry The supply curve of an industry shows the different quantities of output that the industry would supply at different possible prices during some given period of time. (p. 205) Supply-demand diagram A supply-demand diagram graphs the supply and demand curves together. It also determines the equilibrium price and quantity. (p. 64) Supply schedule A supply schedule is a table showing how the quantity supplied of some product changes as the price of that product changes during a specified period of time, holding all other determinants of quantity supplied constant. (p. 61) Supply-side inflation Supply-side inflation is a rise in the price level caused by slow growth (or decline) of aggregate supply. (p. 702) Surplus A surplus is an excess of quantity supplied over quantity demanded. When there is a surplus, sellers cannot sell the quantities they desire to supply at the current price. (p. 65) Takeover A takeover is the acquisition by an outside group (the raiders) of a controlling proportion of a company’s stock. When the old management opposes the takeover attempt, it is called a hostile takeover attempt. (p. 188) Tangent A tangent to the curve is a straight line that touches, but does not cut, the curve at a particular point. (p. 16) Tariff A tariff is a tax on imports. (p. 732) Tax deduction A tax deduction is a sum of money that may be subtracted before the taxpayer computes his or her taxable income. (p. 380) Tax exempt A particular source of income is tax exempt if income from that source is not taxable. (p. 380) Tax loophole A tax loophole is a special provision in the tax code that reduces taxation below normal rates (perhaps to zero) if certain conditions are met. (p. 380) Tax shifting Tax shifting occurs when the economic reactions to a tax cause prices and outputs in the economy to change, thereby shifting part of the burden of the tax onto others. (p. 389)

Technology trading Technology trading is an arrangement in which a firm voluntarily makes its privately owned technology available to other firms either in exchange for access to the technology of the second company or for an agreed-upon fee. (p. 351) Theory A theory is a deliberate simplification of relationships used to explain how those relationships work. (p. 11)

Unemployment insurance Unemployment insurance is a government program that replaces some of the wages lost by eligible workers who lose their jobs. (p. 500) Unemployment rate The unemployment rate is the number of unemployed people, expressed as a percentage of the labor force. (p. 495) Unit of account The unit of account is the standard unit for quoting prices. (p. 628)

Total monetary utility The total utility of a quantity of a good to a consumer (measured in money terms) is the maximum amount of money that he or she is willing to give up in exchange for it. (p. 86)

Unit-elastic demand curve A demand curve is unit-elastic when a given percentage price change leads to the same percentage change in quantity demanded. (p. 112)

Total physical product (TPP) The firm’s total physical product (TPP) is the amount of output it obtains in total from a given quantity of input. (p. 130)

Value added The value added by a firm is its revenue from selling a product minus the amount paid for goods and services purchased from other firms. (p. 555)

Total profit The total profit of a firm is its net earnings during some period of time. It is equal to the total amount of money the firm gets from sales of its products (the firm’s total revenue) minus the total amount that it spends to make and market those products (total cost). (p. 158) Total revenue The total revenue of a supplier firm is the total amount of money it receives from the purchasers of its products, without any deduction of costs. (p. 159)

Variable A variable is something measured by a number; it is used to analyze what happens to other things when the size of that number changes (varies). (p. 14) Variable cost A variable cost is a cost whose total amount changes when the quantity of output of the supplier changes. (pp. 129, 202) Variable taxes Variable taxes are taxes that vary with the level of GDP. (p. 619)

Trade adjustment assistance Trade adjustment assistance provides special unemployment benefits, loans, retraining programs, and other aid to workers and firms that are harmed by foreign competition. (p. 735)

Velocity Velocity indicates the number of times per year that an “average dollar” is spent on goods and services. It is the ratio of nominal gross domestic product (GDP) to the number of dollars in the money stock. That is:

Trade deficit A country’s trade deficit is the excess of its imports over its exports. If, instead, exports exceed imports, the country has a trade surplus. (p. 771)

Velocity 5

Trade surplus A country’s trade surplus is the excess of its exports over its imports. If, instead, imports exceed exports, the country has a trade deficit. (p. 771) Troubled Assets Relief Program (TARP) TARP enabled the US Treasury to purchase assets and equity from banks and other financial institutions as a means of strengthening the financial sector. (p. 790) Transfer payments Transfer payments are sums of money that the government gives certain individuals as outright grants rather than as payments for services rendered to employers. Some common examples are Social Security and unemployment benefits. (pp. 35, 541)

Nominal GDP (p. 662) Money stock

Vertical equity Vertical equity refers to the notion that differently situated individuals should be taxed differently in a way that society deems to be fair. (p. 384) Vertical (long-run) Phillips curve The vertical (long-run) Phillips curve shows the menu of inflation/unemployment choices available to society in the long run. It is a vertical straight line at the natural rate of unemployment. (p. 707) Y-intercept The Y-intercept of a line or a curve is the point at which it touches the vertical axis (the Y-axis). The X-intercept is defined similarly. (p. 17) Zero-sum game A zero-sum game is one in which exactly the amount one competitor gains must be lost by other competitors. (p. 253)

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Index 458 line, 18, 564, 565, 567 458 line diagram, 563–564, 565 2010 Healthcare reform, of America, 328

A Abbott Laboratories, 245 Abilities, of workers, 428 Ability-to-pay principle, 384–385 Absolute advantage, 727, 729 Absolute poverty, 448–449. see also Poverty Abstraction, 8–11, 468 Acid Rain Retirement Fund, 367 Adarand v. Pena, 459 Adecco, 187 Adelphia Communications, 187 Advertising, 123–124, 236, 241, 242 AFDC (Aid to Families with Dependent Children), 455 Affirmative action, 458–459 Africa, 522, 524, 533 African Americans, 425 Agents, 321–323 Aggregate demand. see also Aggregate demand curve Fiscal stimulus debate of 2009–2010, 606 balanced with aggregate supply, 684–685 composition of, 686 equilibrium of, 587–588 excess of, 594 and exchange rates, 764–767 fiscal policy. see Fiscal policy fluctuations in, 597–598 gross domestic product and national income, 537–539 growth, 686, 702 international trade, 764–766 macroeconomic policy, 489–490 and monetary policy, 656, 685 predictability of, 550 and unemployment, 483–484 Aggregate demand curve definition, 470 demand-side equilibrium, 564–566 and economic fluctuations, 703 effect on real GDP and prices, 584, 612 and inflation, 588–589 in Keynesian model, 657–658 and multiplier, 574–575 Aggregate supply. see also Aggregate supply curve balanced with aggregate demand, 684–685 equilibrium of, 587–588 and exchange rates, 765–766 fiscal stimulus debate of 2009–2010, 606 fluctuations in, 584, 597–599 and growth, 686 macroeconomic policy, 489 and monetary policy, 657 in open economy, 766

Aggregate supply curve definition, 470 and exchange rates, 765–766 and inflation, 588–589, 657 shape of, 671–673 shifts in, 585–587 and supply shock, 705–706 upward slope, 584–585 vertical, 710–712 Aggregate supply-demand model, 471, 596–600, 613–614 Aggregation, 468–469 Agriculture, and demand for labor, 423 Aid to Families with Dependent Children (AFDC), 455 AIDS epidemic, 533 AIG (American International Group), 188 Air quality, 358–360, 368. see also Pollution Airbus, 220, 733 Airline industry Airbus, 220, 733 American Airlines, 245, 270 Boeing Corporation, 219–220, 733 Delta Airlines, 245 deregulation, 279–281 regulation of, 275 Airline Pilots Association, 280 Alaska, 361 Alcoa (Aluminum Company of America), 267 Allen & Overy, 427 Allocation of resources as coordination task, 47–49 efficiency, 288–291, 311–312 and excess capacity theorem, 239–240, 257 interest rates, 318–319 by monopoly, 225 and monopoly power, 264–265 and pollution, 324 in practice, 319 between present and future, 318–319 Aluminum Company of America (Alcoa), 267 Amazon.com, 178 American Airlines, 245, 270 American Electric Power, 365, 367 “American exceptionalism,” 746 American Home Products, 245 American International Group (AIG), 188 American Telephone and Telegraph Company (AT&T), 128, 145–146, 218, 267, 270 “American Way of Tax, The” (Baker), 388 America’s 2010 health-care reform, 328 Analytical cost curves, 144, 146 Anticompetitive practices, 270–271 Anticounterfeiting features of money, 629 Antitax sentiment, 377 Antitrust laws. see also Monopoly anticompetitive practices, 270–271 antitrust policy, 265–266

competition, prevention of, 271–273 competition, protection of, 33–34, 268 market power concentration, 267–269, 274 market share, 119 monopolization and vigorous competition, 269–270 price fixing, 245 size and scope of cases, 267 trials, 266 Antitrust policy, 265–266 APP (Average physical products), 130–131 Apple, Inc., 339 Applied research, 351 Appreciate (currency), 746. see also Exchange rates AR (Average revenue), 159–160, 173–174 Aral Sea, 358 Arctic region, and global warming, 361 Argentina, 745, 753, 756, 757, 758 “Arms race” (innovation), 342–343, 345–346 Army Corps of Engineers, 360 Asset, 635–636 Astebro, Thomas, 420 AT&T, 128, 145–146, 218, 267, 270 Australia, 26, 747 Automated Maritime Telecommunications System (AMTS) spectrum, 256 Automatic stabilizers, 609 Autonomous increase in consumption, 573, 576 Auxiliary restrictions, 75 AVC (Average variable costs), 203 Average cost curves, 137–143, 211 Average costs (AC) compared to marginal costs, 6, 173–174 definition, 138 economies of scale, 211 vs. marginal cost pricing, 276–277 optimal decision making, 161 shutdown decisions, 203 Average curves, graphical representation of, 174 Average physical products (APP), 130–131 Average revenue (AR), 159–160, 173–174 Average tax rate, 379 Average variable costs (AVC), 203

B Backward-bending, 427 Baker, Russell, 388 Balance of payments deficit, 753–754, 756 Balance of payments surplus, 753–754 Balance sheet, 636 Balanced budget, 692. see also Budget deficit Bank-a-Mythica, 782 Bank of England, 677

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

825

826

Index

Bank reserves market, 649–650 Banking system central banks, 647–649 discretion over money supply, 632–633 European Union, 648 examinations, 634 Great Depression, 643 history of, 632–633 management principles, 634 money creation, 636–642 panics, 647 profitability, 632 regulation of, 626, 634–635 run on a bank, 626, 633 supervision, 634 U.S. bank failures, 627 of various nations, 649 Barnes & Noble, Inc. (B&N), 272 Barriers to entry, 219–220 Barter, 627–628 Basic research, 350 Bastiat, Frédéric, 739 Behavior analysis, 242 Behavior models, 242–246 Behavioral economics, 92 Belarus, 522 Belgium, 450 Bell, Alexander Graham, 339, 344 Bell curve, 451 Bell Curve, The (Murray/Herrnstein), 451 Benchmark Company LLC, The, 68 Beneficial externality, 312, 314, 315, 350–351, 356 Benefits principle of taxation, 385 Bernanke, Ben, 646, 647, 701, 788, 790 Bethlehem Steel, 245 Big Macs, and purchasing power parity theory, 752 Bigness, advantages/disadvantages, 278–279 Bilateral monopoly, 433 “Bird in the hand” point of view, 319 Black market, 71 Boeing Corporation, 219–220, 733 Bonds buying, 183–185 financing corporate activity, 180–182 municipal/government, 380, 653 and price level, 546 prices, 652 vs. stocks, 181–182 Booms, 178, 192, 574, 764. see also Business cycles Bottlenecks, 270 Boulton, Matthew, 435–436 BP Plc, 68–69 Brazil, 524, 532, 649, 745, 757, 758 Break-even analysis, and shutdown, 202–204 Bretton Woods system, 755 Bridge tolls, 288–290, 306 Bristol-Myers Squibb, 245 Brokerage firms, 183 Browne, John, 69 Bubble, 780 Budget deficit and automatic stabilizers, 609 and Clinton, 40, 377, 481–482

and debt, 687–689 definition, 687 economics of, 698 and Federal Reserve System, 770–771 future prospects, 698 and inflation, 692–694 interpretation of, 689–691 in long run, 685–687 monetization, 693–694 official deficit, 690 politics of, 698 and recession, 698 reduction, international aspects of, 770–772 in short run, 684–685 size of, 684, 696–697 structural, 689–690 supply-side economics, 615 trade deficit link, 771–772 U.S. budget, 40, 46 Budget blueprint, 46 Budget line, 100–101, 103–106, 150 Budget surplus in 1990s, 40 definition, 687 interpretation of, 689–690 in long run, 685–687 on-budget vs. off-budget, 691 quickly turned to deficit, 698 in short run, 684–685 structural, 689–690 Building abandonment, 315 Bundling, 270–271 Burden of a tax, 386. see also Taxation Bureau of Labor Statistics, 497–498 Burundi, 522 Bush, George H.W., 25, 34, 40, 377, 477, 481, 616 Bush, George W. Bernanke appointment, 647 budget deficits, 40 business regulation, 34 capital gains tax, 523 economic growth, 477 election of, 377 fiscal policy, 612 and pollution, 367 Social Security privatization, 382 spending surge, 697 supply-side economics, 613–617 tax cuts, 378, 392, 446, 482–483, 606, 610, 612, 676–677, 689, 697 tax rebates, 538, 547–548 tax share under, 35 Business and professional services, 28 Business confidence, 549 Business cycles, 24–25, 574, 677–678, 792. see also Bonds; Recession Business firms demand curve under perfect competition, 199–200 efficiency of large firms, 128 perfect competition, 199–204 price advantage for, 734 role of, 31–32 short-run equilibrium under perfect competition, 200–201

short-run profit, 201–202 short-run supply curve, 204 short-term losses, 202 shutdown and break-even analysis, 202–204 size, advantages/disadvantages, 278–279 Busnell, Nolan, 155

C Canada currency, 746, 747 educational attainment in, 532 GDP of, 22 health-care costs, 310, 329–330 investor protection, 524 labor costs, 725 labor strikes, 434 openness of economy, 24 taxes in, 35 trade with U.S., 729 unemployment, 26, 497 Canyonlands National Park, 360 “Cap and trade” program, 367, 368 Capital corporate need for, 187–189 definition, 401 in developing countries, 531 earnings of, 30 as factor of production, 401–405 formation of, 522–524, 526 human, 422–423, 451, 520 human capital theory, 429 international flows, 768–770 mobility impediments, 726–727 opportunity cost of, 209–210 and productivity growth, 519 supply of, 586–587 Capital account, 754 Capital account plus, 769 Capital account surplus, 760 Capital formation, 522–524, 526 Capital gains, 506, 614 Capital gains tax, 523 Capitalism, 335. see also Free markets; Market system Capra, Frank, 633 Card, David, 499 Cartel, 243–244, 257 Carter, Jimmy, 324, 701 Caterpillar, 134 Causation, 11 Caveat emptor, 320 CDSs (Credit Default Swaps), 188 Celler-Kefauver Antimerger Act, 266 Census Bureau, 448 Central bank, 647, 648. see also Banking system Central bank independence, 648–649. see also Banking system Central planning, 48, 295–297, 358. see also Communism Chamberlin, Edward, 236–237 “Cheap foreign labor,” 723–724, 731–732, 738 Chechnya, 358 Chicago Board of Trade, 367

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Index

China currency, 753, 757 education and training in, 532 growth, 517, 522, 531, 739 inventions of, 338, 440 investor protection, 524 labor quality, 520 market mechanism, 167 openness of economy, 24 pollution, 358 technology in, 532 trade with U.S., 730 U.S. trade deficit, 772 Chodad, John, 628 Choice. see Scarcity Cigarettes, taxes on, 108, 114–115 Circuit breakers, 187 Circular flow diagram, 33, 539–541, 561, 568 Civil Rights Act of 1964, 458 Clayton Act, 266 Clean Air Act, 365, 367 Clean Air Markets, 368 Climate change. see Global warming Clinton, Bill affirmative action, 459 balanced budget, 691 budget deficits, 40, 377, 481–482 Clintonomics, 481–482 economic growth, 25, 477 government regulation, 34 minimum wage, 499 on supply-side economics, 616 welfare reform, 455 Clinton, Hillary, 724 Closed economy, 23–24, 768–769 Coal industry, 312 Coase, Ronald, 316 Coase theorem, 316 Coca-Cola, 265 Colbert, Jean-Baptiste, 385 Collaboration, 353 Collapse of Lehman Brothers, 789, 791 Collateral asset, 781 Collective bargaining, 430–434. see also Labor union College tuition, 518, 530–531 Collusion, 244–246, 253–254 Command and control approach. see Direct controls Commodity money, 629–630 Common stock, 180–181. see also Stocks Communism, 36, 70, 167, 294, 305. see also Central planning Comparative advantage. see also International trade arithmetic of, 727–728 “cheap foreign labor” fallacy, 723–724, 731–732, 738 definition, 49 generally, 5, 738 graphics of, 728–731 Compensation, 420 Competition, 31, 33–34, 268, 269–270, 271–273 Complements, 117–118 Compound interest, 491. see also Interest rates Concentration, of market power, 267–269, 274

Concentration of an industry, 267 Concentration ratio, 267 Confidence, business, 549 ConocoPhillips, 69 Conservation of matter and energy, law of, 361–363 Conservatives, and small government, 612 Construction wages, in New Orleans, 429 Consumer choice, 83–106 behavioral economics, 92 consumer‘s surplus, 93–95, 299–301 demand and scarcity, 84–85 downward-sloping demand curves, 90–92 indifference curve analysis, 99–106 budget line, 100–101, 150 properties of, 101–103 slope of, 103–106 opportunity cost, 92–96 as trade-off, 92–96 utility analysis, 85–92 Consumer expenditure, 538–539. see also Consumer spending Consumer incomes, and shifts in demand curve, 59 Consumer preferences, and shifts in demand curve, 59–60 Consumer Price Index (CPI), 325, 502, 511, 512, 518, 666, 766 Consumer spending, 30–31, 541–544, 547–548, 613. see also Consumer expenditure Consumer‘s budget, 116 Consumer‘s surplus, 93–95, 299–301 Consumption, 45, 369–371, 541–544, 572, 575. see also Consumer expenditure; Consumer spending Consumption function, 544–548 Consumption possibilities, 730 Consumption schedule, 606–607, 619 Contour maps, 18–19 Convergence hypothesis, 520–522 Coolidge, Calvin, 31, 489 Coordination failure, 568–569 Coordination tasks distribution, 50–52, 292, 294–295 input-output analysis, 295–297 market exchange, 50 output selection, 292, 293, 302 production planning, 293–294 resource allocation, 47–49 savings and investment, 567–568 Copeland, Kemp, 68 Corporate income tax, 380–381, 614 Corporate profits, 31 Corporation, 31–32, 179–183, 187–189, 531–532 Correlation, 11 Corruption, 75 Cost curves, 137–143, 144, 146, 211, 226 Cost disease of personal services, 324–330, 530–531 Cost-plus basis, 277 Costs. see also Average costs (AC); Marginal costs (MC) average variable, 203 average vs. marginal, 6, 173–174

827

curves, 137–139, 140–142, 144, 151–152 dependence on output, 137–142 and entrepreneurs, 437 and environmental policy, 475 fixed vs. variable, 129–130 historical, 144, 146 incidental, 313 of inflation, 506–508, 709 marginal fixed, 139 marginal vs. average vs. total, 161, 211 minimization, 136, 146, 151–152 production and input choice, 130–133 profit maximizing price, 168–169 of research and development (R&D), 345–346, 437 selling below, 157, 169–170 short-run vs. long-run, 128–130 sunk, 219–220 of unemployment, 495, 709 variable costs, 129–130, 138, 202 Council of Economic Advisors, 454 CPI (Consumer Price Index), 325, 502, 511, 512, 518, 666, 766 Cream skimming, 227, 275 Creative destruction, 436 Credible threat, 255–256 Credit Default Swaps (CDSs), 188 Cross elasticity of demand, 117–120 Cross licensing, 352–353 Cross-subsidization, 275 Crowding in, 695–696 Crowding out, 694–695, 698 Cuba, 736 Cumby, Robert, 752 Currency. see Exchange rates Current account, 754 Current account deficit, 760, 769 Cuyahoga River, 357 Cyclical unemployment, 498, 591

D Data, relationship between total, average and marginal, 173–174 De Lamare, Paul, 633 Death duties, 457–458 Debt, 687–689, 694–695. see also National debt Decision making, economic, 118–120, 292–299 Defective telescopic faculty, 319 Defense, Department of, 527 Deficit. see Budget deficit; Trade deficit Deficit spending, inflationary effects of, 693 Deflating, 513 Deflation, 477–478, 591–593 Degree of effort, of workers, 428 Delta Airlines, 245 Demand. see also Demand curve; Demand elasticity; Supply and demand cross elastici ty of, 117–120 derived, 399–400, 403, 422–423 growth of, 523 management of, 538, 715 and scarcity, 84–85 shift by monopoly, 225–226 stimulated by innovation, 339

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

828

Index

Demand curve consumer preferences and income, 59–60 definition, 58 downward-sloping, 90–92 for funds, 402–404 graphical representation, 14–15 from historical statistics, 122–125 individual, 96–97 infinitely elastic, 111 and inputs, 399–400 kinked, 247–250 for labor, 421–424, 428 marginal utility, 90–92 and monopoly, 157, 221 under perfect competition, 199–200 price and quantity, 157–158 shifts in, 58–60, 66–67 straight-line, 112 time period of, 116, 118–120 unit-elastic, 112–113 Demand elasticity determinants of, 115–116 effect on total revenue and total expenditure, 113–115 elasticity as general concept, 116–118 elasticity as measure of responsiveness, 108–113 perfectly elastic, 111 perfectly inelastic, 112 Polaroid vs. Kodak, 120 price elasticity of demand, 109, 111–113 time period of demand curve, 116, 118–120 unit elasticity, 112–113 Demand inflation, 594–595 Demand law, 97–98 Demand schedule, 58, 90 Demand-side equilibrium, 559–581. see also Equilibrium aggregate demand curve, 564–566 equilibrium GDP, 560–561, 565, 574, 607 and full employment, 566–567 income determination, 562–564, 577–578 multiplier analysis, 569–573, 574–575, 577–581 saving and investment coordination, 567–568 Demand-side fluctuations, 597–598 Demand-side inflation, 702 Demarcation line, between macroeconomics and microeconomics, 469 Denmark, 431 Depletable resource pricing, 369–371 Depletability, 317 Deposit creation, 636–640 Deposit destruction, 640 Deposit insurance, 634 Depositors, safety of, 626 Depreciate (currency), 746. see also Exchange rates Depreciation, 555 Depressions, 560. see also Great Depression Deregulation, 279–282 Derivatives, 188

Derived demand, 399–400, 403, 422–423 Detrimental externality, 312, 314, 315, 356 Devaluation (currency), 747, 754 Developing countries, 531–533 Development assistance, 531 Diamond, Gary, 633 Diamond-water puzzle, 84, 95 Diminishing marginal productivity, 140–141 Diminishing marginal returns, 131–134 Diminishing marginal utility, 86–87 Diminishing returns, 135, 143–144 Dioccletian, 56 Direct controls, 364–366 Direct taxes, 379 Dirty float, 758 Discount rate, 654 Discounting, 417–418 Discouraged workers, 498 Discrimination. see Economic discrimination Discriminatory pricing, 437–438 Disposable income, 539, 541–544, 545–548 Distribution, 50–52, 292, 294–295 Division of labor, 48–49, 50 Doe, Jane, 784 Doha Round (tariff reductions), 732, 733 Dollar, U.S., 746, 758–759, 760, 764, 775. see also Exchange rates Dominant strategy, 250–252 Donne, John, 763, 774 Double coincidence of wants, 627 “Double taxation,” 180 Dough, John, 784 Dow Jones Industrial Average, 187 Downsizing trend, 431 Drucker, Peter F., 344 Drugs, 71 Dumping, 737–740 Duopoly, 250–251 Dupont Cellophane decision, 107, 119

E Earned Income Tax Credit (EITC), 457 Earnings, 29–30, 420–421, 439 Earnings, retained, 182–183 Eastern Europe, 70, 167, 305, 330, 358 Eastman-Kodak, 120, 226 ECB (European Central Bank), 787 Economic analysis, graphs in, 14 Economic decision making, 118–120, 292–299 Economic discrimination economic theory of, 461–463 by employers, 461 by fellow workers, 461 as inefficiency, 47 and labor force participation, 425 policies to combat, 458–459 productivity, 452–453 roles of market and government, 462 statistical, 462 wages, 462 Economic forecasts, 613, 676 Economic growth. see Growth Economic model, 12 Economic policy, and politics, 324

Economic profit, 158–163, 207, 209–210, 412–414. see also Profits Economic rent, 406, 408–409, 411. see also Rent Economic theory of discrimination, 461–463. see also Economic discrimination Economics, 3–19 abstraction, 8–11, 468 of America’s 2010 healthcare reform, 328 as discipline, 8 graphs, 14–19 imperfect information and value judgments, 12–13 models, 12 theory, role of, 11–12 Economics of Welfare, The (Pigou), 356 Economies of large size, 278–279 Economies of scale AT&T example, 128, 145–146 and average costs, 211 cost minimization, 136, 146, 151–152 definition, 142, 264 historical costs vs. analytical cost curves, 144, 146 “law” of diminishing returns, 135, 143–144 and monopoly, 220 and perfect competition, 211 and regulation, 274 Economies of scope, 274 Economist, The, 187, 524, 724, 752 Economy, U.S. see U.S. economy Ecuador, 758 Edifice complex, 360 Edison, Thomas, 338, 344, 348, 420 Education and training and demand for labor, 422–423 in developing countries, 532 and growth, 524–526 and income inequality, 451 on-the-job training, 422, 425, 525–526 and poverty, 455 to reduce natural rate of unemployment, 715–716 spending on, 34 Education policy, 525 Educational services, 28 EEOC (Equal Employment Opportunity Commission), 458 Efficiency, 47, 128 vs. equality, 7, 453–454, 458–459 vs. growth, 305 innovation incentives, 277–278 of large firms, 128 and monopoly power, 264, 412 and perfect competition, 211–212, 299–301 of resource allocation, 288–291, 311–312 scarcity and choice, 47 self-correcting mechanism, 709–710 and taxation, 385–387, 391–392 Efficient allocation of resources, 288–291, 311–312 Einstein, Albert, 491

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Index

Eisenhower, Dwight, 92 EITC (Earned Income Tax Credit), 457 Elastic demand curve, 112–113 Elasticity, 108–113, 116–118. see also Demand elasticity Elasticity of demand, 109, 438. see also Demand elasticity Electricity industry, 281 Electricity prices, 60 Electronic calculators, and output selection, 293 Emission taxes. see Pollution charges Emissions permits, 366–367 Employment sectors, 28–29 Energy conservation, 386 Energy prices, 60, 528, 529 Engels, Friedrich, 197, 199 ENIAC (Electronic Numerical Integrator and Computer), 343 Enron, 187 Entrepreneurs discriminatory pricing of innovative product, 437–438 earnings of, 420–421, 439 fixed costs and public good attributes, 437 and growth, 435–440 innovation, 338–340, 435–441 and inputs, 435–441 and institutions, 440–441 negative financial rewards, 439–440 prices and profits of, 436 Entrepreneurship, 398, 413, 436. see also Entrepreneurs Entry to market, and deregulation, 280 Environmental policy approaches to, 363–367 costs excluded from GDP, 475 direct controls, 364–366 economics of, 356–368 emissions permits, 366–367 and externalities, 356–363 pollution charges, 356, 364–366 voluntarism, 363–364 Environmental Protection Agency (EPA), 315, 357, 362, 364, 367, 368 Equal Employment Opportunity Commission (EEOC), 458 Equality, vs. efficiency, 7, 453–454, 458–459 Equal-marginal-revenue rule, 228 Equation of exchange, 662 Equilibrium. see also Demand-side equilibrium of aggregate supply and demand, 587–588 definition, 65, 560 industry, 205–206 industry and firm in long run, 206–209 of interest rates, 404 long-run, 239 and perfect competition, 200–201 in perfectly competitive firm, 201 and real GDP, 596–597 short run, 200–201 of supply and demand, 64–70 Equilibrium GDP, 560–561, 565, 574, 607 Equilibrium price, 742–743 Equilibrium wage, 428

Equity, horizontal, 384 Escalator clause, 716 Euro, 759–760 Europe, 26, 30. see also European Union; individual nations European Central Bank (ECB), 669, 787 European Union, 294, 379, 449, 648, 737, 759–760 Excess burden, 386–387 Excess capacity theorem, 239–240, 257 Excess reserves, 636, 653 Exchange rates and aggregate demand, 765–767 and aggregate supply, 766 appreciate/depreciate, 746 Argentina, 745, 753, 756, 757, 758 Brazil, 745, 757, 758 Canada, 746, 747 China, 753, 757 and deficit reduction, 770–772 determination of, 747–752 devaluation, 747, 754 dollar, value of, 746, 764, 775 and economic activity, 750 effect of supply and demand, 747–752 effects of changes in, 765–766 European Union, 759–760 fiscal expansion, 769 fixed, 753–754, 756–757 floating, 747 Indonesia, 745, 774 inflation, 751–752, 756 interest rates, 749–750, 756 international trade, 726, 764–766 Japan, 747, 767 macroeconomic effects of, 767–768 Mexico, 747, 757, 758 price ratios, 730 purchasing power parity theory, 750–752 and relative prices, 549–550 revaluation, 747, 754 in Russia, 745, 758 in South Korea, 774 and trade deficit, 766, 772–774 of various currencies, 747 Excise tax, 379, 381, 383, 389–390, 619 Excludability, 317 Expansion path, 151–152 Expected inflation, 504–505, 716 Expenditure, consumer, 538–539 Expenditure schedule, 562–563 Expenditures, government, 34 Experience, 422, 452, 715–716 Export subsidy, 733 Exports, 23–24, 579–580, 765. see also Net exports Externalities, 6, 334 beneficial, 312, 314, 315, 350–351, 356 Coase theorem, 316 detrimental, 312, 314, 315, 356 government policy, 315–316 and inefficiency, 47, 312–314 as shortcoming of market mechanism, 312–316, 356–363 Exxon Mobil Corp., 69, 179

829

F Factors of production definition, 22 inputs and their derived demand curves, 399–400 investment, capital and interest, 401–405 marginal productivity, 140–141, 398–399, 414–415 profits, 411–414 rent determination, 405–411 Famines, 335 Farm sector, 29 Farming advertising, 236 economics, 204 price supports, 73–74 and water prices, 147 Fastow, Andrew, 187 Favoritism, 75 FCC (Federal Communications Commission), 256 FDIC (Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation), 634, 790 “Fed.” see Federal Reserve System Federal budget, 40 Federal Communications Commission (FCC), 256 Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC), 634, 790 Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, 60 Federal funds rate, 650 Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC), 647–648, 649 Federal Reserve Board, 319, 481–484, 646, 701 Federal Reserve System and Bernanke, 646 budget deficits, 770–771 central bank independence, 648–649 control debate (money supply or interest rates), 668–671 financial crisis, 788, 789 monetary policy, 647–649 origins and structure of, 647 and recessions, 674 Federal tax system. see Taxation Federal Trade Commission, 267 Federal Trade Commission Act, 266 Fiat money, 630 FIB (Friendly Investment Bank), 786 Final goods and services, 473, 553, 554, 555–556 Financial crisis, 779 of 2007–2008, 646, 653 to Great Recession, 788–791 hitting bottom and recovering, 791–792 housing price bubble, 784–785, 786–787 lessons, 792–793 leverage, 782–784 roots, 780–782 subprime mortgage crisis, 784, 785 profits, 782–784 risk, 782–784 Finland, 450

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

830

Index

Fiscal federalism, 384 Fiscal policy aggregate demand, 605–623, 698 aggregate demand shifts, 657 algebraic treatment, 622–623 contractionary, 611, 667, 698 definition, 479–480, 605 difficulties, 612–613 expansionary, 610, 612, 665–667, 708, 756, 769 of George W. Bush, 612 graphical representation, 619–621 income taxes and consumption schedule, 606–607 and interest rates, 665–667 international capital flows, 769 to limit economic fluctuations, 7 vs. monetary policy, 654, 667–668, 685 and the multiplier, 607–610 in open economy, 768–770 and recessionary gap, 611 Republican Party, 612 spending policy vs. tax policy, 611–612 supply-side tax cuts, 613–617 and taxation, 619–623 time lags, 613 trade deficit, 766, 771–774 and unemployment, 483–484, 708 and velocity, 662–667 Fitzgerald, F. Scott, 531 Fixed consumption function, 565, 572 Fixed costs and entrepreneurs, 437 and profit-maximizing price, 168–169 vs. variable, 129–130 Fixed exchange rates, 753, 756–757 Fixed taxes, 619–620 Floating exchange rates, 747 Fluctuations, economic during 1990s, 705–706 aggregate demand curve, 703 Clintonomics, 481–482 demand-side, 597–598 in George W. Bush economy, 477, 482–483 Great Depression, 478–479 Great Stagflation (1973–1980), 480 growth, 24–25, 475–477 inflation and deflation, 477–478 limiting, 7 Phillips curve, 703–704 Reaganomics, 481 supply-side inflation, 598–599, 702–703, 705–706 World War II to 1973, 25–26, 479–480 Flypaper theory of tax incidence, 387–388, 390 FMOC (Federal Open Market Committee), 647–648, 649 Food stamps, 456, 457 Foreclosure, 785 Ford Motor Co., 31, 32, 241 Forecasts, economic, 613, 676 Foreign aid, 531 Foreign direct investment, 531–532 Fractional reserve banking, 632 France, 22, 26, 35, 434, 497, 725, 747 Franklin, Benjamin, 368, 489, 723

Frederick the Great, 336 Free markets. see also Free trade; Market system; Price system exchange rates, 747–752 growth vs. efficiency, 305 imperfect information, 320, 321 innovation, 338–349 moral hazard, 320, 634 Poland‘s transition to, 294, 358 productivity, 330 research and development spending, 349–351 shortcomings, 309–332 externalities, 312–316, 356–363 government failure, 323–330 imperfect information, 320–321 increasing costs of vital services, 324–330 list of, 310 moral hazard, 320, 634 principal-agent problem, 321–323 provision of public goods, 316–318, 348, 437 rent seeking, 320 resource allocation between present and future, 318–319 Free trade, 735, 738. see also Free markets Freedman, Audrey, 463 Free-rider problem, 317 Frictional unemployment, 498 Friedman, Milton, 666, 670 Friendly Investment Bank (FIB), 786 Fuel crisis, history, 370. see also Oil Full employment, 499, 566–567, 613 Funds, 402–404 Future, 343, 549 Future income expectations, and consumption function, 547–548

G Galbraith, John Kenneth, 645 Game theory, 250–253, 256 Gasoline distribution, 291 Gasoline tax, 69–70 Gates, Bill, 344, 439, 451 GDP. see Gross Domestic Product (GDP) GDP deflator, 513 Gender, workforce composition, 27 General Electric, 267, 468 General Motors, 31, 129, 179, 277, 468, 585 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, The (Keynes), 479, 552, 566 Geography, as problem for developing countries, 532–533 George, Henry, 406 Germany currency, 747 GDP of, 22 hyperinflation, 507–508, 666 investment in, 528 labor strikes, 434 labor union membership, 431 openness of economy, 24 taxes in, 35 unemployment, 26, 497 Gilman, Mark, 68–69 Global financial meltdown, 789

Global warming, 315, 360, 361 Globalization, 723, 724. see also International trade GNP (Gross national product), 555 Gold standard, 754–755 Goods, inferior, 96, 104–105 Goods, intermediate, 473, 554, 555–556 Goods, nature of, 115 Goods and services, future of, 327–328 Google, 185 Gore, Al, 377, 616 Gough, William, 633 Governance, in developing countries, 533 Government budget, and investment, 667 and economic discrimination, 462 as employment sector, 28–29 expenditures, 34 failures, 323–330 and fixed exchange rates, 753–754 intervention, 673–675 policy, 315–316, 677 and pollution, 360 as redistributor, 35 as referee, 33 regulation, 33–34, 211 role of, 32–35 size of, 612, 676–677 spending surge under George W. Bush, 697 taxes. see Taxation transfer payments, 35, 541, 609–610, 716 Government purchases, 539 Graphs average curves, 174 comparative advantage, 728–731 contour maps, 18–19 demand curve, 14–15 economics, 14–19 fiscal policy, 619–621 marginal curves, 174 rays through origin and 458 lines, 17–18 short-run profit, 201–202 slope, definition and measurement, 15–17 two-variable diagrams, 14–15 Grasso, Dick, 187 Great Boom of 1990s, 760 Great Britain. see United Kingdom Great Depression and banking system, 642 economic fluctuations during, 478–479 gold standard, 754–755 Keynes on, 566 and labor, 420 price supports, 73 savings during, 541 and self-correcting mechanism, 592 stock prices during, 183 unemployment, 25–26, 496–497 unemployment insurance, 500 Great Lakes region, 357 Great Recession, 779 financial crisis to, 788–791 Great Stagflation (1973–1980), 480 Greenspan, Alan, 178, 671, 677

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Index

Gross Domestic Product (GDP). see also Potential GDP; Real GDP; Real GDP per capita components, 472–474 definition, 23, 337 equilibrium, 560–561, 565, 574, 607 exceptions to the rules, 552–553 and labor costs, 420, 725 limitation of, 474–475 in macroeconomics, 471–475 national debt relative to, 688 and national income, 537–539 nominal GDP, 472, 476 real GDP. see Real GDP as sum of all factor payments, 553–555 as sum of final goods and services, 553 as sum of values added, 555–556 and taxation, 378–379 in various nations, 22 Gross national income, 540 Gross national product (GNP), 555 Gross private domestic investment, 553 Growth in Africa, 522 of aggregate demand, 702 aggregate demand as determinant of, 686 of aggregate supply, 686 aggregate supply-demand model, 471, 596–600, 613–614 in China, 517, 522, 531, 739 convergence hypothesis, 520–522 of demand, 523 in developing countries, 531–533 as economic goal, 490–495 vs. efficiency, 305 and entrepreneurs, 435–440 investment, 686 long run vs. short run, 533 under market system, 334–338 in Mexico, 522 national debt, 695–696 as part of economic fluctuations, 24–25, 475–477 of potential GDP, 493–494 production capacity, 492–493 productivity growth, 8, 490–491, 518–520, 529 productivity rates, 527–531 rate of, 25, 476–477, 492, 493–495, 520–522 and real GDP, 476 in Russia, 517, 522 slow down (1973–1995), 527–528 slow down, 2006–2007, 468 trade deficit, 766, 771–774 Growth policy capital formation, 522–524, 526 definition, 490, 517 education and training, 524–526 technological change, 526–527

H Haiti, 522 Hamilton, Alexander, 736, 781 Hammurabi, 56

Hardman, Sasha, 427 Harrington, Michael, 446–447 Head tax, 379 Health, in developing countries, 533 Health care costs, 34, 310, 325–326, 328, 329–320 Healthcare reform 2010, of America, 328 Health services, 28 Heinz‘s Pet Products Company, 114 Hemingway, Ernest, 531 Herfindahl-Hirschman Index (HHI), 267–268, 269 Heron of Alexandria, 435, 440 Herrnstein, Richard, 451 Heywood, John, 235 HHI (Herfindahl-Hirschman Index), 267–268, 269 Highmark, Inc., 272 High-tech industries, 340–343. see also Technology Highway congestion, 291 Hirsch, Yale, 191 Hispanic workers, labor force participation, 425 Home mortgage, 781 Hong Kong, 520 Hoover, Herbert, 478, 683 “Hooverville,” 478 Horizontal equity, 384 Horses, and pollution, 359 Hot money, 749 Housing bubble, 482, 635, 784–785 Hub-and-spoke system, 280 Hugo, Victor, 467 Human capital, 422–423, 451, 520 Human capital theory, 429 Human Genome Project, 527 Hungary, 507 Hurricane Katrina, 429 Hyperinflation, 507–508, 666 Hypothesis, 11

I IBM (International Business Machines), 220, 267, 352, 532, 750 IMF (International Monetary Fund), 508, 758 Imperfect information, 320, 321 Imperial Food Products, 432 Imports, 23–24, 578–581, 737–740, 765. see also International trade Incidence of a tax, 387–391 Incidental cost, 313 Incidental damage, 357 Income and circular flow, 539–541 and consumer spending, 541–544 determinants of, 562–564, 577–578 disposable, 539, 541–544, 545–548 distribution, 304–305, 398, 445, 449–450, 615 future expectations of, 547–548 inequality of, 450–452 and inflation, 504 median, 452 vs. money, 646 national, 537–539, 541, 549, 554 per capita, 334

831

and quantity demanded, 95–96 real consumer income, 564–565 taxation, 379, 380–381, 457, 572, 606–609, 614, 619 vs. wealth, 564–565 Income effect, 426, 427 Income elasticity of demand, 116 Income gap, 421 Income security programs, 34 Income-expenditure diagram, 563–564 Incomplete specialization, 731 Increasing costs, principle of, 44 Increasing returns to scale, 142–146 Index fund, 184 Index number, 511 Indexing, 716–717 India, 522, 524, 532, 739 Indifference curve, 102 Indifference curve analysis budget line, 100–101, 150 properties of, 101–103 slope of, 103–106 Indirect taxes, 379 Individual demand curve, 96–97 Individual Retirement Accounts (IRA), 547 Indonesia, 745, 774 Induced increase in consumption, 572 Induced investment, 562–563, 695 Industrial Revolution, 335, 336 Industry and competition, 31 concentration of, 267 equilibrium in long-run, 206–209 equilibrium in short-run, 205–206 long-run supply curve, 210–212 perfect competition, 205–211 protection for particular, 734–735 short-run supply curve, 204, 205 size, and shifts in supply curve, 62–63 Inefficiency, 47, 312–314. see also Efficiency Inelastic curve, 112–113, 438 Inequality, 446, 449–452, 457–458 Infant-industry argument, 736–737 Inferior goods, 96, 104–105 Infinite slope, 15 Infinitely elastic demand curves, 111 Inflation. see also Inflationary gap in 1960s and 1970s, 480 aggregate demand curve, 588–589 aggregate supply curve, 588–589, 657 average level of, 507 and budget deficits, 692–694 combating, 484 Consumer Price Index (CPI), 512 as coordination failure, 568–569 costs of, 506–508, 709 deficit spending, 693 definition, 471 and deflation, 477–478, 591–593 of demand, 594–595 demand-side, 702 demand-side vs. supply-side, 702 distortions of, 505–506 and economic fluctuations, 477–478 as economic goal to keep low, 500–509 effect on bondholders, 181

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

832

Index

exchange rates, 751–752, 756 expectations and the Phillips curve, 710–712 expected rate of, 504–505, 716 hyperinflation, 507–508, 666 and income, 504 index numbers for, 511 and monetary policy, 657 and money growth, 666 and the multiplier, 588–589 myths, 501–504, 509 predictable, 507 pure, 503 real vs. nominal interest rates, 504–505 and real wages, 501–502 real world, 503 as redistributor of income and wealth, 504 and relative prices, 503–504 statistical measurements of, 511–513 supply-side, 598–599, 702–703, 705–706 unemployment, 7–8, 583, 708 unemployment trade-off, 701–717 unexpected, 504–505 unpredictable, 507 using price index to measure, 512–513 variability of, 507 Inflation premium, 716 Inflation targeting, 481, 484, 677, 709–710 Inflationary gap, 567–568, 589–591, 593–595, 611, 706–707 Information Age, 29, 529 Information technology (IT), 528–529 Infrastructure, public, 34 Inherited wealth, 452 Innovation “arms race,” 342–343, 345–346 “assembly lines,” 340–343 as beneficial externality, 350–351 and collaboration, 353 definition, 413–414, 526–527 demand, stimulation of, 339 dissemination of new technology, 351–353 effect of price on, 348–349 effect on outputs, 348–349 entrepreneurs, 338–340, 435–441 financing of, 345–346 as free market accomplishment, 338–349 incentives for, 277–278 kinked revenue curve model of spending, 346–348 labor, 423 licensing of, 351 in market system, 338–349 and monopoly, 227 and monopoly power, 264 natural resource increases, 373 and oligopolistic firms, 340–349 process, 349 product, 348–349 as public good, 348 scale required for, 279 Schumpeter‘s model, 343–344 Innovative entrepreneurship, 413, 436 Input-output analysis, 295–297

Inputs, 32, 42, 489 capital, 30 combinations of, 150–151 and demand curve, 399–400 derived demand curves, 399–400 entrepreneurs, 435–441 labor. see Labor opportunity cost, 137 optimal combination of, 133–137 optimal quantity, 132–133 price changes in, 63, 136–137 production and cost with one variable, 130–133 production capacity, 492–493 quantities, 137–139 scarcity and monopoly, 219 substitutability, 134–135 variability, 128–130 Insolvent, 783 Institutions, and entrepreneurs, 440–441 Interdependence, 84, 236, 242–243, 245 Interest, 34, 402. see also Interest rates Interest rate differentials, 749–750 Interest rate spreads, 780, 781 Interest rates behavior of, 1979–1985, 671 and bond prices, 181–182 compounding, 491 cuts, 482–483 debt, 687–689, 694–695 and demand for funds, 402–404 equilibrium of, 404 exchange rates, 749–750, 756 Federal Reserve System, 668–671 fiscal policy, 665–667 history of, 56 international capital flows, 768–770 monetary policy, 655 monetization, 693–694 multiplier, 666–667 open-market operations, 652 opportunity cost, 318–319 real, 504–506, 522–523, 546–547 resource allocation, 318–319 risk and reward in, 781 role of in resource allocation, 318–319 usury laws, 404–405 velocity, 662–667 Intermediate goods, 473, 554, 555–556 International Business Machines (IBM), 220, 267, 352, 532, 750 International capital flows, 768–770 International Energy Agency, 244 International Ladies Garment Workers‘ Union, 432 International Monetary Fund (IMF), 508, 758 International monetary system, 745–761 adjustment mechanisms, 756 balance of payments, 753–754, 756 Bretton Woods system, 755 current “nonsystem,” 757–760 euro, 759–760 exchange rates. see Exchange rates gold standard, 754–755 International Monetary Fund (IMF), 508, 758 volatile dollar, 758–759

International trade. see also Imports “cheap foreign labor,” 723–724, 731–732, 738 and comparative advantage, 727–732 deficit, 766, 771–774 dumping, 737–740 and exchange rates, 726, 764–766 gains from, 729–730 globalization, 723–724 vs. intranational trade, 726–727 multiplier, 579–580 mutual gains, 725–726 political factors, 726 prices, 742–744 and real GDP, 765 reasons for, 725–726 reasons to inhibit, 734–737 and recessions, 764 supply, demand, and pricing, 742–744 tariffs and quotas, 732–737, 743–744 unfair foreign competition, 739 Internet, 529 Internet bubble, 449, 760 Intimate Bookshop, Inc., 272 Intranational trade, 726–727 Invention, 338, 340, 413–414, 440, 526–527 Inventory, 401, 552 Investment. see also Bonds; Stocks business, 655 capital and interest, 401–405 coordination with savings, 567–568 as factor of production, 401–405 foreign direct, 531–532 in Germany, 528 in government budget, 667 growth, 522–524, 686 in housing, 655 induced, 562–563, 695 lagging, 528 monetary policy, 655–656 and savings, 567–568 surge in, 528–529 trade deficit, 766, 771–774 variability of, 548–549 Investment banks, 187–188 Investment in human capital, 422–423, 429, 451, 520 Investment spending, 539, 548–549 Investor protection, 524 Invisible hand, 56, 70, 211–212, 257, 292, 303, 309 iPhone, 339 IQ tests, 451 IRA (Individual Retirement Accounts), 547 Iran, 736 Iraq, 595, 736 Ireland, 290 Iron ore, 356 “Irrational exuberance,” 178 Irreversible decisions, 319 Isoquant. see Production indifference curves IT (Information technology), 528–529 Italy currency, 747 educational attainment in, 532 GDP of, 22 investor protection, 524 labor strikes, 434

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Index

taxes in, 35 unemployment, 26, 497 It‘s a Wonderful Life (Capra), 633 Ivory trade, 76

J Jackson, Andrew, 629 January barometer stock market predictor, 191 Japan central bank of, 648 deflation, 593 educational attainment in, 532 exchange rates, 747, 767 GDP of, 22 investment in, 528 investor protection, 524 labor, 520, 725 labor strikes, 434 living standards, 731–732 openness of economy, 24 productivity, 490–491 taxation, 35 trade with U.S., 549–550, 727–729, 730–731, 772 unemployment rates, 26 wages, 725 Jefferson, Thomas, 34 Job market for college graduates, 595 Job placement, 715–716 Jobs, Steven, 344 Johnson, Lyndon, 447 Justice, Department of, 267, 270

K Kahn, Alfred, 324 Kansas City, 359 Kelly, Richard, 55 Kennedy, John F., 499, 605 Kenya, 76 Kerry, John, 377, 616 Keynes, John Maynard, 537, 549, 559 Bretton Woods system, 755 on coordination failure, 568 on equilibrium GDP, 560 The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, 479, 552, 566 on Great Depression, 566 on stock market behavior, 192 Keynesian model aggregate demand curve, 657–658 monetary policy, 656–658, 665 money and price level in, 656–658 recessions, 714–715 theory, 11, 12 King, Martin Luther, Jr., 497 Kinked demand curve, 247–250 Kinked revenue curve model, 346–348 Kodak, 120, 226 Kohn, Donald, 787 Kozlowski, Dennis, 187 Krueger, Alan, 499 Kydland, Finn, 678

L Labor bilateral monopoly, 433 costs of, 420, 725

demand for, 421–424, 428 division of, 48–49, 50 during Great Depression, 420 human capital theory, 429 increase in labor force participation, 424–425 and innovation, 423 as input, 26–30 mobility impediments, 726–727 monopsony, 433 quality of, 520 supply of, 424–427, 429, 586–587 supply of and leisure time, 425–427 teenagers, 429–430 unions and collective bargaining, 430–434 wage determination in competitive markets, 421–424 wage differences, 428–430, 450–452 working conditions, 432 Labor force, 492–493 Labor force participation, 424–425 Labor productivity, 327, 491, 493–494, 530 Labor Statistics, Bureau of, 497–498 Labor union, 280, 424, 430–434 Lags, 613, 667–668, 675–679 Laissez-faire, 293 Lake Erie, 357 Lake Karachay, 359 Lake Superior, 364 Land, 405–408. see also Rent Latin America, and property rights, 524 Law of conservation of matter and energy, 361–363 Law of demand. see Demand law Law of diminishing marginal productivity. see Diminishing marginal productivity Law of diminishing marginal returns. see Diminishing marginal returns Law of diminishing marginal utility. see Diminishing marginal utility Law of diminishing returns. see Diminishing returns Law of supply and demand. see Supply and demand Leeson, Nicholas, 188 Leisure time, and labor supply, 425–427 Lemons, 321 Leontief, Wassily, 296 Leverage, 782–784 Liability, 635–636 Limit order, 183–184 Limited liability, 180 Lincoln, Abraham, 435 Liquid Crystal Display (LCD), 353 Liquidity, 631 Living conditions, 336 Living standards, 731–732 Local services, and deregulation, 280 Lockouts, 434 London, fogs of, 357 London School of Economics, 12 Long run, 129, 142–143, 239 Longfellow, Henry Wadsworth, 309 Longfield, Mountifort, 290 Long-run average cost (LRAC), 210–213 Long-run supply curve, 210–212 Long-Term Capital Management, 188

833

Los Angeles Summer Olympic Games, 363–364 Louisiana Pacific Corporation, 364–365 LRAC (Long-run average cost), 210–213 Lucas, Robert E., Jr., 517 Luxembourg Income Study, 450 Luxury goods, 115

M M1, 630–631. see also Money M2, 631. see also Money Maastricht Treaty, 648 Macroeconomic policy, goals of, 489–514 economic growth, 490–495 low inflation, 500–509 low unemployment, 495–500 Macroeconomics, 467–485. see also specific topics and aggregate demand, 489–490 and aggregate supply, 489 and aggregation, 468–469 exchange rates. see Exchange rates fluctuations, economic. see Fluctuations, economic gross domestic product, 471–475 vs. microeconomics, 468–469 stabilization policy, 483–485 supply and demand in, 469–471 ‘Magic box,’ 413 Managed float, 758 Manufacturing, 28, 30, 423, 431, 724–725 Manure, and pollution, 359 Maps, 9–11, 18–19, 149 Marginal analysis to achieve optimal output, 167, 301–306 importance of, 155–156 logic of, 168–170 marginal costs in, 170–171, 302 maximization of total profit, 156, 161–167 optimal purchase rule, 87–90, 92, 135–136, 509 role of, 170–171 selling below costs, 169–170 Marginal cost curves, 137–139 Marginal costs (MC) vs. average cost pricing, 276–277 compared to average costs, 6, 173–174 in marginal analysis, 170–171, 302 optimization, 165–167 perfect competition, 200 public goods, 317 vs. total and average costs, 161, 211 Marginal curves, graphical representation of, 174 Marginal fixed costs, 139 Marginal land, 407 Marginal physical products (MPP), 130–132, 398, 428 Marginal private benefit (MPB), 313 Marginal private cost (MPC), 313–314 Marginal productivity, 140–141, 398–399, 414–415 Marginal productivity theory of distribution, 414–415 Marginal profit, 163–165

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

834

Index

Marginal propensity to consume (MPC), 544–545 Marginal returns, 131–134 Marginal revenue (MR), 159–160, 165–167, 173–174, 200 Marginal revenue product (MRP), 132–133, 398–400 Marginal revenue product of labor (MRPL), 422 Marginal social benefit (MSB), 313 Marginal social cost (MSC), 313–314 Marginal tax rate, 379, 392 Marginal utility, 86–92, 95, 302. see also Utility analysis Market demand curve, 96–97 Market economy, 48, 167. see also Free markets; Free trade; Price system Market exchange, 50 Market failure. see Free markets Market order purchase, 183 Market power, 267–269, 274. see also Antitrust laws; Recession Market price, 41 Market share, 119 Market system in China, 167 definition, 50–52 depletable resource pricing, 369–371 dissemination of new technology, 351–353 externalities, 356–363 growth, 334–338 innovation, 338–349 overview, 330 research and development, 349–351 Market value of time, 42 Markets, 32. see also Free markets Marshall, Alfred, 583 Marshall, Steve, 69 Marx, Karl, 35, 52, 305 Maximization, logic of, 163–170 Maximization of profits, 156, 161–167 Maximum criterion, 252–253 Mayak industrial complex, 359 Mazda, 32 MBS (mortgage-backed securities), 786 McCain, John, 392, 446, 616 McCullough, Robert, 60 McDonnell-Douglas, 733 Medicaid/Medicare, 34, 381, 456 Medium of exchange, 628. see also Money Mercantilism, 732 Mexico central bank of, 649 currency, 747, 757, 758 educational attainment in, 532 growth, 522 investor protection, 524 labor costs, 725 openness of economy, 24 trade with U.S., 730 wages, 724–725 Microeconomics, vs. macroeconomics, 468–469. see also specific topics Microsoft, 220, 222, 267, 270–271, 451 Military spending, 45 Milk consumption, 67 Mill, John Stuart, 625

Minimum wage, 499 Misallocation of resources, 75–76, 311. see also Resource allocation Mixed economy, 36 Mobility impediments, 726–727 Monetarism, 661, 665, 666, 670–671 Monetary control. see Monetary policy Monetary policy aggregate demand, influence on, 656, 685 aggregate supply, 657 changing reserve requirements, 654 contractionary, 654 definition, 645–646 expansionary, 652, 654, 656–657, 693–694, 698, 708, 756 Federal Reserve System, 647–649 vs. fiscal policy, 654, 667–668, 685 inflation, 657 inflation targeting, 481, 484, 677, 709–710 and inflationary effects of deficit spending, 693 interest rates, 655 international capital flows, 768–770 investment, 655–656 Keynesian model, 656–658, 665 lending to banks, 653–654 methods of monetary control, 652–654 money vs. income, 646 multiplier, 656 need for, 643 in open economy, 768–770 open-market operations, 649–652 policy debates, 658 total expenditure, 655–656 trade deficit, 766, 771–774 unemployment, 708 workings of, 654–656 Monetary union, 759 Monetizing the deficit, 693–694 Money, 50. see also Money supply anticounterfeiting features, 629 vs. barter, 627–628 creation of, 636–642 limits by single bank, 636–638 oversimplified formula, 642 by a series of banks, 638–640 full-bodied paper money, 630 growth of, and inflation, 666 vs. income, 646 inflationary expectations, 710–712 M1/M2, 630–631 measurements of, 630–632 as medium of exchange, 628 nature of, 626–630 objects used as, 628–630 and price level in Keynesian model, 656–658 primitive forms of, 628 quantity theory of, 662–665 redesigning bills, 629 Money cost, 41–42, 658 Money market deposit accounts, 631 Money market mutual funds, 631 Money multiplier, 640 Money profit, 43 Money revenue, 132–133

Money supply, 630–632. see also Money bank discretion over, 632–633 contractions of, 640–642 and Federal Reserve System, 668–671 origins of, 635–636 Money-fixed asset, 546, 564 Monopolistic competition attributes of, 258–259 characteristics of, 236–238 excess capacity theorem and resource allocation, 239–240, 257 price and output determination, 238 and public welfare, 257–258 Monopoly, 157, 217–232. see also Antitrust laws Adam Smith on, 217 anticompetitive practices, 270–271 benefits of, 226–227 bilateral, 433 cost curves, 226 definition, 218–221 demand curve, 157, 221 demand shift, 225–226 economies of scale, 220 and innovation, 227 license, 409 natural monopoly, 218, 220–222, 227 and outputs, 224–225 vs. perfect competition, 224–225 power, 264, 412 price discrimination under, 227–230 profits, 224, 345–346 public welfare, 264–265 pure monopoly, 195, 218, 258–259 regulation, 211, 220–221 resemblance of vigorous competition, 269–270 resource allocation by, 225 scarcity of inputs, 219 sources of, 219–220 supply decision, 221–226 Monopoly license, 409 Monopoly power, 264, 412 Monopoly profits, 224, 345–346 Monopsony, 433 Moore‘s law, 343 Moral hazard, 320, 634 Morgenstern, Oskar, 250 Morris, Robert, 449 Mortgage-backed securities (MBS), 786 Mozambique, 524 MPB (Marginal private benefit), 313 MPC (Marginal private cost), 313–314 MPC (Marginal propensity to consume), 544–545 MPP (Marginal physical products), 130–132, 398, 428 MR (Marginal revenue), 159–160, 165–167, 173–174, 200 MRP (Marginal revenue product), 132–133, 398–400 MRPL (Marginal revenue product of labor), 422 MSB (Marginal social benefit), 313 MSC (Marginal social cost), 313–314 Mugabe, Robert, 508 Multinational corporations, 31–32, 531–532

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Index

Multiplier aggregate demand curve, 574–575 algebraic statement, 571–573 and automatic stabilizers, 609 definition, 569–570 and demand-side equilibrium, 569–573, 574–575, 577–581 effect on equilibrium GDP, 607 as general concept, 573–574 and government transfer payments, 35, 541, 609–610, 716 illustration of, 570–571 and income determination, 577–578 inflation, 588–589 interest rates, 666–667 and international trade, 579–580 monetary policy, 656 overstatement of, 608 spending chain, 571 taxes, 607–610, 621 variability of, 613 with variable imports, 578–581 Municipal bonds, 380 Murray, Charles, 451 Mutual fund, 184

N NAAQS (National ambient air quality standards), 357 NAFTA (North American Free Trade Agreement), 724, 732 NASA (National Aeronautics and Space Administration), 527 NASDAQ stock market, 178, 186 Nash, John, 253 Nash equilibrium, 253 National Aeronautics and Space Administration (NASA), 527 National ambient air quality standards (NAAQS), 357 National debt as a burden, 691–692 contributors, 696 definition, 687 facts, 687–689 foreign holders of, 692 interest on, 34 relative to GDP, 688 and slow growth, 695–696 National defense, 34, 735–736 National income, 537–539, 541, 549, 554 National income accounting, 552–556 National Institutes of Health (NIH), 527 National Science Foundation (NSF), 527 Natural monopoly, 218, 220–222, 227 Natural rate of unemployment, 707, 715–716 Natural resources allocation of, 319 economics of, 368–375 actual prices in 20th century, 371–374 depletable resource pricing, 369–371 interferences with price patterns, 372–374 and innovation, 373 price controls, 56–57, 329, 373–374, 480 reserves, 372–373, 375 supply of, 356

Near moneys, 631 Necessities, 115 Negative financial rewards, 439–440 Negative income tax (NIT), 456–457, 610 Negative slope, 15 Net exports, 539, 549–550, 579, 764. see also Exports Net national product (NNP), 554 Net of transfers, 541 Net taxes, 541 Net utility, 88 Net worth, 636 Netherlands, 24, 35, 365, 450 Network externalities, 270 “New Economy,” 481–482, 702 New Orleans, 429 New York City, rent controls in, 72–73 New York Stock Exchange (NYSE), 185–189 New York Times, 76 New York Yankees, 411 Newman, Pauline, 432 NIH (National Institutes of Health), 527 NINJA loans, 781 Nippon Steel Co., 69 Nissan, 32 Nixon, Richard, 374, 480, 755 NNP (Net national product), 554 No Child Left Behind, 525 Nobel Prize winners Finn Kydland, 678 Robert E. Lucas, Jr., 517 Edward Prescott, 678 Robert M. Solow, 3 Nominal GDP, 472, 476 Nominal rate of interest, 504–506 Nominal wage, 502, 585–586, 591–592 Nonconsumption uses, as portion of GDP, 31 Nonmonetary attractiveness, 429 Nordhaus, William, 421, 439 Normal goods, 96 North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA), 724, 732 North Korea, and central planning, 295 Northern Rock (bank), 626, 633 Northern Telecom, 32 Northwest Airlines, 245 Norway, 450 NSF (National Science Foundation), 527 NTT, 32

O Obama, Barack, 46, 606, 612, 616, 684, 724, 780, 787, 791, 792 Official deficit, 690 Offshoring, 724–725 Oglala Sioux, and poverty, 447 Oil, 56, 68–69, 373, 595–596, 600, 705–706. see also Fuel crisis, history Okun, Arthur, 454 Oligopoly, 195, 211, 241–256 advertising, 236, 241 attributes of, 258–259 behavior analysis, 242 behavior models, 242–246 game theory, 250–253, 256 games with dominant strategy, 250–252

835

and innovation, 340–349 kinked demand curve, 247–250 Nash equilibrium, 253 public welfare, 257–258 repeated games, 254–256 sales maximization, 246–247 zero-sum game, 253–254 Olympic Games (Los Angeles), 363–364 On-the-job training, 422, 425, 525–526 OPEC (Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries), 243, 244, 374–375, 480, 528, 595, 600 Open economy, 23–24, 763 aggregate supply in, 766 fiscal and monetary policy, 768–770 fiscal expansion, 769 Open-market operations, 649–652 bank reserves market, 649–650 bond prices, 652 contractionary, 669 expansionary, 669–670 interest rates, 652 mechanics of, 650–652 Opportunity cost of capital, 209–210 and comparative advantage, 49 and consumer choice, 92–96 definition, 4–5 of inputs, 137 interest rates, 318–319 money cost, 41–42, 658 nature of, 45 and production possibilities frontier, 44 rent, 409 scarcity and choice, 40–42 subsidized water prices, 147 Optimal decision, 42, 119, 156, 158–164 Optimal output, 167, 301–306 Optimal purchase quantity, 88 Optimal purchase rule, 87–90, 92, 135–136, 509 Optimal tax, 391–392 Optimization, 165–167 Orange County, California, 188, 291 Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC), 243, 244, 374–375, 480, 528, 595, 600 Origin, 14 Other America, The (Harrington), 446–447 Outputs, 30–31, 32, 42, 489 cost, 137–142 distribution of, 50–52 effect of innovation on, 348–349 electronic calculator example, 293 under monopolistic competition, 238 optimal, 167, 301–306 optimal decision, 164 perfect competition, 301–306 production capacity, 492–493 restricted by monopoly, 224–225 selection of, 292, 293, 302 value of, 541 Overproduction, 264 Ozone, 359

P Panama, 758 Paper money. see Money

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

836

Index

Parmalat, 187 Patents, 120, 219, 440 Paulson, Henry, 790, 791 “Pay-as-you-go” system, 382 “Pay-as-you-throw” programs, 362 Payoff matrix, 250 Payroll tax, 381, 390–391 “Peak, off-peak pricing,” 304–305 Pell Grants, 46 Pensions, 34 Per-capita income, 334 Perfect competition, 195, 197–214 attributes of, 258–259 in business firms, 199–204 definition, 198–199 demand curve under, 199–200 efficiency, 211–212, 299–301 government regulation, 33–34, 211 industry, 205–211 industry equilibrium, 205–206 long-run industry supply curve, 210–212 marginal costs, 200 vs. monopoly, 224–225 optimal output, 167, 301–306 short-run equilibrium, 200–201 short-run supply curve, 204, 205 short-term losses, 202 shutdown and break-even analysis, 202–204 zero economic profit, 209–210, 224 Perfectly contestable, 257–258 Perfectly elastic demand curves, 111 Perfectly inelastic demand curves, 112 Perot, Ross, 732 Personal income tax, 379, 380–381, 457, 614 Personal services, cost disease of, 324–330, 530–531 Peru, 522 Philip Morris, 114 Phillips, A.W., 12, 703 Phillips curve, 12, 701 definition, 706–708 and inflation targeting, 677, 709–710 inflationary expectations, 710–712 origins of, 703–704 short-run, 708, 709, 711 supply-side inflation, 598–599, 702–703, 705–706 vertical long-run, 707, 711–712 Physical assets, 539 Physical resources, 40 Pigou, Arthur C., 319, 356 Pigs, and pollution, 359 Pine Ridge, South Dakota, and poverty, 447 Pizza Hut, 242 Plowback, 182–183 Poland, 294, 358 Polaroid, 120 Political business cycles, 677–678 Political stability, 524 Politics budget deficits, 698 business cycles, 677–678 economic policy, 324

Pollution. see also Environmental policy; Pollution charges and allocation of resources, 319, 324 and animals, 359 in centrally planned economies, 358 in China, 358 as detrimental externality, 315 and George W. Bush, 367 history of, 357–360 law of conservation of matter and energy, 361–363 reduction of, 198 role of individuals and governments, 360 and taxation, 212–213 Pollution charges, 356, 364–366 Polo, Marco, 629 Popular Mechanics, 343 Population, and shifts in demand curve, 59 Portfolio, 184–185 Portfolio diversification, 184–185 Positive slope, 15 Post office, 23 Potato famine, 290 Potential GDP, 492–496, 533, 537, 566, 589, 694 Poverty, 446–449 absolute vs. relative, 448–449 and education, 455 measurements of, 447–448 negative income tax, 456–457 Pine Ridge, South Dakota, 447 policies to combat, 454–457 “War on Poverty,” 447–448 welfare debate, 455–456 Poverty line, 447–449 PPF (Production possibilities frontier), 43–44, 45, 311, 522, 731 Practical policy, vs. theory, 11 Predatory pricing, 270 Predictable inflation, 507 Prescott, Edward, 678 Present value, 417–418 Presidential campaigns, and supply-side economics, 616 Price advantage for domestic firms, 734 and aggregate demand curve, 612 consequences of changes, 105–106 cuts, 114 of depletable resources, 369–371 and deregulation, 279–280 discriminatory, 437–438 effect of innovation on, 348–349 of energy, 60, 528–529 of entrepreneurs, 436 equilibrium, 742–743 fixed costs, 168–169 gasoline distribution, 291 and income distribution, 304–305, 398, 445, 449–450, 615–616 increases, 114 increases and public interest, 290–291 infrequency of changes, 236 innovation, effect on, 348–349 of inputs, 63, 136–137 interference, 372–374 international trade, 742–744 long-run, 225

mechanism, 297–299, 303, 306 under monopolistic competition, 238 monopoly power, 264, 412 of natural resources, 372–374 optimal, 167 “peak, off-peak pricing,” 304–305 predatory, 270 price ratios and exchange rates, 730 profit maximizing, 168–169 and quantity, 157–158 and recessionary gap, 591–592 regulation, 273, 275–277, 282 of related outputs, 64 relative, 503–504, 549–550, 765 San Francisco bridges example, 288, 289–290, 306 short-run, 224–225 sticky, 247–249, 347 subsidized, 147 supports during Great Depression, 73 Price caps, 277, 278 Price ceilings, 70–71 Price controls, 56–57, 329, 373–374, 480 Price discrimination, 227–230 Price elasticity of demand, 109, 111–115 Price elasticity of supply, 117 Price fixing, 245 Price floors, 73 Price index, 512–513 Price leadership, 244–246 Price level, 546, 596–597 Price maker, 221 Price system efficiency, 299–301 optimal output, 167, 301–306 resource allocation, 288–291 scarcity and coordinated decisions, 292–299 Smith on, 56, 288, 732 Price taker, 199, 201, 204 Price war, 245–246 Priceline.com, 178 Princess Palatine, 336 Princeton University, 170–171, 427 Principal-agent problem, 321–323 Principals, 321–323 Principle of increasing costs, 44 Priorities, 40 Prism, Miss, 745 Private goods, 317 Private-enterprise economy, 23 Process innovations, 349 Procter & Gamble, 236, 333, 341 Producer‘s surplus, 299–301 Product differentiation, 242 Product innovation, 348–349. see also Innovation Product quality, and deregulation, 280 Production capacity, 492–493 circular flow, 539–541 input choice and cost with one variable, 130–133 measurements of, 554–555 planning, 293–294 underproduction/overproduction, 264 Production function, 492–493 Production indifference curves, 149–152

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Index

Production indifference maps, 19, 149 Production possibilities frontier (PPF), 43–44, 45, 311, 522, 731 Productivity aggregate supply curve, 586 and capital, 519 definition, 334 discrimination, 452 and free markets, 330–331 growth, 8, 490–491, 518–520, 529 of labor, 327, 491, 493–494, 530 labor quality, 520 levels of, 520–522 marginal, 140–141, 398–399, 414–415 rate of, 527–531 slow down (1973–1995), 527–528 specialization, 48, 50, 725, 728, 731–732 speed-up (1995–?), 528–529 technology, 519 Professional athlete salaries, 410, 411 Profits, 174 corporate, 31 deregulation, 281 economic, 158–163, 207, 209–210, 412–414 of entrepreneurs, 436 excessive, 277 as factor of production, 411–414 marginal, 163–165 maximization, 156, 161–167 monopoly, 224, 345–346 monopoly power, 264, 412 in new market economies, 167 public opinion on, 31 returns to innovation, 413–414 risk bearing, 412–413 selling below costs, 157, 169–170 short run, 201–202 taxation of, 414 total, 158, 161–167 Progressive tax, 379 Progressive taxation, 35 Property rights, 524 Property tax, 379, 383–384 Proportional tax, 35, 379 Protectionism infant-industry argument, 736–737 national defense, 34, 735–736 noneconomic considerations, 735–736 for particular industries, 734–735 popularity of, 736 price advantage for domestic firms, 734 Safire on, 738 satire, 739 strategic trade policy, 737 trade deficit, 766, 771–774 Prudhoe Bay, 68–69 Public debt. see National debt Public facilities, user charges, 305 Public goods, 316–318, 348, 437 Public infrastructure, 34 Public interest. see Public welfare Public school financing, 383–384 Public utilities, 220–221 Public welfare, 257–258, 264–265, 290–291, 362 Publilius Syrus, 83

Purchasing power, 476, 501–502 Purchasing power parity theory, 750–752 Pure inflation, 503 Pure monopoly, 195, 218, 258–259 Putin, Vladimir, 305

Q Quantity, and price, 157–158 Quantity demanded, 57–61, 95–96 Quantity supplied, 61–64 Quantity theory of money, 662–665 Quota, 732–737, 743–744 Qwest, 187

R Radioactive pollutants, 358–359 Random walks, 190–192 Ratchet, 348 Rate averaging, 275 Rational expectations, 712–714 Ray through the origin, 17–18 Rays, 17–18 RBC (Risky Bank Corporation), 786 Ready, Jeff, 413 Reagan, Ronald budget deficits, 40 election of, 25, 477 fiscal policy, 612 quotation, 377 Reaganomics, 481 regulation, 34 supply-side economics, 613–617 tax cuts, 691 Real consumer income, 564–565 Real GDP and aggregate demand curve, 584, 612 definition, 23–25, 472 equilibrium, 596–597 and growth, 476 international trade, 765 Real GDP per capita, 476 Real rate of interest, 504–506, 522–523, 546–547 Real wage rate, 501–502 Real wages, 420, 530 Real-world inflation, 503 Rebates, tax, 538, 547–548 Recapitalize, 790 Recession of 1973–1980, 480–481 of 2001, 698 and budget deficits, 698 definition, 24–25, 471, 533 Federal Reserve System, 674 international trade, 764 Keynesian model, 714–715 national debt, 696 transmission of across borders, 574 unemployment, 471, 480, 560 Recessionary gap adjustment to, 591–593 definition, 566–568, 583, 589–591 fiscal policy, 611 and prices, 591–592 Recycling, 362 Redistributive policies, 453

837

Regressive tax, 379 Regulation of banking system, 626, 634–635 definition, 273 deregulation, 279–282 economies of scale, 274 efficiency and innovation incentives, 277–278 government, 33–34, 211 marginal vs. average cost pricing, 276–277 of monopolies, 211, 220–221 objectives of, 274–275 prices, 273, 275–276, 282 of stock market, 186–187 Reich, Robert, 32 Related goods, prices and availability of, 60–61 Related outputs, prices of, 64 Relative poverty, 448–449 Relative prices, 503–504, 549–550, 765 Rent, 405–411 as a component of an input‘s compensation, 409–410 controls, 72–73, 410–411 economic rent, 406, 408–409, 411 land rents, 405–408 opportunity cost, 409 professional athlete salaries, 410–411 Rent seeking, 320 Repeated games, 254–256 Report on Manufacturers (Hamilton), 736 Research and development (R&D), 279, 340–341, 345–346, 349–351, 437, 526–527 Research and Experimentation Tax Credit, 527 Reserve Mining Company, 364 Reserve requirements, 635 Resource allocation as coordination task, 47–49 efficiency, 288–291, 311–312 and excess capacity theorem, 239–240, 257 interest rates, 318–319 misallocation, 75–76, 311 by monopoly, 225 and monopoly power, 264 in practice, 319 between present and future, 318–319 Resources, 40. see also Resource allocation Restricted grants, 384 Retail sector, 28, 236, 240 Retained earnings, 182–183 Returns to a single input, 143–144 Returns to innovation, 413–414 Returns to scale, 142–146 Revaluation (currency), 747, 754 Revenue, average, 159–160, 173–174 Revenue, marginal, 159–160, 165–167, 173–174, 200 Revenue, money, 132–133 Revenue, total, 113–115, 159–160, 202 Ricardo, David, 49, 397, 406, 727–728, 732, 738 Rigas, John, 187 Risk bearing, 412–413 Risk premium, 780, 781

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

838

Index

Risk sharing, 328 Risk taking, 451 Risky Bank Corporation (RBC), 786 Rite Aid, 187 Riverside Freeway, 291 Robinson, Joan, 236–237 Robinson-Patman Act, 266 Rodriguez, Alex, 411 Roodman, David Malin, 355 Roosevelt, Franklin, 755 Royal Caribbean Cruises Ltd., 365 Ruhr River basin, and pollution charges, 364 Rules-versus-discretion debate, 675–679 Run on a bank, 626, 633 Russia, 24, 517, 522, 524, 745, 758

S Safety, and deregulation, 280–281 Safire, William, 263, 738 Sales maximization, 246–247 Sales tax, 379, 619 San Francisco bridges, and price, 288, 289–290, 306 Savings, 398, 541, 547, 567–568, 773 Savings account, 631 Securitization, 786 Scandals, corporate, 188 Scarcity, 39–52 and choice efficiency, 47 for entire society, 45–46 money cost, 41–42, 658 opportunity cost, 40–42 optimal decision, 42 principle of increasing costs, 44 production possibilities frontier, 43–44 real-world examples, 46 for a single firm, 42–44 coordinated decisions, 292–299 and demand, 84–85 depletable resource pricing, 369–371 input-output analysis, 295–297 in monopoly, 219 price mechanism, 297–299, 303, 306 utility, 95 Scatter diagrams, 542–544 Schor, Juliet, 475 Schultze, Charles, 615 Schumpeter, Joseph, 343–344, 436–438 Schumpeter‘s model, 343–344 Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC), 182, 186 Securities firms, 653 Self-correcting mechanism, 592–593, 611, 675–678, 706, 708–710 Self-employment, 29 September 11 terrorist attacks, 392, 474, 610, 676, 760 Service economy, 29, 423–424, 431 Service industry, 28–29 Shakespeare, William, 419 Sharp Corporation, 353 Shaw, George Bernard, 419, 479, 661 Sherman Act, 266, 268 Shift in demand curve, 58–60, 66–67

Short run, 129 Shortage, 65 Short-run profit, graphical representation, 201–202 Short-run supply curve, 204–205 Short-term losses, 202 Shubik, Martin, 177 Shutdown, and break-even analysis, 202–204 Siemens, 532 Sierra Leone, 522 Simon, Herbert, 156 Singapore, 520, 524 Singer, Elias, 420 Sitting Bull, 445 Slope, definition and measurement, 15–17 Slope of a curved line, 16–17 Slope of a straight line, 15 Slope of an indifference curve, 103–106 Slope of the budget line, 103–106 Slow down (1973–1995), 527–528 Slow down (2006–2007), 468 Smith, Adam diamond-water puzzle, 95 on division of labor, 48–49, 50 invisible hand, 257, 292, 309 on monopoly, 217 on perfect competition, 199, 211–212 on price system, 56, 288, 732 University of Glasgow lecture, 84 on voluntary exchange, 726 Social Security System, 34, 381–383, 541, 691 Socialism, 35 Software industry, 222 Solow, Robert M., 3 Sony Corporation, 353 Soto, Hernando de, 524 South Korea, 520, 532, 725, 774 Southeast Asia, 745, 757, 758 Soviet Union, 35, 48, 70, 338, 358, 525 Spain, 725 Specialization, 48, 50, 725, 728, 731–732 Speculation, 189, 193 Speculators, currency, 757 Spending, 30–31, 539–544, 547–549, 613, 697 Spending chain, 571 Spending policy, 611–612 Stabilization policy and aggregate supply curve, 671–673 automatic stabilizers, 609 criticism of, 662, 674 definition, 517 disagreements about, 714–715 effectiveness, 484–485 and full employment, 566 lags in, 667–668, 676 in macroeconomics, 483–485 role of, 600 Stagflation, 480, 583, 584, 594–596, 600 Standard Oil, 267 State and local government expenditures, 34 State and local tax system. see Taxation Statistics, historical, 122–125

Steam engine, 435–436, 440 Steel industry, 69 Stewart, Jimmy, 633 Sticky prices, 247–249, 347 Stock exchanges, 185–189 Stock market 1987 crash, 187 booms and busts, 178, 192 bubble, 192 regulation, 186–187 unpredictability of, 178–179 Stock option, 322–323 Stock options scandals, 321–323 Stock price index, 184 Stocks, 180–185, 190–192 Store of value, 628 Straight-line demand curve, 112 Strategic argument for protection, 737 Strategic interaction, 243 Strategic trade policy, 737 Strategy, 250 Strikes, 433–434 Structural budget deficit, 689–690 Structural budget surplus, 689–690 Structural unemployment, 498 Studying, 134 Subprime mortgage crisis, 633, 635, 763, 781, 784, 785 Subsidies, 212–213, 733 Substitutability, 134–135 Substitutes, 115–118 Substitution effect, 426 Sudan, 532 Sugar industry, 73–74 Sullivan, Scott, 187 Sunk costs, 219–220 Super Bowl stock market predictor, 191 Supply analysis, 127 Supply and demand, 55–76. see also Demand; Demand curve demand schedule, 58, 90 demand shifts and supply-demand equilibrium, 66–67 effect on exchange rates, 747–752 equilibrium, 64–70 farm price supports, 73–74 gasoline tax analysis, 69–70 international trade, 742–744 invisible hand. see Invisible hand and labor. see Labor law of, 5, 66 in macroeconomics, 469–471 price ceilings, 70–71 price elasticity, 117 price floors, 73 quantity demanded, 57–61, 95–96 quantity supplied, 61–64 rent controls, 72–73, 410–411 supply schedule, 61–62 supply shifts and supply-demand equilibrium, 67–70 Supply curve, 61–64, 124, 204–205, 210–212 Supply curve of a firm, 204 Supply curve of an industry, 205 Supply curve of the perfectly competitive firm, 204

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Index

Supply curve of the perfectly competitive industry, 205–206 Supply decision, monopoly firm, 221–226 Supply schedule, 61–62 Supply shock, 595–596, 600, 705–706 Supply-demand analysis, 69–70, 369–371 Supply-demand diagrams, 64–66 Supply-demand equilibrium, 64–70 Supply-side economics, 613–617 Supply-side fluctuations, 598–599 Supply-side inflation, 598–599, 702–703, 705–706 Supply-side tax cuts, 613–617 Supreme Court, 268, 459 Surplus, 65, 73 SUVs, 386–389 Swartz, Mark, 187 Swaziland, 524 Sweden, 26, 35, 434, 450, 524, 747 Swiss Alps, and global warming, 360 Switzerland, 35, 747 Sysco, 204

T Tacit collusion, 244–246, 253–254 Taiwan, 520, 725 Takeover, 188 TANF (Temporary Assistance to Needy Families), 455 Tangency, point of, 151 Tangency conditions, 104 Tangent, 16, 239 Tanner, Bill, 69 Tariff, 732–737, 743–744 TARP (Troubled Assets Relief Program), 790, 791 Tax deductions, 380–381 Tax exempt, 380 Tax incidence, 387–391 Tax loopholes, 380, 386–387 Tax Reform Act of 1986, 387 Tax shifting, 389 Taxation, 377–392 antitax sentiment, 377 average tax rate, 379 benefits principle of taxation, 385 burden of, 386 and capital formation, 522–524 on cigarettes, 108, 114–115 and consumption schedule, 606–607, 619 corporate income tax, 380–381, 614 criticism of, 506 cuts, 378, 392, 446, 482–483, 538, 606, 610, 612, 676–677, 685, 689, 691, 697 cuts and consumer spending, 547–548 death duties, 457–458 direct, 379 “double taxation,” 180 efficiency in, 385–387, 391–392 to encourage savings, 547 equity in, 384–385 excise tax, 381, 383, 389–390 federal tax system, 379–383 fiscal federalism, 384 fiscal policy, 619–623

fixed taxes, 619–620 gasoline, 69–70 and GDP, 378–379 and government size, 612, 676–677 head tax, 379 homeowner benefits, 380–381 incidence of a tax, 387–391 on income, 379, 380–381, 457, 572, 606–609, 614, 619 indirect, 379 levels and types of, 378–379 loopholes and excess burden, 380, 386–387 marginal tax rates, 379, 392 and the multiplier, 607–610, 621 negative income tax, 456–457, 610 net taxes, 541 optimal tax, 391–392 payroll tax, 381, 390–391 and pollution, 212–213 on profits, 414 progressive, 35, 379 property tax, 379, 383–384 proportional, 35, 379 rebates, 538, 547–548 regressive, 379 sales and excise tax, 379, 381, 383, 389–390, 619 sales tax, 379, 619 share of under George W. Bush, 35 Social Security System, 381–383 vs. spending policy, 611–612 state and local tax system, 383–384 supply-and-demand analysis, 69–70, 369–371 and supply-side cuts, 613–617 variable, 619–620 in various nations, 35, 684–685 Taylor, John, 677 “Taylor rule,” 677 TC (Total costs), 137–138, 161, 202 Teamsters, 280, 433 Technical superiority, and monopoly, 220 Technological progress, and shifts in supply curve, 63 Technology and aggregate supply curve, 586 in Asia, 532 and capital formation, 523, 526 in developing countries, 532 dissemination of, 351–353 and economies of scale. see Economies of scale and education, 526 growth policy, 526–527 and production capacity, 492–493 and productivity growth, 519 spurring change, 526–527 Technology trading, 351 Teenagers, 27–28, 108, 114–115, 429–430, 497 Telephone service, 128, 218, 230–231, 275 Temporary Assistance to Needy Families (TANF), 455 Tennessee Valley Authority, 23 Terrorism, 482. see also September 11 terrorist attacks Terry, Letha, 432

839

Texas Rangers, 411 TFC (Total fixed costs), 139 Thailand, 774 Thames River, 357 TheGroceryGame.com, 204 Theory, 11–12 Third World. see Developing countries Time, market value of, 42 Time inconsistency, 678 Time magazine, 432 Time period, and demand elasticity, 118–120 Tin, 356 Total cost curves, 137–139 Total costs (TC), 137–138, 161, 202 Total expenditure, effect of price elasticity of demand, 113–115 Total fixed costs (TFC), 139 Total monetary utility, 86 Total physical products (TPP), 130–131 Total profit, 158, 161–167 Total profit curve, 163, 164 Total revenue (TR), 113–115, 159–160, 202 Total utility, 86 Total variable cost (TVC), 202 Toyota, 31, 241, 532 TPP (Total physical products), 130–131 TR (Total revenue), 113–115, 159–160, 202 Trade. see International trade. see Intranational trade Trade, as win-win situation, 5–6 Trade adjustment assistance, 735 Trade deficit, 766, 771–774. see also International trade Trade protection. see Protectionism Trade war, 732, 734 Transactions, limitation on volume, 75 Transfer in kind, 456 Transfer payments, 35, 541, 609–610, 716 Treasury, 790 Treasury bills, 649–650 Treaty of Maastricht, 759 Triangle Shirtwaist Factory fire, 432 “Trickle-down economics.” see Supplyside economics Troubled Assets Relief Program (TARP), 790, 791 Trotsky, Leon, 287, 288 Tru-Blu Cooperative, 204 Tucker, Sophie, 494 Tuition, 518, 530–531 Tullock, Gordon, 409 Tundra travel season, 361 Turkey, 745, 758 TVC (Total variable cost), 202 Two-variable diagrams, 14–15 Tyco, 187

U Ukraine, 522 Unlevered bank, 783 Underproduction, 264 Unemployment African Americans, 497 and aggregate demand, 483–484 among teenagers, 497 as automatic stabilizer, 609

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

840

Index

benefits, 381 combating, 483–484 compensation, 34 computation of, 497–498 as coordination failure, 569 costs of, 495, 709 cyclical, 498, 591 economic goal to keep low, 495–500 and efficiency, 47 fighting with fiscal and monetary policy, 483–484, 708 fiscal policy, 483–484, 708 frictional, 498 full employment, 499, 566–567, 613 during Great Depression, 25–26, 496–497 and growth policy, 490 human costs of, 496–497 and inflation, 7–8, 583, 708 inflation trade-off, 701–717 and the market, 560 and minimum wage, 499 monetary policy, 708 natural rate of, 707, 715–716 and recession, 471, 480, 560 and recessionary gap, 591–593 structural, 498 types of, 498 in various nations, 26, 497 Unemployment insurance, 497, 499–500, 541 Unemployment rate, 25–26, 495 Unenforceability, 75 Unexpected inflation, 504–505 Unions. see Labor union Unit elasticity, 112–113 Unit of account, 628 United Auto Workers (UAW), 433, 585 United Kingdom currency, 747 educational attainment in, 532 GDP of, 22 inflation targeting, 677 investor protection, 524 labor costs, 725 labor strikes, 434 market economy of, 167 openness of economy, 24 peak, off-peak pricing, 304–305 Phillips curve, 703–704 productivity, 490–491 taxes in, 35 unemployment rates, 26 wages, 725 United States. see also specific topics Canada, trade with, 729 China, trade with, 730 Japan, trade with, 549–550, 727–729, 730–731, 772 labor strikes, 434 Mexico, trade with, 730 openness of economy, 24 share of GDP, 22 taxes in. see Taxation trade deficit, 772 unemployment rates, 25–26, 495

Unit-elastic demand curve, 112–113 Universal service, 275 University of Glasgow, 84 University of Pittsburgh Medical Center (UPMC), 272 Unpredictable inflation, 507 Uruguay Round (tariff reductions), 732 U.S. dollar, 746, 758–759, 760, 764, 775 U.S. economy, 21–36 aggregate supply-demand model, 471, 596–600, 613–614 bank failures, 627 budget deficits, 40, 46 closed economy, 23–24, 768–769 federal budget, 691 fluctuations. see Fluctuations, economic government intervention, 673–675 growth of. see Growth inflationary gap, 594–595 inputs. see Inputs overview, 22–25 private-enterprise economy, 23 stagflation, 480, 583, 584, 594–595, 600 U.S. Postal Service, 219, 275 U.S. Steel Corp., 69, 245, 267 User charges for public facilities, 305 Usury laws, 404–405 Utilities, public, 220–221 Utility, marginal, 86–92, 95, 302 Utility analysis, 85–92 diminishing marginal utility, 86–87 downward-sloping demand curves, 90–92 optimal purchase rule, 35–36, 87–90, 92, 509 purpose of, 85–86 and scarcity, 95 total vs. marginal utility, 86 water vs. diamonds, 84, 95

V Valley Forge, 57 Value added, 555–556 Value-added tax (VAT), 379 Variable costs, 129–130, 138, 202 Variable taxes, 619–620 Variables, 14–15 Velocity, 662–667 Vertical equity, 384–385 Vertical long-run Phillips curve, 707, 711–712 Vietnam War, 480 Vital services, increasing costs of, 324–329 Volatility, 60 Volcker, Paul, 481, 671 Voluntarism, as environmental policy, 363–364 Voluntary exchange, 726 Von Neumann, John, 250

W Wage premium, for college graduates, 525 Wages, 29–30 construction wages in New Orleans, 429 and deregulation, 281

determination in competitive markets, 421–424 differences in, 428–430, 450–452 discrimination, 462 equilibrium, 428 in Europe, 30 inflationary expectations, 710–712 minimum, 499 nominal, 502, 585–586, 591–592 rate of change, 703 real wage rate, 501–502 real wages, 420, 530 in various nations, 724–725 Wal-Mart, 28, 179 “War on Poverty,” 447–448 Washington, George, 57 Waste disposal, 362 Water, subsidized prices for, 147 Watson, Thomas J., 343 Watt, James, 420, 435–436 Wealth, 452, 504, 546, 564–565 Wealth of Nations, The (Smith), 48 Welfare debate, 455–456 West Penn Allegheny Health Systems, Inc., 272 Whitney, Eli, 420 Wilde, Oscar, 359, 745 Wilhelmina, 336 Women, 27, 170–171, 424–425, 463 Work incentives, and negative income tax, 457 Work slowdowns, 434 Workers, 428, 498 Workforce, American, 27–30, 520, 528 Working conditions, 432 Working population. see Workforce, American Workweek, length of, 475 World Bank, 517, 524, 531 World Trade Organization (WTO), 733, 734 World War II economic fluctuations, 25–26, 479–480 financing of, 696 and labor, 420 production capacity during, 492 and taxation, 378, 380 WorldCom, 187 Wright brothers, 420 WTO (World Trade Organization), 733, 734

X Xerox, 187 X-intercept, 17

Y Y-intercept, 17

Z Zacharakis, Andrew, 413 Zambia, 71 Zero economic profit, 209–210, 224 Zero slope, 15 Zero-sum game, 253–254 Zimbabwe, 508

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Table of Contents PART I: GETTING ACQUAINTED WITH ECONOMICS 1. What is Economics? 2. The Economy: Myth and Reality 3. The Fundamental Economic Problem: Scarcity and Choice 4. Supply and Demand: An Initial Look PART II: THE BUILDING BLOCKS OF DEMAND AND SUPPLY 5. Consumer Choice: Individual and Market Demand 6. Demand and Elasticity 7. Production, Inputs, and Cost: Building Blocks for Supply Analysis 8. Output, Price, and Profit: The Importance of Marginal Analysis 9. The Economics of the Stock Market PART III: MARKETS AND THE PRICE SYSTEM 10. The Firm and the Industry Under Perfect Competition 11. Monopoly 12. Between Competition and Monopoly 13. Limiting Market Power: Regulation and Antitrust

PART VII: FISCAL AND MONETARY POLICY 28. Managing Aggregate Demand: Fiscal Policy 29. Money and the Banking System 30. Managing Aggregate Demand: Monetary Policy 31. The Debate Over Monetary and Fiscal Policy 32. Fiscal Policy, Monetary Policy, and Growth 33. The Trade-off Between Inflation and Unemployment PART VIII: THE UNITED STATES IN THE WORLD ECONOMY 34. International Trade and Comparative Advantage 35. The International Monetary System: Order or Disorder? 36. Exchange Rates and the Macroeconomy PART IX: POSTSCRIPT: THE FINANCIAL CRISIS OF 2007-2009 37. The Financial Crisis and the Great Recession

Ideas for Beyond the Final Exam . . .

PART IV: THE VIRTUES AND LIMITATIONS OF MARKETS 14. The Case for Free Markets I: The Price System 15. The Shortcomings of Free Markets 16. The Market’s Prime Achievement: Innovation and Growth 17. Externalities, the Environment and Natural Resources 18. Taxation and Resource Allocation PART V: THE DISTRIBUTION OF INCOME 19. Pricing the Factors of Production 20. Labor and Entrepreneurship: The Human Inputs 21. Poverty, Inequality, and Discrimination PART VI: THE MACROECONOMY: AGGREGATE SUPPLY AND DEMAND 22. An Introduction to Macroeconomics 23. The Goals of Macroeconomic Policy 24. Economic Growth: Theory and Policy 25. Aggregate Demand and the Powerful Consumer 26. Demand-Side Equilibrium: Unemployment or Inflation? 27. Bringing in the Supply Side: Unemployment and Inflation?

1: 2: 3: 4: 5: 6: 7: 8: 9: 10:

How Much Does it Really Cost? Attempts to Repeal the Laws of Supply and Demand — The Market Strikes Back The Surprising Principle of Comparative Advantage Trade is a Win-Win Situation The Importance of Thinking at the Margin Externalities — A Shortcoming of the Market Cured by Market Methods The Trade-Off Between Efficiency and Equality Government Policies Can Limit Economic Fluctuations — But Don’t Always Succeed The Short-Run Trade-Off Between Inflation and Unemployment Productivity Growth is (Almost) Everything in the Long Run

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.

Selected U.S. Macroeconomic Data, 1929-2009

Year

(1)

(2)

(3)

Gross Domestic Product

Personal Consumption Expenditure

(4)

Gross Private Domestic Government Investment Purchases

(5)

(6)

Net Exports

Gross Domestic Product

(7)

(8)

Gross Personal Private Consumption Domestic Expenditure Investment

(9)

Government Purchases

(10)

Net Exports

Real GDP per capita (In chained 2000 dollars)

(in billions of chained 2000 dollars)a

(in billions of dollars)

(11)

(12)

(13)

Price Level Chained Consumer GDP Price Price Index Index (2000 = 100) (1982-1984 = 100)

(14)

Real Average Hourly Earnings (1982 dollars)

(15)

(16)

Labor Population Forceb (millions)

(17)

Civilian Unemployment Rate (percent)

(18)

(19)

Money Supply M1 M2 (in December) (billions of dollars)

(20)

(21)

Interest Rates Treasury Corp. Bills Bondsc (percent)

(22)

(23)

Exchange Value of U.S. Dollard (January 1997 = 100)

Federal Budget Surplus (+) or Deficit (–)e (billions of dollars)

1929

103.6

77.4

16.5

9.4

0.4

977.0

736.6

101.7

146.5

–9.4

8,016

10.6

17.1

——

121.9

49.2

3.2

——

——

——

4.73

——

2.6

1933 1939

56.4 92.2

45.9 67.2

1.7 9.3

8.7 14.8

0.1 0.8

716.4 1072.8

601.1 811.1

18.9 86.2

157.2 238.6

–10.2 –4.7

5,700 8,188

7.9 8.6

13.0 13.9

—— ——

125.7 131.0

51.6 55.2

24.9 17.2

—— ——

—— ——

—— ——

4.49 3.01

—— ——

-0.5 -0.1

1945

223.0

120.0

10.8

93.0

-0.8

2012.4

1001.4

74.7

1402.2

–26.8

14,382

11.1

18.0

——

139.9

53.9

1.9

——

——

——

2.62

——

-27.3

1950 1955

293.7 414.7

192.2 258.8

54.1 69.0

46.7 86.4

0.7 0.5

2006.0 2500.3

1283.3 1544.5

253.2 285.0

492.4 779.3

–9.0 –14.3

13,225 15,128

14.6 16.6

24.1 26.8

—— ——

151.7 165.3

62.2 65.0

5.3 4.4

—— ——

—— ——

—— 1.72

2.62 3.06

—— ——

6.9 9.2

1960 1965

526.4 719.1

331.8 443.8

78.9 118.2

111.5 151.4

4.2 5.6

2830.9 3610.1

1784.4 2241.8

296.5 437.3

871.0 1048.7

–12.7 –18.9

15,661 18,576

18.6 19.9

29.6 31.5

—— 8.04

180.8 194.3

69.6 74.5

5.5 4.5

140.7 167.8

312.4 459.2

2.87 3.95

4.41 4.49

—— ——

11.4 9.8

1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979

1038.3 1126.8 1237.9 1382.3 1499.5 1637.7 1824.6 2030.1 2293.8 2562.2

648.3 701.6 770.2 852.0 932.9 1033.8 1151.3 1277.8 1427.6 1591.2

152.4 178.2 207.6 244.5 249.4 230.2 292.0 361.3 438.0 492.9

233.7 246.4 263.4 281.7 317.9 357.7 383.0 414.1 453.6 500.7

4.0 0.6 -3.4 4.1 -0.8 16.0 -1.6 -23.1 -25.4 -22.5

4269.9 4413.3 4647.7 4917.0 4889.9 4879.5 5141.3 5377.7 5677.6 5855.0

2740.2 2844.6 3019.5 3169.1 3142.8 3214.1 3393.1 3535.9 3691.8 3779.5

475.1 529.3 591.9 661.3 612.6 504.1 605.9 697.4 781.5 806.4

1233.7 1206.9 1198.1 1193.9 1224.0 1251.6 1257.2 1271.0 1308.4 1332.8

–52.0 –60.6 –73.5 –51.9 –29.4 –2.4 –37.0 –61.1 –61.9 –41.0

20,820 21,249 22,140 23,200 22,861 22,592 23,575 24,412 25,503 26,010

24.3 25.5 26.6 28.1 30.7 33.6 35.5 37.8 40.4 43.8

38.8 40.5 41.8 44.4 49.3 53.8 56.9 60.6 65.2 72.6

8.46 8.64 8.99 8.98 8.65 8.48 8.58 8.66 8.69 8.41

205.1 207.7 209.9 211.9 213.9 216.0 218.1 220.3 222.6 225.1

82.8 84.4 87.0 89.4 91.9 93.8 96.2 99.0 102.3 105.0

4.9 5.9 5.6 4.9 5.6 8.5 7.7 7.1 6.1 5.8

214.4 228.3 249.2 262.9 274.2 287.1 306.2 330.9 357.3 381.8

626.5 710.3 802.3 855.5 902.1 1016.2 1152.0 1270.3 1366.0 1473.7

6.39 4.33 4.06 7.04 7.85 5.79 4.98 5.26 7.18 10.05

8.04 7.39 7.21 7.44 8.57 8.83 8.43 8.02 8.73 9.63

—— —— —— 31.7 32.6 33.7 35.8 36.9 35.1 35.4

-8.4 -22.2 -9.3 3.9 -5.2 -68.2 -46.3 -33.0 -10.2 -1.0

1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989

2788.1 3126.8 3253.2 3534.6 3930.9 4217.5 4460.1 4736.4 5100.4 5482.1

1755.8 1939.5 2075.5 2288.6 2501.1 2717.6 2896.7 3097.0 3350.1 3594.5

479.3 572.4 517.2 564.3 735.6 736.2 746.5 785.0 821.6 874.9

566.1 627.5 680.4 733.4 796.9 878.9 949.3 999.4 1038.9 1100.6

-13.1 -12.5 -20.0 -51.7 -102.7 -115.2 -132.5 -145.0 -110.1 -87.9

5839.0 5987.2 5870.9 6136.2 6577.1 6849.3 7086.5 7313.3 7613.9 7885.9

3766.2 3823.3 3876.7 4098.3 4315.6 4540.4 4724.5 4870.3 5066.6 5209.9

717.9 782.4 672.8 735.5 952.1 943.3 936.9 965.7 988.5 1028.1

1358.8 1371.2 1395.3 1446.3 1494.9 1599.0 1696.2 1737.1 1758.9 1806.8

12.6 8.3 –12.6 –60.2 –122.4 –141.5 –156.3 –148.4 –106.8 –79.2

25,640 26,030 25,282 26,186 27,823 28,717 29,443 30,115 31,069 31,877

47.8 52.3 55.5 57.7 59.8 61.6 63.0 64.8 67.0 69.5

82.4 90.9 96.5 99.6 103.9 107.6 109.6 113.6 118.3 124.0

8.00 7.89 7.87 7.96 7.96 7.92 7.97 7.87 7.82 7.75

227.7 230.0 232.2 234.3 236.4 238.5 240.7 242.8 245.1 247.4

106.9 108.7 110.2 111.6 113.5 115.5 117.8 119.9 121.7 123.9

7.1 7.6 9.7 9.6 7.5 7.2 7.0 6.2 5.5 5.3

408.5 436.7 474.8 521.4 551.6 619.8 724.7 750.2 786.7 792.9

1599.8 1755.5 1909.3 2125.7 2308.8 2494.6 2731.4 2830.8 2993.9 3158.4

11.39 14.04 10.60 8.62 9.54 7.47 5.97 5.78 6.67 8.11

11.94 14.17 13.79 12.04 12.71 11.37 9.02 9.38 9.71 9.26

36.4 40.3 46.8 52.8 60.1 67.2 62.4 60.4 60.9 66.9

-47.8 -49.2 -137.5 -171.4 -147.5 -156.3 -173.9 -137.4 -121.2 -113.8

1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999

5800.5 5992.1 6342.3 6667.4 7085.2 7414.7 7838.5 8332.4 8793.5 9353.5

3835.5 3980.1 4236.9 4483.6 4750.8 4987.3 5273.6 5570.6 5918.5 6342.8

861.0 802.9 864.8 953.3 1097.3 1144.0 1240.2 1388.7 1510.8 1641.5

1181.7 1236.1 1273.5 1294.8 1329.8 1374.0 1421.0 1474.4 1526.1 1631.3

-77.6 -27.0 -32.8 -64.4 -92.7 -90.7 -96.3 -101.4 -161.8 -262.1

8033.9 8015.1 8287.1 8523.4 8870.7 9093.7 9433.9 9854.3 10283.5 10779.8

5316.2 5324.2 5505.7 5701.2 5918.9 6079.0 6291.2 6523.4 6865.5 7240.9

993.5 912.7 986.7 1074.8 1220.9 1258.9 1370.3 1540.8 1695.1 1844.3

1864.0 1884.4 1893.2 1878.2 1878.0 1888.9 1907.9 1943.8 1985.0 2056.1

–54.7 –14.6 –15.9 –52.1 –79.4 -98.8 -110.7 -139.8 -252.6 -356.6

32,112 31,614 32,255 32,747 33,671 34,112 34,977 36,102 37,238 38,592

72.2 74.8 76.5 78.2 79.9 81.5 83.1 84.6 85.5 86.8

130.7 136.2 140.3 144.5 148.2 152.4 156.9 160.5 163.0 166.6

7.66 7.59 7.55 7.54 7.54 7.54 7.57 7.69 7.89 8.01

250.2 253.5 256.9 260.3 263.5 266.6 269.7 273.0 276.2 279.3

125.8 126.3 128.1 129.2 131.1 132.3 133.9 136.3 137.7 139.4

5.6 6.8 7.5 6.9 6.1 5.6 5.4 4.9 4.5 4.2

824.7 897.0 1024.9 1129.6 1150.7 1127.4 1081.6 1072.7 1095.8 1122.6

3276.8 3377.0 3430.3 3480.9 3496.7 3640.7 3820.1 4033.3 4377.3 4635.0

7.50 5.38 3.43 3.00 4.25 5.49 5.01 5.06 4.78 4.64

9.32 8.77 8.14 7.22 7.97 7.59 7.37 7.27 6.53 7.05

71.4 74.4 76.9 83.8 90.9 92.7 97.5 104.4 115.9 116.0

-170.3 -224.2 -303.9 -281.2 -212.2 -197.0 -125.3 -23.8 80.5 140.6

2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009

9951.5 10286.2 10642.3 11142.1 11867.8 12638.4 13398.9 14077.6 14441.4 14256.0

6830.4 7148.8 7439.2 7804.0 8285.1 8819.0 9322.7 9826.4 10129.9 10089.0

1772.2 1661.9 1647.0 1729.7 1968.6 2172.2 2327.2 2288.5 2136.1 1628.8

1731.0 1846.4 1983.3 2112.6 2232.8 2369.9 2518.4 2676.5 2883.2 2930.7

-382.1 -371.0 -427.2 -504.1 -618.7 -722.7 -769.3 -713.8 -707.8 -392.4

11226.0 11347.2 11553.0 11840.7 12263.8 12638.4 12976.2 13254.1 13312.2 12987.4

7608.1 7813.9 8021.9 8247.6 8532.7 8819.0 9073.5 9313.9 9290.9 9235.1

1970.3 1831.9 1807.0 1871.6 2058.2 2172.2 2230.4 2146.2 1989.4 1541.5

2097.8 2178.3 2279.6 2330.5 2362.0 2369.9 2402.1 2443.1 2518.1 2564.6

-451.6 -472.1 -548.8 -603.9 -688.0 -722.7 -729.2 -647.7 -494.3 -355.6

39,750 39,774 40,107 40,728 41,806 42,692 43,425 43,926 43,714 42,238

88.6 90.7 92.1 94.1 96.8 100.0 103.3 106.2 108.5 109.7

172.2 177.1 179.9 184.0 188.9 195.3 201.6 207.3 215.3 214.5

8.04 8.12 8.25 8.28 8.24 8.18 8.24 8.33 8.30 8.60

282.4 285.3 288.1 290.7 293.3 296.0 298.8 301.7 304.5 307.5

142.6 143.7 144.9 146.5 147.4 149.3 151.4 153.1 154.3 154.1

4.0 4.7 5.8 6.0 5.5 5.1 4.6 4.6 5.8 9.3

1087.7 1182.3 1220.4 1306.8 1376.4 1374.2 1365.6 1373.0 1595.2 1693.4

4917.2 5431.2 5784.7 6071.6 6412.2 6674.1 7085.3 7438.8 8155.9 8524.5

5.82 3.40 1.61 1.01 1.37 3.15 4.73 4.36 1.37 0.16

7.62 7.08 6.49 5.66 5.63 5.23 5.59 5.56 5.63 5.31

119.5 125.9 126.7 119.1 113.6 110.7 108.5 103.4 99.8 105.9

226.5 24.6 -306.9 -415.2 -387.8 -257.1 -152.7 -214.8 -682.7 -1224.7

a Components do not add up to GDP due to chain method of deflation. b Persons 14 years and older for 1920-1945; thereafter, persons 16 years and older.

c Moody’s Aaa rating. d Trade-weighted average of broad group of U.S. trading partners. e National income and product accounts basis; calendar years.

Copyright 2011 Cengage Learning, Inc. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part.